Loading [MathJax]/jax/output/SVG/jax.js
Research article

The impact of organizational compliance culture and green culture on environmental behavior: The moderating effect of environmental commitment

  • In this research, we aim to examine the moderating effect of environmental commitment on the relationships between organizational compliance culture and green culture on environmental behavior, under the theoretical stream of the Resource Based Theory (RBT) of the firm, and the Value-Belief-Norm theory (VBN). The research used a quantitative research approach, with a non-experimental transactional design. The sample consisted of 148 Mexican companies with a corporate value system that has implemented environmental sustainability practices, most of them incorporating the GRI guidelines, the SDGs and the Ten Principles of the UN Global Compact into their strategies, policies, procedures, and initiatives. This study contributes to the literature in the field of environmental sustainability, with a first theoretical PLS-SEM model that studies moderating and control variables, through organizational compliance on environmental behavior. Our proposed PLS model is a complex hierarchical component model that brings together and simultaneously maps a higher-order construct combined with three lower-order constructs, with moderation effects, multi-group analysis and predictive performance assessment. The major research findings are both the positive impacts between the proposed higher-order construct, organizational compliance culture, and green culture, on environmental behavior, and the moderating effect of environmental commitment on the relationship between green culture and environmental behavior. The insights obtained enhance the understanding of the factors that determine the environmental behavior through organizational compliance culture and green culture, with the moderating effect of environmental commitment, and help senior management in making strategic decisions to align their environmental objectives in compliance with the 2030 agenda in the area of environmental sustainability. This study highlights the need for companies to strengthen the role of environmental commitment to improve the environmental sustainability and it mentions practical implications both for managers of organizations that are responsible for meeting the objectives of sustainable development, specifically in the environmental field, and for policymakers and authorities that guide environmental policies.

    Citation: Joseph F. Hair, Juan José García-Machado, Minerva Martínez-Avila. The impact of organizational compliance culture and green culture on environmental behavior: The moderating effect of environmental commitment[J]. Green Finance, 2023, 5(4): 624-657. doi: 10.3934/GF.2023024

    Related Papers:

    [1] Bo Lan, Lei Zhuang, Qin Zhou . An evolutionary game analysis of digital currency innovation and regulatory coordination. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(5): 9018-9040. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023396
    [2] Yuanyuan Huang, Yiping Hao, Min Wang, Wen Zhou, Zhijun Wu . Optimality and stability of symmetric evolutionary games with applications in genetic selection. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2015, 12(3): 503-523. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2015.12.503
    [3] Huanhuan Guo, Biao Gao . Game theory analysis of self-awareness and politeness. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(10): 10493-10532. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022491
    [4] A. Swierniak, M. Krzeslak, D. Borys, M. Kimmel . The role of interventions in the cancer evolution–an evolutionary games approach. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(1): 265-291. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019014
    [5] Jialing Li, Guiju Zhu, Xinya Hu, Ruqian Fei, Dan Yu, Dong Wang . Study on the evolutionary strategy of upward patient transfer in the loose medical consortia. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(9): 16846-16865. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023751
    [6] Huan Zhao, Xi Chen . Study on knowledge cooperation of interdisciplinary research team based on evolutionary game theory. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(5): 8782-8799. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023386
    [7] Zheng Liu, Lingling Lang, Lingling Li, Yuanjun Zhao, Lihua Shi . Evolutionary game analysis on the recycling strategy of household medical device enterprises under government dynamic rewards and punishments. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(5): 6434-6451. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021320
    [8] Sharon M. Cameron, Ariel Cintrón-Arias . Prisoner's Dilemma on real social networks: Revisited. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2013, 10(5&6): 1381-1398. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2013.10.1381
    [9] Zhiyan Xing, Yanlong Yang, Zuopeng Hu . Nash equilibrium realization of population games based on social learning processes. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(9): 17116-17137. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023763
    [10] Andrzej Swierniak, Michal Krzeslak . Application of evolutionary games to modeling carcinogenesis. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2013, 10(3): 873-911. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2013.10.873
  • In this research, we aim to examine the moderating effect of environmental commitment on the relationships between organizational compliance culture and green culture on environmental behavior, under the theoretical stream of the Resource Based Theory (RBT) of the firm, and the Value-Belief-Norm theory (VBN). The research used a quantitative research approach, with a non-experimental transactional design. The sample consisted of 148 Mexican companies with a corporate value system that has implemented environmental sustainability practices, most of them incorporating the GRI guidelines, the SDGs and the Ten Principles of the UN Global Compact into their strategies, policies, procedures, and initiatives. This study contributes to the literature in the field of environmental sustainability, with a first theoretical PLS-SEM model that studies moderating and control variables, through organizational compliance on environmental behavior. Our proposed PLS model is a complex hierarchical component model that brings together and simultaneously maps a higher-order construct combined with three lower-order constructs, with moderation effects, multi-group analysis and predictive performance assessment. The major research findings are both the positive impacts between the proposed higher-order construct, organizational compliance culture, and green culture, on environmental behavior, and the moderating effect of environmental commitment on the relationship between green culture and environmental behavior. The insights obtained enhance the understanding of the factors that determine the environmental behavior through organizational compliance culture and green culture, with the moderating effect of environmental commitment, and help senior management in making strategic decisions to align their environmental objectives in compliance with the 2030 agenda in the area of environmental sustainability. This study highlights the need for companies to strengthen the role of environmental commitment to improve the environmental sustainability and it mentions practical implications both for managers of organizations that are responsible for meeting the objectives of sustainable development, specifically in the environmental field, and for policymakers and authorities that guide environmental policies.



    Many physical systems of interest can be described by evolutionary games on graphs within the more general framework of dynamical systems on complex networks [2]. For example, opinion dynamics under social network influence [3], spread of contagious diseases subject to competition and selection [4,5,6], crime dynamics [7], bacterial networks [8], multi-agent decision-making dynamics [9,10], and the emergence of cooperation in networked populations [11,12,13,14,15,16,17,18]. Among the different interaction mechanisms, the simplest ones can be modeled as two-strategy games [19,20,21]. Differently from the standard approaches presented in [11,14,16,17,18], where the interactions among players are described as discrete time stochastic processes, the evolutionary games equation on networks (EGN) proposed in [1], is a system of ordinary differential equations. More specifically, each of them takes the form of a replicator equation [19], ruling the dynamics of any single player in a population of N individuals arranged on a network, while other standard approaches [12,13,15] consider the average dynamics of the whole population. Recently, model reduction and symmetries have been investigated by using the concept of lumpability of graphs [22].

    Similarly to the standard case, the replicator equation on networks possesses different kinds of steady states: mixed steady states that belong to the interior of the simplex (all players play all strategies with the probability in (0, 1)), pure steady states for which all entries belong to the border of the simplex (all players play all strategies with probability 0 or 1), and pure/mixed steady states (where some players play a pure strategy and others play a mixed one. Mixed steady states, hereafter called internal steady states, are particularly important in the EGN because they represent situations where a player assumes hybrid decisions corresponding to partially agree to all available strategies. This includes the case for which some of the strategies are strongly preferred to the others, for example the probability to choose a given strategy can be very close to 1, although different. As a consequence, the probability to choose all the other strategies will be very close to 0 since the sum of all strategy components for each player equals 1. Internal steady states are the most reasonable states for which a group of individuals can be able to agree on a compromised decision.

    Moreover, the importance of the internal states mentioned above lies on the fact that they represent situations where different subpopulations may coexist. Thus, studying the attractiveness of these states is connected to the possibility that subetaoups of the players eventually coexist in an asymptotically stable manner [1,19,20]. On the contrary, oscillations making the dynamics more interesting will be produced only if we have unstable internal steady states [23].

    In this paper, we study the feasibility of internal steady states in the EGN proposed in [1], by considering different situations, such as, for example, the presence of self-connections in the network. This is particularly relevant for social applications, since self-loops describe well how a player is able to interact also with himself, thus modeling positive or negative feedback on player decisions. We find necessary conditions for the feasibility of internal steady states of EGN. We distinguish the cases of dominant, coordination and anti-coordination payoff matrices of the underlying games. Moreover, we prove sufficient conditions for the feasibility of internal steady states when the graph is complete. Existence and feasibility of internal steady states are relevant for solving control and consensus problems. Controlling dynamical systems over networks in order to drive a population of agents towards a specific steady state has been widely studied [24,25,26,27], while the presence of adaptive networks has been tackled in [28,29].

    In [30], the authors developed a new notion: equilibrium interdependence of agents. This investigates how the changes in the parameters impact the equilibrium of the system and how they influence the strategy of other players. In the same direction, we propose a similar approach, where after analyzing the effect of changing some model parameters, we also investigate the effect of modifying the connectivity of players. Therefore, in this work, we prove results concerning how the dynamics of the whole system is influenced by varying the network connectivity of a single node. The problem under investigation connects with the diffusion centrality issue [31], whereby the role of the central individuals in a social network is analyzed by observing indirect information flow.

    Finally, the effect of link removal from central players is studied theoretically for graphs with no self-edges, while numerical results are proposed to investigate the case of graphs with self-edges. Including self-edges in the model proposed in [1] is very promising to study the stability of internal steady states [32]. Indeed, it has been shown that stability of certain internal steady states is not possible for graph with no self-edges. Thus, the stability strongly depends on the strength of self-connections as well as on graph topology.

    The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we illustrate the basics of evolutionary games on networks and in particular on two-strategy game for graphs including self-loops. Section 3 states the necessary conditions for the existence of internal steady states. Some numerical results are provided to analyze the existence of mixed steady states for a generic and heterogeneous scenario. Then, in Section 4 we present sufficient conditions in the case of complete graphs. In Section 5 we tackle the problem of link removal from a player by providing theoretical results for the case of no self-loops, and numerical experiments for the case with self-loops. Finally, in Section 6 we state some conclusions and suggest future developments.

    We start by considering the evolutionary game equation on a network (EGN) introduced in [1]:

    ˙xv,s=xv,s(pGv,sϕGv), (2.1)

    where s belongs to a set of strategies S={1,2,,M}, v belongs to a set of vertices V={1,2,,N} and xv,s is the probability that vertex v chooses strategy s, pGv,s is a Von-Neumann Morgenstern utility payoff of player v using pure strategy s, and ϕGv is the average payoff over the set of strategies available to vertex v.

    In this paper we consider a generalization of the model where pGv,s and ϕGv are both defined by means of player-to-player payoff matrices Bv,uRM×M, such that Bv,u is the payoff matrix used by player v against player u. As a consequence, the model presented in [1] coincides with the special case, whereby Bv,u=Bv,u,vV. As usual, pGv,s and ϕGv depend on the graph G, which in turn is defined by means of an N×N adjacency matrix A=(av,u)RN×N0 with (v,u)V2. More precisely,

    pGv,s=Nu=1av,uesBv,uxu,

    and

    ϕGv=Nu=1av,uxvBv,uxu,

    where es is the s-th canonical-basis vector of RM and xv=[xv,1xv,2xv,M]T is the distribution of pure strategies of player v.

    Moreover, we consider graphs with self-loops, i.e., av,v0. In this regard, it is straightforward to consider also self-games described by payoff matrices Bv,v, where a player v plays against itself. For convenience, we define the degree of a node as deg(v)=Nu=1av,u. Since we are only concerned with graphs without isolated vertices, then Nu=1,uvav,u=deg(v)av,v>0. Hence, δv=av,v/deg(v), which is the relative self-connectivity (i.e., how strong is the self-connection with respect to the sum of all connection weights) is such that 0δv<1.

    Since for every v the constraint xv,1+xv,2++xv,M=1 holds, we have that for M strategies and N vertices the EGN leads to a system with N(M1) ordinary differential equations. Furthermore, in this article we analyze the EGN equation for two-strategy games (M=2). Therefore, for convenience, we drop the second index s of xv,s, introducing the variable yv=xv,1, whereas xv,2=1yv. Thus, in our case the EGN becomes a system of N ODEs:

    ˙yv=yv(pGvϕGv). (2.2)

    Equation (2.2) can be rewritten in a more convenient way as follows: let bv,us,r be the payoff of player v against u when they use strategies s and r, respectively. Then, the payoff function for vertex v against u can be defined by means of the payoff matrix:

    Bv,u=(b1,1v,ub1,2v,ub2,1v,ub2,2v,u) . (2.3)

    We denote by σrv,u=(1)r+1(b1,rv,ub2,rv,u) the payoff difference of player v when u uses strategy r. The sign of parameters σ is associated with the game characteristics:

    ● if σ1v,u>0 and σ2v,u>0, then v is playing a coordination game against u. A prototypical example of this kind of games is the Stag Hunt game.

    ● if σ1v,u<0 and σ2v,u<0, then v is playing an anti-coordination game against u. A prototypical example of this kind of games is the Chicken game.

    ● if σ1v,u<0 and σ2v,u>0, or σ1v,u>0 and σ2v,u<0, then v is playing a dominant game against u. A prototypical example of this kind of games for which σ1v,u<0 and σ2v,u>0 is the well-known Prisoner's dilemma game.

    According to [19], Bv,u can be equivalently rewritten as a diagonal matrix, namely

    Bv,u=diag(σ1v,u,σ2v,u), (2.4)

    and Eq (2.2) reads as

    ˙yv=yv(1yv)fv(y) , (2.5)

    where y=(y1,,yN), fv(y)=Nu=1av,ufv,u(yu) and fv,u(yu)=yuTr(Bv,u)σ2v,u, where Tr(Bv,u) is the trace of matrix Bv,u. Steady states of (2.5) are very important solutions because they influence significantly the asymptotic dynamics of the system. Moreover, they can be related to the Nash equilibria of the game described by the payoff matrix of Eq (2.4). Nash equilibria represent a cornerstone of game theory, since they correspond to strategies such that no player has any incentive to change his or her own strategy. The relationship between steady states and Nash equilibria will be clarified later in the paper.

    A solution y of the EGN is a steady state if, and only if, for all v, yv=0, or yv=1, or fv(y)=0. But,

    fv(y)=0Nu=1av,uTr(Bv,u)yu=Nu=1av,uσ2v,u,vV,

    or equivalently

    [(Σ1+Σ2)A]y=[Σ2A]1, (2.6)

    where Σ1 and Σ2 are matrices with Σ1v,u=σ1v,u, Σ2v,u=σ2v,u, A is the adjacency matrix, 1 is the N dimensional vector with one in every entry, and denotes the Hadamard product defined as PQ=R where R={ri,j}:={pi,jqi,j}, provided that matrices P and Q have the same dimension.

    Our goal is to study how the connectivity of the graph and the presence of self-loops impact the existence of an internal steady state. From [1] we know that if all players have the same payoff matrix and there are no self-loops, then the topology does not matter. We will start by looking at theoretical results on the existence of mixed equilibrium for more general cases than those studied in [1].

    If y satisfies Eq (2.6), then it is a steady state for the ODE system (2.5). Whenever [(Σ1+Σ2)A] is invertible, then we have a unique solution:

    y=[(Σ1+Σ2)A]1[Σ2A]1. (3.1)

    A steady state y satisfying (2.6) is feasible if, and only if, yv[0,1],vV. A feasible steady state y is pure if yv{0,1}N,vV. A feasible steady state y is said to be internal or mixed if, and only if, yv(0,1),vV. Finally, a feasible steady state is non pure if its components belong to both sets (0,1) and {0,1}. We can relate steady states of EGN to Nash equilibria of the underlying game described by the payoff matrices (2.3). Indeed, in two-strategy games, if y is a feasible internal steady state, then it is also a Nash equilibrium of the underlying static game [19].

    However, it is not enough to guarantee the solvability of Eq (2.6) in order for the mixed steady states to exist, because we also need that the solutions of the linear equations (2.6) to belong to the interior of the hypercube ΔS={yRN:0yi1iV}. We start by giving necessary conditions on the values of the σs in order for the mixed steady states to be feasible.

    Suppose that for every game, the payoff matrix that player v uses when it plays with his neighbors is equal for every opponent. In other words, vV,Bv,u=Bv=diag(σv,1,σv,2),uv. In contradistinction, the self-game of player v is represented by the matrix Bv,v=Bv=diag(σv,1,σv,2). Now let us define βv and γv as follows:

    {Tv=βvTvσv,2=γvσv,2,

    where Tv=Tr(Bv) and Tv=Tr(Bv). Note that, if Tv=0 for some v, then either player v has a dominant strategy or it is indifferent to any strategy. In the case he has a dominant strategy, no internal equilibria can be obtained. In the case the player is indifferent, then he will always play the same strategy that he used at the beginning of the game; therefore, in order to look for an internal equilibrium, we could consider the network game without this player. We define dv=σv,2Tv and dv=σv,2Tv=γvσv,2βvTv=γvβvdv. The following theoretical result holds.

    Proposition 3.1. Suppose that the adjacency matrix A is non-negative (ARN×N0) and that each node has at least one neighbor. Moreover, suppose that Tv0. If y is a mixed steady state, then for any vV:

    {dv(1+δv(γv1))yvδv(βv1)(0,1)ifav,v0dv(0,1)ifav,v=0.

    Proof. Let [Ay]v and [A1]v be the v-th component of the vector Ay and A1, respectively.

    Since each node has at least one neighbor, then deg(v)>0,vV. Therefore,

    [Ay]v=Nu=1av,uyumin(y)Nu=1av,u==min(y)deg(v)>0vV.

    Furthermore,

    [Ay]v=Nu=1av,uyu<Nu=1av,u1==deg(v),vV .

    This implies that 0<[Ay]v<deg(v), and hence

    [Ay]vdeg(v)(0,1)vV. (3.2)

    From Eq (2.6), we know that

    Nu=1av,uTr(Bv,u)yu=Nu=1av,uσv,2Tv[Ay]v+av,v(TvTv)yv=σv,2deg(v)+av,v(σv,2σv,2)Tv([Ay]v+av,v(βv1)yv)=σv,2(deg(v)+av,v(γv1)), (3.3)

    vV. If av,v=0 then

    [Ay]vdeg(v)=dv(0,1),vV.

    If av,v0, then dividing both sides of Eq (3.3) by deg(v)Tv, we have:

    [Ay]vdeg(v)+δv(βv1)yv=dv(1+δv(γv1))[Ay]vdeg(v)=dv(1+δv(γv1))δv(βv1)yv(0,1).vV.

    This result represents a necessary condition for having an internal steady state y. The condition depends on the game played, represented by the parameter dv, and on the self-loop, ruled by the parameters δv, βv and γv. If we know the components of y, no such condition is needed. However, the proposition allows us to prove the interesting corollary below. This result will give us a truly necessary condition for having an internal steady state in the cases where we have coordination and anti-coordination payoff matrices. It is also interesting to note that, if δv=0 (i.e., no self-loops), then we have that dv(0,1), recovering the results of [1] for the uniform payoff case. In this sense, the results in the previous theorem are an extension of the results presented in [1].

    Corollary 3.1. Suppose that y is a mixed steady state. Let v=deg(v)av,v be the v-th element of the Laplacian matrix of the graph, i.e., L=diag(deg(v)vV)A. For each v, then:

    (a) if δv=0, then Bv represents a coordination game if Tv>0 or an anti-coordination game if Tv<0;

    (b) if δv>0 and 1<βv<γv, then Bv represents a coordination game if Tv>0 or an anti-coordination game if Tv<0;

    (c) if δv>0, βv>1 and γv<v, then the pure strategy yv=1 is dominant for the game represented by Bv if Tv>0, or the pure strategy yv=0 is dominant for the game represented by Bv if Tv<0.

    Proof.

    ● Proof of (a)

    If δv=0 then av,v=0, by the previous proposition we have that dv(0,1), then if Tv>0, then Bv represents a coordination game, while for Tv<0 we have an anti-coordination game.

    For the cases with δv>0, firstly, notice that

    11δv=av,vdeg(v)av,v.

    Moreover, since δv>0av,v=1, then:

    11δv=av,vdeg(v)=v.

    Secondly, if βv>1, then δv(βv1)>0. Furthermore:

    0<dv(1+δv(γv1))yvδv(βv1)<dv(1+δv(γv1)),

    and

    1>dv(1+δv(γv1))yvδv(βv1)>dv(1+δv(γv1))δv(βv1),

    yielding that

    0<dv(1+δv(γv1))<1+δv(βv1).

    ● Proof of (b)

    If 1<βv<γv, then 1+δv(γv1)>0 and

    0<dv(1+δv(γv1))<1+δv(βv1)dv(0,1+δv(βv1)1+δv(γv1)).

    Since γv>βv then 1+δv(γv1)>1+δv(βv1), which implies dv(0,1) and the conclusion follows.

    ● Proof of (c)

    βv>1 and γv<v, then 1+δv(βv1)1+δv(γv1)<0 and

    0<dv(1+δv(γv1))<1+δv(βv1)dv(1+δv(βv1)1+δv(γv1),0).

    It turns out that dv is a negative number and hence σv,1 and σv,2 have different signs. In particular, if Tv>0, then σv,2<0 and 0<|σv,2|<σv,1, while Tv<0 implies that σv,1<0 and 0<|σv,1|<σv,2. In the former case, Bv represents a game with the pure strategy y=1 dominant; instead for the latter case the pure strategy y=0 is dominant.

    The results of Corollary 3.1 are depicted in Figure 1 for a generic player v. We report the regions were an internal steady state is feasible. Blue and red colors indicates the areas where it is necessary a non-dominant game (bistable or coexistent) and a dominant game, respectively.

    Figure 1.  This figure reports the regions on the plane (βv,γv) where conditions of Corollary 3.1 are met for a generic player v.

    Proposition 1 and Corollary 3.1 relate the existence of the internal steady state with the connectivity of each player v, i.e., δv, the strength of its self-games, i.e., βv and γv, and the game itself. However, these results only provide necessary conditions for the existence of internal mixed steady states.

    While sufficient conditions that work for particular graph structures will be proven in the next sections, here we show a numerical example using an Erdös-Rényi graph sample with N=150 nodes and average degree 10. We assume that av,v=1 for all vV, i.e., each player has a self-loop. For this numerical example, we divide the nodes into six groups of 25 elements each. For each group, we choose the parameters σv,1 and σv,2 in the set {(1,1),(0.9,1),(1,0.9),(1,1),(0.9,1),(1,0.9)}. In this way, half of the nodes have a coordination game payoff matrix, while the other half play anti-coordination games. We also assume that βv=β and γv=γ for all the players. Then, for each couple of values β and γ in the set [30,30]×[30,30], we evaluated the solution y of Eq (3.1). In Figure 2 we report in blue the couples (β,γ) for which Eq (3.1) has no solution, or if the solution cannot be classified as an internal steady state (i.e., yv(0,1)v). Instead, if the solution y is internal, then the couple (β,γ) is depicted in light green. Finally, in dark green we report the non internal steady states that anyway satisfy the condition of Proposition 1. We remark that light and dark green areas refer to the points (β,γ) which satisfy the condition of Proposition 1 for all the players.

    Figure 2.  Existence of the internal mixed equilibrium in the hypothesis that βv=β and γv=γ for all the N=150 players, arranged over an Erdös-Rényi graph with average degree 10. Blue region does not present any internal equilibrium. Light green regions show an internal equilibrium, satisfying Proposition 1. Dark green regions represent the value of β and γ satisfying Proposition 1 for non internal steady states which are solutions of Eq (3.1).

    In this section we report some theoretical results on the feasibility of mixed steady states for complete graphs. In order to study how connectivity plays a role on the existence of steady states, we start our study with the most connected graph: the complete one. Our result shows that the presence of many connections in the graph implies that the payoff matrices of the players should be very similar in order for the system to be able to have an internal steady state.

    Consider a complete undirected and unweighted graph of N nodes with self-edges. Then, the adjacency matrix A is equal to 1N×N. Moreover, we consider that the self-game strengths are given by βv=β and γv=γ for all players. In this case, we get that (Σ1+Σ2)A=diag(Tv)Aβ and Σ2A=diag(σv,2)Aγ where Aβ=1N×N+(β1)IN×N and Aγ=1N×N+(γ1)IN×N.

    Lemma 4.1. Let NN+. If β1 and β1N, then Aβ is invertible and its inverse is given by A1β=[qv,u] where

    {qv,v=β+(N2)(β1)(β+N1)qv,u=1(β1)(β+N1),vu.

    The proof of this lemma is a direct consequence of the remark that Aβ is a circulant matrix.

    To ease the discussion of the upcoming results, we introduce the average of a vector over a set of indices Ψ, xΨ=1|Ψ|vΨxv, where |Ψ| is the cardinality of the set.

    Theorem 4.2. Let A, with N3 vertices, be the adjacency matrix of a complete graph with self-edges. If Tv0 and βv=β{1,1N} for all vV, then there is at most one non-pure steady-state y for the system of ODEs in Eq (2.5) and yV=γ+N1β+N1dV. Moreover, y is an internal steady-state if, and only if, for all vV:

    If sign(γ+N1)=sign(β1), then:

    NdVβ+N1<dv<NdVβ+N1+β1γ+N1. (4.1)

    If sign(γ+N1)sign(β1), then:

    NdVβ+N1+β1γ+N1<dv<NdVβ+N1. (4.2)

    Remark 4.3. For the case N=2, it is easy to check that y is feasible if, and only if, 0<dv<1 for v=1,2.

    Proof. For β{1,1N} and σv,1+σv,20 we have that (Σ1+Σ2)A is invertible. Then, Eq (3.1) becomes:

    y=A1βDAγ1, (4.3)

    where D=diag(Tv)1diag(σv,2)=diag(dv) is a diagonal matrix.

    In this case, the components of the steady state in Eq (4.3) are defined as follows:

    yv=(β+N2)(γ+N1)(β1)(β+N1)dv(γ+N1)(β1)(β+N1)Nu=1uvduyv=(β+N1)(γ+N1)(β1)(β+N1)dv(γ+N1)(β1)(β+N1)Nu=1duyv=γ+N1β1(dvNdVβ+N1),

    while the average of all the components of y is:

    y=γ+N1β1(dVNdVβ+N1)=γ+N1β+N1dV.

    Since each component yv is in the set (0,1), then:

    0<γ+N1β1(dvNdVβ+N1)<1.

    If sign(γ+N1)=sign(β1), then:

    NdVβ+N1<dv<NdVβ+N1+β1γ+N1.

    On the other hand, if sign(γ+N1)sign(β1), then:

    NdVβ+N1+β1γ+N1<dv<NdVβ+N1.

    Corollary 4.4. Under the assumptions of Theorem 4.2, if dv=d for all vV, then y is internal to the simplex if, and only if,

    γ+N1β+N1d(0,1).

    The proof of the corollary is straightforward by plugging dv=dV in (4.1) or (4.2).

    In the following theorems we discuss the feasibility of internal steady states for complete graphs with no self-edges. In this case Theorem 4.2 simplifies as follows.

    Theorem 4.5. Let A, with N3 vertices, be the adjacency matrix of a complete graph with no self-edges. If Tv0,vV, then there is at most one non-pure steady-state y for the system of ODEs in Eq (2.5) and yV=dV. Moreover, y is an internal steady-state if, and only if,

    NdV1N1dvNdVN1,vV. (4.4)

    Corollary 4.6. Under the assumptions of Theorem 4.2, if y is an internal steady-state then:

    |dvdV|<1N1,vV. (4.5)

    Proof. From (4.4), we have that:

    dV1N1<dvdV<dVN1,vV.

    Since y is an internal steady state and Tv0, then by Theorem (4.2), dv(0,1), since βv=γv=0. Therefore,

    1N1<dvdV<1N1,vV,

    which is the statement of the corollary.

    The Corollary 4.6 provides a necessary condition for the system (2.5) to have an internal steady state. If for any vertex v, the distance of dv to the average dV is greater than or equal to 1N1, then the system can only have pure steady states. We can also see that if N is large, then we may only have internal steady states whose components dvs are very close, i.e., in a complete graph, the system can only have internal steady states if the payoff's ratio of every player dv, does not get more than 1N1 distant from the average of all payoff's ratios. For a large system, this will require similar payoffs for all players.

    It is worthwhile to note that the results presented in Sections 3 and 4 highlight a strong dependence of the internal steady state on the connectivity of the network and on self-loops. The numerical experiments reported in Figure 3 show that the steady states reached by a population playing different game typologies without (first row) and with (second row) self-loops, may change significantly according to the network connectivity. The detail of the dynamics of a specific node is also reported (third row). In subplot (A), individuals play anti-coordination games, with σv,1=σv,2=1 for all v. For the case with self-loops, we set βv=4 and γv=6 for all v. In subplot (B), individuals play coordination games, with σv,1=σv,2=1 for all v. For the case with self-loops, we set βv=5 and γv=6 for all v. In subplot (C), individuals play coordination games, with σv,1=1 and σv,2=1.2 for all v. For the case with self-loops, we set βv=2.5 and γv=3.5 for all v. Initial condition used for all experiments is x1(0)=x2(0)=x3(0)=x4(0)=x5(0)=0.3.

    Figure 3.  The effect of link removal. The steady state reached by a population of N=5 individuals arranged on complete network, closed star and open star are reported, with and without the presence of self-loops. In subplots (A), (B) and (C), individuals play anti-coordination, coordination and strategy-two dominant games, respectively. We report the steady state reached by the population when no self-loops are present (first row), and when self-loops are active (second row). The detail of the dynamics of specific nodes is also reported in the third row. Grey lines refer to the dynamics without self-loops, while black lines are used for the dynamics with self-loops. Solid, dashed and dashed-pointed lines are used to distinguish among complete, closed star and open star networks.

    As a conclusive remark, while in [30] it has been shown that, generally, equilibrium agents are indifferent to small changes in games with two strategies, in our framework we show that modifications in the network structure, as well as the presence of self-loops, may produce significant changes in the dynamics of the system. This connects to Section 5, where the effect of link removal has been analyzed from both theoretical and numerical points of view.

    We now consider the following scenario: take a fully connected graph, choose one specific node and start deleting successively different links from this node. The general question under consideration is: what is the effect in the dynamics of such procedure? In general terms, such circle of ideas has attracted the attention of other researchers. For instance, in telecommunications and computer networks this corresponds to the so-called "bond percolation" process (see Section 16.1 of [33]). In Chapter 16 of [33], a comprehensive review of percolation and network resilience can be found. In contradistinction with such approach, we focus on one single node and analyze the resilience with respect to link removal in a deterministic fashion.

    First, we study the effect of link removal from central player starting from a complete network. In particular, we report some theoretical results for the case of graphs with no self-edges (βv=γv=0,vV). The case of networks including self-edges is then investigated by means of numerical simulations, showing that removing links can change dramatically the asymptotic behavior of the system, sometimes destroying the internal steady states.

    Theorem 5.1. Let A be the adjacency matrix of a complete graph with N>3 vertices and no self-edges. Assume that the connection between vertices v0 and u0 is removed and Γ=V{v0,u0}. Moreover, assume that σv,1+σv,20 for all v. If an internal steady state y exists, then following conditions hold

    i)2+dΓ(N1)N3<dv0=du0<dΓ(N1)N3,ii)1+dv0N1+dΓ<dv<dv0N1+dΓ,vΓ.

    Proof. Without loss of generality, let us assume v0=1, u0=2. Writing Eq (2.6) as a system of linear equations, we get

    {y3+y4++yN=d1(N2)y3+y4++yN=d2(N2)y1+y2+y4+yN=d3(N1)y1+y2+y3+yN1=dN(N1).

    If d1d2 then the first two equations would be incompatible, therefore d1=d2. In this case, the system has infinite solutions with y1 and y2 as free variables. Let z=y1+y2 and assume d1=d2, then the system with N equations can be reduced to a system with N1 equations

    {y3+y4++yN=d1(N2)z+y4++yN=d3(N1)z+y3++yN1=dN(N1).

    This system has only one solution given by:

    z=(N3)d1+(N1)dΓ,yv=d1+(N1)dΓ(N1)dv,vΓ.

    If the solution is in the simplex, then for all vΓ, it is true that 0<z<2 and 0<yv<1. This implies that ⅰ) and ⅱ) must hold.

    Suppose now that we start from an almost complete graph and iteratively remove additional links from the same vertex v0. Let Λ={v1,v2,,vM1} be the set of vertices that have been disconnected from vertex v0 and Γ=V(Λ{v0}) the set of vertex that is still connected to v0.

    Theorem 5.2. Let A, with N>3 vertices, be the adjacency matrix of a complete graph where K1 vertices have been disconnected from vertex v0. Let Λ be the set of disconnected vertices and Γ the remaining set of connected vertices. Moreover, let us assume that σv,1+σv,20 for all vV. Then, there exists an internal steady state, if, and only if, all the following conditions hold:

    i) (K1)dΛ(N1)(K2)(N2)dΓ<dv0<(K1)dΛ(N1)(K2)(N2)dΓ+K2N2,

    ii) 1NKK2dv0+(N2)(K1)K2dΛ<(N2)dv<NKK2dv0+(N2)(K1)K2dΛ,vΛ,

    iii) 1+dv0+(N1)dΓ<(N1)dv<dv0+(N1)dΓ,vΓ.

    Proof. Let us assume without loss of generality that Λ={2,3,,K}. Then, A=(av,u)N×N where

    av,u={0,if{v=u or v=1,1uK or 1vK,u=11,otherwise. .

    The matrix A is invertible for all N>2 and its inverse is given by the block matrix

    A1N=[R1R2R3R2R4R5R3R5R6],

    where

    R1=N2(K2)(NK)R2=1K211×(K1)R3=1NK11×(NK)R4=1K21(K1)×(K1)I(K1)R5=0(K1)×(NK)R6=1NK1(NK)×(NK)I(NK).

    In the above formulas, Ii is the i-dimensional identity matrix, and 0i×j and 1i×j are the i×j matrices of all 0 and 1 entries, respectively.

    By Eq (3.1), the steady state can be expressed as

    y1=d1N2K2(N2)(K1)(K2)dΛ+(N1)dΓyv=(NK)d1(N2)(K2)dv+(N2)(K1)dΛ(K2),vΛyu=d1du+(N1)dΓ,uΓ.

    The result thus follows from the fact the yv(0,1), for all vV.

    Remark 5.3 If dv=d(0,1),vV, then we can show that inequalities i), ii) and iii) hold. Then, from Theorem 5.2, we have that the internal steady state exists. This is in agreement with the conclusions obtained by Theorem 1 in [1].

    In the following, we report some numerical results on the effect of link removal in networks with self-edges. In order to study the link removal from networks including self-edges we develop a numerical experiment employing random graphs with 60 nodes. Starting from the complete graph, we use 3 different removal strategies to produce different graphs whose average degree is ¯k{60,59,58,,6,5}, thus obtaining a sequence of 56 graphs with different degrees.

    A comment concerning the different strategies for edge removal is in order. In the so-called random removal strategy, we start from a complete graph, and then we randomly remove 60 links, in order to obtain a new graph with an average degree of 59. In general, starting from a graph with average degree ¯k, we remove 60 links in order to obtain a graph with average degree ¯k1. The random regular removal strategy is similar to the random removal approach, but we remove exactly one link for each node, in order to obtain at each step a random regular graph (i.e., all nodes have the same degree). Finally, the Erdös-Rényi removal strategy consists of starting from an Erdös-Rényi graph sample with average degree ¯k, then removing a certain amount of links in order to obtain an Erdös-Rényi graph sample with average degree ¯k. An existing link remains with probability ¯k1¯k, otherwise, it is removed. In this way we are able to build Erdös-Rényi graph samples using a removal process. For each node we fix βv=γv=30. For this numerical example, we divide the nodes into six groups of 10 elements each. For each group, we choose the parameters σv,1 and σv,2 in the set {(1,1),(0.9,1),(1,0.9),(1,1),(0.9,1),(1,0.9)}. In this way, half on the nodes have a coordination game payoff matrix, while the other half play anti-coordination games. The three random removal strategies have been repeated 1000 times, thus obtaining 3561000=168000 random graphs. For each of them, a random initial condition has been created (i.e., xv(0) is a uniformly distributed random number in the set (0,1)). Thereafter, we let the solutions of the ODE (2.5) evolve towards a steady state. An example of the reached steady states is depicted in the subplots (A), (B) and (C) of Figure (4), where a colored point represents the value of the v-th component of the steady state for a given graph whose average degree is reported in the abscissa. We notice that, for sparser graphs, the behavior of the bistable nodes (i.e., the first 30 nodes), becomes more regular, that is, it is easier for the whole population to reach the similar steady state of consensus as long as the neighbor's size decreases. For supporting this claim, in subplots (D), (E) and (F), we report with lines the average of the whole population steady states as a function of the average degree of the network for each link removal strategy. The lighter dots correspond to the steady states reached by members of the population over 1000 numerical experiments. The dots allow us to show that the variance of steady state decreases as the number of removed links increases. A similar numerical experiment has been performed for a population of players involved in a dominant game. More specifically, we assume that a prisoner's dilemma game, where strategies 1 and 2 stand for cooperation and defection, respectively, is simulated by means of the EGN Eq (2.5). For this numerical example, we divide the nodes into six groups of 10 elements each. For each group, we choose the parameters σv,1 and σv,2 in the set {(1,1.1), (1,0.9), (1.1,1), (1.1,0.9), (0.9,1), (0.9,1.1)}. For each node we fix βv=γv=30. All the couples (σv,1,σv,2) represent games where strategy 2 is dominant, coherently with a prisoner's dilemma game. An example of the reached steady states is depicted in the subplots (A), (B) and (C) of Figure (5). The lines in subplots (D), (E) and (F) represent the average of the whole population steady states as a function of the average degree of the network for each link removal strategy. The lighter dots correspond to the steady states reached by members of the population over 1000 numerical experiments. Interestingly, this experiment shows that link removal policies, as well as the presence of self-loops, allow the system to converge toward strategy 1 for low connectivity, even though the original game is strategy 2 dominant. Moreover, this transition from a population of individuals all converging to strategy 2 to a population of individuals all converging to strategy 1 is sharper if the removal policy is random regular. This result may be useful for further studies investigating the interplay between cooperation and defection in a population of decision makers playing the prisoner's dilemma game. Indeed, Figure (5) shows that including the self-loop as well as removing links can drive individuals to reach some level of cooperation. As a final remark, we note that in [30] the authors conclude that changing the preference of one player usually will not lead a change in the system, which in fact depends on switching the number of strategies' players. We can see a similar effect for the link removal in Figure 5.

    Figure 4.  Effect of link removal on coordination and anti-coordination games. Subplots (A), (B) and (C) report as a function of the average degree of the network, the value at steady state reached by each of the 60 members of the considered population, for each link removal strategy. In this case, the first 30 players play a coordination game, while the others play an anticoordination game. The lines in subplots (D), (E) and (F) represent the average of the whole population steady states as a function of the average degree of the network for each link removal strategy. The lighter dots correspond to the steady states reached by members of the population over 1000 numerical experiments.
    Figure 5.  Effect of link removal on dominant games. Subplots (A), (B) and (C) report as a function of the average degree of the network, the value at steady state reached by each of the 60 members of the considered population, for each link removal strategy. In this case, all players of the population play a strategy 2 dominat game. The lines in subplots (D), (E) and (F) represent the average of the whole population steady states as a function of the average degree of the network for each link removal strategy. The lighter dots correspond to the steady states reached by members of the population over 1000 numerical experiments.

    In this paper, we study the relationship between network topology and self-loops in the Evolutionary Game Equation on Graphs. The mathematical form of this equation allows us to analyze separately the dynamics of any single individual, starting from his initial condition, which refers to his status in the beginning of the observation, to transient evolution of his strategy, until the asymptotic regime.

    In this framework, we state some necessary results for the existence and feasibility of internal steady states. Necessary and sufficient conditions for the case of complete graphs have also been provided. In this scenario, we proved that we can only have a mixed steady state if all payoff matrices are almost similar in terms of the parameters dv (i.e., these parameters must be sufficiently close to their average). In this respect, we also show that the larger the number of nodes of the network, the stronger the conditions for the mixed steady state to be feasible.

    The investigation of the internal steady states conducted in this study is an attempt to solve a well-known problem related to games on networks, such as the cooperation in the prisoner's dilemma game from a different point of view. Specifically, the existence of mixed steady states is an alternative way of conceiving cooperation, moving from a discrete (a player cooperates or defects) to a continuous setup (a player can exhibit an intermediate level of cooperation). Then, we exploited the influence of varying the connectivity of the network by removing iteratively the edges of a single node. This link removal process has been studied starting from a complete network without and with self-loops. The former is developed through theoretical results, whereas the latter through numerical simulations. We showed that the effect of link removal may also favor the presence of mixed steady states, thus fostering the onset of a partial level of cooperation. The present research shows that self-loops and link removal have a deep impact on the steady states of each individual of a networked finite population, and consequently, on the whole dynamics. These two ingredients may be fruitfully used for control purposes: for instance, we showed that it is possible to control the dynamics of a population playing a dominant game like the prisoner's dilemma, driving individuals towards a more profitable strategy. Moreover, our approach shows that, although the individuals are involved in coordination and/or anti-coordination games, which naturally splits the population strategy, the presence of self-loops and the link removal may help to reduce the difference of these strategies, thus driving the population towards a consensus steady state.

    A natural continuation of this research, which is presently under investigation by the authors, concerns the modification of the present model to account for the weak-selection limit, by preserving all the main peculiarities of the EGN equation. Similar investigations are under way concerning the effect of different network topologies, such as small world or scale-free networks, on the feasibility of the steady states of the EGN equation.

    The research of Chiara Mocenni, Jean Carlo Moraes and Jorge P. Zubelli was supported by grant 313773/2013-0 of the Science without Borders Program of CNPq/Brazil. Jorge P. Zubelli was also supported by the CNPq under grant 307873 and by FAPERJ through the program Cientistas do Nosso Estado.

    The authors do not have any conflict of interest.



    [1] Abeysekera I (2022) A framework for sustainability reporting. Sust Account Manage Policy 13: 1386–1409. https://doi.org/10.1108/SAMPJ-08-2021-0316 doi: 10.1108/SAMPJ-08-2021-0316
    [2] Abbas J, Dogan E (2022) The impacts of organizational green culture and corporate social responsibility on employees' responsible behaviour towards the society. Environ Sci Pollut Res 29: 60024–60034. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-022-20072-w doi: 10.1007/s11356-022-20072-w
    [3] Adam DH, Siregar ZME, Supriadi YN (2021) Environmental concern and environmental knowledge, attitude toward pro-environmental behavior as predictors of pro-environmental behavior: Evidence from textile industry in Indonesia. J Inf 22: 138–144.
    [4] Aftab J, Veneziani M (2023) How does green human resource management contribute to saving the environment? Evidence of emerging market manufacturing firms. Bus Strategy Environ, 1–17. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.3508 doi: 10.1002/bse.3508
    [5] Ahmad J, Mamun A, Masukujjama M, et al. (2023) Modeling the workplace pro-environmental behavior through green human resource management and organizational culture: Evidence from an emerging economy. Heliyon 9: 1–17. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2023.e19134 doi: 10.1016/j.heliyon.2023.e19134
    [6] Al-Mamun A, Hayat N, Mohiuddin M, et al. (2022) Modelling the significance of value-belief-norm theory in predicting workplace energy conservation behaviour. Front Energy Res 10: 1–15. https://doi.org/10.3389/fenrg.2022.940595 doi: 10.3389/fenrg.2022.940595
    [7] Al-Swidi AK, Gelaidan HM, Saleh RM (2021) The joint impact of green human resource management, leadership and organizational culture on employees' green behaviour and organisational environmental performance. J Clean Prod 316: 128112. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.128112 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.128112
    [8] Alvesson M (2013) Understanding Organizational Culture, 2nd edition. London: SAGE.
    [9] An H, Razzaq A, Nawaz A, et al. (2021) Nexus between green logistic operations and triple bottom line: Evidence from infrastructure-led Chinese outward foreign direct investment in Belt and Road host countries. Environ Sci Pollut Res 28: 51022–51045. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-021-12470-3 doi: 10.1007/s11356-021-12470-3
    [10] Ansari NY, Farrukh M, Raza A (2021) Green human resource management and employees pro‐environmental behaviours: Examining the underlying mechanism. Corp Soc Responsib Environ Manag 28: 229–238. https://doi.org/10.1002/csr.2044 doi: 10.1002/csr.2044
    [11] Appiah MK, Sam A, Osei-Agyemang V, et al. (2023) Green culture, environmental innovativeness, green intellectual capital, and circular economy implementation behaviour: A sequential mediation model. Cogent Eng 10: 1–17. https://doi.org/10.1080/23311916.2023.2220496 doi: 10.1080/23311916.2023.2220496
    [12] Aragón-Correa JA, Matı́as-Reche F, Senise-Barrio ME (2004) Managerial discretion and corporate commitment to the natural environment. J Bus Res 57: 964–975. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0148-2963(02)00500-3 doi: 10.1016/S0148-2963(02)00500-3
    [13] Asmui M, Mokhtar NM, Musa ND, et al. (2016) The implementation of organizational green culture in higher educational institution, In: Abdullah, M., Yahya, W., Ramli, N., Mohamed, S., Ahmad, B. (eds) Regional Conference on Science, Technology and Social Sciences (RCSTSS 2014), Springer, Singapore: 321–330. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-1458-1_31
    [14] Aziz NAA, Manab NA, Othman SN (2015) Exploring the Perspectives of Corporate Governance and Theories on Sustainability Risk Management (SRM). Asian Econ Financ Rev 5: 1148–1158. https://doi.org/10.18488/journal.aefr/2015.5.10/102.10.1148.1158 doi: 10.18488/journal.aefr/2015.5.10/102.10.1148.1158
    [15] Bakhsh H, Ong TS, Ho JA, et al. (2018) Organizational Culture and Environmental Performance. Sustainability 10: 1–17. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10082690 doi: 10.3390/su10082690
    [16] Barney JB (1986) Organizational Culture: Can It Be a Source of Sustained Competitive Advantage? Acade Manage Rev 11: 656–665. https://doi.org/10.2307/258317 doi: 10.2307/258317
    [17] Barney JB (1991) Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. J Manage 17: 99–120. https://doi.org/10.1177/014920639101700108 doi: 10.1177/014920639101700108
    [18] Barney JB, Ketchen DJ, Wright M (2011) The Future of Resource-Based Theory: Revitalization or Decline? J Manage 37: 1299–1315. https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206310391805 doi: 10.1177/0149206310391805
    [19] Bayard B, Jolly C (2007) Environmental behavior structure and socio-economic conditions of hillside farmers: A multiple-group structural equation modeling approach. Ecol Econ 62: 433–440. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2006.07.004 doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2006.07.004
    [20] Benjamin A, David I (2012) Human resource development climate and employee commitment in recapitalized Nigerian banks. Int J Bus Manage 7: 90–99. https://doi.org/10.5539/ijbm.v7n5p91 doi: 10.5539/ijbm.v7n5p91
    [21] Bissing-Olson MJ, Fieldin KS, Iyer A (2016) Experiences of pride, not guilt, predict pro-environmental behavior when pro-environmental descriptive norms are more positive. J Environ Psychol 45: 145–153. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvp.2016.01.00 doi: 10.1016/j.jenvp.2016.01.00
    [22] Branco MC, Rodrigues LL (2008) Factors influencing social responsibility disclosure by Portuguese companies. J Bus Ethics 83: 685–701. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-007-9658-z doi: 10.1007/s10551-007-9658-z
    [23] Brechin S, Kempton W (1994) Global environmentalism: a challenge to the post-materialism thesis? Soc Sci Q 75: 245–269.
    [24] Brown ME, Treviño LK, Harrison DA (2005) Ethical leadership: A social learning perspective for construct development and testing. Organ. Behav Hum Decis Process 97: 117–134. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2005.03.002 doi: 10.1016/j.obhdp.2005.03.002
    [25] Cameron KS, Quinn RE (2006) Diagnosing and Changing Organizational Culture: Based on the Competing Values Framework San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.
    [26] Castro-Casal C, Vila-Vazquez G, Pardo-Gayoso Á (2019) Sustaining affective commitment and Extra-Role service among hospitality employees: interactive effect of empowerment and service training. Sustainability 11: 4092. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11154092 doi: 10.3390/su11154092
    [27] Chen YS, Chang CH (2013) Enhance environmental commitments and green intangible assets toward green competitive advantages: an analysis of structural equation modeling (SEM). Qual Quant 47: 529–543. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11135-011-9535-9 doi: 10.1007/s11135-011-9535-9
    [28] Chin WW (1998) The partial least squares approach to structural equation modeling, In: Marcoulides GA (Ed.), Modern Methods for Business Research, Lawrence Erlbaum Associates Publisher, Mahwah, NJ 295–336.
    [29] Chin WW, Dibbern J (2010) An Introduction to a Permutation Based Procedure for Multi-Group PLS Analysis: Results of Tests of Differences on Simulated Data and a Cross Cultural Analysis of the Sourcing of Information System Services Between Germany and the USA, In: Esposito Vinzi V., Chin W, Henseler J, Wang H (eds), Handbook of Partial Least Squares, Concepts, Methods, and Applications. Springer Handbooks of Computational Statistics: 171–193.
    [30] Cho YN, Thyroff A, Rapert MI, et al. (2013) To be or not to be green: Exploring individualism and collectivism as antecedents of environmental behavior. J Bus Res 66: 1052–1059. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2012.08.020 doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2012.08.020
    [31] Claessens S, Kelly D, Sibley CG, et al. (2022) Cooperative phenotype predicts climate change belief and pro-environmental behaviour. Sci Rep 12: 1–10. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-022-16937-2 doi: 10.1038/s41598-022-16937-2
    [32] Cop S, Alola UV, Alola AA (2020) Perceived behavioral control as a mediator of hotels' green training, environmental commitment, and organizational citizenship behavior: A sustainable environmental practice. Bus Strateg Environ 29: 3495–3508. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.2592 doi: 10.1002/bse.2592
    [33] Crane A (2000) Corporate greening as amortization. Organ Stud 21: 673–696. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840600214001 doi: 10.1177/0170840600214001
    [34] Dahling JJ, Chau SL, Mayer DM, et al. (2012) Breaking rules for the right reasons? An investigation of pro-social rule breaking. J Organ Behav 33: 21–42. https://doi.org/10.1002/job.730 doi: 10.1002/job.730
    [35] Delmas MA, Toffel MW (2008) Organizational responses to environmental demands: opening the black box. Strateg Manag J 29: 1027–1055. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.701 doi: 10.1002/smj.701
    [36] Dierking LD, Adelman LM, Ogden J, et al. (2004) Using a Behavior Change Model to Document the Impact of Visits to Disney's Animal Kingdom: A Study Investigating Intended Conservation Action. Curator Museum J 47: 322–343. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.2151-6952.2004.tb00128.x doi: 10.1111/j.2151-6952.2004.tb00128.x
    [37] Dobson A (2007) Environmental Citizenship: Towards Sustainable Development. Sustainable Development. Sustain Dev 15: 276–285. https://doi.org/10.1002/sd.344 doi: 10.1002/sd.344
    [38] European Commission (2005) Winning the Battle Against Global Climate Change. Brussels.
    [39] Faul F, Erdfelder E, Lang AG, et al. (2007) G*Power 3: a flexible statistical power analysis program for the social, behavioral, and biomedical sciences. Behav Res Methods 39: 175–191. https://doi.org/10.3758/BF03193146 doi: 10.3758/BF03193146
    [40] Faul F, Erdfelder E, Buchner A, et al. (2009). Statistical power analyses using G-Power 3.1: Tests for correlation and regression analyses. Behav Res Methods 41: 1149–1160. https://doi.org/10.3758/BRM.41.4.1149 doi: 10.3758/BRM.41.4.1149
    [41] Felipe CM, Roldán J, Leal-Rodríguez AL (2017) Impact of Organizational Culture Values on Organizational Agility. Sustainability 9: 1–23. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9122354 doi: 10.3390/su9122354
    [42] Ferrel OC, Fraedrich J, Ferrell LC (2019) Business Ethics Ethical Decision Making and Cases. OH, USA: Cengage Publishing.
    [43] Fietz B, Günther E (2021). Changing Organizational Culture to Establish Sustainability. Control Manag Rev 65: 32–40. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12176-021-0379-4 doi: 10.1007/s12176-021-0379-4
    [44] Fornell C, Larcker DF (1981) Structural Equation Models with Unobservable Variables and Measurement Error: Algebra and Statistics. J Mark Res 18: 382–388. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224378101800313 doi: 10.1177/002224378101800313
    [45] García-Machado JJ, Barbadilla E, Gutiérrez C (2020) A PLS Multigroup Analysis of the Role Businesswomen in the Tourism in Andalusia. Forum Scientiae Oeconomia 8: 37–57. https://doi.org/10.23762/FSO_VOL8_NO2_3 doi: 10.23762/FSO_VOL8_NO2_3
    [46] Gifford R (2014) Environmental psychology matters. Annu Rev Psychol 65: 1–39. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-psych-010213-115048 doi: 10.1146/annurev-psych-010213-115048
    [47] Grant RM (1991) The resource-based theory of competitive advantage: Implications for strategy formulation. Calif Manag Rev 33: 114–135. https://doi.org/10.2307/41166664 doi: 10.2307/41166664
    [48] Gregor SD (2006) The Nature of Theory in Information Systems. MIS Q 30: 611–642. https://doi.org/10.2307/25148742 doi: 10.2307/25148742
    [49] Hair JF, Black WC, Babin BJ, et al. (2019a) Multivariate Data Analysis (8th ed.). Cengage Learning, U.K.
    [50] Hair JF, Hult TG, Ringle CM, et al. (2019b) Manual de Partial Least Squares Structural Equation Modeling (PLS-SEM). SAGE: Spain.
    [51] Hair JF, Risher JJ, Sarstedt M, et al. (2019c) When to use and how to report the result of PLS-SEM. Eur Bus Rev 33: 2–24. https://doi.org/10.1108/EBR-11-2018-0203 doi: 10.1108/EBR-11-2018-0203
    [52] Hair JF, Howard M, Nitzl C (2020) Assessing measurement model quality in PLS-SEM using confirmatory composite analysis. J Bus Res 109: 101–110. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2019.11.069 doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2019.11.069
    [53] Hair JF, Sarstedt M (2021) Explanation plus Prediction – The Logical Focus of Project Management Research. Proj Manag J 52: 319–322. https://doi.org/10.1177/87569728219999 doi: 10.1177/87569728219999
    [54] Hair JF, Hult GTM, Ringle CM, et al. (2022) A Primer on Partial Least Squares Structural Equation Modeling (PLS-SEM), 3rd ed., Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA.
    [55] Hart ST (1995) A Natural-Resource-Based View of the Firm. Acad Manage Rev 20: 986–1014. https://doi.org/10.2307/258963 doi: 10.2307/258963
    [56] Hiratsuk J, Perlaviciute G, Steg L (2018) Testing VBN theory in Japan: Relationships between values, beliefs, norms, and acceptability and expected effects of a car pricing policy. Transp Res Part F Traffic Psychol Behav 53: 74–83. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.trf.2017.12.015 doi: 10.1016/j.trf.2017.12.015
    [57] Hu Q, Dinev T, Hart P, et al. (2012) Managing Employee Compliance with Information Security Policies: The Critical Role of Top Management and Organizational Culture. Decis Sci 43: 615–660. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5915.2012.00361.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-5915.2012.00361.x
    [58] Interligi L (2010) Compliance culture: A conceptual framework. J Manag Organ 16: 235–249. https://doi.org/10.5172/jmo.16.2.235 doi: 10.5172/jmo.16.2.235
    [59] Isensee C, Teuteberg F, Griese K, et al. (2020) The relationship between organizational culture, sustainability, and digitalization in SMEs: A systematic review. J Clean Prod 275: 1–19. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.122944 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.122944
    [60] Jody SL, Davis JL, Green JD, et al. (2009) Interdependence with the environment: Commitment, interconnectedness, and environmental behavior. J Environ Psychol 29: 173–180. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvp.2008.11.001 doi: 10.1016/j.jenvp.2008.11.001
    [61] Karatepe T, Ozturen A, Karatepe OM, et al. (2022) Management commitment to the ecological environment, green work engagement and their effects on hotel employees' green work outcomes. Int J Contemp Hosp Manag 34: 3084–3112. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJCHM-10-2021-1242 doi: 10.1108/IJCHM-10-2021-1242
    [62] Karp DD (1996) Values and their effect on pro-environmental behavior. Environ. Behav 28: 111–133. https://doi.org/10.1177/0013916596281006 doi: 10.1177/0013916596281006
    [63] Kock N (2015) Common method bias in PLS-SEM: A full collinearity assessment approach. Int J e-Collab 11: 1–10. https://doi.org/10.4018/ijec.2015100101 doi: 10.4018/ijec.2015100101
    [64] Kollmuss A, Agyeman J (2002) Mind the Gap: Why do people act environmentally and what are the barriers to pro-environmental behavior? Environ Educ Res 8: 239–260. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504620220145401 doi: 10.1080/13504620220145401
    [65] Kondalkar VG (2007) Organizational Behavior. New Delhi, India: New Age International Publisher.
    [66] Kot S, Haque A, Kozlovski E (2019) Strategic SCM's mediating effect on the sustainable operations: Multinational perspective. Organizacija 52: 219–235. https://doi.org/10.2478/orga-2019-0014 doi: 10.2478/orga-2019-0014
    [67] Kotler P (2011) Reinventing marketing to manage the environmental imperative. J Mark 75: 132–135. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkg.75.4.132 doi: 10.1509/jmkg.75.4.132
    [68] Lee SC, Huang SYB, Hu L, et al. (2023) Why Do Employees Show Pro-Environmental Behaviors? A Perspective of Environment Social Responsibility. Behav Sci 13: 463. https://doi.org/10.3390/bs13060463 doi: 10.3390/bs13060463
    [69] Lee TH (2011) How recreation involvement, place attachment and conservation commitment affect environmentally responsible behavior. J Sustain Tour 19: 895–915. https://doi.org/10.1080/09669582.2011.570345 doi: 10.1080/09669582.2011.570345
    [70] Leonidou LC, Leonidou CN, Fotiadis TA, et al. (2013) Resources and capabilities as drivers of hotel environmental marketing strategy: implications for competitive advantage and performance. Tourism Manage 35: 94–110. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2012.06.003 doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2012.06.003
    [71] Li Y (2014) Environmental innovation practices and performance: moderating effect of resource commitment. J Clean Prod 66: 450–458. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2013.11.044 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2013.11.044
    [72] Linnenluecke MK, Griffiths A (2010) Corporate sustainability and organizational culture. J World Bus 45: 357–366. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jwb.2009.08.006 doi: 10.1016/j.jwb.2009.08.006
    [73] Liu N, Tang SY, Zhan X, et al. (2018) Political commitment, policy ambiguity, and corporate environmental practices. Policy Stud J 46: 190–214. https://doi.org/10.1111/psj.12130LiuP, doi: 10.1111/psj.12130LiuP,
    [74] Teng M, Han C (2020) How does environmental knowledge translate into pro-environmental behaviors? The mediating role of environmental attitudes and behavioral intentions. Sci Total Environ 28: 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2020.138126 doi: 10.1016/j.scitotenv.2020.138126
    [75] Liu X, Lin KL (2020) Green Organizational Culture, Corporate Social Responsibility Implementation, and Food Safet. Front Psychol 11: 1–7. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2020.585435 doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2020.585435
    [76] Lozano R, Nummert B, Ceulemans K (2016) Elucidating the relationship between Sustainability Reporting and Organisational Change Management for Sustainability. J Clean Prod 125: 168–188. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.03.021 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.03.021
    [77] Luque-Vílchez M, Mesa-Pérez E, Husillos J, et al. (2019) The influence of pro-environmental managers' personal values on environmental disclosure: The mediating role of the environmental organizational structure. Sustain Account Manag Policy J 10: 41–61. https://doi.org/10.1108/SAMPJ-01-2018-0016 doi: 10.1108/SAMPJ-01-2018-0016
    [78] McCarty JA, Shrum LJ (2001) The influence of individualism, collectivism and locus of control on environmental beliefs and behavior. J Public Policy Mark 20: 93–104. https://doi.org/10.1509/jppm.20.1.93.17291 doi: 10.1509/jppm.20.1.93.17291
    [79] McLennan M (2021) The Global Risks Report 2021, 16th Edition. USA: World Economic Forum.
    [80] Mendis MVS, Welmilla I (2021) Green consciousness of employees, In: Human Resource Management in Challenging Environments: University of Kelaniya, Sri Lanka: 88–106.
    [81] Mallett RK, Melchiori K, Strickroth T (2013) Self-confrontation via a carbon footprint calculator increases guilt and support for a proenvironmental group. Ecopsychology 5: 9–16. https://doi.org/10.1089/eco.2012.0067 doi: 10.1089/eco.2012.0067
    [82] Marsina S, Hamranova A, Hrivikova T, et al. (2019) How can project orientation contribute to pro-environmental behavior in private organizations in Slovakia. J Clean Prod 231: 772–782. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.05.186 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.05.186
    [83] Minelgaitė A, Liobikienė G (2021) Changes in pro-environmental behaviour and its determinants during long-term period in a transition country as Lithuania. Environ Dev Sustain 23: 6083–16099. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-021-01329-9 doi: 10.1007/s10668-021-01329-9
    [84] Mirahsani N, Azizan O, Shahriari M, et al. (2023) Green culture toward employee green behavior; the mediation roles of perceived support and green identity. Environ Dev Sustain, 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-023-03291-0 doi: 10.1007/s10668-023-03291-0
    [85] Mirhadian N, Azizan O, Shahriari M (2023) The impact of green culture on employee organizational commitment: The mediating role of green identity. J Hum Behav Soc Environ, 1–21. https://doi.org/10.1080/10911359.2023.2222292 doi: 10.1080/10911359.2023.2222292
    [86] Mohamed YH, Adah-Kole E, Onjewu Witold N (2021) Environmental commitment and innovation as catalysts for export performance in family firms. Technol Forecast Soc Chang 173: 1–2. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2021.121085 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2021.121085
    [87] Morrison EW (2006) Doing the Job Well: An Investigation of Pro-Social Rule Breaking. J Manage 32: 5–28. https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206305277790 doi: 10.1177/0149206305277790
    [88] Nejati M, Rabiei S, Jabbour CJC (2017). Envisioning the invisible: understanding the synergy between Green Human Resource Management and Green Supply Chain Management in Manufacturing Firms in Iran in light of the moderating effect of employees' resistance to change. J Clean Prod 168: 163–172. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.08.213 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.08.213
    [89] Nemcsicsné ZA (2007) The role of organisational culture in the environmental awareness of companies. J East Eur Manag Stud 12: 109–131. http://dx.doi.org/10.5771/0949-6181-2007-2-109 doi: 10.5771/0949-6181-2007-2-109
    [90] Norton TA, Zacher H, Ashkanasy NM (2015) Pro-environmental organizational culture and climate, In: the psychology of green organizations, Oxford: Oxford Univerisity Press, 322–348.
    [91] Park H, Russell C, Lee J (2007) National culture and environmental sustainability: a cross-national analysis. J Econ Finan 31: 104–121. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02751516 doi: 10.1007/BF02751516
    [92] Pettigrew AM (1979) On Studying Organizational Cultures. Adm Sci Q 24: 570–581. https://doi.org/10.2307/2392363 doi: 10.2307/2392363
    [93] Piwowar-Sule K (2020) Pro-Environmental Organizational Culture: Its Essence and a Concept for Its Operationalization. Sustainability 12: 1–16. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12104197 doi: 10.3390/su12104197
    [94] Podsakoff PM, MacKenzie SB, Lee JY, et al. (2003) Common method biases in behavioral research: A critical review of the literature and recommended remedies. J Appl Psychol 88: 879–903. https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.88.5.879 doi: 10.1037/0021-9010.88.5.879
    [95] Podsakoff PM, MacKenzie SB, Podsakoff NP (2012) Sources of methods bias in social science and recommendations on how to control it. Annu Rev Psychol 63: 539–569. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-psych-120710-100452 doi: 10.1146/annurev-psych-120710-100452
    [96] Porter LW, Steers RM, Mowday RT, et al. (1974) Organizational commitment, job satisfaction, and turnover among psychiatric technicians. J Appl Psychol 59: 603–609. https://doi.org/10.1037/h0037335 doi: 10.1037/h0037335
    [97] Post JE, Altma BW (1994) Managing the Environmental Change Process: Barriers and Opportunities. J Organ Chang Manage 7: 64–81. https://doi.org/10.1108/09534819410061388 doi: 10.1108/09534819410061388
    [98] Rahman I, Reynolds D (2016) Predicting green hotel behavioral intentions using a theory of environmental commitment and sacrifice for the environment. Int J Hosp Manag 52: 107–116. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijhm.2015.09.007 doi: 10.1016/j.ijhm.2015.09.007
    [99] Reser JP, Bentrupperbaumer JM (2005) What and where are environmental values assessing the impact of current diversity of use of environmental and world heritage values. J Environ Psychol 25: 125–146. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvp.2005.03.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jenvp.2005.03.002
    [100] Riepe C, Liebe U, Fujitani M, et al. (2021) Values, Beliefs, Norms, and Conservation-Oriented Behaviors Native Fish Biodiversity in Rivers: Evidence from Four European Countries. Soc Nat Resour 34: 703–724. https://doi.org/10.1080/08941920.2021.1890865 doi: 10.1080/08941920.2021.1890865
    [101] Ringle C, Wende S, Becker J (2015) SmartPLS 3. Boenningstedt: SmartPLS. Available from: https://www.smartpls.com.
    [102] Ringov D, Zollo M (2007) The impact of national culture on corporate social performance. Corp Gov 7: 476–485. https://doi.org/10.1108/14720700710820551 doi: 10.1108/14720700710820551
    [103] Roldán JL, Cepeda G (2020) Curso de Modelos de Ecuaciones Estructurales Basados en la Varianza: Partial Least Squares (PLS) para Investigadores en Ciencias Sociales (IX Edición), in Módulo 1: Fundamentos básicos (mimeo). Sevilla: Centro de Formación Permanente (Universidad de Sevilla), 164–180.
    [104] Saleem M, Qadeer F, Mahmood F, et al. (2021) Inculcation of Green Behavior in Employees: A Multilevel Moderated Mediation Approach. Int J Environ Res Public Health 18: 1–21. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18010331 doi: 10.3390/ijerph18010331
    [105] Sanyal U, Pal D (2017) Effect of organizational culture in environmental awareness on pro-environmental behaviour at workplace: A new perspective on organizational sustainability. Int J Comm Manage Res, 60–65.
    [106] Sarstedt M, Hair JF, Cheah JH, et al. (2019) How to specify, estimate, and validate higher-order constructs in PLS-SEM. Australas Mark J 27: 197–211. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ausmj.2019.05.003 doi: 10.1016/j.ausmj.2019.05.003
    [107] Sarstedt M, Henseler J, Ringle CM (2011) Multigroup Analysis in Partial Least Squares (PLS) Path Modeling: Alternative Methods and Empirical Results, In: Sarstedt M, Schwaiger M, Taylor CR (Ed.), Measurement and Research Methods in International Marketing (Advances in International Marketing 22), Emerald Group Publishing Limited, Leeds, 195–218. https://doi.org/10.1108/S1474-7979(2011)0000022012
    [108] Schein E (1985) Organizational Culture and Leadership: A Dynamic View, Jossey-Bass, San Francisco, CA.
    [109] Sendawula K, Bagire V, Mbidde CI, et al. (2021) Environmental commitment and environmental sustainability practices of manufacturing small and medium enterprises in Uganda. J Enter Communities People Places Global Economy 15: 588–607. https://doi.org/10.1108/JEC-07-2020-0132 doi: 10.1108/JEC-07-2020-0132
    [110] Shahriari M, Riahi MT, Azizan O, et al. (2023) The effect of green organizational culture on organizational commitment: The mediating role of job satisfaction. J Hum Behav Soc Environ 33: 180–197. https://doi.org/10.1080/10911359.2022.2029789 doi: 10.1080/10911359.2022.2029789
    [111] Sharma S, Prakash G, Anil K, et al. (2021) Analysing the relationship of adaption of green culture, innovation, green performance for achieving sustainability: Mediating role of employee commitment. J Clean Prod 303: 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.127039 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.127039
    [112] Shmueli G, Ray S, Velasquez Estrada JM, et al. (2016) The elephant in the room: Predictive performance of PLS models. J Bus Res 69: 4552–4564. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2016.03.049 doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2016.03.049
    [113] Shmueli G, Sarstedt M, Hair J, et al. (2019) Predictive model assessment in PLS-SEM: Guidelines for using PLSpredict. Eur J Market 53: 2322–2347. https://doi.org/10.1108/EJM-02-2019-0189 doi: 10.1108/EJM-02-2019-0189
    [114] Singh H. (2008) Watching (out for) each other: the role of clan controls in managing project teams. Acad Manage Proc 8: 1–6. https://doi.org/10.5465/ambpp.2008.33725181 doi: 10.5465/ambpp.2008.33725181
    [115] Solomon G, Brown I (2020) The influence of organisational culture and information security culture on employee compliance behaviour. J Enterp Inf Manag 34: 1203–1228. https://doi.org/10.1108/JEIM-08-2019-0217 doi: 10.1108/JEIM-08-2019-0217
    [116] Steg L, Nordlund A (2019) Theories to explain environmental behaviour, In: Steg L, de Groot JIM (eds.) Environmental psychology: an introduction, 2nd ed., Hoboken, NJ: Wiley & Sons, 217–227.
    [117] Stern PC (2000) Toward a coherent theory of environmentally significant behavior. J Soc Issues 56: 407–424. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-4537.00175 doi: 10.1111/0022-4537.00175
    [118] Sugita M, Takahashi T (2013) Influence of Corporate Culture on Environmental Management Performance: An Empirical Study of Japanese Firms. Corp Soc Responsib Environ Manag 22: 182–192. https://doi.org/10.1002/csr.1346 doi: 10.1002/csr.1346
    [119] Sun X, El Askary A, Meo MS, et al. (2022). Green transformational leadership and environmental performance in small and medium enterprises. Ekon Istraz 35: 5273–5291. https://doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2021.2025127 doi: 10.1080/1331677X.2021.2025127
    [120] Tapia-Fonllem C, Corral-Verdugo V, Fraijo-Sing B, et al. (2013) Assessing Sustainable Behavior and its Correlates: A Measure of Pro-Ecological, Frugal, Altruistic and Equitable Actions. Sustainability 5: 711–723. https://doi.org/10.3390/su5020711 doi: 10.3390/su5020711
    [121] Tarique AA, Logan J, Thomas E, et al. (2015) Phenotypic, functional, and plasticity features of classical and alternatively activated human macrophages. Am J Respir Cell Mol Biol 53: 676–688. https://doi.org/10.1165/rcmb.2015-0012OC doi: 10.1165/rcmb.2015-0012OC
    [122] Tilleman S (2012) Is employee organizational commitment related to firm environmental sustainability? J Small Bus Entrep 25: 417–431. https://doi.org/10.1080/08276331.2012.10593582 doi: 10.1080/08276331.2012.10593582
    [123] Varela-Candamio L, Novo-Corti I, García-Álvarez MT (2018) The importance of environmental education in the determinants of green behavior: A meta-analysis approach. J Clean Prod 170: 1565–1578. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.214 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.214
    [124] Wang CH (2019) How organizational green culture influences green performance and competitive advantage. The mediating role of green innovation. J Manuf Technol Manag. 30: 666–683. https://doi.org/10.1108/JMTM-09-2018-0314 doi: 10.1108/JMTM-09-2018-0314
    [125] Wang S, Li J, Zhao D (2017) Institutional Pressures and Environmental Management Practices: The Moderating Effects of Environmental Commitment and Resource Availability. Bus Strateg Environ 27: 52–69. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.1983 doi: 10.1002/bse.1983
    [126] Weaver GR, Trevino LK, Cochran PL (1999) Integrated and decoupled corporate social performance: management commitments, external pressures, and corporate ethics practices. Acad Manage J 42: 539–552. https://doi.org/10.2307/256975 doi: 10.2307/256975
    [127] Wernerfelt B (1995) The Resource-Based View of the Firm: Ten Years After. Strateg Manag J 16: 171–174. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250160303 doi: 10.1002/smj.4250160303
    [128] Wijethilake C, Lama T (2019) Sustainability core values and sustainability risk management: Moderating effects of top management commitment and stakeholder pressure. Bus Strateg Environ 28: 143–154. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.2245 doi: 10.1002/bse.2245
    [129] Williams KJ, Cary J (2002) Landscape preferences, Ecological Quality, and Biodiversity Protection Environ Behav 34: 257–274. https://doi.org/10.1177/0013916502034002006 doi: 10.1177/0013916502034002006
    [130] Wong CA, Mohammad SH, Ramachandran S, et al. (2018) Conceptualizing environmental literacy and factors affecting pro-environmental. Int J Bus Soc 19: 28–139.
    [131] Wynveen CJ, Wynveen BJ, Sutton SG (2015) Applying the value-belief-norm theory to marine contexts: Implications for encouraging pro-environmental behavior. Coast Manag 43: 84–103. https://doi.org/10.1080/08920753.2014.989149 doi: 10.1080/08920753.2014.989149
    [132] Yang Y, Sun L, Han B, et al. (2023) The Trajectory of Anthropomorphism and Pro-Environmental Behavior: A Serial Mediation Model. Int J Environ Res Public Health 20: 32393. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph20032393 doi: 10.3390/ijerph20032393
    [133] Yang-Spencer S, Adams C, Yapa PWS (2013) The mediating effects of the adoption of an environmental information system on top management's commitment and environmental performance. Sustain Account Manag Policy J 4: 75–102. https://doi.org/10.1108/SAMPJ-10-2011-0030 doi: 10.1108/SAMPJ-10-2011-0030
    [134] Ying M, Faraz NA, Ahmed F, et al. (2020) How Does Servant Leadership Foster Employees' Voluntary Green Behavior? A Sequential Mediation Model. Int J Environ Res Public Health 17: 1–21. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph17051792 doi: 10.3390/ijerph17051792
    [135] Yong JY, Yusliza MY, Fawehinmi OO (2020) Green human resource management: A systematic literature review from 2007 to 2019. Benchmarking Int J 27: 2005–2027. https://doi.org/10.1108/BIJ-12-2018-0438 doi: 10.1108/BIJ-12-2018-0438
    [136] Yu J, Win-Hung C, Hon P (2017) Organizational visibility, stakeholder environmental pressure and corporate environmental responsiveness in China. Bus Strateg Environ 26: 371–384. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.1923 doi: 10.1002/bse.1923
    [137] Yu TK, Lin F, Kao KY, et al. (2019). Encouraging Environmental Commitment to Sustainability: An Empirical Study of Environmental Connectedness Theory to Undergraduate Students. Sustainability 11: 342. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11020342 doi: 10.3390/su11020342
    [138] Yusliza MY, Amirudin A, Rahadi RA, et al. (2020) An Investigation of Pro-Environmental Behaviour and Sustainable Development in Malaysia. Sustainability 12: 7083. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12177083 doi: 10.3390/su12177083
    [139] Zaid, AA, Jaaron AAM, Talib Bon A (2018) The impact of green human resource management and green supply chain management practices on sustainable performance: An empirical study. J Clean Prod 204: 965–979. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.09.062 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.09.062
  • GF-05-04-024-s001.pdf
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Dario Madeo, Somnath Mazumdar, Chiara Mocenni, Roberto Zingone, Evolutionary game for task mapping in resource constrained heterogeneous environments, 2020, 108, 0167739X, 762, 10.1016/j.future.2020.03.026
    2. D. Madeo, C. Mocenni, Evolutionary Game Theoretic Insights on the SIRS Model of the COVID-19 Pandemic, 2021, 54, 24058963, 1, 10.1016/j.ifacol.2021.11.016
    3. Dario Madeo, Sergio Salvatore, Terri Mannarini, Chiara Mocenni, Modeling pluralism and self-regulation explains the emergence of cooperation in networked societies, 2021, 11, 2045-2322, 10.1038/s41598-021-98524-5
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(4393) PDF downloads(451) Cited by(3)

Figures and Tables

Figures(4)  /  Tables(12)

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog