Research article Special Issues

Can shocks to the discount factor explain business cycle fluctuations in Bulgaria (1999–2018)?

  • A stochastic discount factor is introduced into a real-business-cycle setup with a government sector. The model is calibrated to Bulgarian data for the period 1999–2018, which is after the introduction of the currency board arrangement. The quantitative importance of shocks to the discount factor is investigated for the propagation of cyclical fluctuations in Bulgaria. In particular, allowing for a stochastic discount factor in the setup improves the model fit vis-a-vis data by increasing variability of employment and wages. However, those improvements are at the cost of increasing the volatility of consumption and investment.

    Citation: Aleksandar Vasilev. Can shocks to the discount factor explain business cycle fluctuations in Bulgaria (1999–2018)?[J]. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(3): 285-296. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020016

    Related Papers:

    [1] Aleksandar Vasilev . A progressive capital income tax — a bad idea, or just a useless idea? Lessons for Bulgaria (1999-2018). National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(4): 402-411. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020024
    [2] David Gray . Medium-term cycles in affordability: what does the house price to income ratio indicate?. National Accounting Review, 2021, 3(2): 204-217. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2021010
    [3] Duncan O. Hongo, Fanglin Li, Max William Ssali, Maurice Simiyu Nyaranga, Zephaniah Moriaso Musamba, Brenda Nelima Lusaka . Inflation, unemployment and subjective wellbeing: nonlinear and asymmetric influences of economic growth. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(1): 1-25. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020001
    [4] Nikolaos T. Giannakopoulos, Damianos P. Sakas, Nikos Kanellos, Christos Christopoulos . Web analytics and supply chain transportation firms' financial performance. National Accounting Review, 2023, 5(4): 405-420. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2023023
    [5] Pavel Ivanov, Tatyana Altufeva . Stimulating the processes of attracting investments in industry of the constituent entities of the Russian Federation. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(3): 352-366. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024016
    [6] Shengyin Ouyang, Ziqing Du, Meiling Cai . Statistical measurement of the impact of monetary policy on price levels. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 188-203. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020011
    [7] Luccas Assis Attílio . Impact of Chinese financial shocks: A GVAR approach. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(1): 27-49. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024002
    [8] Tinghui Li, Zimei Huang, Benjamin M Drakeford . Statistical measurement of total factor productivity under resource and environmental constraints. National Accounting Review, 2019, 1(1): 16-27. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2019.1.16
    [9] Jaroslav Sedláček, Veronika Popelková . Non-financial information and their reporting—evidence of small and medium-sized enterprises and large corporations on the Czech capital market. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(2): 204-216. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020012
    [10] Giorgio Garau . Total factor productivity and relative prices: the case of Italy. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(1): 16-37. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022002
  • A stochastic discount factor is introduced into a real-business-cycle setup with a government sector. The model is calibrated to Bulgarian data for the period 1999–2018, which is after the introduction of the currency board arrangement. The quantitative importance of shocks to the discount factor is investigated for the propagation of cyclical fluctuations in Bulgaria. In particular, allowing for a stochastic discount factor in the setup improves the model fit vis-a-vis data by increasing variability of employment and wages. However, those improvements are at the cost of increasing the volatility of consumption and investment.


    The standard real-business-cycle (RBC) model was introduced in modern quantitative dynamic macroeconomics as a modelling tool that allows researchers to create artificial economies, which approximate those of existing countries along important agammaegate dimensions, and use those simulated environments to generate artificial, or model-predicted time series, which are then compared to the properties of empirical (observed) time series. In this way the models could be interpreted as disciplined data-generating mechanisms for data matching akin to the general method of moments (GMM) in econometrics. Alternatively, those simulated data series could be interpreted as a maximum likelihood estimation (MLE), investigating how likely is that the observed time series were produced by the theoretical model. In addition, and in important contrast to ad hoc dynamic econometric models (e.g., Vector-Auto-Regressions, or VARs) used in time series analysis, the important transmission mechanisms (based on inter- and intra-temporal optimality principles) in these theoretical model economies are explicit, as those setups are based on micro-foundations, so macroeconomic researchers could gain a deeper insight about how the real economy works. Finally, those model economies could be used for computational experiments, which could produce quantitative assessments of policies and reforms that are not yet implemented. This is again a strong advantage to econometric estimation, which is not useful in such contexts.

    The technical procedure used in the quantitative theoretical macroeconomic literature to assign values of the parameters in the model is called calibration. In contrast to what many applied researchers think/believe, calibration is not done in an arbitrary fashion; In particular, calibration is preferred to estimation in cases when we already have data for certain parameters, or we have a target from data that we need to match in the model, which will constrain the calibration procedure and determine ("identify" in econometric language) the value of that parameter. In addition, calibration is preferred in cases when we do not have information on the parameter, and want to investigate how the model predictions change when the parameter changes over a certain (plausible) range, i.e, how robust is the model to slight changes in certain parameters. Then, after calibrating all model parameters, we can proceed to simulate the model to produce artificial time series.

    With regard to the individual variability of the parameter estimates above, the question "why just settle for a particular point estimate?" may be raised. In particular, the core of the criticism raised by some economists is that by giving up the variability in the parameter (or parameters), researchers are giving up information, which might be potentially useful.* We can thus argue that holding the discount factor parameter fixed over the cycle might lead researchers to wrong conclusions. We thus allow the discount factor to vary in order to evaluate the importance of the information contained in the variability of this parameter. It is thus plausible to assume that household's discount factor can change over the business cycle. In the model setup, the discount factor parameter shows up in the dynamic optimality condition for the household, which determines how capital is allocated across periods, so a shock to the discount factor in turn will interest rates, wages, and thus labor, capital, production, investment, and consumption decisions as well. Therefore, allowing for a stochastic discount factor in the theoretical setup can generate additional interesting interactions among model variables.

    * As pointed out in Vasilev (2020), an alternative approach in macroeconomic modelling is to estimate those RBC models using techniques based on Bayesian statistical approach. In particular, those researchers take each parameter to follow a distribution, and thus, in addition to the mean, also take into consideration the standard deviation of the distribution.

    Parkin (1988) uses such a technique (which he refers to as "strip mining") as a test whether RBC model parameters are structural. Similarly, for Bulgaria Vasilev (2020) studies the effect of a stochastic capital share, Vasilev (2019a) studies the effect of a stochastic leisure preference parameter, while Vasilev (2019b) investigates the quantitative effect of an endogenously determined depreciation rate.

    This proposal is taken seriously, and this paper incorporates a stochastic discount factor in an otherwise standard real-business-cycle (RBC) model with a detailed government sector. The model is calibrated for Bulgaria in the period 1999–2018, as Bulgaria provides a good testing case for the theory. The paper then proceeds to quantitatively evaluate the effect of such a stochasticity as a mechanism of business cycle propagation. This is the first study on the issue using modern macroeconomic modelling techniques, and thus an important contribution to the field. Unfortunately, for reasonable degree of discount factor variability, the quantitative effects are tiny.In particular, allowing for a stochastic discount factor in the setup improves the model fit vis-a-vis data by increasing variability of employment and wages. However, those improvements are at the cost of increasing the volatility of consumption and investment. The small effect of the discount factor stochasticity can be viewed as a validation of the robustness of the standard real business cycle model with a constant rate of discounting.

    Before the introduction of proportional income taxation of 10 percent in 2008, Bulgaria operated a progressive income taxation regime during the period 1993–2007 with the same effective rate. In addition, the corporate income tax rate has been reduced, in several steps, to a proportional rate of 10 percent in 2007 as well, to avoid incentives to move earnings across the income categories.

    The remaining of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 presents the model framework and defines the market equilibrium, Section 3 explains the calibration procedure, and Section 4 computes the steady-state model solution. Sections 5 proceeds with the general dynamics of model variables, and compared the theoretical second moments of model variables against their empirical counterparts. Section 6 concludes.

