Loading [MathJax]/jax/element/mml/optable/SuppMathOperators.js
Research article

Asymmetric interdependencies between cryptocurrency and commodity markets: the COVID-19 pandemic impact

  • Using NARDL methodology, this research investigates some asymmetric and non-linear interconnections between leading cryptocurrency and commodity returns. Thus, this study explores potential interconnections between these cryptocurrencies and commodity markets in the period between March 07, 2018, and March 26, 2021. This paper splits the entire sample period into two independent sub-periods in order to enhance robustness: pre-COVID and COVID, to examine the impact of the pandemic on these markets. Our results confirm that the most relevant interconnection (in terms of cointegration, short- and long- asymmetry, and the persistence of the lags) between cryptos and commodities is focused on COVID-19, the pandemic sub-period, in line with previous literature. Finally, the study reveals that some cryptocurrencies such as Tether could serve as a diversifying asset or even a safe haven, in certain scenarios, in investment strategies.

    Citation: Francisco Jareño, María De La O González, Pascual Belmonte. Asymmetric interdependencies between cryptocurrency and commodity markets: the COVID-19 pandemic impact[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(1): 83-112. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022004

    Related Papers:

    [1] Khalil Ur Rehman, Wasfi Shatanawi, Kamal Abodayeh, Taqi A.M. Shatnawi . Parabolic transport measurement of hydrodynamic forces for flow around circular/triangular distance dependent obstructions: Finite element analysis. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(4): 8847-8866. doi: 10.3934/math.2023444
    [2] Bowen Tang, Xiaoying Yang, Lin Su . Shape reconstruction of acoustic obstacle with linear sampling method and neural network. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(6): 13607-13623. doi: 10.3934/math.2024664
    [3] Wanyang Dai . Simulating a strongly nonlinear backward stochastic partial differential equation via efficient approximation and machine learning. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(7): 18688-18711. doi: 10.3934/math.2024909
    [4] Tian Xu, Ailong Wu . Stabilization of nonlinear hybrid stochastic time-delay neural networks with Lévy noise using discrete-time feedback control. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(10): 27080-27101. doi: 10.3934/math.20241317
    [5] Jianwei Jiao, Keqin Su . A new Sigma-Pi-Sigma neural network based on L1 and L2 regularization and applications. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(3): 5995-6012. doi: 10.3934/math.2024293
    [6] Khalil Ur Rehman, Nosheen Fatima, Wasfi Shatanawi, Nabeela Kousar . Mathematical solutions for coupled nonlinear equations based on bioconvection in MHD Casson nanofluid flow. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(1): 598-633. doi: 10.3934/math.2025027
    [7] Changgui Wu, Liang Zhao . Finite-time adaptive dynamic surface control for output feedback nonlinear systems with unmodeled dynamics and quantized input delays. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(11): 31553-31580. doi: 10.3934/math.20241518
    [8] Wei Ma, Ming Zhao, Jiaxin Li . A multi-step Ulm-Chebyshev-like method for solving nonlinear operator equations. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(10): 28623-28642. doi: 10.3934/math.20241389
    [9] Shanhao Yuan, Yanqin Liu, Yibin Xu, Qiuping Li, Chao Guo, Yanfeng Shen . Gradient-enhanced fractional physics-informed neural networks for solving forward and inverse problems of the multiterm time-fractional Burger-type equation. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(10): 27418-27437. doi: 10.3934/math.20241332
    [10] Zongning Zhang, Chunguang Li, Jianqiang Dong . A class of lattice Boltzmann models for the Burgers equation with variable coefficient in space and time. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(3): 4502-4516. doi: 10.3934/math.2022251
  • Using NARDL methodology, this research investigates some asymmetric and non-linear interconnections between leading cryptocurrency and commodity returns. Thus, this study explores potential interconnections between these cryptocurrencies and commodity markets in the period between March 07, 2018, and March 26, 2021. This paper splits the entire sample period into two independent sub-periods in order to enhance robustness: pre-COVID and COVID, to examine the impact of the pandemic on these markets. Our results confirm that the most relevant interconnection (in terms of cointegration, short- and long- asymmetry, and the persistence of the lags) between cryptos and commodities is focused on COVID-19, the pandemic sub-period, in line with previous literature. Finally, the study reveals that some cryptocurrencies such as Tether could serve as a diversifying asset or even a safe haven, in certain scenarios, in investment strategies.



    Generally, there are several different kinds of individuals in economic and management systems; they are homogenous individuals if they are the same, otherwise they are called in-homogenous ones. The interaction can be divided into two categories: One happened between homogenous individuals, and the other happened between in-homogenous individuals, which makes the corresponding system more complex. In this system, the random and dynamic state, behavior, and configuration cannot only be influenced by the environment but also effect the property of the environment, which makes the system a complex adaptive system, then, more important problems should be focused on: Under evolution of this complex adaptive system, what properties would be about the individual behavior, and what could the distribution of the corresponding optimal strategy be? These problems are of much interest.

    Over the past two decades, the study of complex adaptive systems has become a major field [1,2]. A very broad range of complex adaptive systems have been studied, from abstract ones, such as the evolution of economic systems [3,4] and theory of emergence [5,6], to physical ones, such as social [7,8], epidemic [9,10], characteristic of bifurcation [11], which means a minor perturbation may escalate into tectonic shifts in the system, or even abrupt changes in the property and function of the system [12], resulting in symmetry-breaking [13]. In essence, the spontaneous switches in group behavior derive from interactions between individuals [14], during which some behaviors are learned [15] or propagate [16,17], causing the structure and behaviors of the system (or of the collective) to change [18] or even to reach the critical state [19]. All have in common the property that their detailed structure cannot be explained exactly from a mathematical viewpoint. At the beginning of the 21st century, a wealth of stochastic differential game theory has emerged [20,21], which describes the interaction behavior of agents and the optimal strategy coupled with temporary deterministic structure and stochastic complex networks [22]. Kinds of literature in different fields have described the evolution law under various agent interaction rules [23]. Jiang [24] demonstrated the importance of balancing both parties' interests within an ecological compensation agreement while reducing uncertainty around unobserved environmental factors during ex-ante negotiations.

    In this paper, a multi-agent model is constructed to analyze the evolution law of economic and management complex adaptive systems. Based on experimental analysis, it has been found that in the most of cases, the system behavior conforms to a specific distribution when agents work according to this model. Furthermore, some strategies for economic issues, politic events, social questions, and environmental influence would be made scientifically once this distribution law is determined. Compared with the existing works, the main contributions of the paper are summarized as follows:

    1) Both the diverse behaviors of agent and the configuration of the system are all changed randomly with time, and the classic analysis method cannot deal with this dual randomness. There have been few results to discover what the system's behavior would be converged to, as time tends to infinity or a relatively large number under classic methods. We consider not only the growth of the random complex networks, but also the decline. Furthermore, in our model, the network is regarded as a multi-local-event network, and each Multi-Local-World can be regarded as a relative independent subsystem. This case is closer to reality; however, it has not been discussed before.

    2) Most research results have either considered the mixed interaction of non-cooperative/cooperative games in Multi-Local-Worlds stable graph or considered the random Multi-Local-Worlds complex networks with the Boolean game between individuals, which are far away from the property of the real economic and management complex adaptive system. In this sense, new modeling methods should be introduced.

    3) Furthermore, in classic research, the interaction between individuals is set as a preferential attachment with degree. In our study, this preferential attachment is designed from both income coupled with certain strategy and the local configuration, and the phase transfer equations are modeled as a similar mechanism. So, we consider not only the behavior and adaptability of an agent, but also the interaction between environment and system, which could interpret more accurately the economic and management complex adaptive system.

    The paper is organized as follows. In Section 3, the characteristics of a complex adaptive system are analyzed and a hypothesis is proposed. In Section 4, the model coevolving with both strategy and local topological structure of individual interaction is constructed, where agent behavior in the system is described as 6 subprocesses. In Section 5, a computational experiment was conducted to verify the above analysis. Section 6 provides the conclusion of this paper.

    Generally, each agent in a complex adaptive system could interact just with local agents, not global ones, meaning that an arbitrary agent can just act with limited agents in the system; their interaction relies on the system's local topological configuration [25], Furthermore, each agent in the system can change its interacting targets (i.e., its "neighbors") to obtain more benefits; there are complex nonlinear interactions among subjects and between subjects and environments, which lead to the phenomenon of "emergence in large numbers" of the system [26,27,28]. Schlüter [26] has found the emergence that behavior of collective with large enough individuals is far beyond the sum of individuals behavior in social-economical systems, Steffen et al. [27] have studied the emergence in each system by invoking a similar method and draw a same conclusion, and Maia et al. [28] have studied the emergence of societal bubbles, that is, the evolution of microscopic individuals makes the macro system display a new state and a new structure [29,30]. Zhang et al. [29] have proven that the structure, property and function of supply chain is time-varied randomly, and Zou et al. [30] have proven this by introducing a complex networks model. In this sense, the local topological configuration is not stable but dynamic [31,32]. Liang et al. [31] have constructed an avalanche model to describe that the configuration of wiring-economical modular networks could be destroyed without any warning, and Fulker et al. [32] have constructed a dynamic networks model to describe the property of the economic system. Obviously, most complex adaptive systems have two characteristics: complex networks and games. Therefore, it is necessary to introduce new methods to study the properties of optimal agent strategies in complex adaptive systems. A master stability approach for a large class of adaptive networks has been developed [33]; this approach allows for reducing the synchronization problem for adaptive networks to a low-dimensional system by decoupling topological and dynamical properties. An effective new technique called the regulative norms detection technique (RNDT) to detect norms by analyzing odd events that trigger reward or penalty is demonstrated [34]. The test results showed that the RNDT performed well, although the success rate relied on the settings of the environmental variables. Some results claimed that macroeconomics should consider the economy as a complex evolving system whose far-from-equilibrium interactions continuously changed the structure of the system and that the complex interactions of agents led to the emergence of new phenomena and hierarchical structure at the macro level, having constructed a bottom-up model to describe the emergence property of multi-hierarchical structure complex systems [35].

    Generally, a system can be divided into multiple subsystems, and interactions between individuals occur not only within a subsystem, but across different subsystems [36,37]. The interactions occur not merely between neighboring individuals, and the long-range interactions in spatial dimension have significant effects on the critical phase transition of the system [38,39,40]. Furthermore, in addition, the rules met by the interactions between individuals within an economic or management system are far more complex than the rules regulating interactions between individuals in the natural world, such as the conservation of momentum that regulates collisions of particles and the black box of biology (such as the behavior adjustment strategies defined by the Ising model and Vicsek model) [41,42,43,44]. Moreover, it has been scientifically proven that the system structure determined by interactions between individuals is a key contributing factor to the function and nature of the system [45], so the multi-layered structure of economic and management systems leads to a strong cascade effect of collective behaviors [46,47,48]. Furthermore, when individuals interact in varied structures, such as sparse graphs and dense graphs, random graphs and complete graphs, scale-free networks, and small-world networks [49,50,51,52], the diverse and random structures of economic and management systems, due to the dependence on the structure [53,54,55], make the phase transition in these systems far more complex than the critical phase transitions in physical systems comprised of mono-dimensional and simple interactions between individuals [56].

    However, the economic and management system cannot be described by random complex networks models because the Boolean interaction defined in random complex networks models is much simpler than the reality, nor can it be defined by different game models because the configuration of interaction between agents is changed dynamically. So, these two properties must be considered. If this problem is resolved, a universal conclusion would be drawn and many similar economic and management events would be explained by this theory. Furthermore, there are many unknown and unseen scenarios in reality. Due to the lack of real-world data, the conclusions regarding concerted changes in collective behavior reached by classical analysis methods do not apply to unknown scenarios. So, it is necessary to draw a universal conclusion for invariable distribution about the system's behavior. In this paper, co-evolutionary complex adaptive systems with agent behavior and local topological configuration are constructed to describe the property of economic and management systems. In this paper, a Multi-Local-Worlds economic and management complex adaptive system with agent behavior and local configuration is considered. This partially complements the gap between reality and the results of previous studies.

    A complex adaptive system can adjust its behaviors and structure according to the environment changing dynamically; on the contrary, its behaviors, functions, and structure can also react to the environment and make the environment change adaptively [57,58,59]. This property makes the complex adaptive system multi-hierarchical, intelligent, social, and autonomous [60]. There are several "Local-Worlds" in this system, as shown in Figure 1.

    Figure 1.  The universal topological structure of a complex adaptive system.

    From Figure 1(1), the multi-hierarchical topological structure can be seen clearly. The details can be shown in Figure 1(2), and the topological structure of a complex adaptive system driven by the interaction between agents can be divided into several subsystems; similarly, the topological structure of each Sub-system can be divided into several sub-subsystems; and so on. In this sense, a definition of Local-World is introduced here.

    Definition 1. The connected subgraph Gi,i=1,2,...,m of the topological structure of the complex adaptive system G, where GiG, is called Local-World.

    Because there are several hierarchies and there are several Local-Worlds in each corresponding system (system, subsystem and so on), the behavior of the system is more complex. Without loss of generality, we suppose that there are two hierarchies in this system. According to the dynamical property of the configuration of a complex adaptive system, the system configuration can be described in Figure 2.

    Figure 2.  Interaction between agents in the dynamic topology of the complex adaptive system.

    Figure 2 describes the dynamic property of the complex adaptive system with co-evolving behavior and local configuration, where C represents "Cooperation games" that happen in agents and N represents "noncooperation games" that happen in agents. There are two local worlds in this system. At time t, agents 1–4 stand in Local-World 1, and agents 5–8 are in Local-World 2. This interactive configuration is presented on the left side of Figure 2. However, at time t+1, agent 9 takes part in this system and interacts with agent 8, which leads to a change in the system configuration, as seen on the right side of Figure 2. There is a totally different structure, where agents 1–4 and 7 are in Local-World 1, and agents 5, 6, 8 and 9 are in Local-World 2.

    Consider the complex adaptive system that satisfies the following properties:

    1) There exist more than enough Local-Worlds such that the system holds in the spatial dimension. The radius is small enough from the macro spatial scale such that there are more than enough Local-Worlds existing in the system and interacting with each other. Meanwhile, from a micro spatial scale, the radius is large enough such that there are more than enough individuals existing in it and interacting with each other. Both the number of Local-Worlds and the relationships between them are constant, from a macro spatial scale, such that the system structure and function are stable. However, individuals would waver randomly from one Local-World to another, from a micro spatial scale, so that they are variable.

    2) On a relatively short time scale, the interactivities of cooperative stochastic differential games between agents in a certain Local-World are defined. Conversely, the interactions of noncooperative stochastic differential games between agents standing in different Local-Worlds are also defined. Furthermore, the system's topology configuration determines the states, properties, and characters of agents.

    3) On a small time scale, under preferential attachment, growth, and decline mechanisms with agents' intellective, autonomous, and social properties, agents in the system can adjust adaptively to its topological configuration such that the complex adaptive system innovates. Furthermore, on a large time scale, the interactivities between agents can be produced by pursuing more payoffs by improving the interaction structure, which consists of 6 subprocesses: self-improvement strategy; creating a new game in the same Local-World with agents with whom they have not interacted before; creating a new game relationship with agents in other Local-Worlds with whom they have not interacted before; deleting an old game relationship; creating a new game relationship with a new agent, or withdrawing from the system.

    In a small time scale, an arbitrary agent should not pursue the maximum payoff but rather pursue the payoff maximized for that particular time scale. This means that an agent can give up the transitory benefit that is described by a certain integral of the objectivity function [61,62]. Furthermore, the behavior of an agent will be decided due to the corresponding resource it holds. However, there exists a dynamics equation for resources changing with time for each agent such that the objectivity of agents will change together, which should be described by some certain discount function of time.

    On a long time scale, for each agent in the system, there exist 6 behaviors to be selected as a certain probability vector. Its behaviors can be controlled by the mechanisms of both preferential attachment and growth coupled with strategies, trajectory, and topological configuration coevolved together [63]. An agent can adjust its strategy according to a deterministic probability by considering its historical strategies and its neighbor's strategies—a deterministic dynamics, which makes the marginal probability of pure strategy that the agent uses proportional to the marginal income [64]. It is the preferential attachment probability that decides whether an agent creates a new link with another agent or not, and the probability relies on the ratio of the payoff for creating the new game to the payoff of the Local-World. Creating a new game relationship between different Local-Worlds is similar to creating a new game relationship within the same Local-World, except for the differences in parameters. In this sense, we consider both a cooperative and noncooperative stochastic differential game according to Property (2), which describes the system evolution mechanism in detail. The preferential attachment probabilities, in fact, satisfy the Logit properties for the last 5 of the 6 subprocesses.

    This co-evolutional complex adaptive system consists of two kinds of randomness. One is the agent's behavior is random, and the other is his local topological configuration driven by the interaction is also random. Furthermore, the state would be changed dynamically. In this sense, it is a stochastic process. Suppose that homogenous agents interact in the system, i.e., the number of Local-World is equal to 1, as the system has been studied [65]. As analyzed above, the topological structure of a real economic and management complex adaptive system is a stochastic multi-hierarchical, so this model must be revised. An arbitrary agent can select each behavior from 6 subprocesses with a certain probability p1,...,p6, respectively, and at the next one, he could select another behavior.

    Seen as property of the system, for a certain system configuration, there must exist an optimal strategy trajectory; however, because the configurations are always changed randomly, the optimal strategies are changed with changed configuration. So, we hope these optimal strategies should satisfy certain laws, described as the following hypotheses.

    Hypothesis 1. The occurring-time of optimal strategy satisfies an invariable distribution if both behavior and local configuration of each agent in the complex adaptive system are all changed randomly.

    Hypothesis 2. The holding-time of each optimal strategy satisfies another invariable distribution if both behavior and local configuration of each agent in the complex adaptive system are all changed randomly.

    Although similar hypotheses are given by Staudigi [65], the interaction between agents is set according to the rule of prison dilemma with four discrete strategies, but not set according to universe strategies with a continuous change state.

    In practical economic management systems, such as real estate, supply chain, regional economy, financial markets, etc., they are all complex economic management systems with the following characteristics: (ⅰ) The interaction between people changes the system structure and is influenced by the system structure, forming a trend of co evolution between behavior and topology structure; (ⅱ) there are several subsystems in complex systems, including cooperation and competition; and (ⅲ) an optimal strategy can be found in the system. If these economic management systems can be abstracted into a universal system model, with clear system characteristics and optimal strategies of members and their changing characteristics, then these results can be extended to more specific economic management systems.

    For each agent in the system, there exist 6 behaviors to be selected as a certain probability vector. Their behaviors can be controlled by the mechanisms of both preferential attachment and growth coupled with strategies, trajectory, and topological configurations that have coevolved. Their behavior is as follows:

    An arbitrary agent, ji, will change its strategy as probability q1(ω)[0,1]. The probability bji,β(|ω) of the agent changing its behavior in a certain system configuration should satisfy

    bji(ar|ω)P(arargmaxavA(πji(αavji,g)+εjiav)|ω) (1)

    where ar is the most effective strategy within the game radius r, av is the strategy space, A is the strategy space collection, πji() is the payoff of agent ji, A is the strategy of agent ji in the strategy space, and ε is noise. Equation (1) means that an agent transferring from one strategy to another is decided because the expected payoff coupled with the new strategy could make maximize agent ji's payoff, which can be regarded as random selection for strategy in a deterministic hybrid game. Furthermore, this decision relies on not only the neighbor's strategy and the topological structure g, but also on the environment β.

    limβ0logbji,β(a|ω)=cji1(ω,(aαji,g))=v(t)ji(t,xtji,ϕji(t,xtji)) (2)

    where strategy ϕji(t,xtji) for time t and state xt refers to the optimal strategy vector for a specific pure strategy, ϕji(t,xtji)=(ϕj1(t,xtj1),ϕj2(t,xtj2),,ϕjϑ(t,xtjϑ))T, and ϑ is the spatial dimension of agent ji.

    Suppose that arbitrary agent ji creates a new game with a new agent who is not its neighbors with probability w(sub - process2)ji,β(ω)(w(sub - process2)ji,βki(ω))kiI=λ(sub - process2)ji(ω)/λ(sub - process2)(ω), which relies on ration function λ(sub - process2)ji:ΩR+ that satisfies κji(ω)=Ni1λji(ω)=0 and

    (jiI)(ωΩ):λ(sub - process2)ji=kiˉNji(ω)exp(˜W(t){ji,ki}(t,xtji,xtki,ϕji(t,xtji),ϕki(t,xtji))/β) (3)
    λ(sub - process 2)βjiIλ(sub - process 2)ji,β(ω)=ji,ki>jiexp(˜W(t){ji,ki}(t,xtji,xtki,ϕji(t,xtji),ϕki(t,xtji))/β)(1gjiki)    (ji,kiI):w(sub - process 2)ki,βji(ω)=ˆw(sub - process 2)ki,βji(α)(1gjiki) (4)

    The probability of agent ji creating a new game with agent ki is defined as λ(sub - process2)ji(ω)/ˉλ(sub - process2)(ω), which means that payoff of coalition of agent ji and agent ki is larger or equal to the other coalition's payoff affected by noise ςji=(ςjiki)kiˉNji(ω). In this sense, we have

    wjiki(ω)P(˜W(t){ji,ki}(t,xtji,xtki,ϕji(t,xtji),ϕki(t,xtji))+ςjiki          (5)

    and

    \begin{array}{l} (\forall {j_i} \in {\mathscr{I}})(\forall \omega \in \Omega ): - \mathop {\lim }\limits_{\beta \to 0} \beta \log w_{{k_i}}^{({\text{sub - process2}}){j_i}, \beta }(\omega ) = c_2^{{j_i}}(\omega , (a, g \oplus ({j_i}, {k_i}))) \\ \ \ \ \ = \frac{{{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_i}\} }}\left( {t, x_{\{ {j_i}, {k_i}\} }^{(t)*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{k_i}}^*(t, x_{{k_i}}^{t*}), g \oplus ({j_i}, {k_i})} \right)}}{{\sum\limits_{{l_i} \notin {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {l_i}\} }}\left( {t, x_{\{ {j_i}, {l_i}\} }^{(t)*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{l_i}}^*(t, x_{{l_i}}^{t*}), g \oplus ({j_i}, {l_i})} \right)} }} \end{array} (6)

    That is, \exists {\tilde k_l} \ne {k_l}, {\tilde k_l} \notin {\bar {\mathscr{N}}^{{j_i}}}, \mathbb{P}\left\{ {{W^{\{ {j_i}, {k_l}\} }}(t, {x^{t*}}) \geqslant {W^{\{ {j_i}, {{\tilde k}_l}\} }}(t, {x^{t*}})} \right\} = 1 must be satisfied to create a new game relationship with agents from {N_i} - {\bar {\mathscr{N}}_{{j_i}}} with whom agent {j_i} did not interact. It is the link probability, also called preferential attachment mechanism, that states an agent prefers to select a game partner who can bring them more payoff than another. This causes each agent to be selected prior to their payoff coupled with the optimal strategy in the corresponding short time interval. This probability is a multi-dimension logit function, which means there exists a critical point of probability \tilde W_0^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_i}\} } coupled with the agent's payoff in the selected process, such that the probability a certain agent will be selected is far smaller than 0.5 if the agent's payoff is smaller than \tilde W_0^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_i}\} } , but the selecting probability is far larger than 0.5 and close to 1 if the agent's payoff is larger than \tilde W_0^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_i}\} } .

    Similar to subprocess 2, the case where agent {j_i} creates a new game with agent {k_{i'}} must satisfy the following conditions:

    \left( {\forall {j_i} \in {\mathscr{I}}} \right)\left( {\forall \omega \in \Omega } \right):{\lambda ^{({\text{Sub - process 3}}){j_i}, \beta }}(\omega ) = \sum\limits_{{k_{i'}} \notin {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} {\exp \left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{k_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{j_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right)/\beta } \right)} \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ {\lambda ^{({\text{Sub - process 3}})\beta }}(\omega ) \triangleq \sum\limits_{{j_i} \in {\mathscr{I}}} {{\lambda ^{({\text{Sub - process 3}}){j_i}, \beta }}(\omega )} (7)
    \begin{array}{l} w_{{k_j}}^{({\text{Sub - process 3}}){j_i}}(\omega ) \triangleq \mathbb{P}\left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{k_{i'}}}}} \right) + \varsigma _{{k_{i'}}}^{{j_i}} \geqslant \pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{l_{i'}}}}} \right) + \varsigma _{{l_{i'}}}^{{j_i}}\forall {l_{i'}} \notin {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} \right) \hfill \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} = \mathbb{P}\left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{k_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right) + \varsigma _{{k_{i'}}}^{{j_i}}} \right. \hfill \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} \geqslant \mathbb{P}\left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {l_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{l_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{l_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{l_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right)\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{l_{i'}}}}} \right) + \varsigma _{{l_{i'}}}^{{j_i}}} \right., \left. {\forall {l_{i'}} \notin {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} \right) \hfill \end{array} (8)

    So, we have

    \begin{array}{l} \left( {\forall {j_i} \in {\mathscr{I}}} \right)\left( {\forall {k_j} \notin {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} \right):w_{{k_j}}^{({\text{Sub - process 3}}){j_i}, \beta }(\omega ) = \frac{{\exp \left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{k_j}}}} \right)/\beta } \right)}}{{\sum\limits_{{l_j} \notin {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}} {\exp \left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{l_j}}}} \right)/\beta } \right)} }} \hfill \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ = \frac{{\exp \left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{k_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right)/\beta } \right)}}{{\sum\limits_{{l_{i'}} \notin {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}} {\exp \left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {l_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{l_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{l_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{l_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right)/\beta } \right)} }} \hfill \end{array} (9)
    {\lambda ^{({\text{Sub - process 3}})\beta }}(\omega \to \hat \omega ) = {\lambda ^{({\text{Sub - process 3}}){j_i}}}(\omega )w_{{k_j}}^{({\text{Sub - process 3}}){j_i}}(\omega ) + {\lambda ^{({\text{Sub - process 3}}){k_j}}}(\omega )w_{{j_i}}^{({\text{Sub - process 3}}){k_j}}(\omega ) (10)
    {\lambda ^{({\text{Sub - process 3}})\beta }}(\omega \to \hat \omega ) = \exp \left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{k_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right)/\beta } \right) (11)

    If an agent interacts with another one but cannot obtain the expected payoff, it will delete the game relationship without hesitation. Two kinds of agents can be deleted: one standing in the same Local-World and the other standing in another Local-World, who is denoted by {k_i}. Furthermore, only the weakest links are deleted as a maximum probability, which means that the probability of deleting an existing game relationship is a preferential attachment—preferential abbreviation. In this sense, suppose that an arbitrary link ({j_i}, {k_{i'}}) will disappear as probability \xi > 0. That is, if this link exists as probability \xi h + o(h) during a small enough time interval [t, t + h], the expected time of existence will be 1/\xi . Therefore, starting from system state \omega = (\alpha, g), the probability that system transit system state \hat \omega = (\alpha, g - ({j_i}, {k_{i'}})) must be {\eta ^{({\text{Sub - process 4}})\beta }}(\omega \to \hat \omega) = \xi is

    \begin{array}{l} \left( {\forall {j_i} \in {\mathscr{I}}} \right)\left( {\forall \omega \in \Omega } \right):{\eta ^{({\text{Sub - process 4}}){j_i}, \beta }}(\omega ) \hfill \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ = \sum\limits_{{k_j} \in {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} {\exp \left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{k_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right)/\beta } \right)} \hfill \end{array} (12)
    {\eta ^{({\text{Sub - process 4}})\beta }}(\omega ) = \sum\limits_{{j_i} \in {\mathscr{F}}} {{\eta ^{({\text{Sub - process 4}}){j_i}, \beta }}(\omega )} (13)
    \begin{array}{l} v_{{k_{i'}}}^{({\text{Sub - process 4}}){j_i}}(\omega ) \triangleq \mathbb{P}\left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{k_{i'}}}}} \right) + \varsigma _{{k_{i'}}}^{{j_i}} \leqslant \pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{l_{i'}}}}} \right) + \varsigma _{{l_{i'}}}^{{j_i}}\forall {l_{i'}} \notin {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} \right) \hfill \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ = \mathbb{P}\left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{k_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right) + \varsigma _{{k_j}}^{{j_i}}} \right. \hfill \\ \left. {\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \leqslant {{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {l_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{l_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{l_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{l_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right) + \varsigma _{{l_{i'}}}^{{j_i}}\forall {l_{i'}} \notin {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} \right) \hfill \end{array} (14)
    \begin{array}{l} \left( {\forall {j_i} \in {\mathscr{I}}} \right)\left( {\forall {k_j} \in {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} \right):v_{{k_j}}^{({\text{Sub - process 4}}){j_i}, \beta }(\omega ) = 1 - \frac{{\exp \left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{k_j}}}} \right)/\beta } \right)}}{{\sum\limits_{{l_j} \in {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}} {\exp \left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{l_j}}}} \right)/\beta } \right)} }} \hfill \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ = 1 - \frac{{\exp \left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{k_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right)/\beta } \right)}}{{\sum\limits_{{l_{i'}} \in {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}} {\exp \left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {l_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{l_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{l_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{l_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right)/\beta } \right)} }} \hfill \end{array} (15)

    An agent always adjusts their interactive environment to maximize their payoff by adaptively adjusting the local game topological configuration, which can be expressed as adding a new link and deleting an old link with preferential attachment mechanisms. This adaptive behavior on the part of the agent, showing their intelligence by adding or deleting links, is the essence of the complex adaptive system.

    It is easier to decide the probability of deleting a link than it is to decide the probability of adding a link because when considering deleting a link, only agent {k_{i'}} is considered and the required calculation is reduced considerably. Furthermore, the probability of deleting a link is smaller than the probability of creating links either within same Local-World or between different Local-Worlds, because one agent can get the maximum payoff when they create a game relationship with a certain agent, and the payoff cannot decrease sharply with time except in the case where they can obtain more payoff if they interact with other agents (a small probability event).

    Because a complex adaptive system is a dissipative system, a new agent can enter the system and, of course, it can withdraw from the system. When an agent enters the system, the first thing is to select a Local-World for it to stand in, and then it must select an agent to interact with.

    In this paper, when an agent enters the system, it enters an arbitrary Local-World as an identical probability; therefore, the first step of this subprocess should be omitted. The other steps are similar to those of subprocess 2 and should be omitted, too. Therefore, when agent N + 1 enters the complex adaptive system, it will enter Local-World i as probability 1/m and will be reordered to {N_i} + 1, then it will create a game relationship with an arbitrary agent {j_i} with probability w_{{N_i} + 1}^{({\text{sub - process 5}}), {j_i}, \beta }, where:

    \begin{array}{l} \left( {\forall {j_i} \in {\mathscr{I}}} \right)\left( {\forall \omega \in \Omega } \right):{\lambda ^{({\text{Sub - process 5}}){j_i}, \beta }}(\omega ) \hfill \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ = \exp \left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, N + 1\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{N + 1}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{N + 1}^*(t, x_{N + 1}^{t*})} \right)/\beta } \right) \hfill \end{array} (16)
    \begin{array}{l} w_{{N_i} + 1}^{({\text{Sub - process 5}}){j_i}}(\omega ) \triangleq \mathbb{P}\left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{N_i} + 1}}} \right) + \varsigma _{{N_i} + 1}^{{j_i}} \geqslant \pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{l_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{N_i} + 1}}} \right) + \varsigma _{{N_i} + 1}^{{l_i}}\forall {l_i} \in i(\omega )} \right) \hfill \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ = \mathbb{P}\left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, N + 1\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{N + 1}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{N + 1}^*(t, x_{N + 1}^{t*})} \right) + \varsigma _{N + 1}^{{j_i}}} \right. \hfill \\ \left. {\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \geqslant {{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {l_i}, N + 1\} }}\left( {t, x_{{l_i}}^{t*}, x_{N + 1}^{t*}, \phi _{{l_i}}^*(t, x_{{l_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{N + 1}^*(t, x_{N + 1}^{t*})} \right) + \varsigma _{N + 1}^{{l_i}}\forall {l_i} \in i(\omega )} \right) \hfill \end{array} (17)
    \left( {\forall {j_i} \in {\mathscr{I}}} \right)\left( {\forall {l_i} \in i(\omega ), {l_i} \ne {j_i}} \right):w_{{N_i} + 1}^{({\text{Sub - process 5}}){j_i}, \beta }(\omega ) = \frac{{\exp \left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{N_i} + 1}}} \right)/\beta } \right)}}{{\sum\limits_{{l_i} \in i(\omega ), {l_i} \ne {j_i}} {\exp \left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{l_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{N_i} + 1}}} \right)/\beta } \right)} }} (18)
    {\lambda ^{({\text{Sub - process 5}})\beta }}(\omega \to \hat \omega ) = {\lambda ^{({\text{Sub - process 5}}){j_i}}}(\omega )w_{N + 1}^{({\text{Sub - process 5}}){j_i}}(\omega ) (19)

    As mentioned above, several agents are allowed to be deleted from the system, which reflects the property of survival of the fittest of the complex adaptive system. Obviously, when an agent is deleted, the links that expressed its game relationships must be deleted.

    \begin{array}{l} \left( {\forall {j_i} \in {\mathscr{I}}} \right)\left( {\forall \omega \in \Omega } \right):{\eta ^{({\text{Sub - process 6}}){j_i}, \beta }}(\omega ) = \sum\limits_{{k_j} \in {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} {\exp \left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{k_j}}}} \right)/\beta } \right)} \hfill \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ = \sum\limits_{{k_{i'}} \in {{\bar {\mathscr{N}}}^{{j_i}}}(\omega )} {\exp \left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{k_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{k_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right)/\beta } \right)} \hfill \end{array} (20)
    \begin{array}{l} {v^{({\text{Sub - process 6}}){j_i}}}(\omega ) \triangleq \mathbb{P}\left( {\sum\nolimits_{{k_i} \in {N^{{j_i}}}} {\left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{k_i}}}} \right) + \varsigma _{{k_j}}^{{j_i}}} \right)} \leqslant \sum\nolimits_{{l_j} \in {N^{{k_j}}}} {\left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{l_j}}}, {\alpha ^{{k_j}}}} \right) + \varsigma _{{k_j}}^{{l_j}}} \right)} } \right) \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ = \mathbb{P}\left( {\sum\nolimits_{{k_i} \in {N^{{j_i}}}} {\left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {k_i}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{k_i}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{k_i}}^*(t, x_{{k_i}}^{t*})} \right) + \varsigma _{{k_i}}^{{j_i}}} \right)} } \right. \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \leqslant \sum\nolimits_{{l_{i'}} \in {N^{{k_j}}}} {\left( {{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{ {j_i}, {l_{i'}}\} }}\left( {t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}, x_{{l_{i'}}}^{t*}, \phi _{{j_i}}^*(t, x_{{j_i}}^{t*}), \phi _{{l_{i'}}}^*(t, x_{{l_{i'}}}^{t*})} \right) + \varsigma _{{l_{i'}}}^{{j_i}}} \right)} \end{array} (21)
    \begin{array}{l} \left( {\forall {j_i} \in {\mathscr{I}}} \right)\left( {\forall {k_i} \in {\mathscr{I}}, {k_i} \in {N^{{j_i}}}} \right)\left( {\forall {k_j} \in N\backslash {j_i}} \right)\left( {\forall {l_j} \in {\mathscr{I}}, {l_j} \in {N^{{k_j}}}} \right): \hfill \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ {v^{({\text{Sub - process 6}}){j_i}, \beta }}(\omega ) = 1 - \frac{{\sum\nolimits_{{k_i} \in {N^{{j_i}}}} {\exp \left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{j_i}}}, {\alpha ^{{k_i}}}} \right)/\beta } \right)} }}{{\sum\nolimits_{{k_j} \in N\backslash {j_i}} {\sum\nolimits_{{l_j} \in {N^{{k_j}}}} {\exp \left( {\pi \left( {{\alpha ^{{l_j}}}, {\alpha ^{{k_j}}}} \right)/\beta } \right)} } }} \hfill \end{array} (22)

    Reconsidering the case of long time-scale, the binary tuple of an agent's strategy and the local topology would be considered as the system's state. The system evolves according to a state transition equation matched with the 6 subprocesses, which forms a stochastic process, a weak Markov process. By analyzing this process, the invariable distribution can be determined.

    Utilizing a dynamical model on a large time-scale, the complex adaptive system exhibits distinct properties as follows: (ⅰ) The behavior of any given agent within the system necessitates synchronization with the behaviors of its neighboring agents. (ⅱ) Decisions made by arbitrary agents, identifiable within a relatively short time-scale, should persist within this temporal interval. Notably, only a single property undergoes modification during each innovation event. (ⅲ) This intricate process is bifurcated into two levels: a macro level delineating the system's evolution law and a micro-level. This dynamic interplay unfolds through six events triggered by alterations in behavior configuration, local topological configuration, or simultaneous changes in both aspects. Furthermore, at the macro level, the 6 basic events are observable, and they occur as an independent probability that emerges from the micro-level. Set \tau \triangleq \frac{{{\lambda ^{({\text{sub - process 2}})\beta }} + {\lambda ^{({\text{sub - process 3}})\beta }} + {\lambda ^{({\text{sub - process 5}})\beta }}}}{{{\lambda ^{({\text{sub - process 4}})\beta }}}} to describe whether the system grows or declines. If it is far larger than 1, then the topological structure of the complex network decides the system developing, so the focus of the study is on the evolution law of complex networks. On the other hand, if it is far smaller than 1, then the changed behaviors control the system, making the stochastic differential games between agents the focus. If it is equal to or approximately equal to 1, the configuration can be regarded as stable.

    On a long time scale, the system's evolution process should be defined as a continuous stochastic process analyzed above, in which each short time should be reordered to the new order of the continuous-time point in the system evolution process on a long time scale. We introduce a new preferential attachment mechanism in which each agent interacts with another as a probability that relies on the attractor of its payoff converged in the corresponding short time interval to the complex adaptive system, which is an innovation of this paper. The evolution law of this complex adaptive system must be mined if, and only if, the state transition equation of the complex adaptive system is determined and the law of the system evolution is found.

    Let's consider an example with three agents, a smart agent, a normal agent, and a stupid agent; each agent consists of enough individuals; they interact with a homogenous individual or inhomogeneous individual in order to achieve their goal achieved. Smart individuals always have selective competitive behavior, and they are good at distributing resources, but stupid individuals have not; the normal individuals are in the middle. Furthermore, smart individuals make a decision according to Eqs (2), (6), (9), (15), (18) and (22) with larger \bar {\mathscr{N}} and their behavior is denoted by behavior x; the stupid individual would not select behavior with a maximum payoff with smaller \bar {\mathscr{N}} , and their behavior is denoted by behavior z; the behavior of normal individual is denoted by behavior y. We construct a multi-agent computation simulation model to analyze this system.

    This model is adapted from Epstein & Axtell's "Sugarscape" model. Each patch has several resources and a resource capacity (the number of resources) coupled with behavior. Individuals collect resources from the program and consume some resources to survive; this amount is called their metabolism. Each individual has a fixed vision; the larger the vision is, the smarter the individual is. Furthermore, an arbitrary individual's vision comes from both \bar {\mathscr{N}} and the predictive ability of the future, which relies on the noise he receives. Each individual who has the percentage of the best resources should be focused on; generally speaking, the smart one is always willing to struggle for the best resources. In our work, we consider five computational experiments in NetLogo. In the first computation experiment, we consider how different visions affect the system's behaviors. Set the minimum vision of the individual as 1, and the maximum vision as 15; we select 2, 3, 5, 10 and 15 to do this experiment, set the minimum expectation as 1, the maximum expectation 85, and the percent of best resource is 10%. So, the payoff of the average payoff of the system and the evolution process of these three strategies are shown in Figure 3.

    Figure 3.  Average payoff distribution and strategies evolution under a different vision.

    In the second computation experiment, we consider how different metabolisms affect the system's state and behavior. Set the maximum metabolisms as 5, 10, 15, 20 and 25, respectively, and set the minimum expectation as 1, the maximum expectation as 85, the percent of best resource as 10%, and the maximum vision as 1. The payoff of the average payoff of the system and the evolution process of these three strategies are shown in Figure 4.

    Figure 4.  Average payoff distribution and strategies evolution under different metabolism.

    In the third computation experiment, let's consider how different minimum expectations affect the system's state and behavior. Set the minimum expectations to be 10, 25, 50 and 70, respectively, and set the metabolisms to be 15, the maximum expected to be 85, the percent of best resource is 10%, and the maximum vision as 5. The payoff of the average payoff of the system and the evolution process of these three strategies are shown in Figure 5.

    Figure 5.  Average payoff distribution and strategies evolution under different minimum expectations.

    In the fourth computation experiment, let's consider how both different maximum expectations and minimum expectations affect the system's state and behavior. Set the maximum expectations as 70, 75, 80, 85 and 100, respectively, the minimum expectations to be 40, 50, 60 and 70, respectively, set the metabolisms as 15, the percent of best resource as 10%, maximum vision as 5. The payoff of the average payoff of the system and the evolution process of these three strategies are shown in Figure 6.

    Figure 6.  Average payoff distribution and strategies evolution under different minimum expectations and different maximum expectations.

    In the fifth computation experiment, let's consider how both different best resources affect the system's state and behavior. Set the best resources are 5, 15, 20 and 25%, respectively, set the metabolisms as 15, the maximum expectation as 85, the minimum expectation as 1, and the maximum vision as 5. The payoff of the average payoff of the system and the evolution process of these three strategies are shown in Figure 7.

    Figure 7.  Average payoff distribution and strategies evolution under different best resources.

    It is concluded that from Figures 37, the payoff of the system and the population using different strategies have been converted into a narrow interval, which means that there must exist an invariable distribution for these behaviors. Agent's decision-making process is influenced by the evolution of random complex networks driven by preferential attachment, coupled with a volatility mechanism linked to its payment—a dynamic that propels the evolution of the complex adaptive system.

    It is suggested from this example that, although there are different agents coupled with certain behaviors that are reflected by different parameters, collective behavior is converged into a certain attractor. Furthermore, one or few behaviors are selected for the collective behavior; otherwise, other behaviors are abandoned, which reflects that the invariable distribution has emerged under the interaction between agents.

    So, let's consider the corresponding process in this example. Observing the reachable time and holing time of this process, the following results can be described as Table 1.

    Table 1.  Distribution of behavior.
    Experiment Reachable time Holing time
    Behavior x Behavior y Behavior z Behavior x Behavior y Behavior z
    1-1 22 20 17 249 260 260
    1-2 44 30 50 239 230 237
    1-3 35 26 24 244 233 263
    1-4 26 26 21 295 295 277
    1-5 13 12 12 308 308 306
    2-1 92 88 24 174 147 217
    2-2 46 41 16 260 254 252
    2-3 22 16 23 282 273 288
    2-4 15 13 5 275 283 280
    2-5 15 13 4 270 273 270
    3-1 20 19 4 277 279 273
    3-2 63 47 22 258 259 267
    3-3 42 42 14 244 237 251
    3-4 40 38 36 256 254 251
    3-5 41 35 16 258 258 251
    3-6 20 20 7 171 149 240
    4-1 19 24 13 224 198 239
    4-2 31 30 11 254 248 269
    4-3 53 53 45 253 243 249
    4-4 63 30 18 183 182 213
    4-5 40 30 10 248 242 266
    4-6 67 62 29 202 216 214
    4-7 18 20 6 279 278 287
    5-1 26 22 3 294 294 262
    5-2 23 31 18 265 262 258
    5-3 53 53 9 238 234 243
    5-4 37 38 27 162 153 202

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Moreover, the model incorporates the ratios of owned best resources (representing the critical resources currently possessed by agents and anticipated in the future, constituting a pivotal constraint in decision-making) and the maximum metabolism (reflecting the agility of agents in adjusting their strategies and adaptively changing partners, thereby characterizing their volatility and stability). It is noteworthy that, due to the inherent irrationality of agents and their inability to precisely predict future system states, the minimum vision emerges as the least influential factor in behavioral collection. There are three types of agents now, and I would like to know which irrational factors influence the behavior of these three types of agents. So, we did a regression and when choosing we consider two order parameters for irrational behavior: the reachable time and duration of this behavior. We initially speculated that it was a generalized linear model. In this sense, two regressions were made. The result shows that it is basically satisfied. The square value of R is 0.87. Upon conducting a thorough statistical analysis, the principal findings are succinctly summarized in the ensuing Tables 2 and 3.

    Table 2.  The result of the generalized linear model of reachable time of behaviors x, y and z.
    Parameter Behavior x Behavior y Behavior z
    B importance B importance B importance
    (Intercept) 13.583 47.491 35.867
    minimum vision -1.523 0.0971 -1.065 0.0199 -0.670 0.1129
    minimum expectation 0.212 0.1058 0.133 0.1145 0.069 0.1419
    maximum expectation 0.496 0.2272 -0.026 0.1539 -0.186 0.1448
    best resource 267.909 0.2395 316.388 0.2013 74.690 0.2253
    maximum metabolism -2.901 0.3304 -2.936 0.5104 -0.505 0.3751
    (Scale) 186.639a 132.032a 127.743a
    Likelihood Ratio Chi-Square 14.397 17.041 2.069
    Sig. 0.013 0.004 0.840

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 3.  The result of generalized linear models of holding time of behaviors x, y and z.
    Parameter Behavior x Behavior y Behavior z
    B importance B importance B importance
    (Intercept) 211.758 150.397 204.926
    minimum vision 5.103 0.1373 5.158 0.1276 3.999 0.1482
    minimum expectation -0.400 0.2014 -0.459 0.2049 -0.266 0.2007
    maximum expectation 0.625 0.2052 1.246 0.2093 0.591 0.204
    best resource -692.174 0.2062 -805.665 0.2132 -468.154 0.2104
    maximum metabolism 2.784 0.2499 3.953 0.2449 2.391 0.2367
    (Scale) 551.218a 748.422a 194.528a
    Likelihood Ratio Chi-Square 19.361 18.537 24.142
    Sig. 0.002 0.002 0.000

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Based on the analysis presented in Tables 2 and 3, the following key insights emerge: Maximum metabolism reflected by the variable \phi (x_.^{t*}) (describing the transferring resource abilities and sources quantity) stands out as the paramount factor influencing the agent's behavior. Notably, it exerts an indirect negative impact on the reachable time of arbitrary behavior, but demonstrates a positive influence on the corresponding holding time. The ratio of an agent's best resources reflected by the variable x_.^{t*}(describing the absorbing-resource abilities and sources quantity) emerges as the second pivotal factor shaping strategy. This factor exhibits an indirect positive impact on the reachable time of arbitrary behavior while concurrently exerting a negative influence on its holding time. Additionally, the maximum expectation determined by \mathop {\max }\limits_{{a_v} \in {\mathscr{A}}} \left({{\pi ^{{j_i}}}\left({\alpha _{{j_i}}^{{a_v}}, g} \right) + \varepsilon _{{a_v}}^{{j_i}}} \right)\left| \omega \right. in Eq (1) and \left({{{\tilde W}^{(t)\{.\} }}\left({t, x_.^{t*}, \phi _.^*(t, x_.^{t*})} \right)/\beta } \right) in Eqs (2)–(22) ranks as the third critical factor affecting behavior, manifesting positive influences on both the reachable time and holding time of arbitrary behavior—this is because the classic irrational behavior of "every people pursue the expectation, but not the experience". In contrast, minimum vision driven by local configuration \omega is identified as the least consequential factor in shaping behavior, with an indirect negative impact on the reachable time of arbitrary behavior and a positive impact on its holding time. However, the effects are significant difference among smart collective, normal collective and stupid collective.

    This example explains our model well, and the behaviors of individuals and collectives are all co-evolved with local topological structure coming from individual interaction. In this model, according to the principle of "like attracts like", there occurs certain stochastic and dynamical Local-Worlds, and every individual selects the partners to pursue to maximum payment. Because the payment and location of all individuals are changed dynamically, the partners are all changed as Eqs (2)–(22). Similarily because each individual's payment relies on \omega , because \omega is changed dynamically and randomly, and because there are many different individuals in the system, payment is a stochastic process, and the minimum and maximum expectation are more important to set goals and strategies. Once the goal is set for each kind of people, smart individual, normal individual, and stupid individual in this example, the arbitrary individual should try their best to implement the corresponding goal by selecting the optimal strategies from his own strategies set. In this sense, a coevolutional system with behavior and local configuration is produced, as described as the model. In this model, a parameter named game radius is introduced, which is reflected by the rank of set \bar {\mathscr{N}}, to describe the local configuration. In this example, the parameter of vision is equal to game radius. Generally, the larger the vision, the more information he has to make an accurate decision. So, the vision size determines how smart an individual is and describes how rational a person is. As described in this example, it is concluded that the minimum vision has a negligible impact on the behavior and benefits different intelligent agents. However, the maximum vision is quite the opposite; it has a very significant impact on the behavior and benefits different intelligent agents.

    In classical research, the various irrational behaviors of agents have not been discussed in depth. This paper supplements this issue, which is one of the main contributions of this study. In this example, we discussed the coexistence of individuals with different rationalities in the system, interacting with each other according to their own set rules and the model provided in this paper. We found that in any situation, there is a polarization of behavior. In other words, as the interactions continue, agents gradually form behavioral inertia and relatively fixed local structures. Consequently, behaviors with different attributes will converge to a relatively stable attractor, and the system's behavior, function, and properties will become more stable. However, this conclusion, which has been proven to be correct by evidence, has not yet been discovered in existing research. This is enough to demonstrate the correctness of our model and the value of the research presented in this paper.

    Our research is notably intriguing, as the results seamlessly align with diverse social systems encompassing economic, management, political, and social domains. The system investigated in this study closely mirrors reality, offering practical solutions to numerous physical problems and yielding profound and general conclusions. Leveraging insights from the behavior evolution process and the law of invariant distribution in collective behavior enables rational decision-making. In the context of managing complex adaptive systems, the efficacy of optimal management strategies hinges upon the inherent functionality of the system. A pivotal consideration for managers is whether specific states within the complex adaptive system should be rapidly achieved or prolonged. This decision is particularly crucial for scenarios such as epidemic control, where expeditious attainment of certain states is imperative. In such cases, prioritizing the allocation of optimal resources followed by setting a high maximum expectation proves to be the most effective approach. Conversely, for situations requiring the perpetuation of specific states, such as sustainable production and political election campaigns, permitting maximum metabolism alongside establishing high maximum expectations is advised. The broad applicability and significance of this research underscores its universality, constituting a noteworthy contribution.

    The emergence of a stable distribution is contingent upon the strength of decay in a complex adaptive system. A robust decay amplifies the likelihood of an invariant distribution, while a weaker decay diminishes this probability. Consequently, the stability of the complex adaptive system is inherently influenced by the noise inherent in agent behaviors. Moreover, the introduction of random changes in the properties of arbitrary agents augments the complexity of the invariant distribution. With specified parameters, the invariant distribution assumes a deterministic nature. An illustrative example is presented to elucidate the evolution of diverse behaviors, demonstrating their convergence to corresponding attractors contingent on the system's initial conditions or scenarios. Irrespective of scenario changes, our defined conditions ensure system behavior stability.

    However, the introduction of irrational behaviors engenders a different behavioral pattern, a subject beyond the current scope, warranting consideration in future research. The present analysis, while comprehensive, has not delved into the intricacies of individual irrational behaviors such as preferential selection, laziness, prejudgment, and other related factors. This represents a significant and pressing area for future investigation. Understanding the nuanced dynamics of these specific irrational behaviors is paramount for a comprehensive grasp of the complex adaptive system under consideration. As these behaviors can wield substantial influence on decision-making processes and overall system dynamics, their detailed examination is warranted to enhance the depth and scope of our understanding. Consequently, delving into the impact and interplay of preferential selection, laziness, prejudgment, and similar behaviors is identified as a crucial avenue for future research within the context of this study. Addressing these individual irrational behaviors will undoubtedly contribute to a more nuanced and holistic comprehension of the overarching complex adaptive system dynamics, offering valuable insights for both theoretical and practical applications.

    The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    This paper is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (72174064, 12101021); the Natural Science Foundation of Shandong Province (ZR2020MG004).

    The authors declare that they have no competing interests.



    [1] Adekoya OB, Oliyide JA, Oduyemi GO (2021) How COVID-19 upturns the hedging potentials of gold against oil and stock markets risks: Nonlinear evidences through threshold regression and markov-regime switching models. Resour Policy 70: 101926. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2020.101926 doi: 10.1016/j.resourpol.2020.101926
    [2] Algieri B (2017) Assessing contagion risk from energy and non-energy commodity markets. Energy Econ 62: 312–322. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2017.01.006 doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2017.01.006
    [3] Ante L (2020) Bitcoin transactions, information asymmetry and trading volume. Quant Financ Econ 4: 365–381. https://doi.org/ 10.3934/QFE.2020017 doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020017
    [4] Arize AC, Malindretos J, Igwe EU (2017) Do exchange rate changes improve the trade balance: An asymmetric nonlinear cointegration approach. Int Rev Econ Financ 49: 313–326. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2017.02.007 doi: 10.1016/j.iref.2017.02.007
    [5] Balli F, Farid S, Shahzad SJH, et al. (2019) Spillover network of commodity uncertainties. Energy Econ 81: 914–927. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2019.06.001 doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2019.06.001
    [6] Bongards O, Czudaj RL, Van Hoang TH (2021) Price overreactions in the commodity futures market: An intraday analysis of the Covid-19 pandemic impact. Resour Policy 71: 101966. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2020.101966 doi: 10.1016/j.resourpol.2020.101966
    [7] Bouri E, Gupta R, Lahiani A, et al. (2018) Testing for asymmetric nonlinear short- and long-run relationships between bitcoin, aggregate commodity and gold prices. Resour Policy 57: 224–235. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2018.03.008 doi: 10.1016/j.resourpol.2018.03.008
    [8] Bouri E, Jalkh N, Molnár P, et al. (2017). Bitcoin for energy commodities before and after the December 2013 crash: diversifier, hedge or safe haven? Appl Econ 50: 5063–5070. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2017.1299102 doi: 10.1080/00036846.2017.1299102
    [9] Brock WA, Dechert WD, Scheinkman JA, et al. (1996) A Test for Independence Based on the Correlation Dimension. Econometric Rev 15: 197–235. https://doi.org/10.1080/07474939608800353 doi: 10.1080/07474939608800353
    [10] Canh NP, Binh NQ, Thanh SD (2019) Cryptocurrencies and Investment Diversification: Empirical Evidence from Seven Largest Cryptocurrencies. Theor Econ Lett 9: 431–452. https://doi.org/10.4236/tel.2019.93031 doi: 10.4236/tel.2019.93031
    [11] Charfeddine L, Benlagha N, Maouchi Y (2020) Investigating the dynamic relationship between cryptocurrencies and conventional assets: Implications for financial investors. Econ Model 85: 198–217. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2019.05.016 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2019.05.016
    [12] Ciaian P, Rajcaniova M, d'Artis K (2018) Virtual relationships: Short- and long-run evidence from BitCoin and altcoin markets. J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 52: 173–195. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intfin.2017.11.001 doi: 10.1016/j.intfin.2017.11.001
    [13] Conlon T, McGee R (2020) Safe haven or risky hazard? Bitcoin during the Covid-19 bear market. Financ Res Lett 35: 101607. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101607 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101607
    [14] Corbet S, Larkin C, Lucey B (2020a) The contagion effects of the COVID-19 pandemic: Evidence from gold and cryptocurrencies. Financ Res Lett 35: 101554. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101554 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101554
    [15] Corbet S, Hou YG, Larkin C, et al. (2020b) Any port in a storm: Cryptocurrency safe-havens during the COVID-19 pandemic. Econ Lett 194: 109337. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2020.109377 doi: 10.1016/j.econlet.2020.109377
    [16] Corbet S, Meegan A, Larkin C, et al. (2018) Exploring the dynamic relationships between cryptocurrencies and other financial assets. Econ Lett 165: 28–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2018.01.004 doi: 10.1016/j.econlet.2018.01.004
    [17] Demir E, Simonyan S, García-Gómez CD, et al. (2021) The asymmetric effect of bitcoin on altcoins: evidence from the nonlinear autoregressive distributed lag (NARDL) model. Financ Res Lett 40: 101754. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101754 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101754
    [18] Demiralay S, Golitsis P (2021) On the dynamic equicorrelations in cryptocurrency market. Q Rev Econ Financ 80: 524–533. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2021.04.002 doi: 10.1016/j.qref.2021.04.002
    [19] Ferrer R, Jawad S, López R, et al. (2018) Time and frequency dynamics of connectedness between renewable energy stocks and crude oil prices. Energy Econ 76: 1–20. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2018.09.022 doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2018.09.022
    [20] González M, Jareño F, Skinner FS (2020a) Nonlinear Autoregressive Distributed Lag Approach: An Application on the Connectedness between Bitcoin Returns and the Other Ten Most Relevant Cryptocurrency Returns. Mathematics 8: 810. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8050810 doi: 10.3390/math8050810
    [21] González M, Jareño F, Skinner F (2020b) Portfolio Effects of Cryptocurrencies During the COVID-19 Crisis, En C. Bagnoli, M. Billio, & S. Varotto (Edits.), A New World Post COVID-19, Lessons for Business, the Finance Industry and Policy Makers, Venezia: Edizioni Ca' Foscari—Digital Publishing, 149–161. http://doi.org/10.30687/978-88-6969-442-4
    [22] González MO, Jareño F, Skinner FS (2021) Asymmetric interdependencies between large capital cryptocurrency and gold returns during the COVID-19 pandemic crisis. Int Rev Financ Anal 76: 101773. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2021.101773 doi: 10.1016/j.irfa.2021.101773
    [23] Goodell JW, Goutte S (2021) Co-movement of COVID-19 and Bitcoin: Evidence from wavelet coherence analysis. Financ Res Lett 38: 101625. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101625 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101625
    [24] Gyamerah SA (2019) Modelling the volatility of Bitcoin returns using GARCH models. Quant Financ Econ 3: 739–753. https://doi.org/10.3934/QFE.2019.4.739 doi: 10.3934/QFE.2019.4.739
    [25] Jareño F, González MO, López R, et al. (2021) Cryptocurrencies and oil price shocks: A NARDL analysis in the COVID-19 pandemic. Resour Policy 74: 102281. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2021.102281 doi: 10.1016/j.resourpol.2021.102281
    [26] Jareño F, Tolentino M, González MO, et al. (2019) Impact of changes in the level, slope and curvature of interest rates on US sector returns: an asymmetric nonlinear cointegration approach. Econ Res 32: 1275–1297. https://doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2019.1632726
    [27] Jareño F, González M, Tolentino M, et al. (2020) Bitcoin and Gold Price Returns: A Quantile Regression and NARDL Analysis. Resour Policy 67: 101666. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2020.101666 doi: 10.1016/j.resourpol.2020.101666
    [28] Ji Q, Bouri E, Roubaud D, et al. (2018) Risk spillover between energy and agricultural commodity markets: A dependence-switching CoVaR-copula model. Energy Econ 75: 14–27. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2018.08.015 doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2018.08.015
    [29] Ji Q, Zhang D, Zhao Y (2020) Searching for safe-haven assets during the COVID-19 pandemic. Int Rev Financ Anal 71: 101526. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2020.101526 doi: 10.1016/j.irfa.2020.101526
    [30] Jiang Y, Lie J, Wang J, et al. (2021) Revisiting the roles of cryptocurrencies in stock markets: A quantile coherency perspective. Econ Model 95: 21–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2020.12.002 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2020.12.002
    [31] Kang SH, McIver R, Yoon SM (2017) Dynamic spillover effects among crude oil, precious metal, and agricultural commodity futures markets. Energy Econ 62: 19–32. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2016.12.011 doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2016.12.011
    [32] Koirala KH, Mishra AK, D'Antoni JM, et al. (2015) Energy prices and agricultural commodity prices: Testing correlation using copulas method. Energy 81: 420–436. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2014.12.055 doi: 10.1016/j.energy.2014.12.055
    [33] Kwapień J, Wątorek M, Drożdż S (2021) Cryptocurrency Market Consolidation in 2020–2021. Entropy 23: 1674. https://doi.org/10.3390/e23121674 doi: 10.3390/e23121674
    [34] Lin B, Su T (2021) Does COVID-19 open a Pandora's box of changing the connectedness in energy commodities? Res Int Bus Financ 56: 101360. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ribaf.2020.101360 doi: 10.1016/j.ribaf.2020.101360
    [35] Mariana CD, Ekaputra IA, Ananto ZH (2021) Are Bitcoin and Ethereum safe-havens for stocks during the COVID-19 pandemic? Financ Res Lett 38: 101798. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101798 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101798
    [36] Naeem MA, Farid S, Balli F, et al. (2020) Hedging the downside risk of commodities through cryptocurrencies. Appl Econ Lett 28: 153–160. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2020.1739609 doi: 10.1080/13504851.2020.1739609
    [37] Nazlioglu S (2011) World oil and agricultural commodity prices: Evidence from nonlinear causality. Energy Policy 39: 2935–2943. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2011.03.001 doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2011.03.001
    [38] Pabuçcu H, Ongan S, Ongan A (2020) Forecasting the movements of Bitcoin prices: an aplication of machine learning algorithms. Quant Financ Econ 4: 679–692. https://doi.org/10.3934/QFE.2020031 doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020031
    [39] Papadamou S, Kyriazis NA, Tzeremes PG (2021a) Non-linear causal linkages of EPU and gold with major cryptocurrencies during bull and bear markets. North Am J Econ Financ 56: 101343. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2020.101343 doi: 10.1016/j.najef.2020.101343
    [40] Papadamou S, Kyriazis NA, Tzeremes PG, et al. (2021b) Herding behaviour and price convergence clubs in cryptocurrencies during bull and bear markets. J Behav Exp Financ 30: 100469. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2021.100469 doi: 10.1016/j.jbef.2021.100469
    [41] Pesaran M, Shin Y (1999) An autoregressive distributed lag modelling approach to cointegration analysis, In: Storm, S. (Ed.), Econometrics and Economic Theory in the 20th Century: the Ragnar Frisch Centennial Symposium, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
    [42] Peterson OJ, Anokye MA, Tweneboah G, et al. (2020) Connectedness of cryptocurrencies and gold returns: Evidence from frequency-dependent quantile regressions. Cogent Econ Financ 8: 1. https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2020.1804037 doi: 10.1080/23322039.2020.1804037
    [43] Rajput H, Changotra R, Rajput P, et al. (2020) A shock like no other: coronavirus rattles commodity markets. Environ Dev Sustainability 11: 1–12. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-020-00934-4 doi: 10.1007/s10668-020-00934-4
    [44] Salisu AA, Akanni L, Raheem I (2020) The COVID-19 global fear index and the predictability of commodity price returns. J Behav Exp Finance 27: 100383. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2020.100383 doi: 10.1016/j.jbef.2020.100383
    [45] Shin Y, Yu B, Greenwood-Nimmo M (2014) Modelling Asymmetric Cointegration and Dynamic Multipliers in a Nonlinear ARDL Framework, In: Festschrift in Honor of Peter Schmidt, Springer Science and Business Media LLC: New York, NY, 281–314.
    [46] Shruthi MS, Ramani D (2021) Statistical analysis of impact of COVID 19 on India commodity markets. Mater Today Proc 37: 2306–2311. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.matpr.2020.07.729 doi: 10.1016/j.matpr.2020.07.729
    [47] Sifat I (2021) On cryptocurrencies as an independent asset class: Long-horizon and COVID-19 pandemic era decoupling from global sentiments. Financ Res Lett, 102013. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2021.102013 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2021.102013
    [48] Smales LA (2019) Bitcoin as a safe haven: is it even worth considering? Financ Res Lett 30: 385–393. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2018.11.002 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2018.11.002
    [49] Symitsi E, Chalvatzis KJ (2019) The economic value of Bitcoin: A portfolio analysis of currencies Gold oil and stocks. Res Int Bus Financ 48: 97–110. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ribaf.2018.12.001 doi: 10.1016/j.ribaf.2018.12.001
    [50] Umar Z, Gubareva M (2020) A time–frequency analysis of the impact of the Covid-19 induced panic on the volatility of currency and cryptocurrency markets. J Behav Exp Financ 28: 100404. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2020.100404 doi: 10.1016/j.jbef.2020.100404
    [51] Umar Z, Jareño F, Escribano A (2021a) Agricultural commodity markets and oil prices: An analysis of the dynamic return and volatility connectedness. Resour Policy 73: 102147. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2021.102147 doi: 10.1016/j.resourpol.2021.102147
    [52] Umar Z, Jareño F, Escribano A (2021b) Oil price shocks and the return and volatility spillover between industrial and precious metals. Energy Econ 99: 105291. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2021.105291 doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2021.105291
    [53] Umar Z, Jareño F, González M (2021c) The impact of COVID-19 related media coverage on the return and volatility connectedness of cryptocurrencies and fiat currencies. Technol Forecast Social Change 172: 121025, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2021.121025 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2021.121025
    [54] Wang G, Tang Y, Xie C, et al. (2019) Is bitcoin a safe haven or a hedging asset? Evidence from China. J Manage Sci Eng 4: 173–188. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmse.2019.09.001 doi: 10.1016/j.jmse.2019.09.001
    [55] Wu S, Tong M, Yang Z, et al. (2019) Does gold or Bitcoin hedge economic policy uncertainty? Financ Res Lett 31: 171–178. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2019.04.001 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2019.04.001
    [56] Xiao H (2020) Forecasting the Returns of Cryptocurrency: A Model Averaging Approach. J Risk Financ Manage 13: 278. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm13110278 doi: 10.3390/jrfm13110278
    [57] Zivot E, Andrews DWK (1992) Further Evidence on the Great Crash, the Oil-Price Shock, and the Unit-Root Hypothesis. J Bus Econ Stat 10: 251–270. https://doi.org/10.1198/073500102753410372 doi: 10.1198/073500102753410372
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2022 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(3196) PDF downloads(175) Cited by(8)

Figures and Tables

Tables(4)

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog