Loading [MathJax]/jax/element/mml/optable/BasicLatin.js
Review Special Issues

Disruption of the Covid-19 pandemic on the agri-food sector: A systematic review of its implications in post-pandemic and future of food security

  • Received: 11 September 2023 Revised: 20 December 2023 Accepted: 28 December 2023 Published: 22 January 2024
  • The unprecedented challenges posed by the global COVID-19 pandemic have significantly impacted various sectors, with the agri-food system proving especially vulnerable to disruptions. Ensuring food security and bolstering the resilience of agri-food systems in the aftermath of the pandemic has emerged as a crucial concern. Utilizing the PRISMA protocol, this systematic literature review systematically searched relevant databases and repositories using specific keywords related to agri-food security in the pre and post-pandemic context. The final review incorporated 37 articles. The results revealed that the pandemic profoundly impacted all facets of the agri-food sector, particularly agri-food systems. Despite this, we identified several measures that were implemented or recommended to mitigate disruptions caused by the pandemic and ensure the resilience of the agri-food sector for future similar events. Robust policy measures, promotion of urban agriculture, support for small-scale farmers, enhancement of the international market, technological innovations, collaborations, research and development, and the promotion of novel foods were all highlighted as crucial resilience measures. Policymakers, researchers, and stakeholders are urged to adopt a comprehensive approach encompassing these measures to build a resilient and secure food future in the post-pandemic era.

    Citation: Monsuru Adekunle Salisu, Che Rus Ridzwan, Yusuf Opeyemi Oyebamiji, Norhanizan Usaizan, Abiodun Emmanuel Abioye, Idris Fadheelah Biola, Nurudeen Babatunde Bamiro, Ahmed Kayode Omowunmi, Hussain Luqman. Disruption of the Covid-19 pandemic on the agri-food sector: A systematic review of its implications in post-pandemic and future of food security[J]. AIMS Agriculture and Food, 2024, 9(1): 148-168. doi: 10.3934/agrfood.2024009

    Related Papers:

    [1] Zongqi Sun, Peng Yang, Jing Wu, Yunpeng Fan . The defined contribution pension plan after retirement under the criterion of a revised loss considering the economic situation. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(2): 4749-4761. doi: 10.3934/math.2024229
    [2] Yinghui Dong, Chengjin Tang, Chunrong Hua . Optimal investment of DC pension plan under a joint VaR-ES constraint. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(1): 2084-2104. doi: 10.3934/math.2024104
    [3] Wanlu Zhang, Hui Meng . Robust optimal investment-reinsurance strategies with the preferred reinsurance level of reinsurer. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(6): 10024-10051. doi: 10.3934/math.2022559
    [4] Chengjin Tang, Jiahao Guo, Yinghui Dong . Optimal investment based on performance measure with a stochastic benchmark. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(2): 2750-2770. doi: 10.3934/math.2025129
    [5] Peng Yang . Robust optimal reinsurance-investment problem for n competitive and cooperative insurers under ambiguity aversion. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(10): 25131-25163. doi: 10.3934/math.20231283
    [6] Ling Chen, Xiang Hu, Mi Chen . Optimal investment and reinsurance for the insurer and reinsurer with the joint exponential utility under the CEV model. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(7): 15383-15410. doi: 10.3934/math.2023786
    [7] Wuyuan Jiang, Zechao Miao, Jun Liu . Optimal investment and reinsurance for the insurer and reinsurer with the joint exponential utility. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(12): 35181-35217. doi: 10.3934/math.20241672
    [8] Li Deng, Zhichao Chen . Optimal dividends in a discrete-time dual risk model with stochastic expenses. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(11): 31696-31720. doi: 10.3934/math.20241524
    [9] Xiaoyi Tang, Wei Liu, Wanyin Wu, Yijun Hu . An optimal investment strategy for DC pension plans with costs and the return of premium clauses under the CEV model. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(8): 21731-21754. doi: 10.3934/math.20241057
    [10] Fei Yu . Multiperiod distributionally robust portfolio selection with regime-switching under CVaR risk measures. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(4): 9974-10001. doi: 10.3934/math.2025456
  • The unprecedented challenges posed by the global COVID-19 pandemic have significantly impacted various sectors, with the agri-food system proving especially vulnerable to disruptions. Ensuring food security and bolstering the resilience of agri-food systems in the aftermath of the pandemic has emerged as a crucial concern. Utilizing the PRISMA protocol, this systematic literature review systematically searched relevant databases and repositories using specific keywords related to agri-food security in the pre and post-pandemic context. The final review incorporated 37 articles. The results revealed that the pandemic profoundly impacted all facets of the agri-food sector, particularly agri-food systems. Despite this, we identified several measures that were implemented or recommended to mitigate disruptions caused by the pandemic and ensure the resilience of the agri-food sector for future similar events. Robust policy measures, promotion of urban agriculture, support for small-scale farmers, enhancement of the international market, technological innovations, collaborations, research and development, and the promotion of novel foods were all highlighted as crucial resilience measures. Policymakers, researchers, and stakeholders are urged to adopt a comprehensive approach encompassing these measures to build a resilient and secure food future in the post-pandemic era.



    The data released in the "China Aging Report 2024" shows that the trend of aging in China is becoming more evident. In 2000, the population aged 65 and above in China accounted for 7%, and the country started to transition into an aging society. During the year 2021, the share of the population aged 65 and above exceeded 14%, and the country began to transition into a significantly aging society; in 2022 and 2023, the population aged 65 and above accounted for 14.9% and 15.4%, respectively. According to the "China Population Forecast Report 2023" by Yuwa Population, China is predicted to enter a super aging society with an aging proportion accounting for more than 20% around 2030, then continuing to rise rapidly to approximately 37.4% in 2060, and increasing again to about 46% in 2080. After a period of stabilization, almost half of China's total population of 800 million will be elderly. As the aging trend intensifies, the development of pension insurance will be continuously promoted. A report by Xinhua pointed out that, at the end of March 2024, 1.07 billion people had participated in China's basic pension insurance, an increase of 14.34 million compared with that in the same period last year. After years of stable development, China has established the world's largest pension insurance system, and diverse types of pension plans have been developed for individuals to engage in the pension insurance scheme.

    According to the approach of contribution and benefit, pension plans can be classified into two types: defined benefit (DB) and defined contribution (DC) plans. In particular, the former refers to a pension scheme in which the contributions are established based on a predetermined benefit, with the associated risks assumed by the insurance company. The latter refers to a pension scheme that involves a set contribution amount, but the retirement benefits may be modified based on the performance of the venture capital market. In this case, both market risk and longevity risk are assumed by the policyholder. Since this type of pension plan is beneficial for fund managers' investment management and can achieve the preservation and appreciation of pension funds, it is regarded as the main type of pension plan both domestically and internationally [1].

    In the current pension account management, most pension plans require charging a certain amount of management fees. Murthi [2] conducted a macro-level analysis of the management fees of UK pension schemes prior to 1999 and discovered that pension management fees could reduce the wealth value of pension accounts by over 40%. However, through a macro study on the comprehensive data of 13 countries worldwide before 2000, Whitehouse [3] found that the terminal wealth of individual pension accounts can be increased by using certain investment portfolios and controlling pension management fees. Despite the contrasting conclusions, it can still be observed that management fees have a dynamic impact on the entire process of pension accounts. Both studies only conducted macroeconomic analyses of data from different countries using macroeconomic approaches and lacked the application of mathematical finance methods to uncover the quantitative variations in the dynamic relationship between management fees and individual pension accounts. In recent years, scholars have started investigating the issue of pension management fees from the perspective of mathematical finance, such as in literature [4,5,6,7,8,9,10]. Li et al. [11] studied the equivalent management cost of DC pension accounts based on two different charging methods of management fees: asset wealth ratio and salary ratio. Deng [12] investigated the DC pension plan with two types of management costs under the Heston model. Lai et al. [13] considered the management cost of DC pension plans under the premium return clause. Lv et al. [14] studied the optimal portfolio problem of single management fees and mixed charges (charging both management fees and performance fees) of DC pension under the loss aversion criterion.

    In the previously mentioned research on DC pension plans, investigations were limited to two prevalent optimization criteria: the utility function and mean-variance. The utility function is one of the earliest optimization criteria. Its advantage lies in the simple structure of the value function, which facilitates mathematical derivation and calculation. However, this approach focuses only on the benefits at the investment's endpoint while overlooking the associated risks at that moment. The mean-variance criterion can overcome this limitation by considering both the benefits and risks at the end moment, but like the utility criterion, it lacks control of the overall process risk. Given the special livelihood attributes of pension funds, it is necessary to avoid significant losses in pension accounts throughout the venture investment process. In the past few years, minimizing the expected squared loss has increasingly become a novel optimization criterion in pension planning matters.

    In practice, the criterion of minimizing the expected square loss aims to minimize the expected square of the distinction between the actual wealth level and the target wealth level, and it provides a more precise evaluation of the substantial losses within pension accounts. It was initially introduced into the pension plan by Vigna and Habermans [15]. However, it is a risk-averse criterion, which contradicts the existing operational philosophy that insurance companies favor profits. Later, Habermans and Vigna [16] proposed a modified expectation squared loss criterion that considers loss aversion and earning preference based on this criterion, and they studied the DC pension plan with multidimensional assets based on different risk measures. This standard leverages a positive penalty factor to hedge risks by treating the portion of wealth exceeding the expectation as profit and the portion below the expectation as risk. When the penalty coefficient is set to zero, it becomes the general expected square loss criterion, and in this case, managers are generally called risk-averse. When this coefficient is above zero, managers are generally called surplus preference. Under this criterion, Sun Jingyun et al. [6] considered the situation where participants of DC pension have random salaries; Sun Jingyun et al. [7] also considered the situation with multidimensional interdependent risks. Different from the above research conducted only in the preretirement fund accumulation stage, Sun et al. [17] investigated the pension plan under the modified expectation squared loss criterion in the post-retirement stage. However, the abovementioned literature [6,7,15,16,17] did not consider the management costs of the fund account.

    This paper studies the management cost of the DC pension plan under the modified expectation squared loss criterion, the innovations are as follows:

    1) By integrating the penalty coefficient, the general criterion of square loss is modified into a new optimization criterion that considers both loss aversion and earning preference, and the goal of accurately identifying earnings and risks is achieved to a certain extent.

    2) Under the modified expectation square loss criterion, this paper considers the pension plan with participants having random salaries in the preretirement stage and receiving management fees proportionally to the wealth of the fund account, assuming a diffusion model with a drift term of the pension payment rate. Finally, the impact of the change in the management fee rate on the optimal investment strategy and the minimum loss function is compared, and some management suggestions are provided.

    In our study, it is assumed that every stochastic process is established within a complete probability space (Ω,{Ft}t[0,T],P). The σ-filtration flow {Ft}0tT is both complete and right-continuous. {Ft}t[0,T] represents the aggregate of all market information at time t, and every stochastic process functions as an adapted process in (Ω,{Ft}t[0,T],P). T stands for a limited duration, indicating both the investment period for pensions and the benefit period for participants' pensions. In addition, it is assumed that continuous trading and assets can be divided without restriction, there are no frictions involved, self-financing conditions can be applied, and arbitrage opportunities do not exist.

    ω0, ω0+T, and ω0+Td (in units of years) respectively denote the age at which the participant enters the pension plan, the retirement age, and the time when the pension in the life table stops to pay. T also represents the duration of pension investment, Td denotes the stop time in the pension plan, and the period of the subsequent pension accumulation stage (in units of years) satisfies 0tT. In the numerical example section, the settings of these parameter values refer to the "The China Life Insurance Industry Experience Life Table (2010-2013)", which was published by the China Insurance Regulatory Commission on December 21, 2016.

    Fund managers of pension insurance companies operate pension accounts through assert portfolios to minimize losses at the investment termination time ω0+T. The following presents the price process of investment assets, the wealth process, and the loss function.

    The insurance firm deducts a specific percentage π(t,x) of the wealth from participants' pension fund accounts to allocate toward high-risk investments, like stocks. The price P(t) (measured in tens of thousands of yuan) follows a diffusion process.

    dP(t)=P(t)(μdt+σdB1(t)),

    Here, μ means the annual expected investment return for each unit of risk asset; σ stands for the annual price volatility per unit of risk asset; B1(t) represents the standard Brownian motion, which indicates the stochastic elements influencing the value of risky assets. The insurance company will invest the remaining portion of wealth from the fund account in a zero-risk asset (e.g., a savings account), for which the price P0(t) (measured in tens of thousands of yuan) satisfies

    dP0(t)=P0(t)r0dt,

    where r0 represents the yearly interest rate of a zero-risk asset. This paper operates under the assumption that the stochastic wage payment rate is L(t) (in units of ten thousand yuan) of the participant's random salary before retirement conforms to the following diffusion process:

    dL(t)=L(t)[(μb+ξr0)dt+σbdB2(t)],L(0)=l0.

    Here, (μb+ξr0) denotes the growth rate of the stochastic wages, μb represents the basic growth rate of the wages, ξr0 stands for the growth rate of the pension in relation to the general economic context, and ξ(>0) denotes the growth rate coefficient pertaining to the general economic context. When the economic situation is favorable (r0 increases), the increase in the pension payment rate is large; when the economic situation is poor (r0 decreases), the increase in the pension payment rate is small. B2(t) represents a standard Brownian motion, which indicates stochastic elements that influence the pension payout rate. Clearly, random pension payments are closely related to the capital market. This paper assumes that dB1(t),dB2(t)=ρdt, where ρ is the correlation coefficient. The contribution to pension is determined by the proportion of wages q, and the contribution rate is qL(t). The fund company charges a certain percentage of management fees based on the wealth of the fund account. The annual management rate is δ. At the time t, the wealth of the fund account is X(t) (measured in tens of thousands of yuan). It can be inferred from the above assumptions that

    dX(t)=X(t)π(t,x)(μdt+σdB1(t))+X(t)(1π(t,x))r0dt+qL(t)dtδX(t)dt,ω0tω0+T

    i.e.,

    dX(t)=[X(t)π(t,x)(μr0)+X(t)(r0δ)+qL(t)]dt+X(t)π(t,x)σdB1(t),X(0)=x0. (1)

    Definition 1. Define π(t,x) as the unique strong solution to equation (1). If π(t,x) is sequentially measurable by{Ft}t[0,T] and there is E[0π2(t,x)dt]<a.e for xR+, then π(t,x) is referred to as the allowable strategy. The set Π composed of all permissive policies is called the permissive policy set.

    Definition 2. Let R(t,Xπ(t))=(G(t)X(t))2+η(G(t)X(t)) be the revenue recovery loss function, where G(t) represents the expected wealth level of the fund account at the moment, η(0) is the correction coefficient, and the deviation between the expected wealth level and the actual wealth level is denoted as G(t)X(t).

    If η>0, when the actual wealth level X(t) exceeds the expected wealth level G(t), the correction coefficients will reduce the loss of misjudgment and provide compensation for the loss of item (G(t)X(t))2; when the actual wealth level X(t) is lower than the expected wealth level G(t), the correction coefficient will increase the penalty for the loss. η=0 is the case of a general square loss function in literature [15], and it can be seen that this paper presents an improvement of the loss function. Therefore, according to the size relationship between η and 0, pension fund managers can be classified into risk-averse type (η=0) and earning preference type (η>0). This paper conducts research from the perspective of earning preference-type managers.

    Definition 3. For pairs of πΠ and let Jπ(t,x,l)=E[R(T,Xπ(T))|X(t)=x,L(t)=l] be the preference function, V(t,x,l)=min is the value function or the minimum loss function.

    As a result, the problem considered in this study may be reduced to the following stochastic optimal control problem:

    \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {V(t, x, l) = \mathop {\min }\limits_{\pi \in \Pi } {J^\pi }(t, x, l), } \\ {dX(t) = [X(t)\pi (t, x)(\mu + {r_0}) - X(t)({r_0} + \delta ) + qL(t)]dt + X(t)\pi (t, x)\sigma d{B_1}(t) - L(t){\sigma _b}d{B_1}(t).} \end{array}} \right. (2)

    Solution to the problem

    Differentiate the valued function V(t.x, l) as follows

    {\rm{А}}^{\pi }V(t, x, l) = {V}_{t}+[x\pi (\mu -{r}_{0})+x({r}_{0}-\delta )+ql]{V}_{x}+\frac{1}{2}{x}^{2}{\pi }^{2}{\sigma }^{2}{V}_{xx}+({\mu }_{b}+\xi {r}_{0})l{V}_{l}+\frac{1}{2}{l}^{2}{\sigma }_{b}{}^{2}{V}_{ll}+x\pi \sigma l{\sigma }_{b}\rho {V}_{xl} ,

    By applying the principle of stochastic optimal control, Eq (2) is rewritten as the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation.

    \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\mathop {\inf }\limits_{\pi \in \Pi } \{ {\mathcal{A}^\pi }V(t.x, l)\} = 0, } \\ {V(T, X(T), L(T)) = {{(G(T) - X(T))}^2} + \eta (G(T) - X(T)).} \end{array}} \right. (3)

    Equation (3) can be solved by using the test theorem similar to Theorem 1 in literature [17], and the solving process will not be repeated here. Assume the equation is something like

    V(t, x, l) = {A_1}(t){x^2} + {A_2}(t)x + {A_3}(t){l^2} + {A_4}(t)l + A{}_5(t)xl + {A_6}(t) (4)

    Combined with the boundary condition V(T, X(T), L(T)) = {(G(T) - X(T))^2} + \eta (G(T) - X(T)) of Eq (3), it is easy to obtain

    {A_1}(T) = 1 , {A_2}(T) = - (2G(T) + \eta ) , {A_3}(T) = 0 , {A_4}(T) = 0 , {A_5}(T) = 0 , {A_6}(T) = {G^2}(T) + \eta G(T) . (5)

    The partial derivative with respect to V(t, x, l) is

    {V_t} = {A_1}^\prime (t){x^2} + {A_2}^\prime (t)x + {A_3}^\prime (t){l^2} + {A_4}^\prime (t)l + A{{}_5^\prime }(t)xl + {A'_6}(t) ,
    {V_x} = 2{A_1}(t)x + {A_2}(t) + A{}_5(t)l , {V_{xx}} = 2{A_1}(t) , {V_{xl}} = {A_5}(t) ,
    {V_l} = 2{A_3}(t)l + {A_4}(t) + A{}_5(t)x , {V_{ll}} = 2{A_3}(t) .

    By substituting the aforementioned partial derivatives into Eq (3) and applying the first-order optimal condition, we obtain

    {\pi ^ * }(t, x) = - \frac{{(\mu - {r_0})(2{A_1}(t)x + {A_2}(t) + A{}_5(t)l) + \sigma l{\sigma _b}\rho {A_5}(t)}}{{2x{\sigma ^2}{A_1}(t)}} (6)

    Then, substitute {\pi ^ * }(t, x) into Eq (3) and sort it out

    \begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\{ {A_1}^\prime (t) + [2({r_0} - \delta ) - \frac{{{{(\mu - {r_0})}^2}}}{{{\sigma ^2}}}]{A_1}(t)\} {x^2} + \{ {A_2}^\prime (t) + [({r_0} - \delta ) - \frac{{{{(\mu - {r_0})}^2}}}{{{\sigma ^2}}}]{A_2}(t)\} x}\\ {+ \{ {A_3}^\prime (t) + [2({\mu _b} + \xi {r_0}) + \sigma _b^2]{A_3}(t) - \frac{1}{4}{(\frac{{\mu - {r_0}}}{\sigma } + {\sigma _b}\rho )^2}\frac{{{A_5}^2(t)}}{{{A_1}(t)}} + q{A_5}(t)\} {l^2}}\\ {+ \{ {A_4}^\prime (t) + ({\mu _b} + \xi {r_0}){A_4}(t) - \frac{1}{2}[\frac{{{{(\mu - {r_0})}^2}}}{{{\sigma ^2}}} + {\sigma _b}\rho \frac{{\mu - {r_0}}}{\sigma }]\frac{{{A_2}(t){A_5}(t)}}{{{A_1}(t)}} + q{A_2}(t)\} l}\\ {+ \{ {A_5}^\prime (t) + [({\mu _b} + \xi {r_0}) + ({r_0} - \delta ) - \frac{{{{(\mu - {r_0})}^2}}}{{{\sigma ^2}}} - {\sigma _b}\rho \frac{{\mu - {r_0}}}{\sigma }]{A_5}(t) + 2q{A_1}(t)\} xl}\\ {+ [{A_6}^\prime (t) - \frac{1}{4}\frac{{{{(\mu - {r_0})}^2}}}{{{\sigma ^2}}}\frac{{{A_2}^2(t)}}{{{A_1}(t)}}] = 0 .} \end{array}

    Given the arbitrary nature of x and l , the subsequent differential equations can be obtained

    \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {A}_{1}{}^{\prime }(t)+[2({r}_{0}-\delta )-\frac{{(\mu -{r}_{0})}^{2}}{{\sigma }^{2}}]{A}_{1}(t) = 0, \\ {A}_{1}(T) = 1\rm{,}\end{array}} \right. (7)
    \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{A_2}^\prime (t) + [({r_0} - \delta ) - \frac{{{{(\mu - {r_0})}^2}}}{{{\sigma ^2}}}]{A_2}(t) = 0, } \\ {{A_2}(T) = - (2G(T) + \eta ), } \end{array}} \right. (8)
    \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{A_3}^\prime (t) + [2({\mu _b} + \xi {r_0}) + \sigma _b^2]{A_3}(t) - \frac{1}{4}{{(\frac{{\mu - {r_0}}}{\sigma } + {\sigma _b}\rho )}^2}\frac{{{A_5}^2(t)}}{{{A_1}(t)}} + q{A_5}(t) = 0, } \\ {{A_3}(T) = 0, } \end{array}} \right. (9)
    \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{A_4}^\prime (t) + ({\mu _b} + \xi {r_0}){A_4}(t) - \frac{1}{2}[\frac{{{{(\mu - {r_0})}^2}}}{{{\sigma ^2}}} + {\sigma _b}\rho \frac{{\mu - {r_0}}}{\sigma }]\frac{{{A_2}(t){A_5}(t)}}{{{A_1}(t)}} + q{A_2}(t) = 0, } \\ {{A_4}(T) = 0, } \end{array}} \right. (10)
    \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{A_5}^\prime (t) + [({\mu _b} + \xi {r_0}) + ({r_0} - \delta ) - \frac{{{{(\mu - {r_0})}^2}}}{{{\sigma ^2}}} - {\sigma _b}\rho \frac{{\mu - {r_0}}}{\sigma }]{A_5}(t) + 2q{A_1}(t) = 0, } \\ {{A_5}(T) = 0, } \end{array}} \right. (11)
    \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {A}_{6}{}^{\prime }(t)-\frac{1}{4}\frac{{(\mu -{r}_{0})}^{2}}{{\sigma }^{2}}\frac{{A}_{2}{}^{2}(t)}{{A}_{1}(t)} = 0, \\ {A}_{6}(T) = {G}^{2}(T)+\eta G(T)\rm{,}\end{array}} \right. (12)
    V(t, x, l) = {A_1}(t){x^2} + {A_2}(t)x + {A_3}(t){l^2} + {A_4}(t)l + A{}_5(t)xl + {A_6}(t)

    By introducing an initial substitution with {k_1} = \frac{{\mu - {r_0}}}{\sigma } , {k_2} = {r_0} - \delta , {k_3} = {\mu _b} + \xi {r_0} , and {k_4} = {\sigma _b}\rho , the differential equations can be solved in the following manner:

    {A_1}(t) = {e^{(k_1^2 - 2{k_2})(t - T)}} (13)
    {A_2}(t) = - (2G(T) + \eta ){e^{({k_1}^2 - {k_2})(t - T)}} (14)
    {A_3}(t) = \frac{{{q^2}{e^{(2{k_3} + {\sigma _b}^2)(T - t)}}}}{{{{({k_2} - {k_3} + {k_1}{k_4})}^2}}}[\frac{{{k_1}^2 + 2{k_1}{k_4} + {k_4}^2}}{{{k_1}^2 + 2{k_1}{k_4} + {\sigma _b}^2}}({e^{({k_1}^2 + 2{k_1}{k_4} + {\sigma _b}^2)(t - T)}} - 1) + \frac{{2{k_2} - 2{k_3} - 2{k_1}^2 - 2{k_4}^2 - 2{k_1}{k_4}}}{{{k_1}^2 - {k_2} + {k_3} + {k_1}{k_4} + {\sigma _b}^2}}({e^{({k_1}^2 - {k_2} + {k_3} + {k_1}{k_4} + {\sigma _b}^2)(t - T)}} - 1)\\ \;\;\;\;\;\;\;\;\;+ \frac{{{k_1}^2 - 2{k_2} + 2{k_3} + {k_4}^2}}{{{k_1}^2 - 2{k_2} + 2{k_3} + {\sigma _b}^2}}({e^{({k_1}^2 - 2{k_2} + 2{k_3} + {\sigma _b}^2)(t - T)}} - 1)] (15)
    {A_4}(t) = \frac{{q(2G(T) + \eta )}}{{{k_2} - {k_3} + {k_1}{k_4}}}({e^{({k_1}^2 + {k_1}{k_4} - {k_3})(t - T)}} - {e^{({k_1}^2 - {k_2})(t - T)}}) (16)
    {A_5}(t) = \frac{{2q}}{{{k_2} - {k_3} + {k_1}{k_4}}}{e^{({k_1}^2 - 2{k_2})(t - T)}}(1 - {e^{({k_2} - {k_3} + {k_1}{k_4})(t - T)}}) (17)
    {A_6}(t) = \frac{1}{4}{(2G(T) + \eta )^2}({e^{{k_1}^2(t - T)}} - 1) + ({G^2}(T) + \eta G(T)) (18)

    At this point, by substituting the above solutions into Eqs (6) and (4), the optimal investment strategy {\pi ^ * }(t, x) and the value function V(t, x, l) can be explicitly solved, which will not be repeated here.

    First, let's ascertain the investment objective G(T) of the pension account at the end of the investment period. Assume that upon the participant's retirement, the present value of the life annuity paid per unit is G(T) = ka(T) , where a(T) is the annuity payment rate. To facilitate the calculation, the commonly used death force model {\rm{De Moivre}} is used. Then, the survival probability of {\omega _0} + s at the moment after retirement is {}_{s - T}{P_{{\omega _0} + T}} = \frac{{{T_d} - s}}{{{\omega _0} + {T_d}}} , T \leqslant s \leqslant {T_d} . To ensure that the participants' annuities maintain the same purchasing power after retirement, this paper considers the existence of inflation and assumes that the inflation rate is i , then

    a(T) = \int_T^{{T_d}} {{}_{s - T}{P_{{\omega _0} + T}}} {e^{i(s - T)}}{e^{ - {r_0}(s - T)}}ds = \frac{{{T_d} - T}}{{({r_0} - i)({\omega _0} + {T_d})}} + \frac{1}{{{{({r_0} - i)}^2}({\omega _0} + {T_d})}}({e^{(i - {r_0})({T_d} - T)}} - 1) (19)

    The adjusted closing price data of the Power Construction Corporation of China (601669.SH) on 425 valid working days from January 1, 2021 to September 30, 2022 was obtained from the Tushare website and were utilized as research samples after the elimination of null values and outliers. After further processing of the data, the annual average return rate and the annual return volatility of the stock of Power China was calculated to be \mu {\rm{ = 0}}{\rm{.342865}} and \sigma {\rm{ = 0}}{\rm{.479892}} , respectively. In the following, by taking the investment in Power Construction of China as an example, the effect of several important parameters on the optimal investment strategy {\pi ^ * }(0, {x_0}) is investigated, the minimum loss function V(0, {x_0}, l{}_0) at the initial time t{\rm{ = 0}} of the pension plan is analyzed using six numerical examples, and the economic importance is discussed. Then, the rationality of the modeling and results is verified, and several management suggestions are provided. First, the following basic parameters are given.

    Table 1.  Basic parameters.
    {\omega _0} T {T_d} {r_0} i q {\mu _b} {\sigma _b} \xi {l_0} \rho
    30 30 75 0.03 0.02 0.1 0.02 0.01 0.3 6 0.75

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    According to the parameters provided above, it is easy to calculate a(T) = 7.03 .

    Numerical examples 1. The annual payment rate of pension annuity after retirement is set as k = {\rm{8}} million yuan per year, the starting salary level of pension plan participants is set as {l_0}{\rm{ = 6}} million yuan per year, and the penalty coefficient is set as \eta {\rm{ = 6}}{\rm{.0}} . Subsequently, by employing {\rm{MATLAB}} software, the functional relationship between the initial wealth {x_0} , the wealth management rate \delta of the pension account, and the optimal investment {\pi ^ * }(0, {x_0}) can be obtained, as illustrated in Figure 1.

    Figure 1.  The functional relationship between the initial wealth {x_0} , the management rate \delta , and the optimal investment {\pi ^ * }(0, {x_0}) .

    It can be observed from Figure 1:

    1) The more sufficient the initial wealth {x_0} , the lower the investment proportion of the risky assets, the more easily the final investment objective can be achieved, which aligns with individuals' basic comprehension;

    2) While the wealth management rate \delta of the pension account increases, the wealth level of the pension account declines. To fulfill the determined terminal wealth goal, it is essential to raise the share of risky assets to obtain greater returns, which also agrees with people's fundamental understanding.

    Numerical examples 2. The annual payment rate of pension annuity after retirement is as k = {\rm{8}} million yuan per year, the starting salary level of pension plan participants is set as {l_0}{\rm{ = 6}} million yuan per year, and the wealth at the beginning time t{\rm{ = 0}} of the pension account is set as {x_0} = 1.0 million yuan. Then, the functional relationship between the penalty coefficient \eta , the wealth management rate \delta and the optimal investment {\pi ^ * }(0, {x_0}) may be obtained through the utilization of {\rm{MATLAB}} , as presented in Figure 2.

    Figure 2.  The functional relationship among the wealth management fee \delta , the penalty coefficient \eta and the optimal investment strategy {\pi ^ * }(0, {x_0}) .

    In Figure 2, when \eta increases, {\pi ^ * }(0, {x_0}) also increases, which indicates that under more precise risk identification criteria, investors typically transition from risk-averse conservative investors to so-called aggressive investors with earning preference, and the investment proportion will rise to obtain more wealth to fulfill the ultimate wealth goal. This is consistent with people's general comprehension.

    Numerical examples 3. The annual payment rate of pension annuity after retirement is set as k = {\rm{8}} million yuan per year, the starting salary level of pension plan participants is set as {l_0}{\rm{ = 6}} million yuan per year, and the penalty coefficient is set as \eta {\rm{ = 7}}{\rm{.8}} . Then, the relationship between the wealth management rate \delta , the initial wealth {x_0} of the pension account, and the function V(0, {x_0}, {l_0}) of the minimum loss function can be obtained by using {\rm{MATLAB}} , as shown in Figure 3.

    Figure 3.  The functional relationship between the wealth management fee \delta , the initial wealth {x_0} of the pension account, and the minimum loss function V(0, {x_0}, {l_0}) .

    It can be seen from Figure 3 that a relatively sufficient initial reserve of the account is conducive to reducing the minimum loss. Therefore, if possible, the manager should provide a relatively sufficient reserve of the pension account. Meanwhile, charging a certain amount of wealth management fees can help to reduce the minimum loss, which is beneficial for risk management.

    Numerical examples 4. The annual payment rate of pension annuity after retirement is set as k = {\rm{8}} million yuan per year, the starting salary level of pension plan participants is set as {l_0}{\rm{ = 6}} million yuan per year, and the initial wealth of the pension account at the starting moment is set as {x_0}{\rm{ = 1}}{\rm{.5}} million yuan. Then, the functional relationship between the wealth management rate \delta , the penalty coefficient \eta , and the minimum loss function V(0, {x_0}, {l_0}) can be obtained by using {\rm{MATLAB}} , as demonstrated in Figure 4.

    Figure 4.  The functional relationship between the wealth management fee \delta , the penalty coefficient \eta , and the minimum loss function V(0, {x_0}, {l_0}) .

    It can be observed from Figure 4 that a larger penalty coefficient can be used to measure a smaller minimum loss. Therefore, introducing the penalty coefficient is conducive to accurately measuring the risk. However, the aggressive managers with earning preference should select an appropriate penalty coefficient for risk measurement and avoid choosing an excessively large penalty coefficient to measure risks unrestricted, so as to prevent risks from being overly reduced in form, leading to aggressive adverse consequences.

    Numerical examples 5. With the annual wealth rate set to \delta {\rm{ = 0}}{\rm{.0005}} and the penalty coefficient of the pension account set to \eta {\rm{ = 6}}{\rm{.0}} , the functional relationship among {x_0} , the annual pension payment rate k and {\pi ^ * }(0, {x_0}) may be obtained through the utilization of {\rm{MATLAB}} , as illustrated in Figure 5.

    Figure 5.  The functional relationship between the initial wealth {x_0} , the annual pension payment rate k , and the optimal investment {\pi ^ * }(0, {x_0}) .

    It can be seen from Figure 5 that a larger pension payment rate leads to a decrease in the wealth of the pension account, and it is inevitable to increase risky investment to achieve the terminal target wealth.

    Numerical examples 6. Under the annual wealth rate \delta {\rm{ = 0}}{\rm{.0005}} , the penalty coefficient \eta {\rm{ = 6}}{\rm{.0}} , and the penalty coefficient \eta {\rm{ = 7}}{\rm{.8}} , the functional relationship between the annual pension payment rate k , the initial wealth {x_0} of the fund account, and the minimum loss function V(0, {x_0}, {l_0}) can be obtained by using {\rm{MATLAB}} , as illustrated in Figure 6.

    Figure 6.  The functional relationship between the pension annual payment rate k , the initial fund account wealth {x_0} , and the minimum loss function V(0, {x_0}, {l_0}) .

    As shown in Figure 6, the increase in the pension annual payout rate k will cause the minimum loss to increase, so it is necessary to select an appropriate pension annual payout rate to facilitate risk control.

    By increasing the penalty coefficient, this paper modifies the general square loss criterion into a novel criterion to identify risks and returns more precisely. Then, under this criterion, this study investigates the optimal portfolio for the defined contribution pensions with wealth management fees before retirement. The research discovers that charging wealth management fees will affect the optimal investment strategy and the minimum loss function. As the wealth management fee increases, the minimum loss function will decline to a certain extent. Therefore, imposing certain wealth management fees helps to lower the risk level. As the wealth management fee rises, so does the optimal investment strategy. This is because the wealth level of the pension account is decreased due to the increase in management fees, and the fund manager needs to add a certain amount of risky investment to achieve the target wealth at the terminal.

    Meanwhile, it is found that the increase in the penalty coefficient also affects the minimum loss function and the optimal investment strategy. Under the modified squared loss criterion with a larger penalty coefficient, fund managers typically transition from conservative risk-averse managers to aggressive ones with earning preferences. Due to the correct identification of earnings and losses, the minimum loss function will decrease with the increase in the penalty coefficient. Therefore, under a low risk control level, increasing the optimal investment strategy is a financial method to achieve the target wealth as soon as possible. However, it is noteworthy that an appropriate penalty coefficient should be selected because an overly large penalty coefficient will excessively expand profits and reduce losses, leading to an adverse effect on risk prevention and control.

    Finally, it is discovered that the pension rate for fund participants after retirement also affects the minimum loss function and the optimal investment strategy. The higher the annual pension rate, the lower the fund account wealth level, and the minimum loss function will increase. As a result, it needs to enhance the optimal investment strategy to achieve a higher fund account wealth level.

    It is evident that the model used in this study has certain limitations. There is no definite method to select the appropriate penalty coefficient, and using a certain constant to represent the market environment is not consistent with its random changes. The stochastic market model with the Markov switching of Xu et al. [18,19] has some reference value for our further research. In addition, for the convenience of mathematical deduction, the paper only considers the post-retirement stage and does not consider the preretirement stage regarding inflation factors, which is also inconsistent with the practice of financial markets. The study by Wei et al. [20,21] considered two-stage inflation factors, which provides a valuable reference for our next research.

    Zongqi Sun: Conceptualization, idea, methodology, resources, data cu-ration, formal analysis, software, writing; Peng Yang: Supervision, validation; Ying Wang: Project administration; Jing Lu: Investigation. All authors have read and approved the final version of the manuscript for publication.

    The authors declar they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    The author appreciates the insightful feedback and recommendations provided by the anonymous reviewers. The authors would like to thank the anonymous referee for very careful reading of the manuscript and helpful comments.

    Z. Sun received partial funding from the Humanities and Social Sciences Research Project of China's Ministry of Education (No. 24YJAZH193).

    The authors declare no conflict of interest.



    [1] Giorgi G, Lecca LI, Alessio F, et al. (2020) COVID-19-related mental health effects in the workplace: A narrative review. Intl J of Environ Res and Pub H 17: 7857. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph17217857 doi: 10.3390/ijerph17217857
    [2] Trevino LK (1986) Ethical decision making in organizations: A person-situation interactionist model. Acad Manage Rev 11: 601–617. https://doi.org/10.2307/258313 doi: 10.2307/258313
    [3] Reid G, O'Beirne N, Gibson N (2020) How to reshape results during the COVID-19 crisis E.Y. Ireland. Available from: https://www.ey.com/en_ie/transactions/companies-can-reshape-results-and-planfor-covid-19-recovery.
    [4] Galanakis CM (2020) The food systems in the era of the coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic crisis. Foods 9: 523. https://doi.org/10.3390/foods9040523 doi: 10.3390/foods9040523
    [5] ECDC (2020) COVID-19 clusters and outbreaks in occupational settings in the EU/EEA and the U.K. Stockholm: ECDC.
    [6] Del Rio C, Malani PN (2020) COVID-19-new insights on a rapidly changing epidemic. JAMA 323: 1339–1340. https://doi.org/10.1001/jama.2020.3072 doi: 10.1001/jama.2020.3072
    [7] Agbugba IK, Agbagwa SK, Anumudu CK, et al. (2022) The evolving state of food security in Nigeria amidst the COVID-19 pandemic review. Open Agric 7: 899–909. https://doi.org/10.1515/opag2022-0149 doi: 10.1515/opag2022-0149
    [8] Boughton D, Goeb J, Lambrecht I, et al. (2021) Impacts of COVID-19 on agricultural production and food systems in late transforming Southeast Asia: The case of Myanmar. Agric Syst 188: 103026. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.agsy.2020.103026 doi: 10.1016/j.agsy.2020.103026
    [9] Cariappa AA, Acharya KK, Adhav CA, et al. (2021) Impact of COVID-19 on the Indian agricultural system: A 10-point strategy for post-pandemic recovery. Outlook Agric 50: 26–33. https://doi.org/10.1177/0030727021989060 doi: 10.1177/0030727021989060
    [10] Sers CF, Mughal M (2020) Covid-19 outbreak and the need for rice self-sufficiency in West Africa. World Dev 135: 105071. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.105071 doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.105071
    [11] Devereux S, Béné C, Hoddinott J (2020) I am conceptualizing COVID-19's impacts on household food security. Food Secur 12: 769–772. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12571-020-01085-0 doi: 10.1007/s12571-020-01085-0
    [12] Hirvonen K, Abate GT, de Brauw A (2020) Survey suggests the rising food and nutrition insecurity risk in Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, as COVID-19 restrictions continue. In: COVID-19 and global food security, International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) book chapters, chapter 10, 46–49. Available from: https://ideas.repec.org/h/fpr/ifpric/133822.html.
    [13] Espitia A, Rocha N, Ruta M (2020) Covid-19 and food protectionism: The impact of the pandemic and export restrictions on world food markets. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 9253. https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-9253
    [14] Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) (2020) Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC): Food systems and COVID-19 in Latin America and the Caribbean: Health risks; safety of workers and food safety, Bulletin 4. Available from: https://doi.org/10.4060/ca9112en.
    [15] Jha PK, Middendorf G, Faye A, et al. (2023) Lives and livelihoods in smallholder farming systems of Senegal: Impacts, adaptation, and resilience to COVID-19. Land 12: 178. https://doi.org/10.3390/land12010178 doi: 10.3390/land12010178
    [16] U.N. General Assembly International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights and Optional Protocol to the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights, 16 December 1966, A/RES/2200 2023. Available from: https://www.refworld.org/docid/3b00f47924.html.
    [17] Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) (2008) An introduction to the basic concepts of food security. Food security information for action Practical guides. Available from: https://www.fao.org/3/al936e/al936e00.pdf.
    [18] Sridhar A, Balakrishnan A, Jacob MM, et al. (2023). Global Impact of COVID-19 on agriculture: role of sustainable agriculture and digital farming. Environ Sci Pollut Res 30: 42509–42525. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-022-19358-w doi: 10.1007/s11356-022-19358-w
    [19] Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) (2023) From Sustainable crop production and COVID-19. Food and Agriculture Organization. Available from: https://www.fao.org/3/ca8807en/CA8807EN.pdf.
    [20] Weersink A, Von Massow M, Bannon N, et al. (2021) COVID-19 and the agri-food system in the United States and Canada. Agric Syst 188: 103039. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.agsy.2020.103039 doi: 10.1016/j.agsy.2020.103039
    [21] Dagunga G, Ayamga M, Laube W, et al. (2023) Agroecology and resilience of smallholder food security: A systematic review. Front Sustainable Food Syst 7: 1267630. https://doi.org/10.3389/fsufs.2023.1267630 doi: 10.3389/fsufs.2023.1267630
    [22] Lawrence M (2023) Reimagining resilient agri-food supply chains. National Institute of Food and Agriculture USDA. Available from: https://www.nifa.usda.gov/about-nifa/impacts/reimagining-resilient-agri-food-supply-chains.
    [23] Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2021). Keep calm and carry on feeding: Agriculture and food policy responses to the COVID-19 crisis, 2023. Available from: https://www.oecd.org/coronavirus/policy-responses/keep-calm-and-carry-on-feeding-agriculture-and-food-policy-responses-to-the-covid-19-crisis-db1bf302/.
    [24] Raptou E, Mattas K, Tsakiridou E, et al. (2022) Assessing the aftermath of COVID-19 outbreak in the agro-food system: An exploratory study of experts' perspectives. Front Nutr 9: 769626. https://doi.org/10.3389/fnut.2022.769626 doi: 10.3389/fnut.2022.769626
    [25] Page MJ, McKenzie JE, Bossuyt PM, et al. (2021) The PRISMA 2020 statement: An updated guideline for reporting systematic reviews. Int J Surg 88: 105906. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijsu.2021.105906 doi: 10.1016/j.ijsu.2021.105906
    [26] Jansen C, van der Merwe P (2015) Teaching practice in the 21st century: Emerging trends, challenges and opportunities. Univers J Educ Res 3: 190–199. https://doi.org/10.13189/ujer.2015.030304 doi: 10.13189/ujer.2015.030304
    [27] Tumin D, Tobias JD (2019) The peer review process. Saudi J Anaesth 13: S52–8. https://doi.org/10.4103/sja.SJA_544_18 doi: 10.4103/sja.SJA_544_18
    [28] Organization for Economic and Cooperation Development (OECD) Statistics for coronavirus SARS CoV-2 and COVID-19 disease in country. Gynevra: OECD, 2022. Available from: https://www.oecd.org/economic-outlook/november-2022/.
    [29] Kansiime MK, Tambo JA, Mugambi I, et al. (2021) COVID-19 implications on household income and food security in Kenya and Uganda: Findings from a rapid assessment. World Dev 137: 105199. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.105199 doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.105199
    [30] Janssen M, Chang BP, Hristov H, et al. (2021) Changes in food consumption during the COVID-19 pandemic: Analysis of consumer survey data from the first lockdown period in Denmark, Germany, and Slovenia. Front Nutr 8: 60. https://doi.org/10.3389/fnut.2021.635859 doi: 10.3389/fnut.2021.635859
    [31] Rudin-Rush L, Michler JD, Josephson A, et al. (2022) Food insecurity during the first year of the COVID-19 pandemic in four African countries. Food Policy 111: 102306. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2022.102306 doi: 10.1016/j.foodpol.2022.102306
    [32] Tripathi HG, Smith HE, Sait SM, et al. (2021) Impacts of COVID-19 on diverse farm systems in Tanzania and South Africa. Sustainability 13: 9863. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13179863 doi: 10.3390/su13179863
    [33] Priyadarshini P, Abhilash PC (2021) Agri-food systems in India: Concerns and policy recommendations for building resilience in post-COVID-19 pandemic times. Global Food Secur 29: 100537. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2021.100537 doi: 10.1016/j.gfs.2021.100537
    [34] Nchanji EB, Lutomia CK (2021) Regional impact of COVID-19 on the production and food security of common bean smallholder farmers in Sub-Saharan Africa: Implication for SDGs. Global Food Secur 29: 100524. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2021.100524 doi: 10.1016/j.gfs.2021.100524
    [35] Hassen TB, El Bilali H, Allahyari MS, et al. (2021) Food purchase and eating behaviour during the COVID-19 pandemic: A cross-sectional survey of Russian adults. Appetite 165: 105309. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.appet.2021.105309 doi: 10.1016/j.appet.2021.105309
    [36] Skalko D, Kalyva ZC (2023) Exploring the impact of COVID-19 pandemic on food choice motives: A systematic review. Sustainability 15: 1606. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15021606 doi: 10.3390/su15021606
    [37] de Souza TSP, Miyahira RF, Matheus JRV, et al. (2022) Food services in times of uncertainty: Remodeling operations, changing trends, and looking into perspectives after the COVID-19 pandemic. Trends Food Sci Technol 120: 301–307. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tifs.2022.01.005 doi: 10.1016/j.tifs.2022.01.005
    [38] Lombardo M, Guseva E, Perrone MA, et al. (2021) Changes in eating habits and physical activity after COVID-19 pandemic lockdowns in Italy. Nutrients 13: 4522. https://doi.org/10.3390/nu13124522 doi: 10.3390/nu13124522
    [39] Rodrigues JF, dos Santos Filho MTC, de Oliveira LEA, et al. (2021) Effect of the COVID-19 pandemic on food habits and perceptions: A study with Brazilians. Trends Food Sci Technol 116: 992–1001. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tifs.2021.09.005 doi: 10.1016/j.tifs.2021.09.005
    [40] Kumareswaran K, Jayasinghe GY (2022) A systematic review on ensuring the global food security and COVID-19 pandemic resilient food systems: Towards accomplishing sustainable development goals targets. Discover Sustainability 3: 29. https://doi.org/10.1007/s43621-022-00096-5 doi: 10.1007/s43621-022-00096-5
    [41] Njora B, Yilmaz H (2023) The future of food systems and food security in the context of lessons learned from COVID-19 pandemic as a global challenge: insights from a qualitative perspective. AgriLife Sci J 12: 143–157. https://doi.org/10.17930/AGL2023117 doi: 10.17930/AGL2023117
    [42] Fan S, Teng P, Chew P, et al. (2021) Food system resilience and COVID-19–Lessons from the Asian experience. Global Food Secur 28: 100501. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2021.100501 doi: 10.1016/j.gfs.2021.100501
    [43] Weinkauf K, Everitt T (2023) Food system resilience during COVID-19: The role of local producers in rural Canada. Can Food Stud (La Revue canadienne des études sur l'alimentation) 10: 82–101. https://doi.org/10.15353/cfs-rcea.v10i2.594
    [44] Balistreri E, Baquedano F, Beghin JC (2022) The Impact of COVID‐19 and associated policy responses on global food security. Agric Econ 53: 855–869. https://doi.org/10.1111/agec.12749 doi: 10.1111/agec.12749
    [45] Nemes G, Chiffoleau Y, Zollet S, et al. (2021) The impact of COVID-19 on alternative and local food systems and the potential for the sustainability transition: Insights from 13 countries. Sustainable Prod Consumption 28: 591–599. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spc.2021.06.022 doi: 10.1016/j.spc.2021.06.022
    [46] Galanakis CM, Rizou M, Aldawoud TM, et al. (2021) Innovations and technology disruptions in the food sector within the COVID-19 pandemic and post-lockdown era. Trends Food Sci Technol 110: 193–200. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tifs.2021.02.002 doi: 10.1016/j.tifs.2021.02.002
    [47] Sama-Berrocal C, Martínez-Azúa BC (2022) How has the COVID-19 pandemic affected the different branches of the agri-food industry in Extremadura (Spain)? Land 11: 938. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11060938 doi: 10.3390/land11060938
    [48] Ghosh-Jerath S, Kapoor R, Dhasmana A, et al. (2022) Effect of COVID-19 pandemic on food systems and determinants of resilience in indigenous communities of Jharkhand State, India: A serial cross-sectional study. Front Sustainable Food Syst 6: 724321. https://doi.org/10.3389/fsufs.2022.724321 doi: 10.3389/fsufs.2022.724321
    [49] Manduna K (2023) The implications of the COVID-19 pandemic on South African food security: A paradigmatic turn for building back better. Int J Soc Agric Food 29: 45–64.
    [50] O'Hara S, Toussaint EC (2021) Food access in crisis: Food security and COVID-19. Ecol Econ 180: 106859. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2020.106859 doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2020.106859
    [51] Manyong V, Bokanga M, Nyamuhirwa DMA, et al. (2022) COVID-19 outbreak and rural household food security in the Western Democratic Republic of the Congo. World Dev Perspectives 28: 100469. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.wdp.2022.100469 doi: 10.1016/j.wdp.2022.100469
    [52] Rahman MT, Akter S, Rana MR, et al. (2022) How COVID-19 pandemic affects achieved food security in Bangladesh: A perspective with required policy interventions. J Agric Food Res 7: 100258. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jafr.2021.100258 doi: 10.1016/j.jafr.2021.100258
    [53] Éliás BA, Jámbor A (2021) Food security and COVID-19: A systematic review of the first-year experience. Sustainability 13: 5294. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13095294 doi: 10.3390/su13095294
    [54] Béné C, Bakker D, Chavarro MJ, et al. (2021) Global assessment of the impacts of COVID-19 on food security. Global Food Sec 31: 100575. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gfs.2021.100575 doi: 10.1016/j.gfs.2021.100575
    [55] Onyeaka H, Tamasiga P, Nkoutchou H, et al. (2022) Food insecurity and outcomes during COVID-19 pandemic in Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA). Agric Food Sec 11: 1–12. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40066-022-00394-1 doi: 10.1186/s40066-022-00394-1
    [56] Gaitán-Rossi P, Vilar-Compte M, Teruel G, et al. (2021) Food insecurity measurement and prevalence estimates during the COVID-19 pandemic in a repeated cross-sectional survey in Mexico. Public Health Nutr 24: 412–421. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1368980020004000 doi: 10.1017/S1368980020004000
    [57] Kleve S, Bennett CJ, Davidson ZE, et al. (2021) Food insecurity prevalence, severity and determinants in Australian households during the COVID-19 pandemic from the perspective of women. Nutrients 13: 4262. https://doi.org/10.3390/nu13124262 doi: 10.3390/nu13124262
    [58] Lauren BN, Silver ER, Faye AS, et al. (2021) Predictors of households at risk for food insecurity in the United States during the COVID-19 pandemic. Public Health Nutr 24: 3929–3936. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1368980021000355 doi: 10.1017/S1368980021000355
    [59] Agbugba IK, Agbagwa SK, Anumudu CK, et al. (2022) The evolving state of food security in Nigeria amidst the COVID-19 pandemic—A review. Open Agric 7: 899–909. https://doi.org/10.1515/opag-2022-0149 doi: 10.1515/opag-2022-0149
    [60] Kakaei H, Nourmoradi H, Bakhtiyari S, et al. (2022) Chapter One—Effect of COVID-19 on food security, hunger, and food crisis. In: Dehghani MH, Karri RR, Roy S (Eds.), COVID-19 and the Sustainable Development Goals, Elsevier, 3–29. https://doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-323-91307-2.00005-5
    [61] Tan SP, Ng LC, Lyndon N, et al. (2023) A review on post-COVID-19 impacts and opportunities of the agri-food supply chain in Malaysia. Peer J 11: e15228. https://doi.org/10.7717/peerj.15228 doi: 10.7717/peerj.15228
    [62] Kumar A, Mangla SK, Kumar P, et al. (2021) Mitigate risks in perishable food supply chains: Learning from COVID-19. Technol Forecast Soc Change 166: 120643. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2021.120643 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2021.120643
    [63] Cavallo A, Olivieri FM (2022) Sustainable local development and agri-food system in the post-Covid crisis: The case of Rome. Cities 131: 103994. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cities.2022.103994 doi: 10.1016/j.cities.2022.103994
    [64] Biazoti AR, Nakamura AC, Nagib G, et al. (2021) The impact of COVID-19 on urban agriculture in São Paulo, Brazil. Sustainability 13: 6185. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13116185 doi: 10.3390/su13116185
    [65] Coleman-Jensen A, Rabbit M, Gregory C, et al. (2021) Household food security in the United States in 2020. United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, Report number: ERR-298. Washington, DC.
    [66] O'Hara S, Ivanic M (2022) Food security and lifestyle vulnerabilities as systemic influencers of COVID-19 survivability. Med Res Arch 10: 2989. https://doi.org/10.18103/mra.v10i8.2989 doi: 10.18103/mra.v10i8.2989
    [67] Ahmed F, Islam A, Pakrashi D, et al. (2021) Determinants and dynamics of food insecurity during COVID-19 in rural Bangladesh. Food Policy 101: 102066. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2021.102066 doi: 10.1016/j.foodpol.2021.102066
    [68] Amare M, Abay KA, Tiberti L, et al. (2021) COVID-19 and food security: Panel data evidence from Nigeria. Food Policy 101: 102099. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2021.102099 doi: 10.1016/j.foodpol.2021.102099
    [69] Basiron NA, Mazlan M, Adenkunle SM (2022) Consumer's behaviour in the consumption of fresh farm product during Covid-19 pandemic at Alor Gajah, Melaka. AgroTech-Food Sci, Tech Environ 1: 25–32. https://doi.org/10.53797/agrotech.v1i1.4.2022 doi: 10.53797/agrotech.v1i1.4.2022
    [70] Hadi FSA, Yin CF, Ahmad MA (2022) Impact of the Covid-19 pandemic on food expenditure in Perak. Int J Acad Res Bus Soc Sci 12: 2703–2712. https://doi.org/10.6007/IJARBSS/v12-i11/15740 doi: 10.6007/IJARBSS/v12-i11/15740
    [71] Suraya A, Noor Dzuhaidah O, Erni Marlina S, et al. (2021) A review on food security policy on agriculture and food in Sabah, Malaysia. IOP Conf Ser: Earth Environ Sci 1103: 012023. https://doi.org/10.1088/1755-1315/1103/1/012023 doi: 10.1088/1755-1315/1103/1/012023
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2024 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(2382) PDF downloads(159) Cited by(11)

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog