
This paper argues that any economic phenomena should be observed by two different scales, and any economic laws are scale-dependent. A one-scale law arising in either macroeconomics or microeconomics might be mathematically correct and economically relevant, however, sparking debates might arise for a different scale. This paper re-analyzes the basic assumptions of the Evans model for dynamic economics, and it concludes that they are quite reasonable on a large time-scale, but the assumptions become totally invalid on a smaller scale, and a fractal modification has to be adopted. A two-scale price dynamics is suggested and a fractal variational theory is established to maximize the profit at a given period. Furthermore Evans 1924 variational principle for the maximal profit is easy to be solved for a quadratic cost function using the Lagrange multiplier method. Here a quadratic-cubic cost function and a nonlinear demand function are used, and the stationary condition of the variational formulation is derived step by step, and a more complex dynamic system is obtained. The present derivation process can be extended to a more complex cost function and a more complex demand function, and the paper sheds a promising light on mathematics treatment of complex economic problems.
Citation: Ji-Huan He, Chun-Hui He, Hamid M. Sedighi. Evans model for dynamic economics revised[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(9): 9194-9206. doi: 10.3934/math.2021534
[1] | Abdon Atangana, Ali Akgül . Analysis of a derivative with two variable orders. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(5): 7274-7293. doi: 10.3934/math.2022406 |
[2] | Nadiyah Hussain Alharthi, Abdon Atangana, Badr S. Alkahtani . Numerical analysis of some partial differential equations with fractal-fractional derivative. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(1): 2240-2256. doi: 10.3934/math.2023116 |
[3] | Asifa Tassaddiq, Muhammad Tanveer, Muhammad Arshad, Rabab Alharbi, and Ruhaila Md Kasmani . Fractal generation and analysis using modified fixed-point iteration. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(4): 9462-9492. doi: 10.3934/math.2025437 |
[4] | Ihtisham Ul Haq, Shabir Ahmad, Sayed Saifullah, Kamsing Nonlaopon, Ali Akgül . Analysis of fractal fractional Lorenz type and financial chaotic systems with exponential decay kernels. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(10): 18809-18823. doi: 10.3934/math.20221035 |
[5] | Emile Franc Doungmo Goufo, Abdon Atangana . On three dimensional fractal dynamics with fractional inputs and applications. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(2): 1982-2000. doi: 10.3934/math.2022114 |
[6] | Chatthai Thaiprayoon, Jutarat Kongson, Weerawat Sudsutad . Dynamics of a fractal-fractional mathematical model for the management of waste plastic in the ocean with four different numerical approaches. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(4): 8827-8872. doi: 10.3934/math.2025405 |
[7] | Martin Do Pham . Fractal approximation of chaos game representations using recurrent iterated function systems. AIMS Mathematics, 2019, 5(6): 1824-1840. doi: 10.3934/math.2019.6.1824 |
[8] | Xuezai Pan, Minggang Wang . The uniformly continuous theorem of fractal interpolation surface function and its proof. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(5): 10858-10868. doi: 10.3934/math.2024529 |
[9] | Arunachalam Murali, Krishnan Muthunagai . Generation of Julia and Mandelbrot fractals for a generalized rational type mapping via viscosity approximation type iterative method extended with $ s $-convexity. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(8): 20221-20244. doi: 10.3934/math.2024985 |
[10] | Mohammad Sajid, Lucas Wangwe, Hemanta Kalita, Santosh Kumar . Fixed point theorem on $ CAT_{p}(0) $ metric spaces with applications in solving matrix equations and fractional differential equations. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(5): 11131-11158. doi: 10.3934/math.2025505 |
This paper argues that any economic phenomena should be observed by two different scales, and any economic laws are scale-dependent. A one-scale law arising in either macroeconomics or microeconomics might be mathematically correct and economically relevant, however, sparking debates might arise for a different scale. This paper re-analyzes the basic assumptions of the Evans model for dynamic economics, and it concludes that they are quite reasonable on a large time-scale, but the assumptions become totally invalid on a smaller scale, and a fractal modification has to be adopted. A two-scale price dynamics is suggested and a fractal variational theory is established to maximize the profit at a given period. Furthermore Evans 1924 variational principle for the maximal profit is easy to be solved for a quadratic cost function using the Lagrange multiplier method. Here a quadratic-cubic cost function and a nonlinear demand function are used, and the stationary condition of the variational formulation is derived step by step, and a more complex dynamic system is obtained. The present derivation process can be extended to a more complex cost function and a more complex demand function, and the paper sheds a promising light on mathematics treatment of complex economic problems.
In 1924, Evans [1] suggested a dynamical model for monopoly, and the economic dynamics was then born [2,3,4,5]. Evans was a mathematician, his PhD thesis was on Volterra's integral equations, which are now widely applied to various engineering problems [6], and he had a chance to work with the famous Italian mathematician, Vito Volterra (May 5, 1860~October 11, 1940), from 1910 to 1912. In 1920, Evans turned his interest to economics [3], and his theory shed a promising and challenging light in dynamic economics. Paul A. Samuelson (May 15, 1915~December 13, 2009) [7,8,9,10], a famous American economist, further developed Evans theory, and obtained the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences in 1970 due to his contribution to the dynamic economics.
Evans [1] took for granted the following quadratic cost function
C=a0+a1Q+a2Q2, | (1) |
and a well-defined market demand function,
Q=b0−b1P(t)+b2dPdt, | (2) |
where C is the cost function, Q is the demand function, P is the price, ai(i = 0, 1, 2) and bi(i = 0, 1, 2) are constants.
The profit is then obtained as
L=R−C=PQ−C=PQ−a0−a1Q−a2Q2−a3Q3. | (3) |
Here R = PQ is the gross income function. The Evans model is to maximize the profit at a period of T [1]:
J(P)=∫T0(PQ−C)dt=∫T0(PQ−a0−a1Q−a2Q2)dt→max. | (4) |
The Evans model is to choose an optimal path among all admissible paths from an initial time to a terminal time. A detailed introduction to mathematical economics is available in [11,12], where complex economic problems are explained using simple mathematical concepts.
In Eq (2), the demand function depends upon the price dynamics by assuming that the price changes smoothly, however, the price change is discontinuous and a fractal modification is needed [13]. Fractal models can describe many discontinuous problems using a two-scale fractal derivative [14,15,16].
The initial concept for the two-scale economic theory was suggested in 2020 [17], which was to bridge the macro-economics and the micro-economics using two different scales. The two-scale theory argues that any economic phenomena should be described by the two different scales so that a more reasonable decision can be made than those by a single scale.
Beginning with the two-scale dynamic model, we introduce first a famous Chinese economist, Ma Yin-Chu (June 24, 1882~May 10, 1982), his population theory led to China's family planning in a period from 1980 to 2016, that was a couple had only one child. The family planning became a basic state policy in China for many years. Ma concluded that China's population grew exponentially, and there would be a serious population explosion if no family planning was carried out. Ma's population model can be written as
dxdt=kx,Q(0)=Q0, | (5) |
where x is the population, k is the population growth ratio, x0 is the initial population. Eq (5) leads to the following result
x=x0ekt. | (6) |
Ma's assumption is correct for a large scale, but when the measured scale becomes smaller, the population grows in a zig-zag form, so the population is not a smooth function of time, x(t), actually it is non-differentiable with respect to time, the change path is similar to a coastline, which can be modelled by the fractal theory [18,19]. When a man walks along the coastline, its motion property depends on the fractal dimension of the coastline and the man's step length. Any discontinuity within the step length is ignored. We assume that the step length is Δx, if there is a groove with a width less than Δx, then the groove is ignored. However, when the groove's width is larger than Δx, the man has to walk along the groove's boundary to the opposite point. Similar to the coastline motion, the price can be expressed as [20]
P=P(tα,Δt), | (7) |
where α is the two-scale fractal dimension of time [20], Δt is the minimal time scale to measure the price change.
As an illustrative example, we consider the change of a share price within one year. If we measure the change using a scale of one year, we can assume that the price changes linearly and smoothly. If we observe its change using a scale of a quarter, it is mixed, and has a simple zig-zag path. If the scale reduces further, the price change becomes totally non-differentiable. So the prediction of the share price depends upon the measured scale and the path's fractal dimension.
When the measure scale is fixed, the price can be expressed as
P=P(tα). | (8) |
A modification of Eq (6) can be written as
x=x0exp(ktα). | (9) |
It is obvious that the fractal dimension affects greatly the population as illustrated in Figure 1.
Considering the price is non-differential with t, but it is differential with respect to tα for given time scale, so Eq (2) can be modified as
Q=b0−b1P(t)+b2dPdtα, | (10) |
where the fractal derivative is defined as [20]
dPdtα=Γ(1+α)limt−t0→ΔtP(t)−P(t0)(t−t0)α,0<α<2. | (11) |
The gamma function is defined as Γ(1+α)=∫∞0tαe−tdt, whenαis a natural number, Γ(1+α)=1×2×3×⋯×α=α!. The fractal derivative is now widely used to model various discontinuous problems [21,22,23,24,25,26,27,28,29].
In order to maximize the profit, the fractal variational theory [30] has to be used. Now fractal variational principle is a hot topic in mathematics and engineering [31,32,33,34]. The fractal variational principle for the maximal profit becomes
J(P)=∫Tα0α(PQ−C)dtα=∫Tα0α(PQ−a0−a1Q−a2Q2)dtα→max. | (12) |
Taking the first-order variation to Eq (12), we have
δJ(P)=∫Tα0α(PδQ+QδP−a1δQ−2a2QδQ)dtα=∫Tα0α{QδP+(P−a1−2a2Q)δQ}dtα. | (13) |
According to Eq (10), the first-order variation of Q is
δQ=−b1δP+b2δdPdtα=−b1δP+b2ddtα(δP). | (14) |
Substituting Eq (14) into Eq (13) results in
δJ(P)=∫Tα0α{QδP+(P−a1−2a2Q)(−b1δP+b2ddtα(δP))}dtα=∫Tα0α{[Q−b1(P−a1−2a2Q)]δP+ddtα[(b2(P−a1−2a2Q)δP]−d[b2(P−a1−2a2Q)]dtαδP}dtα=∫Tα0α{[Q−b1(P−a1−2a2Q)−d[b2(P−a1−2a2Q)]dtα]δP}dtα+{[(b2(P−a1−2a2Q)δP]δP}Tα0α | (15) |
We consider the following initial and terminal conditions
P(0α)=P0, | (16) |
P(Tα)=PT, | (17) |
where P0 and PT are constants. So we have
δP(0α)=0, | (18) |
δP(Tα)=0. | (19) |
Setting the first-order variation of J to zero, we have
δJ(P)=∫Tα0α{[Q−b1(P−a1−2a2Q)−d[b2(P−a1−2a2Q)]dtα]δP}dtα=0. | (20) |
We, therefore, obtain the following Euler-Lagrange equation
Q−b1(P−a1−2a2Q)−d[b2(P−a1−2a2Q)]dtα=0, | (21) |
or
(1+2a2b1)Q−b1P+a1b1−b2dPdtα+2a2b2dQdtα=0. | (22) |
In view of Eq (10), we have
(1+2a2b1)(b0−b1P+b2dPdtα)−b1P+a1b1−b2dPdtα+2a2b2(−b1dPdtα+b2d2Pdt2α)=0. | (23) |
Simplifying Eq (23) results in
d2Pdt2α−λ2P+A=0, | (24) |
where
λ2=2b1(1+a2b1)2a2b22, | (25) |
A=b0(1+2a2b1)+a1b12a2b22. | (26) |
Eq (24) with boundary conditions of Eqs (16) and (17) can be easily solved, which reads
P=mexp(λtα)+nexp(−λtα)+Aλ2, | (27) |
where m and n are constants which can be determined by the boundary conditions of Eqs (16) and (17):
m+n+Aλ2=P0, | (28) |
mexp(λTα)+nexp(−λTα)+Aλ2=PT. | (29) |
Evans suggested a variational theory for dynamical economics in 1924 [1], which is to maximize the profit at the period of T. Using the Lagrange multiplier method [35], the constraints of Eqs (1) and (2) can be eliminated, the augmented variational functional is
J(P,Q,C,η,μ)=∫T0{PQ−C+η(C−a0−a1Q−a2Q2)+μ(Q−b0+b1P(t)−b2dPdt)}dt, | (30) |
where η,μ are Lagrange multipliers. The stationary conditions with respect to P, Q and C are, respectively, as follows
Q+b1μ+b2dμdt=0, | (31) |
P+η(−a1−2a2Q)+μ=0, | (32) |
−1+η=0. | (33) |
From Eqs (32) and (33), we have
μ=−P+a1+2a2Q. | (34) |
So Eq (31) becomes
Q+b1(−P+a1+2a2Q)−b2dPdt+2a2b2dQdt=0. | (35) |
In view of Eq (1), we obtain the following differential equation for P:
a1b1+b0(1+2a2b1)−2b1(1+a2b1)P+2a2b22d2Pdt2=0. | (36) |
This is a linear differential equation, and its solution can be easily obtained for the given boundary conditions P(0) = P0 and P(T) = PT.
The quadratic cost function leads to a linear differential equation given in Eq (36), generally the cost function can be expressed as
C=N∑i=0anQn. | (37) |
This will result in a complex nonlinear differential equation. Here we use a quadratic-cubic cost function to show the derivation process.
C=a0+a1Q+a2Q2+a3Q3, | (38) |
The variational principle becomes
J(P)=∫T0(PQ−C)dt=∫T0(PQ−a0−a1Q−a2Q2−a3Q3)dt→max. | (39) |
Using the Lagrange multiplier method, we have
J(P,Q,λ)=∫T0{PQ−a0−a1Q−a2Q2−a3Q3+λ(Q−b0+b1P−b2dPdt)}dt | (40) |
where λ is the Lagrange multiplier. The stationary conditions are
Q+b1λ+b2dλdt=0, | (41) |
P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2+λ=0. | (42) |
From Eq (42), the multiplier can be identified as
λ=−(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2). | (43) |
Eq (41) becomes
Q−b1(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)+b2(−dPdt+2a2dQdt+3a3QdQdt)=0. | (44) |
Replacing Q in Eq (44) by Eq (2), we can obtain a differential equation of P.
The Lagrange multiplier method always works, but sometimes it might fail, see detailed discussion in [35]. We can also obtain Eq (18) without using the Lagrange multiplier. The Euler-Lagrange equation can be obtained from the following equation
δJ(P)=∫T0(PδQ+QδP−a1δQ−2a2QδQ−3a3Q2δQ)dt=0. | (45) |
From Eq (2), we have
δQ=−b1δP+b2δP′(t). | (46) |
Substituting Eq (46) into Eq (45) gives
δJ(P)=∫T0{QδP+(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)(−b1δP+b2δP′)}dt=∫T0{[Q−b1(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)]δP+b2(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)ddtδP}dt=∫T0{[Q−b1(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)]δP−ddt[b2(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)]δP}dt+{[b2(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)]δP}|t=Tt=0=∫T0{[Q−b1(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)]−ddt[b2(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)]}δPdt=0. | (47) |
In the above derivation, we useδP(0)=δP(T)=0. From Eq (47), we obtain the following equation
Q−b1(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)−ddt[b2(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)]=0, | (48) |
which is exactly same as Eq (44).
Submitting Eq (2) into Eq (44), we obtain the following nonlinear differential equation:
b0−b1P+b2P′−b1P+a1b1+2a2b1(b0−b1P+b2P′)+3a3b1(b0−b1P+b2P′)2−b2P′+2a2b2(−b1P′+b2P″)+6a3b2(b0−b1P+b2P′)(−b1P′+b2P″)=0 | (49) |
Simplifying Eq (49) leads to following one
A0P″+A1P′+A2P+A3+A00P2+A11P′2−A02PP″+A12P′P″=0, | (50) |
where the coefficients are given as
A0=2(a2+3a3b0)b22A1=b2+2a2b1b2+6a3b0b1b2−b2−2a2b1b2−6a3b0b1b2A2=−2b1(1+a2b1+3a3b0b1)A3=b0+a1b1+2a2b0b1+3a3b20b1A00=3a3b31A11=−3a3b1b22A02=−6a3b1b22A12=−2b1b2+6a3b21b2+6a3b32 | (51) |
This equation with given initial and terminal conditions, P(0) = P0 and P(T) = PT, can be approximately solved by either the variational iteration method [36,37] or the homotopy perturbation method [38,39,40,41,42,43,44,45].
In this paper we consider the following nonlinear demand function
Q(t)=b00−b10P+b20P2+b01P′+b02P′2+b11PP′, | (52) |
where bij (i = 0, 1; j = 0, 1) are constants.
The first variation of Q is
δQ(t)=−b10δP+2b20PδP+b01δP′+2b02P′δP′+b11PδP′+b11P′δP=(−b10+2b20P+b11P′)δP+(b01+2b02P′+b11P)δP′ | (53) |
Substituting Eq (53) into Eq (47) results in
δJ(P)=∫T0{QδP+(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)[(−b10+2b20P+b11P′)δP+(b01+2b02P′+b11P)δP′]}dt=∫T0{[Q+(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)(−b10+2b20P+b11P′)]δP}dt+∫T0{[(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)(b01+2b02P′+b11P)δP′]}dt=0 | (54) |
Proceeding a similar way as above, we can obtain the following Euler-Lagrange equation
Q+(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)(−b10+2b20P+b11P′)−ddt{(P−a1−2a2Q−3a3Q2)(b01+2b02P′+b11P)}=0 | (55) |
Solving the nonlinear system of Eqs (52) and (55), we can find the solution of P and Q.
The one child policy was mathematically correct according to Ma Yinchu's population theory as discussed above, however, Ma's basic assumption used a large scale and a smooth population growth was obtained, however it becomes invalid for a smaller scale, and various debates arose [46,47,48,49]. As an illustrative example, we consider a seedling's growth. When we measure its height every year, it grows exponentially, however its prediction deviates greatly, and its error becomes infinitely large when time tends to infinity. This deviation arises in its large-scale observation. When we measure its height every hour, we can find it stops growing at the night period; if we use a scale of a month, we find it stops growing during winter. So the law for the seedling's growth is scale-dependent, any a law based on a single scale assumption will derivate remarkably when observed on a different scale.
Now we turn to Ma's population theory, it has sparked furious uproars. In view of the two-scale theory, its findings must be flawed on a different scale. The two-scale economics can avoid many unnecessary debates.
To be concluded, this paper, for the first time ever, suggests the basic concepts for a promising two-scale economic theory, all economic laws are scale-dependent. A decision based on a single-scale economic law will lead to a large derivation on a different scale, two scales are a must for analysis of many economic phenomena, and seeing with a single scale is always unbelieving [50,51,52,53].
Generally the cost function can be written as
C=N∑i=0anQn, | (56) |
and the demand function can be expressed as
Q(t)=b00−N∑n=1bn0Pn+M∑m=1b0m(dPdtα)m+N∑n=1M∑m=1bnmPn(dPdtα)m. | (57) |
This paper shows that the variational principle can deal with complex economic problems with ease. An oversimplification assumption might lead to a simple equation as given in Eq (36), but it might lose some important facts for future prediction. This paper provides economists with a powerful mathematical tool to analysis of complex economic problems.
H. M. Sedighi is grateful to the Research Council of Shahid Chamran University of Ahvaz for its financial support (Grant No. SCU.EM99.98).
This work does not have any conflicts of interest.
[1] | G. C. Evans, The dynamics of monopoly, Am. Math. Mon., 31 (1924), 77-83. |
[2] |
V. E. Tarasov, Fractional econophysics: Market price dynamics with memory effects, Phys. A: Stat. Mech. Appl., 557 (2020), 124865. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2020.124865
![]() |
[3] |
M. Pomini, Economic dynamics and the calculus of variations in the interwar period, J. Hist. Econ. Thought, 40 (2018), 57-79. doi: 10.1017/S1053837217000116
![]() |
[4] |
Z. Nahorski, H. F. Ravn, A review of mathematical models in economic environmental problems, Ann. Oper. Res., 97 (2000), 165-201. doi: 10.1023/A:1018913316076
![]() |
[5] | K. D. Avinash, J. E. Stiglitz, Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity, Am. Econ. Rev., 67 (1977), 297-308. |
[6] | J. H. He, A simple approach to Volterra-Fredholm integral equations, J. Appl. Comput. Mech., 6 (2020), 1184-1186. |
[7] |
P. A. Samuelson, Law of conservation of the capital-output ratio, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., 67 (1970), 1477-1479. doi: 10.1073/pnas.67.3.1477
![]() |
[8] | P. A. Samuelson, Two conservation laws in theoretical economics, In: R. Sato, R. V. Ramachandran, Conservation Laws and Symmetry: Applications to Economics and Finance, Springer, 1990. |
[9] | P. A. Samuelson, Law of conservation of the capital-output ratio in closed von Neumann systems, In: R. Sato, R. V. Ramachandran, Conservation Laws and Symmetry: Applications to Economics and Finance, Springer, 1990. |
[10] |
P. A. Samuelson, Conserved energy without work or heat, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., 89 (1992), 1090-1094. doi: 10.1073/pnas.89.3.1090
![]() |
[11] | D. Romer, Advanced Macroeconomics, 4 Eds., McGraw-Hill Equcation, 2019. |
[12] | A. C. Chiang, Element of Dynamic Optimization, Singapore: Science Typographers Inc, 1992. |
[13] |
J. H. He, Fractal calculus and its geometrical explanation, Results Phys., 10 (2018), 272-276. doi: 10.1016/j.rinp.2018.06.011
![]() |
[14] |
Y. Khan, Fractal Lakshmanan-Porsezian-Daniel model with different forms of nonlinearity and its novel soliton solutions, Fractals, 29 (2021), 2150032. doi: 10.1142/S0218348X21500328
![]() |
[15] |
Y. Khan, Fractal modification of complex Ginzburg-Landau model arising in the oscillating phenomena, Results Phys., 18 (2020), 103324. doi: 10.1016/j.rinp.2020.103324
![]() |
[16] |
Y. Khan, A novel soliton solutions for the fractal Radhakrishnan-Kundu-Lakshmanan model arising in birefringent fibers, Opt. Quant. Electron., 53 (2021), 127. doi: 10.1007/s11082-021-02775-5
![]() |
[17] |
J. H. He, Thermal science for the real world: Reality and Challenge, Therm. Sci., 24 (2020), 2289-2294. doi: 10.2298/TSCI191001177H
![]() |
[18] | N. Anjum, C. H. He, J. H. He, Two-scale fractal theory for the population dynamics, Fractals, 2021. Available from: https://doi.org/10.1142/S0218348X21501826. |
[19] |
B. Mandelbrot, How long is the coast of Britain? Statistical self-similarity and fractional dimension, Science, 156 (1967), 636-638. doi: 10.1126/science.156.3775.636
![]() |
[20] |
J. H. He, Q. T. Ain, New promises and future challenges of fractal calculus: From two-scale thermodynamics to fractal variational principle, Therm. Sci., 24 (2020), 659-681. doi: 10.2298/TSCI200127065H
![]() |
[21] |
J. H. He, A tutorial review on fractal spacetime and fractional calculus, Int. J. Theor. Phys., 53 (2014), 3698-3718. doi: 10.1007/s10773-014-2123-8
![]() |
[22] |
X. J. Li, Z. Liu, J. H. He, A fractal two-phase flow model for the fiber motion in a polymer filling process, Fractals, 28 (2020), 2050093. doi: 10.1142/S0218348X20500930
![]() |
[23] | D. Tian, C. H. He, J. H. He, Fractal pull-in stability theory for microelectromechanical systems, Front. Phys., 9 (2021), 145. |
[24] | C. H. He, C. Liu, J. H. He, K. A. Gepreel, Low frequency property of a fractal vibration model for a concrete beam, Fractals, 2021. Available from: https://doi.org/10.1142/S0218348X21501176. |
[25] | C. H. He, C. Liu, J. H. He, A. H. Shirazi, H. Mohammad-Sedighi, Passive atmospheric water harvesting utilizing an ancient Chinese ink slab and its possible applications in modern architecture, Facta Univ. Ser.-Mech. Eng., 2021. Available from: http://casopisi.junis.ni.ac.rs/index.php/FUMechEng/article/view/7202. |
[26] | C. H. He, C. Liu, J. H. He, H. Mohammad-Sedighi, A. Shokri, K. A. Gepreel, A fractal model for the internal temperature response of a porous concrete, Appl. Comput. Math., 20 (2021). |
[27] |
J. H. He, S. J. Kou, C. H. He, Z. W. Zhang, K. A. Gepreel, Fractal oscillation and its frequency-amplitude property, Fractals, 29 (2021), 2150105. doi: 10.1142/S0218348X2150105X
![]() |
[28] | J. H. He, W. F. Hou, N. Qie, K. A. Gepreel, A. H. Shirazi, H. Mohammad-Sedighi, Hamiltonian-based frequency-amplitude formulation for nonlinear oscillators, Facta Univ. Ser.-Mech. Eng., 2021. Available from: http://casopisi.junis.ni.ac.rs/index.php/FUMechEng/article/view/7223. |
[29] |
C. H. He, Y. Shen, F. Y. Ji, J. H. He, Taylor series solution for fractal Bratu-type equation arising in electrospinning process, Fractals, 28 (2020), 2050011. doi: 10.1142/S0218348X20500115
![]() |
[30] |
J. H. He, N. Qie, C. H. He, T. Saeed, On a strong minimum condition of a fractal variational principle, Appl. Math. Lett., 119 (2021), 107199. doi: 10.1016/j.aml.2021.107199
![]() |
[31] |
J. H. He, N. Qie, C. H. He, Solitary waves travelling along an unsmooth boundary, Results Phys., 24 (2021), 104104. doi: 10.1016/j.rinp.2021.104104
![]() |
[32] |
Y. T. Zuo, Effect of SiC particles on viscosity of 3-D print paste: A fractal rheological model and experimental verification, Therm. Sci., 25 (2021), 2405-2409. doi: 10.2298/TSCI200710131Z
![]() |
[33] | J. H. He, W. F. Hou, C. H. He, T. Saeed, T. Hayat, Variational approach to fractal solitary waves, Fractals, 29 (2021). |
[34] |
Y. Wu, J. H. He, A remark on Samuelson's variational principle in economics, Appl. Math. Lett., 84 (2018), 143-147. doi: 10.1016/j.aml.2018.05.008
![]() |
[35] | J. H. He, Lagrange crisis and generalized variational principle for 3D unsteady flow, Int. J. Numer. Methods Heat Fluid Flow, 30 (2020), 1189-1196. |
[36] | J. H. He, N. Anjum, P. S. Skrzypacz, A variational principle for a nonlinear oscillator arising in the microelectromechanical system, J. Appl. Comput. Mech., 7 (2021), 78-83. |
[37] | J. H. He, P. S. Skrzypacz, Y. N. Zhang, J. Pang, Approximate periodic solutions to microelectromechanical system oscillator subject to magnetostatic excitation, Math. Meth. Appl. Sci., 2020. Available from: https://doi.org/10.1002/mma.7018. |
[38] | J. H. He, Y. O. El-Dib, The enhanced homotopy perturbation method for axial vibration of strings, Facta Univ. Ser.-Mech. Eng., 2021. Available from: http://casopisi.junis.ni.ac.rs/index.php/FUMechEng/article/view/7385. |
[39] | J. H. He, Y. O. El-Dib, Homotopy perturbation method with three expansions, J. Math. Chem., 59 (2021), 1139-1150. |
[40] | J. H. He, G. M. Moatimid, D. R. Mostapha, Nonlinear instability of two streaming-superposed magnetic Reiner-Rivlin Fluids by He-Laplace method, J. Electroanal. Chem., 2021. Available from: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jelechem.2021.115388. |
[41] | M. Ali, N. Anjum, Q. T. Ain, J. H. He, Homotopy perturbation method for the attachment oscillator arising in nanotechnology, Fibers Polym, 2021. Available from: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12221-021-0844-x. |
[42] | N. Anjum, J. H. He, Q. T. Ain, D. Tian, Li-He's modified homotopy perturbation method for doubly-clamped electrically actuated microbeams-based microelectromechanical system, Facta Univ. Ser.-Mech. Eng., 2021. Available from: http://casopisi.junis.ni.ac.rs/index.php/FUMechEng/article/view/7346. |
[43] | J. H. He, Y. O. El-Dib, The reducing rank method to solve third-order Duffing equation with the homotopy perturbation, Numer. Methods Partial Differ. Equations, 37 (2021), 1800-1808. |
[44] | J. H. He, Y. O. El-Dib, Homotopy perturbation method for Fangzhu oscillator, J. Math. Chem. 58 (2020), 2245-2253. |
[45] | J. H. He, Y. O. El-Dib, Periodic property of the time-fractional Kundu-Mukherjee-Naskar equation, Results Phys., 19 (2020), 103345. |
[46] | M. Hvistendahl, Analysis of China's onechild policy sparks uproar colleagues call demographer's findings flawed and irresponsible, Science, 358 (2017), 283-284. |
[47] | L. Cameron, N. Erkal, L. Gangadharan, X. Meng, Little emperors: Behavioral impacts of China's one-child policy, Science, 339 (2013), 953-957. |
[48] | M. Hvistendahl, Has China outgrown the one-child policy? Science, 329 (2010), 1458-1461. |
[49] | C. Djerassi, Political, not scientific, birth control solutions, Science, 297 (2002), 1120-1120. |
[50] |
J. H. He, Seeing with a single scale is always unbelieving: From magic to two-scale fractal, Therm. Sci., 25 (2021), 1217-1219. doi: 10.2298/TSCI2102217H
![]() |
[51] | Y. Khan, Fractal higher-order dispersions model and its fractal variational principle arising in the field of physcial process, Fluctuation Noise Lett., 2021. Available from: https://doi.org/10.1142/S0219477521500346. |
[52] | Y. Khan, Novel solitary wave solution of the nonlinear fractal Schrödinger equation and its fractal variational principle, Multidiscip. Model. Mater. Struct., 17 (2020), 630-635. |
[53] |
Y. Khan, A variational approach for novel solitary solutions of FitzHugh-Nagumo equation arising in the nonlinear reaction-diffusion equation, Int. J. Numer. Methods Heat Fluid Flow, 31 (2021), 1104-1109. doi: 10.1108/HFF-05-2020-0299
![]() |
1. | Jian-She Sun, Approximate analytic solution of the fractal Fisher’s equation via local fractional variational iteration method, 2022, 26, 0354-9836, 2699, 10.2298/TSCI2203699S | |
2. | KANG-LE WANG, A NOVEL VARIATIONAL APPROACH TO FRACTAL SWIFT–HOHENBERG MODEL ARISING IN FLUID DYNAMICS, 2022, 30, 0218-348X, 10.1142/S0218348X22501560 | |
3. | RAHEEL GOHAR, SALIM BAGADEEM, BISHARAT HUSSAIN CHANG, MUYU ZONG, DO THE INCOME AND PRICE CHANGES AFFECT CONSUMPTION IN THE EMERGING 7 COUNTRIES? EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE USING QUANTILE ARDL MODEL, 2022, 17, 2010-4952, 10.1142/S2010495222500245 | |
4. | KANGLE WANG, FRACTAL SOLITARY WAVE SOLUTIONS FOR FRACTAL NONLINEAR DISPERSIVE BOUSSINESQ-LIKE MODELS, 2022, 30, 0218-348X, 10.1142/S0218348X22500839 | |
5. | Shuxian Deng, Ermin Wang, Xinxin Ge, Analytic algorithm for local fractional Caudrey-Dodd-Gibbon-Kaeada equation based on the new iterative method, 2022, 26, 0354-9836, 2771, 10.2298/TSCI2203771D | |
6. | ALEX ELÍAS-ZÚÑIGA, ON TWO-SCALE DIMENSION AND ITS APPLICATION FOR DERIVING A NEW ANALYTICAL SOLUTION FOR THE FRACTAL DUFFING’S EQUATION, 2022, 30, 0218-348X, 10.1142/S0218348X2250061X | |
7. | Guang-qing Feng, Jing-yan Niu, An analytical solution of the fractal toda oscillator, 2023, 44, 22113797, 106208, 10.1016/j.rinp.2023.106208 | |
8. | Wei Xu, Jiahui Yi, Jinhua Cheng, The Heterogeneity of High-Quality Economic Development in China’s Mining Cities: A Meta Frontier Function, 2022, 19, 1660-4601, 6374, 10.3390/ijerph19116374 | |
9. | Zhao Yao, Kehui Sun, Shaobo He, Dynamics of Fractional-Order Chaotic Rocard Relaxation Econometric System, 2022, 32, 0218-1274, 10.1142/S0218127422501954 | |
10. | Guojuan Lv, Dynamic behaviors for the graphene nano/microelectromechanical system in a fractal space, 2023, 1461-3484, 146134842311626, 10.1177/14613484231162657 | |
11. | Serhii Zabolotnii, Sergii Mogilei, MODIFICATIONS OF EVANS PRICE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL, 2023, 13, 2391-6761, 58, 10.35784/iapgos.3507 | |
12. | Dong Siwei, Wongvanichtawee Chalermkiat, An analysis on the relationship between ESG information disclosure and enterprise value: A case of listed companies in the energy industry in China, 2023, 10, 2331-1975, 10.1080/23311975.2023.2207685 | |
13. | Shuxian Deng, Zihao Deng, Approximate analytical solutions of generalized fractional Korteweg-de Vries equation, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 1873, 10.2298/TSCI2303873D | |
14. | YU-TING ZUO, VARIATIONAL PRINCIPLE FOR A FRACTAL LUBRICATION PROBLEM, 2024, 32, 0218-348X, 10.1142/S0218348X24500804 | |
15. | YARONG ZHANG, NAVEED ANJUM, DAN TIAN, ABDULRAHMAN ALI ALSOLAMI, FAST AND ACCURATE POPULATION FORECASTING WITH TWO-SCALE FRACTAL POPULATION DYNAMICS AND ITS APPLICATION TO POPULATION ECONOMICS, 2024, 32, 0218-348X, 10.1142/S0218348X24500828 | |
16. | Jianshe Sun, Fractal modification of Schrödinger equation and its fractal variational principle, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 2029, 10.2298/TSCI2303029S | |
17. | Jianshe Sun, Variational principle for fractal high-order long water-wave equation, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 1899, 10.2298/TSCI2303899S | |
18. | Chu-Han Shang, Huai-An Yi, Solitary wave solution for the non-linear bending wave equation based on He’s variational method, 2024, 28, 0354-9836, 1983, 10.2298/TSCI2403983S | |
19. | Mubashir Qayyum, Efaza Ahmad, Ferdous M. Tawfiq, Zabidin Salleh, Syed Tauseef Saeed, Mustafa Inc, Series form solutions of time–space fractional Black–Scholes model via extended He-Aboodh algorithm, 2024, 109, 11100168, 83, 10.1016/j.aej.2024.08.053 | |
20. | Bin Chen, Lei Chen, Zhong-Ze Xia, He-Laplace method for time fractional burgers-type equations, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 1947, 10.2298/TSCI2303947C | |
21. | Xiao-Qun Cao, Si-Hang Xie, Hong-Ze Leng, Wen-Long Tian, Jia-Le Yao, Generalized variational principles for the modified Benjamin-Bona-Mahony equation in the fractal space, 2024, 28, 0354-9836, 2341, 10.2298/TSCI2403341C | |
22. | J. Hussain, Muhammad Afzal Soomro, Safia Amir Dahri, K.N. Memon, Mehak Bano, Fuad A. Awwad, Emad A.A. Ismail, Hijaz Ahmad, A study of maximizing skew Brownian motion with applications to option pricing, 2024, 17, 16878507, 100732, 10.1016/j.jrras.2023.100732 | |
23. | Xiuquan Zhang, Approximate analytical solution to the Kudryashov-Sinelshchikov equation with he’s fractional derivative, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 1795, 10.2298/TSCI2303795Z | |
24. | Yue Wu, Guang-Qing Feng, Variational principle for an incompressible flow, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 2039, 10.2298/TSCI2303039W | |
25. | Shuxian Deng, Zihao Deng, Approximate analytical solutions for a class of generalized perturbed KdV-burgers equation, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 1881, 10.2298/TSCI2303881D | |
26. | Xiumei Li, Weiwei Ling, Wenbo Xiao, Zhiliang Zhan, Feng Zou, Variational principle of the 2-D steady-state convection-diffusion equation with fractal derivatives, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 2049, 10.2298/TSCI2303049L | |
27. | Jun-Feng Lu, Li Ma, Numerical analysis of space-time fractional Benjamin-Bona-Mahony equation, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 1755, 10.2298/TSCI2303755L | |
28. | Hongjin Ma, Variational principle for a generalized Rabinowitsch lubrication, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 2001, 10.2298/TSCI211201071M | |
29. | Qi Ma, Ruifu Yuan, Chun Wang, Variational method to fractal long-wave model with variable coefficients, 2023, 27, 0354-9836, 1779, 10.2298/TSCI2303779M | |
30. | Enhai Liu, Zhanghui Guo, Yu Wang, Xiaotong Wei, Man Li, Biomass analysis of resource utilization system, 2024, 28, 0354-9836, 2093, 10.2298/TSCI2403093L | |
31. | Lyudmyla Malyarets, Oleksandr Dorokhov, Anatoly Voronin, Irina Lebedeva, Stepan Lebedev, Models of microeconomic dynamics: Bifurcations and complex system behavior algorithms, 2024, 72, 0042-8469, 1552, 10.5937/vojtehg72-52213 | |
32. | Slavi G. Georgiev, Lubin G. Vulkov, Computational Reconstruction of the Volatility Term Structure in the General Hull–White Model, 2025, 13, 2079-3197, 16, 10.3390/computation13010016 | |
33. | Aljawhara H Almuqrin, CGL Tiofack, DV Douanla, A Mohamadou, Weaam Alhejaili, Sherif ME Ismaeel, Samir A El-Tantawy, On the “Tantawy technique” and other methods for analyzing fractional Fokker–Plank type equations, 2025, 1461-3484, 10.1177/14613484251319893 | |
34. | XUEJUAN LI, XINYUE YANG, YE-CHENG LUO, YING WANG, MATHEMATICAL MODEL FOR NANOFIBERS’ DIFFUSION IN A NANOFLUID AND NUMERICAL SIMULATION, 2025, 33, 0218-348X, 10.1142/S0218348X24501445 |