
Citation: Paul Adjei Kwakwa, Hamdiyah Alhassan, Solomon Aboagye. Environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis in a financial development and natural resource extraction context: evidence from Tunisia[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(4): 981-1000. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.4.981
[1] | Brandy Rapatski, Petra Klepac, Stephen Dueck, Maoxing Liu, Leda Ivic Weiss . Mathematical epidemiology of HIV/AIDS in cuba during the period 1986-2000. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2006, 3(3): 545-556. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2006.3.545 |
[2] | Seiko Fujiwara, Hiroshi Nishiura . On the rate of clinical AIDS on diagnosis: The mathematical interpretation and goal for the successful control of HIV/AIDS. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2025, 22(8): 2105-2119. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2025077 |
[3] | Divine Wanduku . A nonlinear multi-population behavioral model to assess the roles of education campaigns, random supply of aids, and delayed ART treatment in HIV/AIDS epidemics. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(6): 6791-6837. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020354 |
[4] | Nawei Chen, Shenglong Chen, Xiaoyu Li, Zhiming Li . Modelling and analysis of the HIV/AIDS epidemic with fast and slow asymptomatic infections in China from 2008 to 2021. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(12): 20770-20794. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023919 |
[5] | Esther Chigidi, Edward M. Lungu . HIV model incorporating differential progression for treatment-naive and treatment-experienced infectives. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2009, 6(3): 427-450. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2009.6.427 |
[6] | Federico Papa, Francesca Binda, Giovanni Felici, Marco Franzetti, Alberto Gandolfi, Carmela Sinisgalli, Claudia Balotta . A simple model of HIV epidemic in Italy: The role of the antiretroviral treatment. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2018, 15(1): 181-207. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2018008 |
[7] | Tefa Kaisara, Farai Nyabadza . Modelling Botswana's HIV/AIDS response and treatment policy changes: Insights from a cascade of mathematical models. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(1): 1122-1147. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023052 |
[8] | Sophia Y. Rong, Ting Guo, J. Tyler Smith, Xia Wang . The role of cell-to-cell transmission in HIV infection: insights from a mathematical modeling approach. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(7): 12093-12117. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023538 |
[9] | Helong Liu, Xinyu Song . Stationary distribution and extinction of a stochastic HIV/AIDS model with nonlinear incidence rate. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2024, 21(1): 1650-1671. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2024072 |
[10] | Ying Liu, Weidong Ji, Yi Yin, Zhengrong Yang, Shu Yang, Chao Zhou, Yongli Cai, Kai Wang, Zhihang Peng, Daihai He, Weiming Wang . An analysis on the trend of AIDS/HIV incidence in Chongqing and Shenzhen, China from 2005–2015 based on Age-Period-Cohort model. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(5): 6961-6977. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021346 |
Symbiosis is an important aspect of ecology [1]. In fact, an entire journal, titled Symbiosis, is devoted to the study of symbiotic interactions at all levels ranging from the molecular to the organismic. The precise meaning assigned to the term symbiosis may vary depending on context; a fairly general definition, given in [2], is a close physical association between different species, regardless of whether that association is harmful, beneficial or neutral to any of the species involved.
In many cases of interest, the symbiosis is between a host, and one or more types of symbiont living within the host, often in large numbers. Two examples, both relating to humans, are infectious diseases [3,4] and gut microbe interactions [5]. A harmful symbiont is a pathogen, while a beneficial symbiont is a mutualist. Previous mathematical studies have focused on studying either the pathogen case [6] or the mutualist case [7,8], however it would be useful to understand, from a unified perspective, how the nature of the host-symbiont relationship affects the range of observed interactions.
To this end, we study a simple two-variable model of host-symbiont interactions with four parameters (described in the next section) that includes both horizontal and vertical transmission of the symbiont, and naturally incorporates both the pathogen and mutualist cases, as well as the intermediate neutral (neither harmful nor beneficial) case, modelled by the symbiont's effect on the host birth rate. As well, we assume recovery is possible; that is, it is possible for the symbiont within a host to die without killing the host. For simplicity, we assume perfect vertical transmission of the symbiont, and distinguish only presence or absence of the symbiont within the host, tracking the population density of both unassociated hosts (those without the symbiont) and associated hosts. A generalization to imperfect vertical transmission is also easily implemented, though we have not considered it here.
A special case of our model appears in [9], in which the authors discuss how it is possible, with a mixture of horizontal and vertical transmission, for a pathogen to successfully invade and persist within a host population, and they also give precise conditions for the pathogen to reach full occupation. In their model, only the pathogen case is considered, and recovery from the symbiont does not occur. In addition, the concern is with existence of certain equilibria and so a full description of the dynamics is not given. However, they also consider the case of imperfect transmission which is not covered here. From a different perspective, a model of mutualism [7], which is similar though not identical to this model, shows a qualitatively similar nullcline structure in some cases that leads to bistability; interestingly, this similarity is only observed after a change of variables is made in our model, from associated and unassociated host density to total host density and proportion of hosts that are associated.
For our model we are able to obtain a complete description of the dynamics for all values of the four parameters. In all but a single case, every trajectory tends to one of at most three distinct equilibria, ruling out sustained oscillations and reducing the study of the model to the characterization of equilibria. In turn, the number and location of equilibria is closely related to two factors:
● the effect of the symbiont upon the host (pathogen, mutualist or neutral), and
● which of the two is larger: the difference in the birth rate of associated vs. unassociated hosts (which is positive only for mutualists), and the horizontal rate of spread of the symbiont through the host population.
The second quantity is shown to be relevant only after making the above-mentioned change of variables. One way to view it is by how the symbiont allocates resources: is it focused on increasing the host's rate of birth and thus vertical transmission, or is it focused on spreading immediately to existing hosts via horizontal transmission?
An important finding for this model is that bistability (between host-symbiont coexistence and either host extinction or host survival only) can only occur when the symbiont is a mutualist that is more focused on horizontal transmission than on improving host birth rate (i.e. when the second quantity above is positive), and that in the absence of bistability, all solutions with a positive density of both host and symbiont tend to a unique equilibrium. Moreover, in the absence of bistability the set of qualitative behaviours displayed by the system is insensitive as to whether the symbiont is a pathogen or a mutualist, except in the difference in host density between the host-without-symbiont equilibrium vs. the host-symbiont coexistence equilibrium, when both exist.
The original motivation for making a detailed study of this model was to obtain complementary results for a study of the corresponding stochastic spatial model [10]. When working on that paper, a preliminary analysis of the differential equations yielded partial but artifically restrictive results. The reason for this restriction was revealed only after making the change of variables mentioned above, from associated vs. unassociated host density to total host density vs. proportion of hosts that are associated, which made evident the occurrence of bistability, which previously we had thought was not possible. Thus one conclusion of this analysis is that the (biological) perspective of host-symbiont interactions as being a "stacked" system, in which hosts have their own birth-death dynamics, while symbionts within the host population have a similar birth-death dynamics taking place over the host population, is also a useful perspective when analyzing the dynamical system. It is worth noting that the stacked perspective is also used in [11] and indeed in our paper [10], where it assists in the analysis of the stochastic spatial model by suggesting comparisons with simpler models.
For simplicity, we ignore environmental transmission of the symbiont, and distinguish only presence or absence of the symbiont within the host. Unassociated hosts reproduce at some rate, and all hosts die at some rate which is normalized to 1. Associated hosts can infect unassociated hosts, and can also recover and become unassociated. Moreover, associated hosts reproduce at some possibly different rate from associated hosts. We assume, again for simplicity, perfect vertical transmission of the symbiont, so that offspring of associated parents are always associated. The symbiont is identified as pathogen, mutualist, or neutral by its effect on the host's birth rate.
To derive the differential equations that we study, we begin with a set of N sites each of which can be either empty, occupied by an unassociated host, or occupied by an associated host. Each unassociated host attempts to give birth to an unassociated host onto a site chosen uniformly at random at rate λ10, being successful if that site is empty. Similarly, each associated host attempts to give birth to an associated host at rate λ20. Each host dies at rate 1, while each associated host becomes an unassociated host at rate δ. Each associated host attempts to transmit the symbiont to a randomly chosen site at rate λ21, being successful if the recipient is an unassociated host. Let U(N)0(t),U(N)1(t),U(N)2(t) denote the number of empty sites, unassociated hosts and associated hosts, respectively. Since ∑2i=0U(N)i(t)=N, we find that (U(N)1(t),U(N)2(t)) is a Markov chain with the following transitions.
(U1,U2)→(U1,U2)+{(1,0)at rateλ10U0U1/N(−1,0)at rateU1(0,1)at rateλ20U0U2/N(0,−1)at rateU2(−1,1)at rateλ21U1U2/N(1,−1)at rateδU2 |
If we rescale to proportions u(N)i(t)=U(N)i(t)/N, then a result of Kurtz [12] implies that as N→∞, on any bounded time interval, sample paths of (u(N)1(t),u(N)2(t)) converge in probability to solutions of the following pair of equations, which we take as our object of study:
u′1=λ10u0u1−u1+δu2−λ21u1u2u′2=λ20u0u2−u2−δu2+λ21u1u2. | (2.1) |
We note of course that the asymptotic behaviour of these equations is, in general, not the same as the above stochastic process. That said, for such models the connections often run deeper than just finite-time convergence; see for example the work of [13].
As it turns out, it is more productive to study the total proportion of hosts: x1=u1+u2 and the proportion of hosts that are associated: x2=u2/x1. Letting λa=λ20−λ10 and λb=−λa+λ21, after a bit of algebra we obtain the system
x′1=G1(x1,x2)=x1((λ10+λax2)(1−x1)−1)x′2=G2(x1,x2)=x2((λa+λbx1)(1−x2)−δ). | (2.2) |
The coordinate change u→x is singular at x1=0 but note the inverse u1=x1(1−x2), u2=x1x2 is smooth and onto. Thus, every solution of (2.1) is the image of a solution of (2.2), so to understand (2.1) it is enough to study (2.2). In terms of the original description, the host population survives if lim inft→∞x1(t)>0 and the symbiont survives if lim inft→∞x2(t)>0. The symbiont takes over if limt→∞x2(t)=1. It should be clear that takeover is only possible if δ=0, and even then only if further conditions are satisfied.
From the form of (2.2) it should be clear that (x1,x2) is a more natural choice of variables than (u1,u2), since the right-hand sides in (2.2) both factor nicely into density dependent form, with a good deal of symmetry between the two equations. This form is the previously mentioned "stacked" perspective, wherein the total host density, and the prevalence of the symbiont within the host population, are thought to be the best descriptors of the population demographics. The sign of λa separates the pathogen, neutral and mutualist cases by λa<0,=0,>0 respectively. The sign of λb determines whether or not a higher host density is beneficial to the spread of the symbiont, measured by the proportion of hosts that are associated – since it depends on λ21, we say the symbiont is weakly infectious if λb<0, neutrally infectious if λb=0 and strongly infectious if λb>0. Distinguishing various cases according to the sign of λa and λb is crucial to making a complete analysis.
We first identify the regions of interest. Define the feasible region Λ=[0,1]2 and let
Λ+={(0,1]×(0,1)={(x1,x2)∈Λ:x1>0, 0<x2<1}if δ=0,(0,1]2={(x1,x2)∈Λ:x1,x2>0}if δ>0. |
In addition, let
p0=(0,0),p1=(a1,0)=(1−1/λ10,0),p2=(a2,1)=(1−1/λ20,1) andp3=(0,a3)=(0,1−δ/λa). |
Except for some corner cases, these are the only candidates for equilibria on the boundary of Λ.
Define λM=max(λ10,λ20) which is an upper bound on the host birth rate. Also define the conditions
(AinvU):λ20(1−a1)+λ21a1>1+δ and(UinvA):λ10(1−a2)−λ21a2>1. |
(AinvU) stands for "associated invades unassociated", and is relevant iff λ10>1, in which case it corresponds to parameter values for which a small introduction of associated hosts in a stable population of unassociated hosts leads to an increase in the proportion of associated hosts. Equivalently, G2(p1+ϵe2)>0 for small ϵ>0, where e2=(0,1). (UinvA) is analogous, and is relevant iff λ20>1 and δ=0.
The following is the main result of this article. Since the classification is somewhat lengthy we begin with a brief summary. There are four main cases: (E), (UH), (AH), (C), and two exceptional cases: (RS) and (B). In every case except for redundant symbiont (RS), every trajectory in Λ+, the interior of the feasible region, tends to one of at most three equilibria, and tends to a unique equilibrium when bistability (B) does not occur. When (RS) and (B) do not occur, the system settles into one of the following four states:
● extinction of both host and symbiont (E),
● survival of host and extinction of symbiont (UH),
● survival of host and complete adoption of the symbiont (AH), which is only possible if δ=0, and
● survival of host, with stable coexistence of associated and unassociated hosts (C).
Case (RS) is defined precisely as λ10=λ20>1, δ=λ21=0 and would otherwise correspond to (UH). Case (B) is defined later, under section heading Subcase 5b, in terms of intersections of the nullclines. It falls strictly within the range of parameter values satisfying λa>0 and λb>0, that is a strongly infectious, mutualist symbiont, and would otherwise correspond to either (E) or (UH).
Theorem 2.1. The following six cases include all parameter values.
We begin with two exceptional cases.
1. Redundant symbiont (RS). Suppose λ10=λ20>1 and δ=λa=λ21=0, which would otherwise correspond to (UH). For all x∈Λ+, limt→∞ϕ1(t,x)=a1 and t↦ϕ2(t,x) is constant.
2. Bistability (B). This occurs for a non-empty set of parameter values satisfying min(λa,λb)>0, δ>0, that would otherwise correspond to (E) if λ10≤1, or to (UH) if λ10>1. Moreover, the set of values (δ,λ21) that gives (B) is non-empty iff λ20>max(1,λ210).
There are three subcases: onset (OB), marginal (MB) and non-marginal (NB) bistability. (NB) is an open, contractible set of parameter values and (OB), (MB) are piecewise smooth and on the boundary of (NB). In each subcase there is an interior equilibrium ˉx∈Λ+ satisfying max(0,a1)<ˉx1<a2.
i) Onset of bistability (OB). limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=ˉx for x∈Λ+.
ii) Marginal bistability (MB). There is a set U⊂Λ+, open in Λ+ and not containing ˉx, such that
limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=(max(0,a1),0)forx∈U,andlimt→∞ϕ(t,x)=ˉxforx∈Λ+∖U. |
iii) Non-marginal bistability (NB). There are ˉx∈U2, ˉy∈Λ∖(U1∪U2), with max(0,a1)<ˉy1<ˉx1<a2 and max(0,a3)<ˉy2<ˉx2<1, and disjoint sets U1,U2⊂Λ+ both open in Λ+, with Λ+∖(U1∪U2) the stable manifold of ˉy, such that
limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=(max(0,a1),0)forx∈U1,limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=ˉxforx∈U2, andlimt→∞ϕ(t,x)=ˉyforx∈Λ+∖(U1∪U2). |
Suppose (RS) and (B) do not hold. Then, there exists ˉx∈Λ such that limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=ˉx for all x∈Λ+.
Assuming (RS) and (B) do not hold, four cases are possible.
1. Extinction. (E) ˉx=(0,max(0,a3)), if λ10≤1 and λ20≤1+δ.
2. Survival and coexistence of associated and unassociated host. (C)
max(0,min(a1,a2))<ˉx1<max(a1,a2)andmax(0,a3)<ˉx2<1,if |
(a) δ>0 and either
i. λ10≤1 and λ20>1+δ, or
ii. λ10>1 and (AinvU) holds, or
(b) δ=0 and either
i. λ10≤1, λ20>1 and (UinvA) holds,
ii. λ10>1, λ20≤1 and (AinvU) holds, or
iii. min(λ10,λ20)>1, (AinvU) holds and (UinvA) holds.
3. Survival of unassociated host only. (UH) ˉx=p1 if λ10>1 and (AinvU) does not hold.
4. Survival of associated host only. (AH) ˉx=p2 if δ=0, λ20>1 and (UinvA) does not hold.
It is worth noting the behaviour under (OB) is the same as in (C). The reason why we do not include it in (C) is because it occurs for parameter values that would otherwise satisfy either (E) or (UH).
In Figure 2 we show streamlines together with nullclines in a few different cases.
Theorem 2.1 gives a complete picture of the dynamics, with the possible objections that
● the exact parameter ranges for (OB), (MB), and (NB) are not specified, and
● a precise formula for interior equilibria is not given.
In the case of (MB) and interior equilibria this is because they are determined by intersection conditions between curved nullclines on the interior of Λ. Despite this, in Subcase 5b we give a fairly nice formula for (OB), which leads to the iff condition λ20>max(1,λ210) for the possibility of bistability given in Theorem 2.1. We also give a satisfying characterization of the values of (δ,λ21) such that (NB) occurs.
Before moving onto the proof we unpack somewhat the result of Theorem 2.1, tying it to the original motivation. We begin with (B) since it is the most unusual case. Ignoring (OB) and (MB) since they are boundary cases, when (NB) occurs there are two stable equilibria; the first gives either extinction of the host (if λ10≤1) or survival without symbiont (if λ10>1), while the second is a coexistence equilibrium at a higher host density. The case λ10≤1 is obligate mutualism, as for example with termites and their protozoa [14], since neither the host nor the symbiont can survive without the other; this has been previously observed mathematically in, for example, [15]. The case λ10>1 is facultative mutualism, whereby the host is able to survive without the symbiont, but still benefits from its introduction. We note that, in order for (B) to occur, not only must the symbiont be a mutualist, but because of the condition λ20>max(1,λ210), the benefit it imparts must be sufficiently high, and quite significant if λ10 is fairly large. On the other hand, since λb=−λ21+λa, its tendency λ21 to spread through the host population must also exceed the benefit λa=λ20−λ10 that it imparts to the host birth rate. Thus bistability can only occur when we have a very helpful, yet selfish mutualist in the sense that the significant benefit it provides is still exceeded by its rate of spread through the host population. The latter trait can also be viewed as a strategy for survival which is more focused on horizontal transmission than on vertical transmission.
When we have either a pathogen (λa<0), or a mutualist that does more to aid host survival than to spread itself through the host population (λb<0), (B) does not occur. In this case there is a single equilibrium attracting all solutions in the interior of the feasible region, which is determined by the location of boundary equilibria (survival of unassociated hosts or associated hosts, in isolation) together with the invasion conditions (AinvU) or (UinvA), and whether or not the recovery rate is zero. In particular, it is straightforward to determine whether we have host extinction (E), survival of unassociated host only (UH), coexistence (C), or survival of associated host only (AH), so we leave it to the reader to inspect each case. This description, of course, bears the exception of the trivial case (RS) that essentially corresponds to two equally viable species that don't interact except in their competition for space.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 3 we recall some basic theory of plane systems of differential equations. In Section 4 we take care of the dynamics on Λ∖Λ+, which consists of invariant lines on the boundary of the feasible region. In Section 5 we study the dynamics on the interior of Λ, in several steps. We first study special parameter values where (2.2) separates into a simpler form. We then determine boundary equilibria and their stability. Next we study the nullclines, and move on to study the itinerary of trajectories on regions delineated by the nullclines. We then give a sufficient condition to rule out periodic orbits, homoclinic orbits and heteroclinic cycles, using Dulac's criterion. At this point, we have the tools to study the dynamics in the remaining cases where (2.2) does not assume a simple form, and we complete the proof.
We first recall some basic theory that can be found in [16], specialized to the present context. Let F∈C1(R2,R2). Corresponding to F there exists a C1 function ϕ:S→R2 called the flow, defined on an open S⊂R×R2 containing {0}×R2 and satisfying
ϕ(0,x)=xand∂tϕ(t,x)=F(ϕ(t,x)) for (t,x)∈S. |
In particular, for fixed x, t↦ϕ(t,x) solves the initial value problem
y′=F(y),y(0)=x |
in an open time interval around 0. Letting τ+(x)=sup{t:(t,x)∈S} and τ−(x)=inf{t:(t,x)∈S}, if we require that for every x∈R2,
1. τ−(x)=−∞ or limt↓τ−(x)‖ϕ(t,x)‖=∞ and that
2. τ+(x)=∞ or limt↑τ+(x)‖ϕ(t,x)‖=∞,
then ϕ exists and is the unique function with the stated properties. In particular, for every x∈R2 the above initial value problem has a unique solution forward and backward in time, to either ±t=∞ or until it diverges. Given x∈R2, the corresponding trajectory Γ is defined as
Γ(x)={ϕ(t,x):τ−(x)<t<τ+(x)}, |
and the sets {Γ(x):x∈R2} form a partition of R2 into trajectories. We are also interested in the positive semi-trajectory
Γ+(x)={ϕ(t,x):0≤t<τ+(x)}. |
We say that a set E⊂R2 is invariant if x∈E implies Γ(x)⊂E, and forward invariant if x∈E implies Γ+(x)⊂E. If E is both bounded and forward invariant, the above implies τ+(x)=∞ for every x∈E. In this case we are interested in the omega-limit set of points x∈E, defined by
ω(x)={y:y=limn→∞ϕ(tn,x) for some sequence (tn) with limn→∞tn=∞} |
and contained in the closure of E. Omega-limit sets are known to be closed, connected, invariant, and made up of trajectories, which can be of a few types, including the following. An equilibrium point is a point x such that F(x)=0. A periodic orbit is the positive semi-trajectory of a point x satisfying ϕ(T,x)=x for some T>0, and a separatrix cycle is the union of finitely many equilibrium points p1,…,pm for some m≥1 and trajectories Γ(xi),i=1,…,m satisfying
limt→∞ϕ(−t,xi)=pifori=1,…,m,limt→∞ϕ(t,xi)=pi+1fori=1,…,m−1 andlimt→∞ϕ(t,xm)=p1. | (3.1) |
A separatrix cycle with m=1 is a homoclinic orbit, and with m>1 is a heteroclinic cycle. It should be clear from the definition that if ω(x) is a single point, then limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=ω(x).
We return to (2.2) and begin by studying the dynamics on invariant boundary lines.
Dynamics on Λ∖Λ+. Let L1={x2=0}, L2={x1=0} and L3={x2=1}, so that
Λ+={Λ∖(L1∪L2)ifδ>0Λ∖(L1∪L2∪L3)ifδ=0. |
The lines L1,L2 are invariant, as is L3 if δ=0. On L1 the equilibria are p0 and p1. Since G1=x1(λ10(1−x1)−1) if x2=0, the segment {0<x1≤1, x2=0} is forward invariant and for x in that segment,
limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=(max(0,a1),0). |
On L2 the equilibria are p0 and p3. Since G2=x2(λa(1−x2)−δ) if x1=0, the segment {x1=0, 0<x2≤1} is forward invariant and for x in that segment,
limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=(0,max(0,a3)). |
On L3, G2=−δx2, so if δ=0 that line is invariant and the equilibria are p3 and p2. Since G1=x1(λ20(1−x1)−1) if x2=1, the segment {0<x1≤1, x2=1} is forward invariant and for x in that segment,
limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=(max(0,a2),1). |
Forward invariance of Λ,Λ+. Note that on the line {x1=1}, G1=−1<0, and if δ>0 then G2<0 on {x1>0, x2=1}. Therefore Λ is forward invariant. This is because every side of [0,1]2 is either invariant, or else is such that for x on that side, ϕ(t,x)∈(0,1)2 for small enough t>0, which means that trajectories cannot exit [0,1]2 along any of its four sides. The same is true if we remove any number of invariant lines from Λ. In particular, Λ+ is also forward invariant.
Next we determine ω(x) for x∈Λ+, proving Theorem 2.1. By forward invariance ω(x)⊂Cl(Λ+)=Λ, where Cl denotes the closure. The analysis is broken up into five broad cases. In each situation we point out which case in Theorem 2.1 ((RS), (OB), (MB), (NB), (E), (C), (UH), (AH)) applies.
Case 1 – low host birth rate: λM=max{λ10,λ20}≤1 (E). If x∈Λ then G1≤x1(λM(1−x1)−1).
So, λM≤1 implies G1≤−x21 and limt→∞ϕ1(t,x)=0.
Case 2 – neutral symbiont: λM>1, λa=0. In this case λ10=λ20>1 and λb=λ21, so
G1=x1(λ10(1−x1)−1)andG2=x2(λ21x1(1−x2)−δ). |
Since λ10,λ20>1, a1,a2>0. Moreover if x∈Λ then limt→∞ϕ1(t,x)=a1. Since λ10=λ20, we have λ20(1−a1)=λ10(1−a2)=1, so (AinvU)⇔λ21a1>δ and (UinvA)⇔λ21a2>0⇔λ21>0.
If δ=λ21=0 (RS) then G2=0, so t↦ϕ2(t,x) is constant.
If δ=0 and λ21>0 (AH) then G2>0 for x1>0 and 0<x2<1, so limt→∞ϕ2(t,x)=1 for x∈Λ+.
If δ>0 and λ21=0 (UH) then G2<0 for x2>0, so limt→∞ϕ2(t,x)=0 for x∈Λ+.
If δ,λ21>0, then using the limiting value of ϕ1 we find that
limt→∞ϕ2(t,x)=ˉx2=max(0,1−δλ21a1) for x∈Λ+. |
If λ21a1≤δ (UH) then ˉx2=0 and if λ21a1>δ (C) then 0<ˉx2<1.
Case 3 – neutrally infectious symbiont: λM>1, λa≠0, λb=0. In this case λ10≠λ20 and λ10=λ20−λ21. This forces λ20>λ10 so that λa>0 and λ21>0. Multiplying on both sides by λ10,
(AinvU) ⇔λ20+λ21(λ10−1)>(1+δ)λ10⇔λ21λ10>δλ10 |
which is ⇔λ10>0 and λ21>δ. Multiplying on both sides by λ20,
(UinvA) ⇔λ10−λ21(λ20−1)>λ20⇔−λ21λ20>0, |
so (UinvA) does not hold. We find
G1=x1((λ10+λax2)(1−x1)−1)andG2=x2(λa(1−x2)−δ), |
so
limt→∞ϕ2(t,x)=ˉx2=max(0,1−δ/λa) for x∈Λ+. |
Then,
ifδ=0thenˉx2=1,(AH)if0<δ<λathen0<ˉx2<1(C) or (E)and ifδ≥λathenˉx2=0(UH) or (E). |
Plugging ˉx2 into the equation for G1 we find
limt→∞ϕ1(t,x)=max(0,1−1/(λ10+λaˉx2)) for x∈Λ+. |
In particular, ϕ1→0 exactly on the condition λ10+λaˉx2≤1, which
ifδ=0isλ20≤1 thus empty,if0<δ<λaisλ20≤1+δ(E)and ifδ≥λaisλ10≤1(E). |
This concludes the easy cases. To treat cases with λa,λb≠0, more effort is required. We will start by studying equilibria on the boundary of Λ+, then nullclines on Λ+, then itineraries on Λ+. Then, we will be ready to consider the remaining cases.
Equilibria on L. Let L=L1∪L2 if δ>0 and L=L1∪L2∪L3 if δ=0, so that Λ+=Λ∖L. Since λa,λb≠0, p0,p1,p2,p3 are the possible equilibria (eq) on L. Letting a1=1−1/λ10, a2=1−1/λ20, a3=1−δ/λa,
1. p0=(0,0)∈L1∩L2 is always an eq in Λ.
2. p1=(a1,0)∈L1 is an eq in Λ∖{p0} if λ10>1.
3. p3=(0,a3)∈L2 is an eq in Λ∖{p0} if δ<λa, and if δ=0 then p3=(0,1)∈L2∩L3.
4. p2=(a2,1)∈L3 is an eq in Λ∖{p3} if δ=0 and λ20>1.
To assess stability we compute the Jacobian matrix J(x)=(∂jGi(x))ij.
J(x)=((λ10+λax2)(1−2x1)−1λax1(1−x1)λbx2(1−x2)(λa+λbx1)(1−2x2)−δ). |
If x∈L then at least one of x1,x2 is equal to 0 or 1, and J(x) is triangular, so its eigenvalues are equal to its diagonal entries. Straightforward computation shows that
1. J(p0) has eigenvalues λ10−1 and λa−δ,
2. J(p1) has eigenvalues 1−λ10 and J22(p1),
3. J(p2) has eigenvalues 1−λ20 and J22(p2) if δ=0, and
4. J(p3) has eigenvalues λ20−(1+δ) and δ−λa.
Since λb=−λa+λ21, λa=λ20−λ10, λ10(1−a1)=1 and 1−a1=1/λ10,
J22(p1)=λa+λba1−δ=λa(1−a1)+λ21a1−δ=λ20(1−a1)+λ21a1−(1+δ)=λ20/λ10+λ21(1−1/λ10)−(1+δ), |
and if δ=0 then since −λa=λ10−λ20 and λ20(1−a2)=1,
J22(p2)=−λa−λba2=−λa(1−a2)−λ21a2=λ10(1−a2)−λ21a2−1=λ10/λ20−λ21(1−1/λ20)−1. |
Using these calculations and the fact that G2(x+ϵe2)=ϵG2(x)+o(ϵ),
ⅰ) J22(p1)>0⇔ (AinvU) ⇔ G2>0 just above p1.
ⅱ) J22(p2)>0⇔ (UinvA) ⇔ G2<0 just below p2.
Recall the following three types of equilibria p:
ⅰ) Attracting: for some ϵ>0, |x−p|<ϵ implies limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=p.
ⅱ) Saddle point: the stable manifold and unstable manifold
Ws(p)={x:limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=p} and Wu(p)={x:limt→−∞ϕ(t,x)=p} |
are smooth curves each consisting of p and a pair of trajectories, and the tangent lines to Ws,Wu at p are eigenvectors of J(p) with eigenvalues whose real part is negative, respectively positive.
ⅲ) Repelling: for some ϵ>0, |x−p|<ϵ implies limt→−∞ϕ(t,x)=p.
Given equilibrium p, let μ1,μ2 be the eigenvalues of J(p), and recall that [hartman-grobman]
ⅰ) p is attracting if (μ1), (μ2)<0,
ⅱ) p is a saddle point if (μ1)<0<(μ2), and
ⅲ) p is repelling if 0<(μ1), (μ2).
If one or both of (μi)=0 then p could be of any type, or none.
Nullclines.
{G1=0}={x1=0}∪γ1whereγ1={(λ10+λax2)(1−x1)=1}, and{G2=0}={x2=0}∪γ2whereγ2={(λa+λbx1)(1−x2)=δ}. |
γ1 is a hyperbola with vertical asymptote x1=1, so instead let γ1 be the branch with x1<1.
If δ=0 then γ2={x2=1}∪{x1=−λa/λb} so instead let γ2 be the vertical line {x1=−λa/λb}.
If δ>0 then γ2 is a hyperbola with horizontal asymptote x2=1, so instead let γ2 be the branch with x2<1. Both γ1 and γ2 intersect each of the invariant lines at most once. The intersection points, and conditions for existence, are
● γ1∩{x2=0}=p1 if λ10>0,
● γ1∩{x1=0}=r1=(0,b1) with b1=(1−λ10)/λa,
● γ1∩{x2=1}=p2 if λ20>0,
● γ2∩{x2=0}=r2=(b2,0) with b2=(δ−λa)/λb,
● γ2∩{x1=0}=p3, and
● γ2∩{x2=1}=r3=(b2,1) if δ=0.
By considering what happens when x2=0 and noting that {x1=0},γ1 are the only null sets for G1 when 0≤x1≤1, it follows that G1>0 to the left of γ1 in Λ+. On the other hand, since ∂x1G2=λbx2(1−x2), if λb<0 then G2>0 to the left of γ2, while if λb>0 then G2>0 to the right of γ2, in Λ+.
If λ10>1 then b2=a1 marks the boundary between (AinvU) and its complement.
Similarly, if λ20>1 and δ=0 then b2=a2 marks the boundary between (UinvA) and its complement.
Also, it's easy to check that b1=a3 is equivalent to λ20=1+δ.
It's useful to think of γ1 as the graph of the function
x2=g1(x1), x1<1whereg1(x1)=λ−1a(11−x1−λ10), |
and when δ>0 to think of γ2 as the graph of the function
x2=g2(x1), x2<1whereg2(x1)=1−δλa+λbx1. |
If δ=0 then γ1∩γ2 has cardinality 0 or 1 as γ1 has at most one intersection point with any vertical line. If δ>0 then since the sign of the pairs (g′1(x1),g″1(x1)) and (g′2(x1),g″2(x1)) do not depend on x1 and never coincide (to see this, break up according to (sgn(λa),sgn(λb)), noting that λa+λb=λ21≥0 implies (sgn(λa),sgn(λb))≠(−1,−1)), γ1∩γ2 has cardinality 0,1 or 2.
Itineraries. Let G=(G1,G2) and for a pair (a,b) let sgn(a,b)=(sgn(a),sgn(b))∈{−1,0,1}2. For each sign vector σ∈{−1,0,1}2 let
R(σ)={x∈Λ+:sgn(G(x))=σ}. |
Since all signs are represented, {R(σ):σ∈{−1,0,1}2} is a partition of Λ+. Note that one or more of these sets could be empty.
● The set R(0,0)=γ1∩γ2∩Λ+ consists of equilibrium points and has cardinality 0,1 or 2.
● The sets R(0,1)∪R(0,−1)=γ1∩Λ+∖γ2 and R(1,0)∪R(−1,0)=γ2∩Λ+∖γ1, so we refer to the union of all four as Rγ. Since neither hyperbola has either a horizontal or vertical tangent at any point, while G is horizontal or vertical on each one (or if δ=0, γ2 is vertical while G is horizontal on γ2), it follows that on Rγ, G is transverse to the tangent space of Rγ, so for any x∈Λ+, the set of times {t:ϕ(t,x)∈Rγ} is a discrete set.
● The sets R(σ) for σ∈{−1,1}2 are open subsets of (0,1]2 that, based on the number of intersection points of γ1 and γ2, each have at most 2 connected components.
If x∈(0,1]2∖R(0,0) then since R(0,0) is invariant and {t:ϕ(t,x)∈Rγ} is discrete, there is a (possibly finite) symbolic sequence I(x)=(σ1,σ2,…) called the itinerary of x, with each σi∈{−1,1}2, and an increasing sequence of times t(x)=(t1,t2,…), with t0=0, and with ti=∞ iff I(x) has length i, with the property that
ϕ(t,x)∈R(σi) for t∈(ti−1,ti). |
Define a directed graph called the sign graph with vertices {−1,1}2 by including each directed edge (σ,σ′) iff there is x such that (Ii(x),Ii+1(x))=(σ,σ′) for some i≥1. The sign graph is cyclic if there is a sequence of edges (σ1,σ2),…,(σk,σ1), and acyclic if not. Appearance of (σ,σ′) in the sign graph is also represented by R(σ)→R(σ′). R(σ) is absorbing if none of the edges (σ,⋅) appear on the sign graph. An equilibrium point p∈Cl(R(σ)) is a sink for R(σ) if for some x∈R(σ), I(x)=σ and limt→∞ϕ(t,x)=p. If p is a sink for R(σ) then it is a local maximum of x↦σ⋅x on R(σ). The following lets us seal the fate of trajectories, when the sign graph is acyclic. The proof is given in the Appendix.
Lemma 5.1. If I(x) is finite and its last entry is σ then ω(x) is a sink for R(σ).
In particular, if the sign graph is acyclic then for all x∈Λ+, ω(x) is a sink.
Periodic orbits and cycles. Lemma 1 makes our life easier when the sign graph is acyclic. When the sign graph is cyclic, we will use the following proposition to simplify the analysis.
Proposition 5.1. For each x∈Λ+, ω(x) is either
1. an equilibrium point or
2. contains a separatrix cycle intersecting an equilibrium in L.
Proof. There are three steps.
1. Show there are no periodic orbits in Λ and no separatrix cycles in Λ+.
2. Show that a separatrix cycle intersecting L must intersect an equilibrium in L.
3. Invoke a generalized form of the Poincaré-Bendixson theorem.
Step 1. We begin with
Lemma 5.2 (Dulac's criterion). - Suppose we have the planar system
u′=F(u)whereu∈R2andF:R2→R2 isaC1function. |
Let R⊂R2 be a simply connected region in the plane and B:R2→R2 be a C1 function (called a Dulac function) such that the divergence of BF is non-zero and has constant sign almost everywhere on R. Then, the system u′=F(u) has no periodic orbit and no separatrix cycle on R.
Since most proofs of Dulac's criterion only rule out periodic orbits, we include a proof in the appendix.
No periodic orbit or separatrix cycle in Λ+. Since the restriction of x↦(x1(1−x2),x1x2) to {0<x1≤1, 0<x2<1} maps bijectively onto {u1,u2>0, u1+u2≤1}, periodic orbits and separatrix cycles are mapped to the same. So, to rule them out on the former set, we find a Dulac function for (2.1) on the latter set. The function B(u)=1/(u1u2) works, since
∇⋅(BF)=∂u1(λ10u0/u2−1/u2−λ21+δ/u1)+ ∂u2(λ20u0/u1−1/u1+λ21−δ/u1)=−λ10/u2−δ/u21−λ20/u1 |
is strictly negative when u1,u2>0 (at least one of λ10,λ20 is positive).
If δ=0 the set {0<x1≤1, 0<x2<1} is equal to Λ+.
If δ>0, Λ+ includes also the segment {0<x1≤1, x2=1}. Since G2<0 on that segment, any trajectory that intersects it also intersects Λc, so is not contained in Λ.
No periodic orbit in L. If a periodic orbit C intersects L=Λ∖Λ+, it intersects an invariant line on L. Since C is a single trajectory, it is a subset of that invariant line. Since C is the continuous injective image of a circle and L is either a pair of orthogonal lines, or two parallel lines and an orthogonal line, this cannot occur.
Step 2. A separatrix cycle is the continuous injective image of a circle. If it intersects L, it intersects an invariant line on L, so it must contain an equilibrium point on that line. If it did not, it would consist of a single trajectory on that line.
Step 3. This step is a trivial application of the following result.
Theorem 5.1 (Generalized Poincaré-Bendixson Theorem). - Let E⊂R2 be an open set and F∈C1(E,R2). Suppose the system x′=F(x) has a positive semi-trajectory Γ+(x) contained in a compact set K⊂E with the property that F(x)=0 for at most finitely many x∈K. Then, ω(x) is either
1. an equilibrium point,
2. a periodic orbit, or
3. contains a separatrix cycle.
Proof. This is given by Theorem 2 in Section 3.7 of [17], and the comments that follow.
This concludes the proof of Proposition 5.1.
Trajectories. We are now ready to study dynamics in the remaining cases. We break up our analysis according to the sign of λa,λb. The interested reader will note that Case 3 above can also be covered here using the same methods, although it does not give an explicit formula for the interior equilibrium, when there is one.
Case 4 – pathogen: λM>1, λa<0, λb≠0. In this case, λ10>max(1,λ20) and λb=−λa+λ21>0, so a1=1−1/λ10>0, b2=(δ−λa)/λb>0 and G2>0 to the right of γ2. g1 is decreasing and concave, and if δ>0 then g2 is increasing and concave, while if δ=0 then γ2={x1=b2} – in either case γ2 lies to the right of {x1<b2} so G2<0 on this set. Since G1>0 near p0 it attracts no points in Λ+, and since p3=(0,a3) with a3=1−δ/λa≥1, if p3∈Λ then δ=0, p3=(0,1) and G2<0 in a Λ+-neighbourhood of p3, which means p3 attracts no points in Λ+.
If b2≥a1 then (AinvU) does not hold, which gives (UH). R(−1,1)→R(−1,−1)→R(1,−1) appear from right to left. If p2∈Λ then since λ20<λ10, a2<a1≤b2 so G2<0 in a Λ+-neighbourhood of p2. Since the sign graph is acyclic, every solution tends to a sink, and the only candidate is p1.
If δ>0 and b2<a1 (AinvU) which gives (a.ii) of (C), or δ=0 and a2<b2<a1 which gives (AinvU) and (UinvA) and thus (b.iii) of (C) if a2>0 or (b.ii) of (C) if a2≤0, then (C) holds. γ1∩γ2 is a unique point p4∈Λ+ and p1 is a saddle, as is p2 if δ=0. The sign graph is cyclic, so we use Proposition 1 to conclude that solutions tend to p4 provided no separatrix cycles on Λ contain an equilibrium on L – let C denote a possible candidate. Since p1 is a saddle, Ws(p1)={0<x1, x2=0} so p1∈C implies p0∈C. Since p0 is a saddle with Ws(p0)={x1=0, x2<a3=1−δ/λa}, p0∈C implies p3∈C. If δ>0, p3∉Λ so C cannot exist, otherwise δ=0 and p0∈C implies p3=(0,1)∈C. If λ20<1 then Ws(p3)={a2<x1, x2=1} and C cannot exist. If λ20=1 then since γ2 does not intersect p3, still G2<0 in a Λ+-neighbourhood of p3, so Ws(p3) is disjoint from Λ+ which means Ws(p3)={0≤x1, x2=1} and C cannot exist. If λ20>1 then p3 is repelling, and C cannot exist. If δ>0 then p2∉Λ, and if δ=0 and p2∈Λ then p2 is a saddle with Ws(p2)={0<x1, x2=1}, so p2∈C implies p3∈C. Since p3 is repelling, C cannot exist.
If δ=0 and b2≤a2<a1 then (AinvU) holds but (UinvA) does not, which gives (AH). R(1,−1)→R(1,1)→R(−1,1) appear from left to right, and p1 is a saddle. Since the sign graph is acyclic, solutions tend to a sink, and the only candidate is p2.
Case 5 – mutualist: λM>1, λa>0, λb≠0. In this case λ20>max(1,λ10) so a2>0, and g1 is increasing and convex. Notice that g1 intersects the set {x1=0,0≤x2<1}∪{0≤x1<a2, x2=0} at exactly one point, which is p1 if λ10>1, p0 if λ10=1 and r1=(0,b1)=(0,(1−λ10)/λa) if λ10<1.
Subcase 5a – weakly infectious mutualist: λb<0. If δ>0 then g2 is decreasing and concave, and recall γ2∩{x2=0} contains only the single point (b2,0) with b2=(δ−λa)/λb, and γ2∩{x1=0} contains only the single point p3=(0,a3) with a3=1−δ/λa. γ1∩γ2∩Λ+ contains exactly one point if either 0<a1<b2 or a1≤0 and a3>b1, both of which correspond to (C), and otherwise is empty. Notice that
a3>b1⇔(λa−δ)/λa>(1−λ10)/λa⇔λa−δ>1−λ10⇔λ20>1+δ. |
If δ=0 then b2=−λa/λb>0 and p3=(0,1) is a saddle, so attracts no points in Λ+. If a1<b2<a2, which corresponds to (C), then γ1∩γ2∩Λ+ contains exactly one point, otherwise γ1∩γ2∩Λ+ is empty.
If δ>0 and γ1∩γ2∩Λ+ is empty then either a1>0 and a1≥b2 (UH), or a1≤0 and a3≤b1 which implies λ10≤1 and λ20≤1+δ (E). There are at most three sign regions in Λ (two if b2≤0): R(1,1)→R(1,−1)→R(−1,−1), appearing in that order from left to right. In case of (UH), p0 is a saddle and p1∈Λ, and in case of (E), p0 is the only equilibrium in Λ.
If γ1∩γ2∩Λ+ is not empty then it is a unique point p4∈Λ+. If a1≤0 then p0 is a saddle, otherwise p0 is repelling and p1 is a saddle, and if δ=0 then p2,p3 are saddles. A similar argument as before shows there is no periodic orbit or separatrix cycle in Λ. Thus, all solutions tend to p4.
If δ=0 and 0<b2≤a1<a2 (UH), R(1,1)→R(1,−1)→R(−1,−1) appear from left to right. Since a1>0, p0 is a saddle and p1∈Λ, while p2,p3 are saddles, so solutions tend to p1.
If δ=0 and a1<a2≤b2 (AH), then R(−1,−1)→R(−1,1)→R(1,1) appear from right to left, p0 is repelling, and p1,p3 are saddles, so solutions tend to p2.
Subcase 5b – strongly infectious mutualist: λb>0. In this case (B) can occur, so we take a moment to define precisely the three conditions in terms of the nullclines:
1. (OB) occurs when g1,g2 intersect at two points in Λ, one in Λ+ and the other on the subset {x1=0,0≤x2≤1}∪{0≤x1≤1,x2=0} of the boundary.
2. (MB) occurs when g1,g2 intersect tangentially at one point in Λ+.
3. (NB) occurs when g1,g2 intersect at two points, both in Λ+.
As we go through the various cases we will point out when one of the above might occur; in particular, we'll see that they all occur for values that would otherwise correspond to (E) or (UH). We'll also describe the dynamics in all possible cases. We'll then show that each of (OB), (NB), (MB) does occur, make some effort to characterize them, and show (NB) is simply connected.
If δ=0 then G2=x2((λa+λbx1)(1−x2)>0 on Λ+, so (AH) holds. b1=−λa/λb<0 and R(−1,1)→R(1,1) appear from right to left. Because of the sign of G2, p0 (and p1 if a1>0) attract no points, and p3=(0,1) is a saddle. Since the sign graph is acyclic, solutions tend to a sink, and the only candidate is p2.
For the rest we assume δ>0. g2 is increasing and concave, so γ2 intersects the set {x1=0,0≤x2<1}∪{x1≥0,x2=0} at exactly one point, which is p3=(0,a3)=(0,1−δ/λa) if δ<λa, p0=(0,0) if δ=λa and r2=(b2,0)=((δ−λa)/λb,0) if δ>λa.
If either a1>max(b2,0), or a1≤0 and a3>max(b1,0), then γ1∩γ2∩Λ+ is a unique point p4∈Λ+. A similar argument as before shows that all solutions tend to p4. The first option gives λ10>1 and (AinvU) so corresponds to (C). For the second option, note that a1≤0⇔λ10≤1 and
a3>b1⇔λa−δ>1−λ10⇔λ20>1+δ, |
so it also corresponds to (C).
If b2=a1>0 (UH), then γ1,γ2 intersect at p1. If g′1(a1)≥g′2(a1), then γ1∩γ2∩Λ+ is empty, and the sign regions R(1,−1),R(−1,−1),R(−1,1) appear from left to right with R(1,−1),R(−1,1)→R(−1,−1), so the sign graph is acyclic. Since b2>0 and γ2 is increasing, a3<0 so p3∉Λ+ and G1>0 near p0 so solutions tend to p1. If g′1(a1)<g′2(a1), which as we'll see corresponds to (OB), then γ1∩γ2∩Λ+ is a single point p4. All four sign regions now appear, with R(1,−1),R(−1,1)→R(1,1),R(−1,−1). To show all solutions tend to p4 it remains to show that p1 is not a sink for any sign region. p1 is in the closure of R(1,−1),R(−1,1) and R(1,1). Since G2>0 on R(−1,1) p1 cannot be a sink, and p1 is a local minimum of x↦x⋅(1,1) on R(1,1), whereas a sink is a local maximum. The only remaining candidate is R(1,−1). G2 has a double root at p1, which can be seen from either the transverse intersection of two x2-nullclines ({x2=0} and γ2) or by writing G2 as a function of ˜x=x−p1. Writing G in these coordinates,
G1=(˜x1+a1)((λ10+λa˜x2)(1−(˜x1+a1))−1)=(˜x1+a1)(λ10+λa˜x2)(λ−110−˜x1)−1)=(˜x1+a1)(−λ10˜x1+λa˜x2(λ−110−˜x1)) |
and
G2=˜x2(λa+λb(˜x1+(δ−λa)/λb)(1−˜x2)−δ)=λb˜x1˜x2(1−˜x2)−δ˜x22 |
If a trajectory in R(1,−1) tends to p1 then ˜x1→0− and ˜x2→0+. If ˜x1<0<˜x2 are small in magnitude then by 1st-order approximation G1≥c1(−˜x1+˜x2)>0 for some c1>0, and by 2nd-order approximation, G2≤c2˜x1˜x2−c3˜x22<0 with c3,c4>0. Writing a solution to (2.2) as ˜x2=h(˜x1),
h′=ddt˜x2ddt˜x1=G2G1≥c2˜x1˜x2−c3˜x22c1(−˜x1+x2)=−c2c1˜x2−˜x1−˜x1+˜x2−c3c1˜x2˜x2−˜x1+˜x2≥−c2+c3c1˜x2, |
noting that 0<−˜x1,x2≤−˜x1+x2 on the last step. So, given initial value ˜x1(0),˜x2(0), the corresponding solution has h(˜x1)≥˜x1(0)e−c˜x1 with c=(c2+c3)/c1, so intersects {˜x1=0} at a positive value of ˜x2. Thus no trajectories tend to p1.
If a3=b1≥0 (E), then γ1,γ2 intersect at p3. If g′1(a3)≥g′2(a3), then as above, \gamma_1\cap\gamma_2\cap \Lambda_+ is empty and R(1, -1), R(-1, 1) \to R(-1, -1) . Since a_1\le 0 , if a_3 = 0 then p_0 is the only equilibrium, and if a_3 > 0 then G_2 > 0 near p_0 and p_1 \notin \Lambda_+ so solutions tend to p_3 . If g_1'(a_3) < g_2'(a_3) , then \gamma_1\cap \gamma_2\cap \Lambda_+ is a single point p_4 , and R(1, -1), R(-1, 1) \to R(1, 1), R(-1, -1) . A similar argument as above shows that p_3 attracts no points in \Lambda_+ – this time, G_1 has a double root, so write a solution as \tilde x_1 = h(\tilde x_2) and perform a similar estimate. This situation corresponds to (OB).
If 0 < a_1 < b_2 (UH) then \gamma_1\cap\gamma_2\cap \Lambda_+ has cardinality 0, 1 or 2 , with a saddle node bifurcation when the cardinality is 1 .
1. If the cardinality is 0 , then R(1, -1), R(-1, 1) \to R(-1, -1) and solutions tend to p_1 , similar to the case g_1'(a_1)\ge g_2'(a_1) above.
2. If the cardinality is 1 , then we have (MB). To see this, note that p_1 is attracting, and there is a unique interior equilibrium p_4 . Three sign regions R(1, -1), R(-1, -1), R(-1, 1) appear, with R(1, -1), R(-1, 1)\to R(-1, -1) and R(-1, -1) disconnected by p_4 into two components, the lower of which with sink p_1 and the upper with sink p_4 . Since p_1 is locally stable it attracts an open neighbourhood S \ni p_1 of points in \Lambda_+ . Since the basin of attraction of p_1 is \bigcup_{t < 0}\phi(t, S) it is open in \Lambda_+ .
3. If the cardinality is 2 , we have (NB). To see this, note that p_1 is again attracting, and there are two interior equilibria p_4, p_5 , letting p_5 denote the upper one. All sign regions appear, with R(1, -1), R(-1, 1) \to R(-1, -1), R(1, 1) and R(-1, -1) split in two as before. p_1 is the unique sink for the lower part of R(-1, -1) , and p_5 the unique sink for R(1, 1) and the upper part of R(-1, -1) . Since \gamma_1, \gamma_2 intersect transversally at p_4 and p_5 and are the only nullclines through those points, the Jacobian is non-singular so both equilibria are hyperbolic. Since p_5 attracts more than a single curve of points it is attracting, and since p_4 fails to attract nearby points in R(-1, -1) and R(1, 1) it is not attracting. As argued above, both p_1 and p_5 have open basins of attraction in \Lambda_+ . Since \Lambda_+ \setminus \{p_4\} is open in \Lambda_+ and connected, it cannot be the combined basins of attraction of p_1 and p_5 since that would imply a disconnection. The only option is that some points other than p_4 tend to p_4 , so p_4 is a saddle and its basin of attraction is its stable manifold, which is a smooth curve.
If a_1 \le 0 and 0 < a_3 < b_1 (E) then \gamma_1 \cap \gamma_2 \cap \Lambda_+ has cardinality 0, 1 or 2 as before. Similar observations show that (E), (MB), (NB) occur, respectively.
Properties of (B). We now show that each of (OB), (MB) and (NB) occurs for some parameter values, that (MB) and (OB) lie on the boundary of (NB), and that (NB) is simply connected. For this it is helpful to view the parameter space in terms of the four independent variables (\lambda_{10}, \lambda_a, \delta, \lambda_b) , subject to the general constraints \lambda_{10}, \delta \ge 0 , \lambda_a \ge - \lambda_{10} and \lambda_b \ge - \lambda_a . Here, of course, we may assume further that \delta, \lambda_a, \lambda_b > 0 , since (B) has been ruled out in other cases. We'll let \bar x and \bar y, \bar x denote \gamma_1\cap \gamma_2 \cap \Lambda when its cardinality is, respectively, 1 or 2, with \bar y < \bar x in the elementwise order.
We recall g_1, g_2 and their derivatives:
\begin{align*} g_1(x_1) & = \frac{1}{ \lambda_a}(\frac{1}{1-x_1}- \lambda_{10}), \quad g_2(x_1) = 1 - \frac{\delta}{ \lambda_a + \lambda_bx_1}, \\ g_1'(x_1) & = \frac{1}{ \lambda_a}\frac{1}{(1-x_1)^2} \quad \hbox{and} \quad g_2'(x_1) = \frac{\delta \lambda_b}{( \lambda_a + \lambda_bx_1)^2}. \end{align*} |
Existence. Our approach is to first characterize (OB), then show a small change in \delta leads to (NB), then show a large enough change in \delta gives (MB). We treat separately the cases a_1\le 0 and a_1 > 0 , beginning with a_1 \le 0 . To have (OB) we need g_1(0) = g_2(0) , i.e., b_1 = a_3 , and g_1'(0) < g_2'(0) . Earlier we showed that a_3 = b_1 \Leftrightarrow \lambda_{20} = 1+\delta , that we write as \delta = \lambda_a+ \lambda_{10}-1 , which requires \lambda_a+ \lambda_{10} > 1 , i.e., \lambda_{20} > 1 , since \delta > 0 by assumption. If g_1'(0) < g_2'(0) then \lambda_a^{-1} < \delta \lambda_b/ \lambda_a^2 , so \lambda_a < \delta \lambda_b , that we write as \lambda_b > \lambda_a/\delta . Thus if \lambda_{10}\le 1 and \lambda_a are fixed, (OB) occurs iff \lambda_a+ \lambda_{10} > 1 , \lambda_b \in (\lambda_a/(\lambda_a+ \lambda_{10}-1), \infty) and \delta = \lambda_a+ \lambda_{10}-1 , which is a non-empty set of parameters. Take some such choice of parameters, and note that g_1(0)-g_2(0) = 0 and g_1'(0)-g_2'(0) < 0 . Since g_2 decreases with \delta while g_1 is unchanged, a small increase in \delta then gives (NB). If \delta is increased enough, then g_2(1) < g_1(0) and \gamma_1\cap\gamma_2\cap \Lambda_+ is empty, so there is a unique intermediate value of \delta that gives (MB). This is depicted in Figure 3.
If a_1 > 0 , to have (OB) we need a_1 = b_2 > 0 and g_1'(a_1) < g_2'(b_2) . The former gives a_1 = (\delta- \lambda_a)/ \lambda_b , that we write as \delta = \lambda_b a_1 + \lambda_a noting a_1 depends only on \lambda_{10} , while the latter gives \lambda_{10}^2/ \lambda_a < \delta \lambda_b/\delta^2 , or \delta < \lambda_a \lambda_b/ \lambda_{10}^2 . Plugging in \delta and putting \lambda_b terms to one side gives the condition \lambda_b(\lambda_a/ \lambda_{10}^2-a_1) > \lambda_a . Given \lambda_{10} and \lambda_a , \lambda_b can be chosen large enough to satisfy this inequality iff
\lambda_a/ \lambda_{10}^2 \gt a_1 \Leftrightarrow \lambda_a \gt a_1 \lambda_{10}^2 = \lambda_{10}^2- \lambda_{10} \Leftrightarrow \lambda_{20} \gt \lambda_{10}^2. |
Thus for a_1 > 0 , (OB) occurs iff \lambda_a > \lambda_{10}^2- \lambda_{10} , \lambda_b \in (\lambda_a/(\lambda_a/ \lambda_{10}^2-a_1), \infty) and \delta = \lambda_ba_1+ \lambda_a . Again, this is a non-empty set of parameters. As before, we can vary \delta to obtain (NB) and (MB).
A consequence of the above existence arguments is that they specify for which values of \lambda_{10} and \lambda_a bistability can be achieved by appropriate choice of \delta, \lambda_b , namely, for \lambda_{20} > \max(1, \lambda_{10}^2) . They also show that for any choice of \lambda_{10}, \lambda_a, \lambda_b , the set of values of \delta that gives (B) is a bounded set, with (OB) at the lower endpoint, (MB) at the upper endpoint and (NB) in the interior. A slice of the phase portrait is shown in Figure 4.
Geometry. It's clear that (NB) is an open set in parameter space. Define the functions \tilde \lambda_a = \lambda_{10}+\max(1, \lambda_{10}^2) and
\tilde \lambda_b = \begin{cases} \lambda_a/( \lambda_a+ \lambda_{10}-1) & \text{if} \ \ \lambda_{10} \le 1, \\ \lambda_a/( \lambda_a/ \lambda_{10}^2-(1-1/ \lambda_{10})) & \text{if} \ \ \lambda_{10} \gt 1. \end{cases} |
Note that both functions are continuous. From the above discussion we obtain functions \delta^-(\lambda_{10}, \lambda_a, \lambda_b) and \delta^+(\lambda_{10}, \lambda_a, \lambda_b) with domain \lambda_{10}\ge 0 , \lambda_a > \tilde \lambda_a and \lambda_b > \tilde \lambda_b such that (OB), (NB) and (MB) occur iff (\lambda_{10}, \lambda_a, \lambda_b) are in the domain and \delta = \delta^- , \delta^- < \delta < \delta^+ and \delta = \delta^+ , respectively. The function \delta^- is given above explicitly, piecewise:
\delta^-( \lambda_{10}, \lambda_a, \lambda_b) = \begin{cases} \lambda_a+ \lambda_{10}-1 & \text{if} \ \ \lambda_{10} \le 1 \\ \lambda_a+ \lambda_b(1-1/ \lambda_{10}) & \text{if} \ \ \lambda_{10} \gt 1,\end{cases} |
and one easily verifies its continuity. The function \delta^+ is not given explicitly, but we can show it is smooth, using the implicit function theorem. (MB) corresponds to a unique \bar x_1 \in (0, 1) such that g_1(\bar x_1)-g_2(\bar x_1) = g_1'(\bar x_1)-g_2'(\bar x_1) = 0 . We have
\partial_{(x_1,\delta)}(g_1-g_2,g_1'-g_2') = \begin{pmatrix} g_1'-g_2' & \partial_{\delta}(g_1-g_2) \\ g_1''-g_2'' & \partial_{\delta}(g_1'-g_2') \end{pmatrix} |
where the ' indicates \partial_{x_1} . At (MB), g_1(\bar x_1)'-g_2(\bar x_1)' = 0 , moreover g_1''-g_2'' > 0 since g_1-g_2 is convex. Also, \partial_\delta(g_1-g_2) = -1/(\lambda_a+ \lambda_bx_1)^2 > 0 since \lambda_a > 0 by assumption. Thus the above matrix is invertible. Since (g_1-g_2, g_1'-g_2') is a smooth function of parameters, and of x_1 , when \lambda_a > 0 and x_1 \in (0, 1) , by the implicit function theorem, (\bar x_1, \delta^+) is a smooth function of (\lambda_{10}, \lambda_a, \lambda_b) , on the domain of \delta^+ .
We now show (NB) is a contractible set, via a sequence of homotopies that gives a deformation retraction. Define \tilde \delta = (\delta^-+\delta^+)/2 , which is continuous, and note that (NB) occurs when \delta = \tilde\delta . Notice that \tilde \lambda_a, \tilde \lambda_b and \tilde \delta are functions of \lambda_{10} , \lambda_{10} and \lambda_a , and \lambda_{10}, \lambda_a and \lambda_b respectively. Define the sequence of homotopies as follows, at each step letting \tilde \lambda_a, \tilde \lambda_b and \tilde \delta take the previous values in the list as their input:
(ⅰ) H_1 = (\lambda_{10}, \lambda_a, \lambda_b, (1-t)\delta + t \, \tilde \delta) ,
(ⅱ) H_2 = (\lambda_{10}, \lambda_a, (1-t) \lambda_b + t (\tilde \lambda_b+1), \tilde\delta) ,
(ⅲ) H_3 = (\lambda_{10}, (1-t) \lambda_a + t(\tilde \lambda_a+1), \tilde \lambda_b+1, \tilde \delta) ,
(ⅳ) H_4 = ((1-t) \lambda_{10}+t, \tilde \lambda_a+1, \tilde \lambda_b+1, \tilde \delta) .
Note that t\in [0, 1] is the deformation parameter. In words,
(ⅰ) H_1 acts only on \delta , centering its value to \tilde \delta ,
(ⅱ) H_2 acts on \lambda_b and \delta , centering \lambda_b to \tilde \lambda_b+1 while keeping \delta = \tilde \delta ,
(ⅲ) H_3 centers \lambda_a to \tilde \lambda_a+1 while keeping \lambda_b = \tilde \lambda_b+1 and \delta = \tilde \delta and
(ⅳ) H_4 centers \lambda_{10} to 1 while keeping other parameters centered.
We have already checked the continuity of component functions, and it's clear they keep points in (NB). Applying the H_i in sequence deforms (NB) to the single point with \lambda_{10} = 1 and the corresponding values of \tilde \lambda_a, \tilde \lambda_b and \tilde \delta .
In this article we consider a simple differential equation model of host-symbiont dynamics, that includes both vertical and horizontal transmission of the host, as well as recovery (i.e. transition from associated [with symbiont] to unassociated [without symbiont] host). The model naturally incorporates the pathogen, neutral, and mutualist cases through the choice of parameter values, providing a unified setting for the study of all three cases.
Our analysis indicates that the most natural way to view the process is through the total host density (both associated and unassociated) and the proportion of hosts that are associated. Moreover, the two main factors governing the dynamics are (ⅰ) the effect of the symbiont on the host (i.e. whether it is pathogen, neutral or mutualist) and (ⅱ) the difference between the additional birth rate of associated vs. unassociated hosts (which is positive only for mutualists) and the rate of horizontal transmission of the symbiont.
We obtain a complete picture of the model's dynamic phases, as follows. Except for the very special case when the symbiont is completely redundant (neutral, no recovery and no horizontal transmission), populations that initially contain both host and symbiont, and not located at an unstable equilibrium, always settle down to one of at most three equilibria. The limiting equilibrium is unique when the symbiont is either a pathogen, is neutral, or is a mutualist but focuses more on increasing the host birth rate than on horizontal transmission. Bistability (exactly two locally attracting equilibria) can occur when the symbiont is a sufficiently beneficial mutualist that focuses more on horizontal transmission than on increasing the host birth rate. There are three limiting equilibria only in a boundary case at the onset of bistability. When the limiting equilibrium is unique, survival and coexistence are determined by straightforward invasibility conditions, i.e., whether one type can invade the extinction equilibrium (for survival) or the stable equilibrium containing only the other type (for coexistence).
Interestingly, the dynamical behaviour, and in particular the number of stable equilibria, hinges less on whether the symbiont is pathogen or mutualist, and more on whether the symbiont is highly beneficial (increases host birth rate), versus highly infectious (has a high rate of horizontal transmission). Moreover, we have shown that, at least when including only the simple mechanisms considered in this model, stable periodic behaviour is not possible.
All authors declare that there is no conflicts of interest in this paper.
Proof of Lemma 5.1. For a definite sign vector \sigma \in \{-1, 1\}^2 and \epsilon > 0 let
R(\sigma, \epsilon) = \{x \in \Lambda_+: \hbox{sgn}(G(x)) = \sigma \ \hbox{and} \ \|G(x)\| \gt \epsilon\}, |
noting that R(\sigma) = \bigcup_{ \epsilon > 0}R(\sigma, \epsilon) and \sigma \cdot G(x) \ge \epsilon \ \hbox{for} \ x \in R(\sigma, \epsilon) . If x \in R(\sigma, \epsilon) for definite \sigma and letting
\tau(x, \epsilon) = \inf\{t:\phi(t,x) \notin R(\sigma, \epsilon)\}, |
\phi(t, x) \in R(\sigma, \epsilon) for t < \tau(x, \epsilon) , so using the second fact above,
\partial_t \sigma \cdot \phi(t,x) = \sigma \cdot G(\phi(t,x)) \ge \epsilon. |
Since for y, z \in \Lambda_+ , |\sigma \cdot y- \sigma \cdot z| \le 2 , it follows that \tau(x) \le 2/ \epsilon . Thus, letting E(\sigma, \epsilon) = \text{Cl} \left(R(\sigma) \setminus R(\sigma, \epsilon) \right) and
E(\sigma) = \bigcap\limits_{ \epsilon \gt 0} E(\sigma, \epsilon) |
where \text{Cl} denotes the closure, E(\sigma) consists of equilibrium points in \text{Cl}(R(\sigma)) . Letting \tau(x) = \inf\{t:\phi(t, x) \notin R(\sigma)\} , the only way that \tau(x) = \infty is if for any \epsilon > 0 , eventually \phi(t, x) \in E(\sigma, \epsilon) , which means that \omega(x) \in E(\sigma) . Since \omega(x) is connected and (for the cases that remain) the set of equilibrium points in \Lambda is finite, the first claim follows. The second claim follows since acyclic implies itineraries are finite.
Proof of Lemma 5.2. Suppose \Gamma is a periodic orbit or a separatrix cycle, both of which are the image of a circle in \mathbb{R}^2 , under a piecewise C^1 function. Since trajectories do not cross, the image is injective, so let D be the interior of \Gamma , whose existence is given by the Jordan curve theorem. By Green's theorem,
\iint_D \nabla\cdot (BF) dxdy = \oint -BF_2 dx + BF_1 dy. |
where F = (F_1, F_2) . First suppose \Gamma is a periodic orbit with solution curve u(t) satisfying u(T) = u(0) . Ignoring the orientation, since it only changes the sign, the latter integral can be parametrized with dx = \dot u_1(s)ds, \ dy = \dot u_2(s)ds as
\int_0^T -B(u(s))(F_2(u(s))\dot u_1(s) + F_1(u(s))\dot u_2(s))ds. |
However, F_2(u(s)) = \dot u_2(s) and F_1(u(s)) = \dot u_1(s) so the integrand is identically zero, thus so is the integral, and this contradicts the assumption on \nabla \cdot (BF) . Suppose instead that \Gamma is a separatrix cycle and let u^{(1)}(t), \dots, u^{(m)}(t) denote the corresponding heteroclinic solutions. Since solutions are arranged tip-to-tail as described by (3.1), it follows that \{\dot u^{(i)}(t):t \in \mathbb{R}, i = 1, \dots, m\} orients the tangent space for \Gamma , so up to its sign, we can parametrize the above contour integral as
\sum\limits_{i = 1}^m \int_{-\infty}^\infty -B(u(s))(F_2(u(s))\dot u_1(s) + F_1(u(s))\dot u_2(s))ds |
and the same observation shows the integral is zero, which is a contradiction.
[1] |
Aboagye S (2017) Economic Expansion and Environmental Sustainability Nexus in Ghana. Afr Dev Rev 29: 155–168. doi: 10.1111/1467-8268.12247
![]() |
[2] | Aboagye S, Nketiah-Amponsah E, Barimah A (2014) Disaggregated Growth and Environmental quality in developing countries: Some evidence from Sub Saharan. Rev Soc Sci 9: 17–30. |
[3] | Aboagye S, Kwakwa PA (2014) The relationship between economic growth and environmental sustainability: evidence from selected Sub Sahara African countries. Ghanaian J Econ 2: 135–153. |
[4] |
Adom PK, Kwakwa PA, Amankwaa A (2018) The long-run effects of economic, demographic, and political indices on actual and potential CO2 emissions. J Environ Management 218: 516–526. doi: 10.1016/j.jenvman.2018.04.090
![]() |
[5] | Akin CS (2014) The impact of foreign trade, energy consumption and income on CO2 emissions. Int J Energy Econ Policy 4: 465–475. |
[6] | Amri F (2018) Carbon dioxide emissions, total factor productivity, ICT, trade, financial development, and energy consumption: testing environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis for Tunisia. Environ Sci Pollut Res 1–11. |
[7] |
Amuakwa-Mensah F, Adom PK (2017) Quality of institution and the FEG (forest, energy intensity, and globalization) environment relationships in sub-Saharan. Afri Environ Sci Pollut Res 24: 17455–17473. doi: 10.1007/s11356-017-9300-2
![]() |
[8] |
Alper A, Onur G (2016) Environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis for sub-elements of the carbon emissions in China. Nat Hazards 82: 1327–1340. doi: 10.1007/s11069-016-2246-8
![]() |
[9] |
Alam MM, Muradb MW, Nomanc AHM, et al. (2016) Relationships amongcarbon emissions, economic growth, energy consumption and population growth: testing Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis for Brazil, China, India and Indonesia. Ecol Indic 70: 466–479. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2016.06.043
![]() |
[10] |
Al-Mulali U, Ozturk I (2016) The investigation of environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis in the advanced economies: the role of energy prices. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 54: 1622–31. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2015.10.131
![]() |
[11] | Behera B, Vishnu R (2011) Analysing the Impact of Anthropogenic Factors on the Environment in India. Environ Nat Resources Res 1: 117–129. |
[12] | Boopen S, Vinesh S (2011) On the Relationship between Carbon Emissions and Economic Growth: the Mauritian Experience. Available from: http://www.csae.ox.ac.uk/conferences/2011-EDiA/papers/776-Seetanah.pdf |
[13] | Casey G, Galor O (2017) Is faster economic growth compatible with reductions in carbon emissions? The role of diminished population growth. Environ Res Lett 12: 014003. |
[14] | Chebbi H-E, Olarreaga M, Zitouna H (2009) Trade openness and CO2 emissions in Tunisia. In proceedings of Shocks vulnerability and therapy ERF 16th annual conference November 7–9 Cairo Egypt. |
[15] | Dickey DA, Fuller WA (1979) Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with a unit root. J Am Stat Assoc 74: 427–431. |
[16] |
Dogan E, Seker F (2016) The influence of real output, renewable and non-renewable energy, trade and financial development on carbon emissions in the top renewable energy countries. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 60: 1074–1085. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2016.02.006
![]() |
[17] |
Dogan E, Ozturk I (2017) The influence of renewable and non-renewable energy consumption and real income on CO2 emissions in the USA: evidence from structural break tests. Environ Sci Pollut Res 24: 10846–10854. doi: 10.1007/s11356-017-8786-y
![]() |
[18] |
Dong K, Sun R, Li H, et al. (2018) Does natural gas consumption mitigate CO2 emissions: Testing the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis for 14 Asia-Pacific countries. Renew Sust Energy Rev 94: 419–429. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2018.06.026
![]() |
[19] | Fatawu NA, Allan A (2014) Managing the impacts of mining on Ghana's water resources from a legal perspective. JENRM I: 156–165. |
[20] | Grossman GM, Krueger AB (1993) Pollution and growth: what do we know? In: Goldin, I., Winters, L. (Eds.), The Economics of Sustainable Development, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. |
[21] |
Hilson G (2002) The environmental impact of small-scale gold mining in Ghana: identifying problems and possible solutions. Geogr J 168: 57–72. doi: 10.1111/1475-4959.00038
![]() |
[22] | Hussen AM (2005) Principles of environmental economics and sustainability: an integrated and ecological approach, In: Bouvier, R. (Ed.), Air Pollution and Per Capita Income, Working Paper Series 84. Political Economy Research Institute (PERI) Routledge, New York. |
[23] |
Johansen S (1988) Statistical Analysis of Cointegrating Vectors. J Econ Dyn Control 12: 231–54. doi: 10.1016/0165-1889(88)90041-3
![]() |
[24] |
Jalil A, Feridun M (2011) The impact of growth, energy and financial development on the environment in China: a cointegration analysis. Energy Econ 33: 284–291. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2010.10.003
![]() |
[25] |
Jebli MB, Belloumi M (2017) Investigation of the causal relationships between combustible renewables and waste consumption and CO2 emissions in the case of Tunisian maritime and rail transport. Renew Sust Energy Rev 71: 820–829. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2016.12.108
![]() |
[26] | Johansen S, Juselius K (1990) Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on Cointegration with Applications to the Demand for Money. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 52: 169–210. |
[27] | Kwakwa PA, Adu G (2016) Effects of income, energy consumption, and trade openness on carbon emissions in sub-Saharan Africa. J Energy Dev 41: 86–117. |
[28] | Kwakwa PA, Alhassan H, Adu G (2018) Effect of natural resources extraction on energy consumption and carbon dioxide emission in Ghana. MPRA Paper No. 85401. https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/85401/ |
[29] | Kwakwa PA, Arku FS, Aboagye S (2014) Environmental degradation effect of agricultural and industrial growth in Ghana. J Rural Industrial Dev 2: 1–8. |
[30] |
M'raihi R, Mraihi T, Harizi R, et al. (2015) Carbon emissions growth and road freight: Analysis of the influencing factors in Tunisia. Transp Policy 42: 121–129. doi: 10.1016/j.tranpol.2015.05.018
![]() |
[31] |
Maji IK, Habibullah MS, Saari MY (2017) Financial development and sectoral CO2 emissions in Malaysia. Environ Sci Pollut Res 24: 7160–7176. doi: 10.1007/s11356-016-8326-1
![]() |
[32] |
Nassani AA, Aldakhil AM, Abro MMQ, et al. (2017) Environmental Kuznets curve among BRICS countries: spot lightening finance, transport, energy and growth factors. J Clean Prod 154: 474–487. doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.04.025
![]() |
[33] |
Onafowora O, Owoye O (2014) Bounds testing approach to analysis of the environment Kuznets curve hypothesis. Energy Econ 44: 47–62. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2014.03.025
![]() |
[34] |
O'Neill BC, Liddle B, Jiang L, et al. (2012) Demographic change and carbon dioxide emissions. Lancet 380: 157–64. doi: 10.1016/S0140-6736(12)60958-1
![]() |
[35] |
Park JY (1992) Canonical cointegrating regressions. Econometrica 60: 119–43. doi: 10.2307/2951679
![]() |
[36] |
Pal D, Mitra SK (2017) The environmental Kuznets curve for carbon dioxide in India and China: Growth and pollution at crossroad. J Policy Model 39: 371–385. doi: 10.1016/j.jpolmod.2017.03.005
![]() |
[37] |
Phillips PC, Perron P (1988) Testing for a unit root in time series regression. Biometrika 75: 335–346. doi: 10.1093/biomet/75.2.335
![]() |
[38] |
Raupach MR, Marland G, Ciais P, et al. (2007) Global and regional drivers of accelerating CO2 emissions. Proc Natl Acad Sci 104: 10288–93. doi: 10.1073/pnas.0700609104
![]() |
[39] |
Sadorsky P (2011) Financial development and energy consumption in central and eastern European frontier economies. Energy Policy 39: 999–1006. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2010.11.034
![]() |
[40] |
Shahbaz M, Lean HH, Shabbir MS (2012) Environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis in Pakistan: cointegration and Granger causality. Renew Sust Energy Rev 16: 2947–2953. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2012.02.015
![]() |
[41] |
Sekrafi H, Sghaier A (2018) The effect of corruption on carbon dioxide emissions and energy consumption in Tunisia. PSU Res Rev 2: 81–95. doi: 10.1108/PRR-11-2016-0008
![]() |
[42] |
Sghari MBA, Hammami S (2016) Energy, pollution, and economic development in Tunisia. Energy Reports 2: 35–39. doi: 10.1016/j.egyr.2016.01.001
![]() |
[43] | Shahbaz M, Ferrer R, Shahzad SJH, et al. (2018) Is the tourism-economic growth nexus time-varying? Bootstrap rolling-window causality analysis for the top 10 tourist destinations. Appl Econ 50: 2678–2697. |
[44] |
Shahbaz M, Khan S, Tahir MI (2013) The dynamic links between energy consumption, economic growth, financial development and trade in China: fresh evidence from multivariate framework analysis. Energy Econ 40: 8–21. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2013.06.006
![]() |
[45] |
Sinha A, Shahbaz M (2018) Estimation of Environmental Kuznets Curve for CO2 emission: Role of renewable energy generation in India. Renew Energy 119: 703–711. doi: 10.1016/j.renene.2017.12.058
![]() |
[46] |
Sinha A, Shahbaz M, Balsalobre D (2017) Exploring the relationship between energy usage segregation and environmental degradation in N-11 countries. J Clean Prod 168: 1217–1229. doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.071
![]() |
[47] |
Sinha A, Sen S (2016) Atmospheric consequences of trade and human development: A case of BRIC countries. Atmos Pollut Res 7: 980–989. doi: 10.1016/j.apr.2016.06.003
![]() |
[48] |
Tamazian A, Chousa JP, Vadlamannati KC (2009) Does higher economic and financial development lead to environmental degradation: evidence from BRIC countries. Energy Policy 37: 246–253. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2008.08.025
![]() |
[49] |
Tiwari AK, Shahbaz M, Adnan Hye MQ et al. (2013) The environmental Kuznets curve and the role of coal consumption in India: cointegration and causality analysis in an open economy. Renew Sust Energy Rev 18: 519–527. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2012.10.031
![]() |
[50] | World Development Indicators (2017). Available from: http://databank.worldbank.org/data/reports.aspx?source=world-development-indicators. |
[51] |
Wang SS, Zhou DQ, Zhou P, et al. (2011) CO2 emissions, energyconsumption and economic growth in China: a panel data analysis. Energy Policy 39: 4870–5. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2011.06.032
![]() |
[52] | Xiong L, Qi S (2016) Financial development and carbon emissions in Chinese provinces: a spatial panel data analysis. Singap Econ Rev 10: 11–42. |
[53] | Yeh J-C, Liao C-H (2017) Impact of population and economic growth on carbon emissions in Taiwan using an analytic tool STIRPAT. Sust Environ Res 27: 41–48. |
[54] |
Ziaei SM (2015) Effects of financial development indicators on energy consumption and CO2 emissions of European, East Asian and Oceania countries. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 42: 752–759. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2014.10.085
![]() |
[55] | Zivot E, Andrews DWK (1992) Further Evidence on the Great Crash, the Oil-Price Shock, and the Unit-Root Hypothesis. J Bus Econ Stat 10: 251–270. |
1. | E. Numfor, S. Bhattacharya, S. Lenhart, M. Martcheva, S. Anita, N. Hritonenko, G. Marinoschi, A. Swierniak, Optimal Control in Coupled Within-host and Between-host Models, 2014, 9, 0973-5348, 171, 10.1051/mmnp/20149411 | |
2. | F. Nyabadza, Z. Mukandavire, S.D. Hove-Musekwa, Modelling the HIV/AIDS epidemic trends in South Africa: Insights from a simple mathematical model, 2011, 12, 14681218, 2091, 10.1016/j.nonrwa.2010.12.024 | |
3. | Farai Nyabadza, ON THE COMPLEXITIES OF MODELING HIV/AIDS IN SOUTHERN AFRICA, 2008, 13, 1392-6292, 539, 10.3846/1392-6292.2008.13.539-552 | |
4. | Marilyn Ronoh, Faraimunashe Chirove, Josephine Wairimu, Wandera Ogana, Gabriela Paz-Bailey, Evidence-based modeling of combination control on Kenyan youth HIV/AIDS dynamics, 2020, 15, 1932-6203, e0242491, 10.1371/journal.pone.0242491 | |
5. | C. S. Bornaa, Baba Seidu, M. I. Daabo, Mathematical Analysis of Rabies Infection, 2020, 2020, 1110-757X, 1, 10.1155/2020/1804270 | |
6. | Tunde T. Yusuf, Francis Benyah, Optimal strategy for controlling the spread of HIV/AIDS disease: a case study of South Africa, 2012, 6, 1751-3758, 475, 10.1080/17513758.2011.628700 | |
7. | O. Sharomi, A.B. Gumel, Dynamical analysis of a multi-strain model of HIV in the presence of anti-retroviral drugs, 2008, 2, 1751-3758, 323, 10.1080/17513750701775599 | |
8. | Naveen K Vaidya, Jianhong Wu, HIV epidemic in Far-Western Nepal: effect of seasonal labor migration to India, 2011, 11, 1471-2458, 10.1186/1471-2458-11-310 | |
9. | Symon Chibaya, Moatlhodi Kgosimore, Estomih S. Massawe, Mathematical analysis of drug resistance in vertical transmission of HIV/AIDS, 2013, 03, 2165-7459, 139, 10.4236/ojepi.2013.33021 | |
10. | Hai-Feng Huo, Li-Na Gu, Hong Xiang, MODELLING AND ANALYSIS OF AN HIV/AIDS MODEL WITH DIFFERENT WINDOW PERIOD AND TREATMENT, 2021, 11, 2156-907X, 1927, 10.11948/20200279 | |
11. | A. Alla Hamou, E. Azroul, S. L'Kima, The effect of migration on the transmission of HIV/AIDS using a fractional model: Local and global dynamics and numerical simulations, 2024, 0170-4214, 10.1002/mma.9946 | |
12. | A. Alla Hamou, E. Azroul, S. L’kima, Fractional order modeling of parasite-produced marine diseases with memory effect, 2024, 2363-6203, 10.1007/s40808-024-02106-z |