    In the model, there is a representative household, which derives utility out of private consumption and leisure. The total time available to the household can be used as a labor resource, or as leisure. The government taxes private consumption, and levies a proportional tax rate on labor and capital income, in order to finance government consumption and public transfers. On the production side, there is a stand-in firm, which uses labor and capital to produce final output, which could be used for consumption, investment, or government spending.

    There is a representative household, which maximizes its discounted utility function

    maxE0t=0βtt{lnctγht} (1)

    where E0 is the household's expectation operator as of period 0, ct refers to household's private consumption in period t, ht are hours spent working in period t, 0<βt<1 is the stochastic discount factor, and γ>0 is the relative utility weight attached to leisure.

    The household begins with a positive initial stock of physical capital k0>0, and chooses how much to increase it via investment. The evolution of physical capital is as follows:

    kt+1=it+(1δ)kt (2)

    where 0<δ<1 is the linear depreciation rate. Next, the real interest rate is denoted by rt, thus the before-tax capital income of the household in period t is represented by rtkt. In addition, the household can earn labor income: the going hourly wage rate of wt, so pre-tax labor income generated is wtht. Lastly, the household is a sole owner of the firm in the economy and receives all of the firm's profit, πt.

    The household's problem becomes

    maxE0t=0βtt{lnctγht} (3)

    s.t.

    (1+τc)ct+kt+1(1δ)kt=(1τy)[rtkt+πt+wtht]+gtt (4)

    where where τc is the tax on consumption, τy is the proportional income tax rate on labor (0<τc,τy<1), and gtt are government transfers. The household takes the tax rates {τc,τy}t=0, government spending categories, {gct,gtt}t=0, profit {πt}t=0, the realized technology process {At}t=0, the process followed by the discount factor {βt}t=0, prices {wt,rt}t=0, and chooses allocations {ct,ht,kt+1}t=0 to maximize its discounted expected utility subject to the budget constraint.§ The first-order optimality conditions as as follows:

    § Note that by choosing kt+1 the household is implicitly setting investment it optimally.

    ct:1ct=λt(1+τc) (5)
    ht:γ=λt(1τy)wt (6)
    kt+1:λt=Etβt+1λt+1[1+[1τy]rt+1δ] (7)
    TVC:limtβttλtkt+1=0 (8)

    where λt denotes the Lagrangean multiplier attached to household's budget constraint in period t. In turn, the first-order conditions above are interpreted as follows: for each household, at the optimum, the marginal utility of consumption balances the marginal utility of wealth, corrected for the consumption tax rate. Next, when choosing optimal labor supply, a balance is achieved between the benefit from working, and the cost in terms of lower utility. The third equation is referred to as the "Euler condition, " which indirectly determines how the household optimally allocates physical capital across any two congruent periods. Note that the stochastic discount factor will disturb the Euler condition. The last condition is referred to as the "transversality condition" (TVC): ithis is a boundary condition, which states that beyond the optimization horizon, capital becomes worthless.

    There is a stand-in firm in the economy, which produces all final output. The price of output is chosen to be the numeraire. The production technology is assumed to be Cobb-Douglas, which requires both capital, kt, and labor, ht, to produce and maximize firm's static profit

    Πt=Atkαth1αtrtktwtht (9)

    where At denotes the level of total factor productivity in period t. As the firm rents the inputs from the market, the problem of the firm collapses to a sequence of static profit maximizing problems. In equilibrium, each factor of production is priced competitively, i.e.:

    kt:αytkt=rt (10)
    ht:(1α)ytht=wt (11)

    In equilibrium, given that the inputs of production are paid their marginal products, πt=0, t.

    In this model economy, the government is levying taxes on labor and capital income, as well as consumption, in order to finance spending on wasteful government purchases, and government transfers. The government period budget constraint is as follows:

    gct+gtt=τcct+τy[wtht+rtkt+πt] (12)

    In the calibration section later, income and consumption tax rates and government consumption-to-output ratio would be chosen to match the average share in data, while transfers would be determined residually to keep the government budget balanced.

    For a given processes followed by total factor productivity and the stochastic discount factor, {At,σt}t=0, the two tax schedules {τc,τy}t=0, initial value of the physical capital stock {k0}, the DCE for this economy is a list of sequences {ct,it,kt,ht,gct,gtt}t=0, and input prices {wt,rt}t=0 such that (i) the representative household maximizes its discounted expected utility function subject to its budget constraint; (ii) the stand-in firm maximizes total profit; (iii) government runs a balanced budget; (iv) all markets clear.

    To characterize the business cycle fluctuations in Bulgaria, we focus on the period 1999–2018, which is after the introduction of the currency board (1999–2018). Quarterly data on output, consumption and investment was collected from the National Statistical Institute (2020), while the real interest rate series is taken from Bulgarian National Bank Statistical Database (2020). The calibration strategy described in this section is standard: first, as in Vasilev (2016), the steady-state discount factor, β=0.982, is chosen to match the equilibrium capital-to-output ratio in Bulgaria, k/y=13.964. Next, labor share, 1α=0.571, was set to the average value of labor income in agammaegate output over the period 1999–2018. Next, the average income tax rate was set to its average effective rate in data, τy=0.1. Similarly, the average tax rate on consumption is set to its value over the period, τc=0.2.

    Next, the relative weight attached to the utility out of leisure in the household's utility function, γ, is calibrated to match the steady-state hours worked. Next, capital depreciation rate, δ=0.013, was set equal to the average quarterly depreciation rate over the period. Finally, an AR(1) process was fit on the total factor productivity series. Due to the lack of data, we make use of the same parameters for the stochastic discount factor process in the computational experiments performed later. Table 1 below summarizes the values of all model parameters used in the paper.

    Table 1.  Model parameters.
    Parameter Value Description Method
    β 0.982 Discount factor Calibrated
    α 0.429 Capital Share Data average
    γ 0.873 Relative utility weight, leisure Calibrated
    δ 0.013 Depreciation rate, physical capital Data average
    τy 0.100 Income tax rate Data average
    τc 0.200 VAT/consumption tax rate Data average
    ρa 0.701 AR(1) persistence coefficient, TFP process Estimated
    σa 0.044 st. error, TFP process Estimated
    ρβ 0.701 AR(1) persistence coefficient, discount factor Set
    σβ 0.044 st. error, discount factor Set

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Given the model parameters, the steady-state equilibrium system can be now solved, and the "big ratios" can be compared to their empirical averages. The results are reported in Table 2 below. The stochastic discount factor plays no role in these computation. Next, the model matches quite well consumption-to-outpu, government purchases ratio, and investment ratios are also closely approximated. Labor and capital income shares of income are also identical to those in data, which follows from the Cobb-Douglas form of the agammaegate production function. The after-tax return on capital, denoted by ˉr=(1τy)rδ is also relatively well-approximated by the model economy.

    Table 2.  Data Averages and Long-run Solution.
    Variable Description Data Model
    y Steady-state output N/A 1.000
    c/y Consumption-to-output ratio 0.648 0.674
    i/y Investment-to-output ratio 0.201 0.175
    k/y Capital-to-output ratio 13.96 13.96
    gc/y Government consumption-to-output ratio 0.151 0.151
    wh/y Labor income-to-output ratio 0.571 0.571
    rk/y Capital income-to-output ratio 0.429 0.429
    h Share of time spent working 0.333 0.333
    ˉr After-tax net return on capital 0.014 0.016

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    For the general case, the model in this paper does not possess an analytical solution, so we need to solve it numerically. We do this by log-linearizing the original system of equations around the steady-state, which produces a first-order system of stochastic difference equations; Those are easy to solve for. Next, we present the effects of an isolated shock to the total factor productivity process and the discount factor; then we fully simulate the model to compare the theoretical moments of the model against the empirical ones.

    This subsection documents the impulse responses of model variables to a 1% surprise innovation to total factor productivity, and the discount factor. The impulse response functions (IRFs) are presented in Figure 1 and Figure 2 for the ttotal factor productivity and the discount-factor shocks, respectively. As a result of the one-time shock to total factor productivity, output increases contemporaneously, which expands the availability of all resources in the economy; hence, all uses of output---consumption, investment, and government consumption also increase upon impact.

    Figure 1.  Impulse Responses to a 1% surprise innovation in technology.
    Figure 2.  Impulse Responses to a 1% surprise innovation in discount factor.

    At the same time, the jump in total factor productivity increases the two input prices, those of labor and capital. The representative households then respond to these developments and begins to accumulate capital, and works more. In turn, the increase in capital and labor use in production increases output further.

    Over time, as capital stock increases, decreasing returns kick in, and its after-tax marginal product begins to decrease, which lowers the households' incentives to invest, and capital returns to its steady-state in a hump-shaped fashion. The rest of the model variables return to their old steady-states following a monotone pattern.

    The second shock is a one-time innovation to the discount factor. The results are summarized in Figure 2 on the next page. Overall, the effect of this shock is quite small, so changes in discount factor are unlikely candidates for business cycle propagators. In particular, upon impact of the shock, the Euler equation is disturbed. Investment increases, and capital accumulation speeds up. Next, due to the complementarity between capital and labor, the marginal product of labor increases, and hours worked increase. The increase in hours worked increases directly output, and indirectly capital through the increase in the marginal productivity of capital, the interest rate, which incentivizes the household to invest in capital. In the short run the increase in investment is at the cost of current consumption, so it falls upon impact of the shock. Overall, the effect of the shock to the discount factor is very short-lived, and variables return quickly to their old steady-states.

    As in Vasilev (2017b), we proceed to fully simulate the model for the length of the data horizon. Both the actual and simulated data is detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott (1980) filter. Table 3 on the next page summarizes the second moments of data vs the model predicted ones. The generated results are the case with both shocks, and discount-factor, and technology shocks only, respectively.

    Table 3.  Business cycle moments.
    Data Both Shocks Beta shocks only Technology Shocks only
    σy 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05
    σc/σy 0.55 0.92 1.01 0.85
    σi/σy 1.77 3.42 4.92 2.24
    σg/σy 1.21 1.00 1.00 1.00
    σh/σy 0.63 0.71 1.01 0.48
    σw/σy 0.83 0.92 1.01 0.85
    σy/h/σy 0.86 0.92 1.01 0.85
    corr(c,y) 0.85 0.66 0.35 0.90
    corr(i,y) 0.61 0.65 0.66 0.80
    corr(g,y) 0.31 1.00 1.00 1.00
    corr(h,y) 0.49 0.31 0.35 0.39
    corr(w,y) 0.01 0.80 0.35 0.90

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    As in Vasilev(2016, 2017b, 2017c), the models match quite well the absolute volatility of output and investment. In addition, the predicted consumption and investment volatilities are too high. Still, the models are qualitatively consistent with the pattern that consumption is smoother than output, while investment is much more variable than output. The model with both shocks at work generates a more variable consumption, investment, wage- and employment series, as compared to a model with only total factor productivity at work. Therefore, it can be argued that the addition of stochasticity in the discount-factor improves the model performance vis-a-vis data, as it adds disturbance in the Euler equation, which is a central equation in the model.

    Looking at the labor market variables, the variability of employment and wages in the model with both shocks is higher than that in data, which confirms that the assumption of perfect competition, e.g. Vasilev (2009), as well as the benchmark calibration here, is not a good approximation of reality. Next, in terms of correlations with output, the model with both shocks systematically under-predicts the pro-cyclicality of consumption, investment, and over-predicts the pro-cyclicality of government consumption. Next, the correlation of employment with output in the model is too low, while wages are predicted to be highly pro-cyclical, which is a puzzle, as in data wages are acyclical. This mismatch follows from the wage being equal to the labor productivity condition produced by the model.

    In the next subsection, as in Vasilev (2016), we turn our attention to the dynamic correlation between labor market variables and output. To this end, the autocorrelation functions (ACFs) are compared and contrasted to the simulated ones from the model economy.

    This subsection presents and analyzes the auto-(ACFs) and cross-correlation functions (CCFs) of the main variables featured in the model. In particular, the coefficients empirical ACFs and CCFs are presented in Table 4 below against the simulated ones. To economize on space, we only present the case with both total factor productivity and discount-factor shocks.

    Following Canova (2007), this is used as measure capturing overall goodness-of-fit of the model.

    Table 4.  Autocorrelations for Bulgarian data and the model economy.
    k
    Method Statistic 0 1 2 3
    Data corr(nt,ntk) 1.000 0.484 0.009 0.352
    Model corr(nt,ntk) 1.000 0.952 0.893 0.825
    (s.e.) (0.000) (0.029) (0.055) (0.080)
    Data corr(yt,ytk) 1.000 0.810 0.663 0.479
    Model corr(yt,ytk) 1.000 0.957 0.906 0.846
    (s.e.) (0.000) (0.025) (0.048) (0.070)
    Data corr(at,atk) 1.000 0.702 0.449 0.277
    Model corr(at,atk) 1.000 0.956 0.902 0.839
    (s.e.) (0.000) (0.027) (0.052) (0.075)
    Data corr(ct,ctk) 1.000 0.971 0.952 0.913
    Model corr(ct,ctk) 1.000 0.955 0.900 0.838
    (s.e.) (0.000) (0.027) (0.052) (0.075)
    Data corr(it,itk) 1.000 0.810 0.722 0.594
    Model corr(it,itk) 1.000 0.952 0.892 0.822
    (s.e.) (0.000) (0.030) (0.058) (0.084)
    Data corr(wt,wtk) 1.000 0.760 0.783 0.554
    Model corr(wt,wtk) 1.000 0.959 0.909 0.853
    (s.e.) (0.000) (0.024) (0.047) (0.069)

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    As seen from Table 4 above, the model specification featuring both shocks compares relatively well vis-a-vis empirical labor market autocorrelations. The persistence of labor market variables are also relatively well-approximated by the simulated model dynamics. Overall, the model with both total factor productivity- and discount factor shocks generates too much persistence in output and hours, and is again subject to the critiques of Nelson and Plosser (1992), Cogley and Nason (1995) and Rotemberg and Woodford (1996b), who blaim the RBC class of models for their lack of a strong internal propagation mechanism when there is little persistence in the TFP process. In addition, as in Vasilev (2009), and in the current one, labor market is assumed to be perfectly-competitive, and output and employment series feature little persistence.

    Next, as seen from Table 5 below, labor productivity leads hours in data. This pattern cannot be captured by the model, as the total factor productivity shock shifts the labor demand curve only; the effect between hours and labor productivity is then only a contemporaneous one, and a stochastic discount factor does not improve the model fit in this direction.

    Table 5.  Dynamic correlations for Bulgarian data and the model economy.
    k
    Method Statistic 3 2 1 0 1 2 3
    Data corr(ht,(y/h)tk) 0.342 0.363 0.187 0.144 0.475 0.470 0.346
    Model corr(ht,(y/h)tk) 0.044 0.073 0.115 0.803 0.537 0.444 0.353
    (s.e.) (0.326) (0.286) (0.240) (0.232) (0.269) (0.296) (0.321)
    Data corr(ht,wtk) 0.355 0.452 0.447 0.328 0.040 0.390 0.57
    Model corr(ht,wtk) 0.044 0.073 0.115 0.803 0.537 0.444 0.353
    (s.e.) (0.326) (0.286) (0.240) (0.232) (0.269) (0.296) (0.321)

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    A stochastic discount factor is introduced into a relatively standard real-business-cycle setup with a government sector. The model is calibrated to Bulgarian data for the period 1999–2018, which is after the introduction of the currency board arrangement in 1997. The quantitative importance of the presence of shocks to the discount factor is investigated for the propagation of cyclical fluctuations in Bulgaria. In particular, allowing for a stochastic discount factor in the setup improves the model fit vis-a-vis data by increasing variability of employment and wages. However, those improvements are at the cost of increasing the volatility of consumption and investment. Overall, the quantitative effect of such stochasticity is found to be very small, and thus not important for business cycle propagation.

    The author declares no conflicts of interest in this paper.



    [1] Bulgarian National Bank (2020) Bulgarian National Bank Statistics. Available from: http://www.bnb.bg.
    [2] Canova F (2007) Methods for Applied Macroeconomic Research, Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.
    [3] Cogley T, Nason J (1995) Output dynamics in Real-Business-Cycles. Am Econ Rev 85: 492-511.
    [4] Di Nola A, Kocharkov G, Vasilev A (2019) Envelope wages, Hidden Production, and Labor Productivity. BE J Macroecon 19: 1-30.
    [5] Hodrick R, Prescott E (1980) Post-war US business cycles: An empirical investigation, Mimeo, Carnegie-Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA.
    [6] National Statistical Institute (2020) Aggregate Statistical Indicators. Available from: http://www.nsi.bg.
    [7] Parkin M (1988) A method for determining whether parameters in aggregative models are structural, In: Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy, North-Holland, 29: 215-252.
    [8] Rotemberg J, Woodford M (1996) Real-Business-Cycle Models and the Forecastable Movements in Output, Hours, and Consumption. Am Econ Rev 86: 71-89.
    [9] Vasilev A (2020) A Real-business-cycle Model with a Stochastic Capital Share: Lessons for Bulgaria(1999-2018). J Appl Econ Res 14: 107-121.
    [10] Vasilev A (2019a) How important are consumer confidence shocks for the propagation of business cycles in Bulgaria? LEAF Working Papers, Lincoln, UK: University of Lincoln.
    [11] Vasilev A (2019b) The role of endogenous capital depreciation rate for business cycle dynamics: lessons from Bulgaria (1999-2018), Mimeo, University of Lincoln, Lincoln, UK.
    [12] Vasilev A (2017a) Business Cycle Accounting: Bulgaria after the introduction of the currency board arrangement (1999-2014). Eur J Comp Econ 14: 197-219.
    [13] Vasilev A (2017b) A Real-Business-Cycle model with efficiency wages and a government sector: the case of Bulgaria. Cent Eur J Econ Econometrics 9: 359-377.
    [14] Vasilev A (2017c) A Real-Business-Cycle model with reciprocity in labor relations and fiscal policy:the case of Bulgaria. Bulg Econ Pap 3: 1-26.
    [15] Vasilev A (2017d) VAT Evasion in Bulgaria: A General-Equilibrium Approach. Rev Econ Inst 8: 2-17.
    [16] Vasilev A (2017e) Progressive taxation and (in) stability in an exogenous growth model with an informal sector. J Econ Econometrics 60: 1-13.
    [17] Vasilev A (2016a) Progressive taxation and (in) stability in an endogenous growth model with human capital accumulation. J Econ Econometrics 59: 1-15.
    [18] Vasilev A (2016b) Search and matching frictions and business cycle fluctuations in Bulgaria. Bulg Econ Pap 3: 2-41.
    [19] Vasilev A (2015a) Welfare effects of flat income tax reform: the case of Bulgaria. East Eur Econ 53:205-220.
    [20] Vasilev A (2015b) Welfare gains from the adoption of proportional taxation in a general-equilibrium model with a grey economy: the case of Bulgaria's 2008 flat tax reform. Econ Change Restructuring 48: 169-185.
    [21] Vasilev A (2009) Business cycles in Bulgaria and the Baltic countries: an RBC approach. Int J Comput Econ Econometrics 1: 148-170. doi: 10.1504/IJCEE.2009.029256
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2020 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(3834) PDF downloads(70) Cited by(0)

Figures and Tables

Figures(2)  /  Tables(5)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog