
Access to electricity is touted as one of the ways of reducing poverty and improving the livelihoods of people. However, an increased consumption may also contribute to higher carbon dioxide emissions. While many studies have therefore assessed the determinants of electricity consumption for developing countries that have a lower electricity consumption and inadequate supply to meet demand, the effect of financial development on electricity consumption has been mixed. Consequently, this study models electricity consumption in Ghana with special attention on the effect of financial development. The results show that price reduces electricity consumption while income and population density increase consumption of electricity. When financial development is represented by domestic credit to private sector, domestic credit to private sector by banks and broad money supply, the effect is negative on electricity consumption. However, the effect is positive when financial development is represented by foreign direct investment. A financial index constructed from the four indicators shows financial development reduces electricity consumption in Ghana. Among other things the policy implication includes the need to formulate appropriate policy based on a specific indicator for financial development.
Citation: Peter Ansu-Mensah, Paul Adjei Kwakwa. Modelling electricity consumption in Ghana: the role of financial development indicators[J]. Green Finance, 2022, 4(1): 54-70. doi: 10.3934/GF.2022003
[1] | Yanchao He, Yuzhen Bai . Finite-time stability and applications of positive switched linear delayed impulsive systems. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2024, 4(2): 178-194. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2024016 |
[2] | Hongyu Ma, Dadong Tian, Mei Li, Chao Zhang . Reachable set estimation for 2-D switched nonlinear positive systems with impulsive effects and bounded disturbances described by the Roesser model. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2024, 4(2): 152-162. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2024014 |
[3] | Hongwei Zheng, Yujuan Tian . Exponential stability of time-delay systems with highly nonlinear impulses involving delays. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2025, 5(1): 103-120. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2025008 |
[4] | Yunsi Yang, Jun-e Feng, Lei Jia . Recent advances of finite-field networks. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2023, 3(3): 244-255. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2023021 |
[5] | Wen Zhang, Jinjun Fan, Yuanyuan Peng . On the discontinuous dynamics of a class of 2-DOF frictional vibration systems with asymmetric elastic constraints. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2023, 3(4): 278-305. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2023024 |
[6] | Bangxin Jiang, Yijun Lou, Jianquan Lu . Input-to-state stability of delayed systems with bounded-delay impulses. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2022, 2(2): 44-54. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2022006 |
[7] | Lusong Ding, Weiwei Sun . Neuro-adaptive finite-time control of fractional-order nonlinear systems with multiple objective constraints. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2023, 3(4): 355-369. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2023029 |
[8] | Yulin Guan, Xue Zhang . Dynamics of a coupled epileptic network with time delay. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2022, 2(1): 13-23. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2022003 |
[9] | Shipeng Li . Impulsive control for stationary oscillation of nonlinear delay systems and applications. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2023, 3(4): 267-277. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2023023 |
[10] | Gani Stamov, Ekaterina Gospodinova, Ivanka Stamova . Practical exponential stability with respect to h−manifolds of discontinuous delayed Cohen–Grossberg neural networks with variable impulsive perturbations. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2021, 1(1): 26-34. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2021003 |
Access to electricity is touted as one of the ways of reducing poverty and improving the livelihoods of people. However, an increased consumption may also contribute to higher carbon dioxide emissions. While many studies have therefore assessed the determinants of electricity consumption for developing countries that have a lower electricity consumption and inadequate supply to meet demand, the effect of financial development on electricity consumption has been mixed. Consequently, this study models electricity consumption in Ghana with special attention on the effect of financial development. The results show that price reduces electricity consumption while income and population density increase consumption of electricity. When financial development is represented by domestic credit to private sector, domestic credit to private sector by banks and broad money supply, the effect is negative on electricity consumption. However, the effect is positive when financial development is represented by foreign direct investment. A financial index constructed from the four indicators shows financial development reduces electricity consumption in Ghana. Among other things the policy implication includes the need to formulate appropriate policy based on a specific indicator for financial development.
Switched cascade nonlinear systems (SCNSs) combine both features of switched systems [1,2,3,4,5] and cascade systems [6,7,8,9] and are characterized by complex dynamics and broad applications [10,11,12]. On this ground, a great number of researchers have intensively investigated dynamics, especially stability and control issues, of SCNSs, see [13,14,15,16] and the references therein.
Consider the following SCNS with delays:
˙x(t)=hσ(t)(t,xt,d(t)), | (1.1a) |
˙y(t)=fσ(t)(t,yt,d(t))+gσ(t)(t,xt,d(t)), | (1.1b) |
where d(t) is delay, σ(t) is a switching signal. System (1.1a) and
˙y(t)=fσ(t)(t,yt,d(t)), | (1.2) |
are called separate systems 1 and 2 of cascade system (1.1), respectively, and the term gσ(t) is the coupling term. Clearly, evolution of (1.1a) is completely determined by (1.1a) itself and it affects that of system (1.1b) via gσ(t).
Lyapunov theory is a powerful and popular tool to study stability of cascade systems [17,18,19]. Since cascade systems have particular structure, a widely employed method is composite Lyapunov function (functional) [20] which is based on separate Lyapunov function (functional) constructed for each separate system. This method uses an intuitive idea: The property of a cascade system is related to all separate systems and the coupling terms among them.
Note that (1.1b) can be viewed as perturbed system of (1.2) with perturbation gσ(t). It would be desirable that one can draw a stability conclusion for system (1.1) from stability properties of systems (1.1a) and (1.2) and property of perturbation gσ(t). Actually, several papers have been reported on stability of delayed SCNSs using the intuitive point of view. Suppose always that coupling term gσ(t) has a linear growth bound [21]. With the assumption that system (1.2) is exponentially stable, it was revealed that system (1.1) is exponentially stable if and only if so is system (1.1a), and that it is asymptotically stable if so is system (1.1a) [14,16]. These results essentially rely on the following key observation: For a nominal delayed switched nonlinear system being exponentially stable, trajectories of the corresponding perturbed system exponentially (asymptotically) decay to origin if the perturbation can be upper bounded by a function exponentially (asymptotically) converging to zero. Note that many systems are asymptotically stable but not exponentially stable since asymptotic stability is weaker than exponential one. Therefore, it is more significant to study the situation where the nominal systems are asymptotically stable. Recently, it was proposed in Ref. [22] that for a nominal discrete-time switched system being asymptotically stable, trajectories of the corresponding perturbed system asymptotically converge to zero if the perturbation exponentially approaches zero. Based on this fact and with assumption that separate system 2 is asymptotically stable, it was shown that a discrete-time SCNS is asymptotically stable if separate system 1 is exponentially stable [22].
Our motivations are as follows: (ⅰ) The key assumption in Ref. [14] is that separate system 2 is exponentially stable. The stability property keeps unknown in the situation where separate system 2 is asymptotically stable and will be investigated in the present paper. (ⅱ) Explore the robust convergence of an asymptotically stable nominal system with perturbations. Since asymptotic stability is much weaker than exponential one, the issue discussed here is of more importance than that in [14]. (ⅲ) Provide a counterpart of Ref. [22] for continuous-time SCNSs, which is more challenging.
The main contribution lies in three aspects: (ⅰ) The concept of uniform switching signals is proposed, which makes main results in the present paper applicable to many classes of switched systems. (ⅱ) It is shown that, with the assumption that the nominal delayed switched nonlinear system is asymptotically stable, trajectories of the perturbed system asymptotically approach zero if the perturbation can be upper bounded by an exponentially decaying function. (ⅲ) Some sufficient asymptotic stability conditions are presented for continuous-time delayed SCNSs. These results can be applied to stability analysis and controller design for SCNSs in a decomposition way.
The rest is organized as follows. Preliminaries are presented in Section 2. Convergence property of delayed switched nonlinear systems subject to perturbations is discussed in Subsection 3.1, and stability conditions of SCNSs are proposed in Subsection 3.2. A numerical example is provided in Section 4. Finally, Section 5 concludes this paper.
Notation. Rn×m is the set of n×m-dimensional real matrices and Rn=Rn×1. R0,+=[0,∞) and R+=(0,∞). N0={0,1,2,…} and N={1,2,…}. AT is the transpose of matrix A. Given vectors x,y, col(x,y)=[xTyT]T. For a fixed real number a, ⌈a⌉ is the minimum integer greater than or equal to a and |a| is its absolute value. ‖x‖∞=max{|x1|,…,|xn|} is the l∞ norm of x∈Rn and is denoted by ‖x‖. For any continuous function x(s) on [−d,a) with scalars a>0, d>0 and any t∈[0,a), xt denotes a continuous function on [t−d,t] defined by xt(θ)= x(t+θ) for each θ∈[−d,0]. ‖xt‖= supt−d≤s≤t{‖x(s)‖}. C([a,b],Rn) is the set of continuous functions from interval [a,b] to Rn, and Cϑ([a,b],Rn)={x∈C([a,b],Rn):‖x‖<ϑ} with ϑ>0. Let κ∈(0,∞]. A continuous function α:[0,κ)→[0,∞) belongs to class K if it is strictly increasing and α(0)=0, and a continuous function β:[0,κ)×[0,∞)→[0,∞) belongs to class KL, if for each fixed s, β(r,s) belongs to class K with respect to r, and for each fixed r, β(r,s) is decreasing with respect to s and β(r,s)→0 as s→∞ [21]. Throughout this paper, the dimensions of matrices and vectors will not be explicitly mentioned if clear from context.
Consider the following switched nonlinear system:
˙x(t)=fσ(t)(t,xt,d(t)),t≥t0,x(t)=φ(t),t∈[t0−d,t0], | (2.1) |
where t0≥0, x(t)∈Rn is the state, σ:[t0,∞)→{1,…,m} is a switching signal with m being the number of subsystems and is piecewise constant and continuous from the right. It is assumed in the sequel that σ is with switching sequence {ti}∞i=0. d(t)=col(d1(t),…,dι(t))∈Dι≜[d11,d12]×⋯×[dι1,dι2], where di2≥di1≥0,∀i∈{1,…,ι}, and di(t)∈[di1,di2] is piecewise continuous [23]. d=maxi∈{1,…,ι}{di2}. For each l∈{1,…,m}, fl maps [t0,∞)×C([−d,0],Rn)×Dι into Rn. φ∈C([t0−d,t0],Rn) is an initial vector-valued function.
Remark 2.1. By definition, xt has implicitly included the information of d(t) since xt(θ)= x(t+θ),∀θ∈[−d,0]. Thus, the parameter d(t) in system (2.1) is somewhat redundant in some sense. However, due to the fact that several vectors of delays will be introduced in Subsection 3.2, we prefer to write d(t) explicitly in order to distinguish them. The vector d(t) can describe multiple delays including constant, time-varying, distributed, and interval ones [23].
The following assumption is made for system (2.1).
Assumption 2.1. fl(⋅,0,⋅)=0. fl is continuous on [t0,∞)×C([−d,0],Rn)×Dι and is (locally) Lipschitz in the second argument, uniformly in [t0,∞)×Dι, that is, there exist positive scalars L,ϑ such that
‖fl(⋅,x,⋅)−fl(⋅,y,⋅)‖≤L‖x−y‖,∀x,y∈Cϑ([−d,0],Rn). | (2.2) |
Note that fl is globally Lipschitz if ϑ=∞.
There are many kinds of switching signals in literature which play a fundamental role on system dynamics. To motivate our new concept, let us recall some kinds of familiar switching signals in literature.
1. Periodically switching signals: There exists a scalar κ>0 such that σ(t+κ)=σ(t),∀t≥t0, which clearly implies that σ(t+κ)=σ(t),∀t≥t0+c with c>0.
2. Switching signals having property of finite discontinuities on finite interval: σ has finite discontinuities on any finite interval contained in [t0,∞). Clearly, σ also has finite discontinuities on any finite interval contained in [t0+c,∞) with c>0.
Now introduce the concept of uniform switching signal which includes most switching signals frequently encountered in literature.
Definition 2.1. (Uniform switching signals) A switching property P is said to uniform (with respect to t) if P is valid on [t0+c,∞) for any c>0. A switching signal σ satisfying a uniform property P is said to be a uniform one (with P). The set S(P)={σ:σ has uniform property P} is said to be uniform with P.
One can easily check the following properties are uniform. (ⅰ). Property satisfying average dwell time constraint: There exist positive numbers N0 and τa such that Nσ(T,t)≤N0+T−tτa with Nσ(T,t) being the switching number of σ on the open interval (t,T),∀T>t≥t0 [24]. (ⅱ). Property satisfying dwell time constraint (which is actually a special case of (ⅰ) with N0=1 [24,page 58]). (ⅲ). Fast switching property [25,26]. (ⅳ). Homogeneous Markov switching property [27]. (ⅴ). Property satisfying mode-dependent average dwell time constraint [28].
In the sequel, it is always assumed that the underlying set S is uniform with certain given P. Since we do not discuss any specific P, P will not be mentioned explicitly. Moreover, when speaking of "a switched system has some dynamic property", we mean that the property holds for any σ∈S.
It is worth noting that there may exist some relationship between different uniform P's and that for a given switched system with specified subsystems, its dynamic property may vary with P. If P1 is "arbitrary switching" and P2 has a dwell time τd, then it may occur that a system is asymptotically stable over S(P2) but diverges over S(P1). Conversely, if a system is asymptotically stable over S(P1) then it is also asymptotically stable over S(P2) since S(P2)⊆S(P1).
Though most switching signals possess uniformity, there do exist exceptions one of which is the so-called Zeno behavior admitting an infinite number of switches in a finite interval [29].
To make notation concise, from now on we denote the solution to (2.1) by x(t;φ) rather than x(t;t0,φ) with starting time t0 and initial function φ defined on [t0−d,t0], since t0 is indicated by φ. xc is the solution to (2.1) on interval [c−d,c] for c≥t0. This convention will be applied to systems (3.1) and (3.40) without further statement.
Definition 2.2. ([30]) Given a set of switching signals S. System (2.1) is locally uniformly exponentially stable (LUES) if there exist positive scalars α,γ,δ satisfying ‖x(t;φ)‖≤αexp(−γ(t−t0))‖φ‖,∀t0≥0,t≥t0,‖φ‖≤δ,d(t)∈Dι,σ∈S; if δ can be arbitrarily large, then it is globally uniformly exponentially stable (GUES). (2.1) is locally uniformly asymptotically stable (LUAS) if there exists a function β of class KL and a scalar δ such that ‖x(t;φ)‖≤β(‖φ‖,t−t0),∀t0≥0,t≥t0,‖φ‖≤δ,d(t)∈Dι,σ∈S; if δ can be arbitrarily large, then it is globally uniformly asymptotically stable (GUAS). The scalar δ is called the radius of attraction if (2.1) is LUES or LUAS.
Now introduce the following lemma:
Lemma 2.1. Let (2.1) be GUAS, that is, there exists a function β∈KL satisfying ‖x(t;φ)‖≤β(‖φ‖,t−t0),∀t≥t0. Fix positive scalars a,b,ν satisfying a≤b. Then there exists a scalar τ>0 such that β(‖φ‖,t−t0)≤ν‖φ‖ and ‖x(t;φ)‖≤ν‖φ‖, ∀t≥t0+τ,a≤‖φ‖≤b.
Proof. Fix a,b,ν. Since (2.1) is GUAS, there exists β∈KL such that ‖x(t;φ)‖≤β(‖φ‖,t−t0). Suppose by contradiction that for any τ>0, there exists a pair (φ,c) with a≤‖φ‖≤b and c≥τ such that β(‖φ‖,c)>ν‖φ‖. Take an increasing positive sequence {τi}∞i=1 with τ1≥t0,limi→∞τi=∞, and there exists a sequence of pairs {(φi,ci)}∞i=1 satisfying a≤‖φi‖≤b,τi≤ci, and β(‖φi‖,ci)>ν‖φ‖. ‖φi‖≤b means limi→∞β(b,ci)≥limi→∞β(‖φi‖,ci)≥ν‖φ‖≥νa>0, contradicting the fact limi→∞β(b,ci)=0. Therefore, there necessarily exists τ>0 satisfying β(‖φ‖,t−t0)≤ν‖φ‖,∀t≥t0+τ,a≤‖φ‖≤b. Since ‖x(t;φ)‖≤β(‖φ‖,t−t0), it is clear that ‖x(t;φ)‖≤ν‖φ‖,∀t≥t0+τ,a≤‖φ‖≤b.
A similar proof immediately yields the next corollary:
Corollary 2.1. Assume that (2.1) is LUAS with radius of attraction δ, that is, there exists a function β∈KL satisfying ‖x(t;φ)‖≤β(‖φ‖,t−t0),∀t≥t0,‖φ‖≤δ. Fix positive scalars a,b,ν such that a≤b≤δ. Then there exists a scalar τ>0 such that β(‖φ‖,t−t0)≤ν‖φ‖ and ‖x(t;φ)‖≤ν‖φ‖, ∀t≥t0+τ,a≤‖φ‖≤b.
This section first investigates the convergence of delayed switched systems with perturbations, and then analyzes stability of switched cascade systems with delays.
Consider the following perturbed system of (2.1)
˙y(t)=fσ(t)(t,yt,d(t))+u(t),t≥t0,y(t)=φ(t),t∈[t0−d,t0], | (3.1) |
with u(t) being perturbation. The next assumption is always imposed on u(t):
Assumption 3.1. ‖u(t)‖≤α1exp(−γ1(t−t0)),∀t≥t0, for some α1>0,γ1>0.
The following lemma estimates the error between the trajectories of (2.1) and (3.1) with the assumption that both systems are with a same initial function.
Lemma 3.1. Assume that systems (2.1) and (3.1) evolve from c≥t0 and are with a same initial function ϕ defined on [c−d,c]. Let x(t;ϕ),y(t;ϕ) be solutions to (2.1) and (3.1), respectively. Define
e(t;c)=y(t;ϕ)−x(t;ϕ),ci=c+i2L,i∈N0,‖u‖i=supci−1≤s≤ci{‖u(s)‖},i∈N. |
The following statements hold:
1. Suppose that Assumption 2.1 holds with ϑ=∞. Then
‖e(t;c)‖≤1Li∑l=12i−l‖u‖l,t∈[ci−1,ci),i∈N. | (3.2) |
2. Suppose that Assumption 2.1 holds with ϑ∈R+. If xs,ys∈Cϑ([−d,0],Rn) hold for any s∈[c,t], then (3.2) is true.
Proof. Item 2 is exactly [14,Lemma 7], and Item 1 naturally holds for ϑ=∞.
Note that the above lemma provides an estimate of difference between solutions to (2.1) and (3.1) on [ci−1,ci), which is completely determined by perturbation u(t) and is not affected by initial condition. Item 1 is a global version and Item 2 is a local one.
Define
μ(t)=2⌈t/L⌉−1Lα1. | (3.3) |
Clearly, μ(t) monotonically increases. It follows from (3.2) that
‖e(t;c)‖≤1L⌈(t−c)/L⌉∑l=12⌈(t−c)/L⌉−lsupc≤s≤t‖u(s)‖=2⌈(t−c)/L⌉−1Lsupc≤s≤t‖u(s)‖, |
which, by Assumption 3.1, further means that
‖e(t;c)‖≤μ(t−c)exp(−γ1(c−t0)),t≥c. | (3.4) |
The identity y(t;φ)=y(t;yc) clearly holds for t≥c≥t0. If (2.1) is GUAS, then there exists a β∈KL satisfying ‖x(t;φ)‖≤β(‖φ‖,t−t0),∀t0≥0,t≥t0, and thus
‖y(t;φ)‖=‖y(t;yc)‖≤‖x(t;yc)‖+‖e(t;c)‖≤β(‖yc‖,t−c)+‖e(t;c)‖,t≥c. |
Hence,
‖y(t;φ)‖≤‖x(t;yc)‖+‖e(t;c)‖,t≥c, | (3.5) |
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(‖yc‖,0)+‖e(t;c)‖,t≥c, | (3.6) |
(3.5) and (3.6), together with (3.4), indicate that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤‖x(t;yc)‖+μ(t−c)exp(−γ1(c−t0)),t≥c, | (3.7) |
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(‖yc‖,0)+μ(t−c)exp(−γ1(c−t0)),t≥c. | (3.8) |
Fix ϑ in Assumption 2.1. If (2.1) is LUAS with the radius of attraction δ and if ‖ys‖≤min{δ,ϑ} for s∈[c,t], then (3.5)-(3.8) also hold.
Lemma 3.2. Fix a uniform Si. Suppose that system (2.1) is LUAS. Then the solution to system (3.1) is bounded on [t0,∞) with ‖φ‖≤δ1,α1≤δ1 for some δ1.
iHere we drop the uniform property P from S(P). In the sequel, S(P) will also be denoted by S.
Proof. The importance of uniformity of S is demonstrated first. We are concerned with the dynamics of system (3.1) over given set S and will exploit evolution of system (2.1) with different starting time c>t0 and initial function yc defined on [c−d,c]. Define Sc={σ:[c,∞)→{1,…,m},σ∈S}. Since S is uniform with given uniform P, Sc is necessarily uniform with P. System (2.1) is LUAS implies that there exists a constant ε>0 and a function β∈KL such that ‖x(t;φ)‖≤β(‖φ‖,t−t0),∀t0≥0,t≥t0,‖φ‖≤ε, where φ∈C([t0−d,t0],Rn). It also holds that ‖x(t;ϕ)‖≤β(‖ϕ‖,t−c),∀c>t0,t≥c,‖ϕ‖≤ε with ϕ∈C([c−d,c],Rn) since both S and Sc are uniform with P.
β∈KL implies existence of τ>0 such that
β(ε,t−t0)≤0.5ε,∀t≥t0+τ. | (3.9) |
Let ζ=0.5Lε2⌈(τ+d)/L⌉−1 and take δ1=min{ε,ζ}. Suppose that φ,α1 satisfy ‖φ‖≤δ1,α1≤δ1. By definition of μ(t),
μ(τ+d)≤0.5ε. | (3.10) |
Inequality (3.7) with c=t0 indicates that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤‖x(t;φ)‖+μ(t−t0)≤β(δ1,t−t0)+μ(t−t0),t≥t0, | (3.11) |
(3.9) and the definition of δ1 mean that β(δ1,t−t0)≤β(ε,t−t0), which, together with (3.10), (3.11), and the monotonicity of μ, gives the following estimate:
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(ε,t−t0)+0.5ε≤ε,t∈[t0+τ,t0+τ+d]. | (3.12) |
By (3.7),
‖y(t;φ)‖≤‖x(t;yt0+τ+d)‖+μ(t−t0−τ−d)exp(−γ1(τ+d)),t≥t0+τ+d. | (3.13) |
The consequence of (3.12) is ‖yt0+τ+d‖≤ε. Clearly, exp(−γ1(τ+d))<1. Therefore, (3.13) implies that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(ε,t−t0−τ−d)+μ(τ+d)≤ε,t∈[t0+2τ+d,t0+2τ+2d]. | (3.14) |
Following a similar process, one can show that for any i∈N0, the following inequality holds:
‖y(t;φ)‖≤ε,t∈[t0+(i+1)τ+id,t0+(i+1)τ+(i+1)d]. | (3.15) |
By (3.8) and (3.15), it is not difficult to see that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(‖yt0+iτ+id‖,0)+μ(t−t0−iτ−id)exp(−γ1(iτ+id))≤β(ε,0)+μ(τ+d)exp(−γ1(iτ+id))≤β(ε,0)+0.5ε,t∈[t0+iτ+id,t0+(i+1)τ+(i+1)d],i∈N0. | (3.16) |
In a word, if ‖φ‖≤δ1,α1≤δ1, then
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(ε,0)+0.5ε,t≥t0. | (3.17) |
The proof is completed.
We are in a position to present the following result which shows that the solution to system (3.1) approaches zero asymptotically provided that system (2.1) is LUAS.
Theorem 3.1. Fix a uniform S and consider system (3.1). Suppose that system (2.1) is LUAS and that Assumption 2.1 holds. Then there exists a ˉβ∈KL and a scalar δ1>0 such that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤ˉβ(θ,t−t0),∀t≥t0,t0≥0, | (3.18) |
for any ‖φ‖<δ1,θ<δ1, where θ=max{‖φ‖,α1}.
Proof. Since system (2.1) is LUAS, there exists a β∈KL and ϑ such that Assumption 2.1 is satisfied and that
‖x(t;φ)‖≤β(‖φ‖,t−t0),∀t≥t0,t0≥0,‖φ‖≤ϑ. | (3.19) |
It is easy to see that there exists a unique constant ε>0 such that β(ε,0)+0.5ε=ϑ. According to (3.17) and Lemma 3.2, one can fix δ1>0 such that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤ϑ,∀t≥t0,‖φ‖≤δ1,α1≤δ1, | (3.20) |
which means that δ≜sup‖φ‖≤δ1,α1≤δ1,t≥t0{‖y(t;φ)‖}≤ϑ exists. Fix φ,α1 with ‖φ‖<δ1,α1<δ1 and let θ=max{‖φ‖,α1}. Thus,
‖y(t;φ)‖≤δ,∀t≥t0. | (3.21) |
Since β(δq,0)+0.5δq2=0 if q=0 and β(δq,0)+0.5δq2 is strictly increasing with respect to q, we can pick the unique q∈(0,1) satisfying β(δq,0)+0.5δq2=δ (note that β(δ,0)≥δ).
By Corollary 2.1, there exists a positive increasing sequence {τi}∞i=1 such that
β(s,t−t0)≤0.5qs,∀t0≥0,t≥t0+τi,δqi≤s≤δqi−1, | (3.22) |
which further means
β(s,t−t0)≤0.5δqi,∀t0≥0,t≥t0+τi,s≤δqi−1, | (3.23) |
Denote μi=μ(τi+d) with μ defined in (3.3). Choose a1>0 satisfying μ1θexp(−a1γ1)≤0.5δq. Note that such an a1 does exist, since μ1,θ,γ1,δ and q are all known positive constants. Then, pick the minimal b1∈N and a2>0 such that μ2θexp(−a2γ1)≤0.5δq2 and a2=a1+b1(τ1+d). Construct in the same manner a positive sequence {ai}∞i=1 and a positive integer sequence {bi}∞i=1 which are minimal in the sense that ai(i>1),bi(i≥1) are minimal values satisfying
μiθexp(−aiγ1)≤0.5δqi,ai+1=ai+bi(τi+d),i∈N. | (3.24) |
Note that ai,bi are independent of t0. The following symbols will be used repeatedly.
ci=t0+ai,ail=ai+l(τi+d),cil=t0+ail,i∈N,l∈{0,1,…,bi}Iil=[cil−1,cil],I_il=[cil−1,cil−d],ˉIil=[cil−d,cil],i∈N,l∈{1,…,bi}. | (3.25) |
It is clear that
ai0=ai,aibi=ai+1,ci0=ci,cibi=ci+1,i∈N.
Taking c=cil−1, it follows form (3.4) that
‖e(t;cil−1)‖≤μ(t−cil−1)exp(−γ1(cil−1−t0)),t∈Iil,i∈N,l∈{1,…,bi}. | (3.26) |
Since μ(s) is increasing in s, it holds that μ(t−cil−1)≤μ(cil−cil−1)=μ(τi+d)=μi,∀t∈Iil. This, together with (3.26), implies that
‖e(t;cil−1)‖≤μiexp(−γ1(cil−1−t0))=μiexp(−ail−1γ1),t∈Iil,i∈N,l∈{1,…,bi}. |
By definition of ail in (3.25), ai=ai0<ai1<⋯<aibi. The above inequality means that
‖e(t;cil−1)‖≤μiexp(−aiγ1),t∈Iil,i∈N,l∈{1,…,bi}, |
which, by considering the inequality in (3.24), results in
‖e(t;cil−1)‖≤0.5δqi,t∈Iil,i∈N,l∈{1,…,bi}. | (3.27) |
First prove that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤δq,t∈ˉI1b1. | (3.28) |
Condition (3.21) clearly means that
‖yci‖≤δ,i∈N. | (3.29) |
By the definition of τ1, it holds that β(s,t−t0)≤0.5qs,t≥t0+τ1,δq≤s≤δ. This inequality, combining (3.27) (with i=l=1), (3.29) (with i=1), and (3.5), yields that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤0.5q‖yc1‖+0.5δq≤δq,c11−d≤t≤c11. | (3.30) |
If b1=1 then (3.28) holds; otherwise suppose that ‖y(t;φ)‖≤δq(t∈ˉI1l) with l∈{1,…,b1−1}. (3.7) and (with c=c11) and (3.27) and (with i=1,l=l+1) imply that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(‖yc1l‖,t−c1l)+0.5δq≤δq,t∈ˉI1l+1. |
By induction, ‖y(t;φ)‖≤δq,t∈ˉI1l+1 holds for any l∈{1,…,bi}. Therefore (3.28) is true.
Now show that for i∈N∖{1}, it holds that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(δqi−1,0)+0.5δqi,ci<t≤ci+1 | (3.31) |
‖y(t;φ)‖≤δqi,t∈ˉIibi. | (3.32) |
Consider (3.31) and (3.32) for the case i=2. By condition (3.28) and the definitions of b1,c2, we have
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(‖yc2‖,t−c2)+0.5q2δ≤β(qδ,t−c2)+0.5q2δ,t∈I21. | (3.33) |
By the definition of τ2 and considering (3.23) (with i=2), (3.33) further means that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(qδ,τ2)+0.5q2δ≤0.5δq2+0.5δq2=δq2,t∈ˉI21. | (3.34) |
If b2=1, then (3.31) and (3.32) hold for i=2. Otherwise, following a reasoning similar to the process from (3.33) to (3.34), and using the mathematical induction principle, it yields that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(‖yc2l−1‖,t−c2l−1)+0.5δq2,t∈I2l,l∈{1,…,b2}, | (3.35) |
‖y(t;φ)‖≤q2δ,t∈ˉI2l,l∈{1,…,b2}. | (3.36) |
Since β is decreasing in the second argument, (3.35) and (3.36) respectively imply that (3.31) and (3.32) hold for i=2. Moreover, in a very similar manner proving the case i=2, it is straightforward to verify that (3.31) and (3.32) hold for i+1 provided that they hold for i≥2. Therefore, by the mathematical induction principle, (3.31) and (3.32) hold for any i∈N∖{1}.
Conditions (3.21), (3.31) and the fact β(δq,0)+0.5δq2=δ produce that
‖y(t;φ)‖≤δ,t∈[t0,c2],‖y(t;φ)‖≤β(δqi−1,0)+0.5δqi,t∈(ci,ci+1],i∈N∖{1}. | (3.37) |
Fix a scalar ϵ>0 and introduce
ˉβ(θ,t)={δ+ϵθ,t∈[0,a2],β(δqi−1,0)+0.5(δ+ϵθ)qi,t∈(ai,ai+1],i∈N∖{1}. | (3.38) |
Since δ=sup‖φ‖≤θ,α1≤θ,t≥t0{‖y(t;φ)‖}, δ is increasing in θ. Fix 0≤θ1<θ2,t≥0. If t∈[0,a2], then ˉβ(θ2,t)−ˉβ(θ1,t)≥ϵθ2−ϵθ1>0; if t∈(ai,ai+1] for some i∈N∖{1}, then ˉβ(θ2,t)−ˉβ(θ1,t)>0 also holds. That is, ˉβ(θ,t) strictly monotonically increases in θ. Moreover, ˉβ(θ,t) monotonically decreases in t, and approaches zero as t→∞. Therefore, ˉβ belongs to KL and is independent of t0.
(3.37) and (3.38) indicate that ‖y(t;φ)‖≤ˉβ(θ,t−t0). The proof is completed.
It seems that the constraint ‖u(t)‖≤α1exp(−γ1(t−t0)) in Assumption 3.1 is too restrictive. Actually, in our context, if ‖u(t)‖ is upper bounded by a function asymptotically rather than exponentially decaying to zero, then the perturbed system may diverge, as indicated in the next example.
Example 3.1. Consider the following scalar system:
˙x(t)=a(t)x(t), | (3.39a) |
˙y(t)=a(t)y(t)+u(t). | (3.39b) |
Let a(t)=ln0.5<0,u(t)=1 for t∈[0,1), a(t)=−0.6ln0.5>0 for t∈[1,2),a(t)=ln0.5 for t∈[2,3),u(t)=0.6 for t∈[1,3). Define for i∈N∖{1} the interval Ωi=[2i−1,2i+1−1) and u(t)=0.6i,∀t∈Ωi. Thus, u(t)→0 as t→0. Note that u(t) does not satisfy Assumption 3.1. Further define Ωil=[2i+l−1,2i+l),∀l∈{0,1,…,2i−1}. a(t) is defined on Ωi,i≥2, in the following way:
a(t)={−0.6ln0.5,t∈Ωi0,ln0.5,t∈Ωil,l∈{1,3,…,2i−1},−ln0.5,t∈Ωil,l∈{2,3,…,2i−2}. |
It is not difficult to show that (3.39a) is asymptotically rather than exponentially stable and that (3.39b) diverges. This fact is shown in Figure 1.
Consider the following cascade system
˙x(t)=˜fσ(t)(t,xt,˜d(t)),t≥t0, | (3.40a) |
˙y(t)=fσ(t)(t,yt,d(t))+gσ(t)(t,xt,ˉd(t)),t≥t0, | (3.40b) |
col(x(t),y(t))=φ(t),t∈[t0−d,t0],
where x(t)∈Rn1,y(t)∈Rn2, and φ=col(φ1,φ2), which means that for each t∈[t0−d,t0], φ(t)=col(φ1(t),φ2(t)) with φ1(t)∈Rn1,φ2(t)∈Rn2. ˜d(t),d(t),ˉd(t) are different delay vectors, and d is upper bound of all delays. (3.40a) and
˙y(t)=fσ(t)(t,yt,d(t)),y(t)=φ2(t),t∈[t0−d,t0], | (3.41) |
are two separate systems of system (3.40), and gσ(t)(t,xt,ˉd(t)) in (3.40b) is the coupling term. Note that the state of system (3.40) is col(x(t),y(t)). As usual, it is assumed that ˜fl(⋅,0,⋅)=0,fl(⋅,0,⋅)=0,l∈{1,…,m}.
Assumption 3.2. There exist two positive scalars L,ϑ such that
‖gl(⋅,x,⋅)‖≤L‖x‖,∀x∈Cϑ([−d,0],Rn1). | (3.42) |
The following result is a consequence of Theorem 3.1.
Theorem 3.2. Fix a uniform S. Suppose that Assumption 3.2 holds with ϑ∈R+ and that ˜fl,fl are continuous and are locally Lipschitz in the second argument, uniformly in the first and third ones. System (3.40) is LUAS if (3.40a) is LUES and (3.41) is LUAS.
Proof. Let us view (3.41) and (3.40b) as the nominal system (2.1) and the perturbed system (3.1) with perturbation u(t)=gσ(t)(t,xt,ˉd(t)) in Theorem 3.1, respectively.
Let ϑ,L be as in Assumption 3.2. System (3.40a) being LUES means that there exist δ1>0,α≥1\footnoteii and γ>0 such that ‖x(t;φ1)‖≤αexp(−γ(t−t0))‖φ1‖,∀t≥t0,‖φ1‖≤δ1. If we choose φ1 satisfying ‖φ1‖≤min{ϑαexp(γd),δ1α} then ‖x(t;φ1)‖≤δ1,∀t≥t0. As a result, ‖xt‖≤αexp(−γ(t−t0−d))‖φ1‖≤αexp(γd)‖φ1‖≤ϑ, ∀t≥t0. By Assumption 3.2,
iiBy definition of exponential stability, α>0. By the continuous dependence of solution on initial function, it is easy to that α≥1 holds (for example, take φ as a nonzero constant function).
‖gσ(t)(t,xt,ˉd(t))‖≤Lαexp(−γ(t−t0−d))‖φ1‖=ς‖φ1‖exp(−γ(t−t0)),∀t≥t0, | (3.43) |
where ς=Lαexp(γd).
Note that (3.41) is LUAS. It follows from (3.43) and Theorem 3.1 that there exists a constant δ2 and a β∈KL such that ‖y(t;φ2)‖≤β(max{‖φ2‖,ς‖φ1‖},t−t0) for ‖φ2‖<δ2,ς‖φ1‖<δ2,∀t≥t0, where y(t;φ2) is the solution to (3.40b).
Now take δ=min{δ2,δ2ς}. Fix φ=col(φ1,φ2) with ‖φ‖<δ. It follows that
‖col(x(t;φ),y(t;φ))‖≤‖x(t;φ)‖+‖y(t;φ)‖≤αexp(−γ(t−t0))‖φ1‖+β(max{‖φ2‖,ς‖φ1‖},t−t0)≤αexp(−γ(t−t0))‖φ‖+β(max{‖φ‖,ς‖φ‖},t−t0)≤αexp(−γ(t−t0))‖φ‖+β(max{1,ς}‖φ‖,t−t0), ∀t≥t0. | (3.44) |
Function αexp(−γ(t−t0))‖φ‖+β(max{1,ς}‖φ‖,t−t0) belongs to KL. The proof is completed.
It is worth pointing out that [14,Corollary 18] also holds for system (3.40) with uniform S. This conclusion follows from a proof line similar to Theorem 3.2. Combining this conclusion and Theorem 3.2 above, one has the next corollary:
Corollary 3.1. Fix a uniform S. Suppose that Assumption 3.2 holds and that ˜fl,fl are continuous and are locally Lipschitz in the second argument, uniformly in the first and third ones. System (3.40) is LUAS if one of the following statements holds:
1. (3.40a) is LUES and (3.41) is LUAS.
2. (3.40a) is LUAS and (3.41) is LUES.
Remark 3.1. One special case of switched systems is non-switched systems, that is, there exists only one subsystem. All the main results in the present paper are valid for non-switched systems.
Remark 3.2. The main results presented in Corollary 3.1, can be easily employed for designing controller. Consider the following control system
˙x(t)=˜fσ(t)(t,xt,˜d(t))+˜v(t), | (3.45a) |
˙y(t)=fσ(t)(t,yt,d(t))+gσ(t)(t,xt,ˉd(t))+v(t), | (3.45b) |
with ˜v(t),v(t) being control inputs and gσ(t) satisfying Assumption 3.2. To design a controller making (3.45) asymptotically stable, it suffices to design ˜v(t),v(t) such that (3.45a) is uniformly asymptotically (exponentially) stable and ˙y(t)=fσ(t)(t,yt,d(t))+v(t) is uniformly exponentially (asymptotically) stable, without paying any attention to the term gσ(t)(t,xt,ˉd(t)).
Remark 3.3. It is assumed in Theorem 3.2 that system (3.41) is uniformly asymptotically stable. In this case, Theorem 3.2 can only provide a local stability condition, leaving the global one open. If system (3.41) is uniformly exponentially stable, then both local and global stability conditions can be established, for details see [14,Corollary 18].
This section provides an example to demonstrate Theorem 3.2.
Example 4.1. Consider the following system which is a reduced version of (3.40):
˙x(t)=˜fσ(t)(x(t),x(t−d)), | (4.1a) |
˙y(t)=fσ(t)(y(t),y(t−d))+g(x(t),x(t−d)), | (4.1b) |
where σ:[t0,∞)→{1,2}, x(t)=col(x1(t),x2(t))∈R2,y(t)=col(y1(t),y2(t))∈R2, and
˜f1(x,y)=[−5−0.1sinx1−1+0.2sinx21+0.1cosy1−4−0.3cosy2]x+[−0.06+0.1siny10.04−0.2siny20.02−0.2cosx1−0.02−0.1cosx2]y,˜f2(x,y)=[−3+0.4cosx12+0.2cosx2−1−0.1siny1−3.8+0.2siny2]x+[0.02+0.1cosy10.04−0.2siny2−0.06−0.2cosx10.02−0.1cosx2]y,˜f1(x,y)=[−2−11−3]x+[−0.60.40.8−0.5]y,˜f2(x,y)=[−32−2−4]x+[0.70.3−0.40.5]y,˜g(x,y)=col(y2sinx2,y1cosx1)˜x=col(x1,x2),y=col(y1,y2)∈R2. |
By [31,Theorem 1], system (4.1a) is exponentially stable with d=2 under arbitrary switching signals. Moreover, it follows from [32] that system ˙y(t)=fσ(t)(y(t),y(t−d)) is asymptotically stable with d=2 under arbitrary switching signals.
By Theorem 3.2, system (4.1) is asymptotically stable under arbitrary switching signals; this fact is shown in Figures 2 and the involved switching signal is plotted in Figures 3.
This paper has addressed the asymptotic stability issue of continuous-time switched cascade nonlinear systems with delays. Technically, the main results rely on the robust convergence property of delayed switched nonlinear systems with perturbations. It was shown that trajectory of the perturbed system asymptotically approaches origin if the perturbation can be upper bounded by an exponentially decaying function and if the nominal system is asymptotically stable. This property was then employed to analyse the asymptotic stability of switched cascade nonlinear systems with delays, and some stability conditions have been proposed. Two points should be pointed out: (ⅰ) The considered delays are bounded. (ⅱ) Perturbations in this paper are additive. Therefore, more challenging work in the future is to investigate dynamics of systems involving unbounded delays and multiplicative perturbations.
This work was partially supported by National Nature Science Foundation (62073270), State Ethnic Affairs Commission Innovation Research Team, Innovative Research Team of the Education Department of Sichuan Province (15TD0050), and Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (2021HQZZ02).
The authors declare there is no conflict of interests.
[1] |
Abbasi K, Lv K, Nadeem MA, et al. (2020) Agricultural and Manufacturing Sector Determinants of Consumption, Price, and Real GDP from Pakistan. North Am Acad Res 3: 21-46. https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.3604943 doi: 10.5281/zenodo.3604943
![]() |
[2] |
Aboagye S (2017) The policy implications of the relationship between energy consumption, energy intensity and economic growth in Ghana. OPEC Energy Rev 41: 344-363. https://doi.org/10.1111/opec.12114 doi: 10.1111/opec.12114
![]() |
[3] | Abokyi E, Appiah-Konadu P, Sikayena I, et al. (2018) Consumption of Electricity and Industrial Growth in the Case of Ghana. J Energy 2018: 1-11. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1155/2018/8924835 |
[4] |
Abosedra S, Shahbaz M, Sbia R (2015) The Links between Energy Consumption, Financial Development, and Economic Growth in Lebanon: Evidence from Cointegration with Unknown Structural Breaks. J Energy 2015: 1-15. https://doi.org/10.1155/2015/965825 doi: 10.1155/2015/965825
![]() |
[5] | Adom PK (2011) Electricity consumption-economic growth nexus: the Ghanaian case. Int J Energy Econ Policy 1: 18-31. |
[6] |
Adom PK, Bekoe W (2013) Modelling electricity demand in Ghana revisited: The role of policy regime changes. Energy Policy 61: 42-50. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.05.113 doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2013.05.113
![]() |
[7] |
Adom, PK (2013) Time-varying analysis of aggregate electricity demand in Ghana: A rolling analysis. OPEC Energy Rev 37: 63-80. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1753-0237.2012.00227.x doi: 10.1111/j.1753-0237.2012.00227.x
![]() |
[8] |
Adu, G, Marbuah G, Mensah JT (2013) Financial development and economic growth in Ghana: Does the measure of financial development matter? Rev Dev Financ 3: 192-203. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rdf.2013.11.001 doi: 10.1016/j.rdf.2013.11.001
![]() |
[9] |
Adusah-Poku F, Adjei-Mantey K, Kwakwa PA (2021) Are energy-poor households also poor? Evidence from Ghana. Poverty Public Policy 13: 32-58. https://doi.org/10.1002/pop4.301 doi: 10.1002/pop4.301
![]() |
[10] |
Alam MM, Murad MW, Noman AHM, et al. (2016) Relationships among carbon emissions, economic growth, energy consumption and population growth: Testing Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis for Brazil, China, India and Indonesia. Ecol Indic 70: 466-479. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolind.2016.06.043 doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2016.06.043
![]() |
[11] |
Al-Bajjali SK, Shamayleh AY (2018) Estimating the determinants of electricity consumption in Jordan. Energy 147: 1311-1320. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2018.01.010 doi: 10.1016/j.energy.2018.01.010
![]() |
[12] |
Ali SSS, Razman MR, Awang A, et al. (2021) Critical determinants of household electricity consumption in a rapidly growing city. Sustainability 13: 4441. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13084441 doi: 10.3390/su13084441
![]() |
[13] |
Amoah A, Larbi DA, Offei D, et al. (2017) In gov we trust: the less we pay for improved electricity supply in Ghana. Energy Sustain Soc 7: 1-9. https://doi.org/10.1186/s13705-017-0133-0 doi: 10.1186/s13705-017-0133-0
![]() |
[14] |
Amoako S, Insaidoo M (2021) Symmetric impact of FDI on energy consumption: Evidence from Ghana. Energy 223. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2021.120005 doi: 10.1016/j.energy.2021.120005
![]() |
[15] |
Ansu-Mensah P, Bein MA (2019) Towards sustainable consumption: Predicting the impact of social-psychological factors on energy conservation intentions in Northern Cyprus. Nat Resour Forum 43: 181-193. https://doi.org/10.1111/1477-8947.12174 doi: 10.1111/1477-8947.12174
![]() |
[16] |
Ansu-Mensah P, Marfo EO, Awuah LS, et al. (2021) Corporate social responsibility and stakeholder engagement in Ghana's mining sector: a case study of Newmont Ahafo mines. Int J Corp Soc Resp 6: 1-22. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40991-020-00054-2 doi: 10.1186/s40991-020-00054-2
![]() |
[17] | Asuamah YS (2016) Modelling financial development and electricity consumption nexus for Ghana. Munich Personal RePEc Archive. |
[18] |
Asumadu-Sarkodie S, Owusu AP (2017) The relationship between carbon dioxide emissions, electricity production and consumption in Ghana. Energ Source Part B 12: 547-558. https://doi.org/10.1080/15567249.2016.1227885 doi: 10.1080/15567249.2016.1227885
![]() |
[19] | Bhagat, RB (2011) Urbanisation and access to basic amenities in India. Urban India 31: 1-14. |
[20] | Boakye NAB, Twenefour FB, McArthur-Floyd M (2016) The impact of power outage "dumsor" on the hotel industry: Evidence from Ghana. J Energy Technol Policy 6: 39-47. |
[21] |
Bohlmann JA, Inglesi-Lotz R (2021) Examining the determinants of electricity demand by South African households per income level. Energy Policy 148. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2020.111901 doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2020.111901
![]() |
[22] |
Burgess, R, Greenstone, M, Ryan, N (2020) The consequences of treating electricity as a right. J Econ Perspect 34: 145-169. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.34.1.145 doi: 10.1257/jep.34.1.145
![]() |
[23] |
Churchill SA, Ivanovski K, Munyanyi ME (2021) Income inequality and renewable energy consumption: Time-varying non-parametric evidence. J Clean Prod 296: 1-26. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.126306 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.126306
![]() |
[24] |
Craig, MT, Jaramillo, P, Hodge, B (2018) Carbon dioxide emissions effects of grid-scale electricity storage in a decarbonizing power system. Environ Res Lett 13: 1-11. https://doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/aa9a78 doi: 10.1088/1748-9326/aa9a78
![]() |
[25] |
Diawuo FA, Pina A, Baptista PC, et al. (2018) Energy efficiency deployment: A pathway to sustainable electrification in Ghana. J Clean Prod 186: 544-557. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.03.088 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.03.088
![]() |
[26] |
Dramani JB, Tewari DD (2014) An economic analysis of residential electricity demand in Ghana. Mediterranean J Soc Sci 5: 209-222. https://doi.org/10.5901/mjss.2014.v5n16p209 doi: 10.5901/mjss.2014.v5n16p209
![]() |
[27] |
Gore CD, Brass JN, Baldwin E, et al. (2018) Political autonomy and resistance in electricity sector liberalization in Africa. World Dev 120: 193-209. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.03.003 doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.03.003
![]() |
[28] | Huang H, Du Z, He Y (2018) The effect of population expansion on energy consumption in Canton of China: A simulation from computable general equilibrium approach. Int J Eng Sci Manage Res 5: 19-26. |
[29] |
Jiang Q, Iqbal S, Rahman UZ (2021) Measuring the simultaneous effects of electricity consumption and production on carbon dioxide emissions (CO2e) in China: New evidence from an EKC-based assessment. Energy 229: 1-10. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2021.120616 doi: 10.1016/j.energy.2021.120616
![]() |
[30] |
Karmellos M, Kosmadakis V, Dimas P, et al. (2021) A decomposition and decoupling analysis of carbon dioxide emissions from electricity generation: Evidence from the EU-27 and the UK. Energy 231. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2021.120861 doi: 10.1016/j.energy.2021.120861
![]() |
[31] |
Kemausuor F, Ackom E. (2017) Toward universal electrification in Ghana. WIREs: Energy Environ 6: 1-14. https://doi.org/10.1002/wene.225 doi: 10.1002/wene.225
![]() |
[32] |
Kumar A (2015) Indian Urban Households' Access to Basic Amenities: Deprivations, Disparities and Determinants. Margin: J Appl Econ Res 9: 278-305. https://doi.org/10.1177/0973801015579754 doi: 10.1177/0973801015579754
![]() |
[33] | Kwakwa PA (2012) Disaggregated energy consumption and economic growth in Ghana. Int J Energy Econ policy 2: 34-40. |
[34] |
Kwakwa PA (2017) Electricity consumption in Egypt: a long-run analysis of its determinants. OPEC Energy Rev 41: 3-22. https://doi.org/10.1111/opec.12091 doi: 10.1111/opec.12091
![]() |
[35] |
Kwakwa PA (2018) Analysis of the determinants of electricity consumption in Benin. J Energy Manage and Technol 2: 42. http://dx.doi.org/10.22109/jemt.2018.125839.1075. doi: 10.22109/jemt.2018.125839.1075
![]() |
[36] |
Kwakwa PA (2021) The carbon dioxide emissions effect of income growth, electricity consumption and electricity power crisis. Int J Mange Environ Qual 32: 470-487. https://doi.org/10.1108/MEQ-11-2020-0264 doi: 10.1108/MEQ-11-2020-0264
![]() |
[37] |
Kwakwa PA, Adu G, Osei-Fosu AK (2018) A time series analysis of fossil fuel consumption in Sub-Saharan Africa: evidence from Ghana, Kenya and South Africa. Int J Sustain Energy Plan Manage 17: 31-44. https://doi.org/10.5278/ijsepm.2018.17.4 doi: 10.5278/ijsepm.2018.17.4
![]() |
[38] |
Kwakwa PA, Adusah-Poku F, Adjei-Mantey K (2021) Towards the attainment of sustainable development goal 7: what determines clean energy accessibility in sub-Saharan Africa? Green Financ 3: 268-286. https://doi.org/10.3934/GF.2021014 doi: 10.3934/GF.2021014
![]() |
[39] |
Kwakwa PA, Alhassan H (2018) The effect of energy and urbanisation on carbon dioxide emissions: evidence from Ghana. OPEC Energy Rev 42: 301-330. https://doi.org/10.1111/opec.12133 doi: 10.1111/opec.12133
![]() |
[40] |
Kwakwa PA, Solomon K (2014) Energy Consumption in Ghana and the Story of Economic Growth, Industrialization, Trade Openness and Urbanization. Asian Bull Energy Econ Technol 1: 1-6. https://doi.org/10.1177/016224399502000203 doi: 10.1177/016224399502000203
![]() |
[41] |
Liddle B, Sadorsky P (2017) How much does increasing non-fossil fuels in electricity generation reduce carbon dioxide emissions? Appl Energy 197: 212-221. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2017.04.025 doi: 10.1016/j.apenergy.2017.04.025
![]() |
[42] |
Lin B, Agyeman DS (2019) Assessing Ghana's carbon dioxide emissions through energy consumption structure towards a sustainable development path. J Clean Prod 238. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.117941 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.117941
![]() |
[43] |
Liu J, Murshed M, Chen F, et al. (2021) An empirical analysis of the household consumption-induced carbon emissions in China. Sustain Prod Consum 26: 943-957. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spc.2021.01.006 doi: 10.1016/j.spc.2021.01.006
![]() |
[44] | Lütkepohl H (2005) New Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis. Berlin: Springer Verlag. |
[45] | Maddala GS, Kim IM (1998) Unit Roots, Co-integration, and Structural Change. New York: Cambridge University Press. |
[46] |
Mahalik MK, Mallick H (2014) Energy Consumption, Economic Growth and Financial Development: Exploring the Empirical Linkages for India. J Dev Areas 48: 139-159. https://doi.org/10.1353/jda.2014.0063 doi: 10.1353/jda.2014.0063
![]() |
[47] |
Matar A (2020) Does electricity consumption impacting financial development? Wavelet analysis. Future Bus J 6: 1-9. https://doi.org/10.1186/s43093-020-00017-w doi: 10.1186/s43093-020-00017-w
![]() |
[48] |
Meles TH (2020) Impact of power outages on households in developing countries: Evidence from Ethiopia. Energy Econ 91. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2020.104882 doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2020.104882
![]() |
[49] |
Mensah JT, Adu G (2015) An empirical analysis of household energy choice in Ghana. Renew Sust Energ Rev 51: 1402-1411. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2015.07.050 doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2015.07.050
![]() |
[50] | Muibi OS, Omoju OE (2016) Macroeconomic determinants of renewable electricity technology adoption in Nigeria. Econ and Environ Stud 16: 65-83. |
[51] |
Mukhtarov S, Humbatova S, Seyfullayev I, et al. (2020) The effect of financial development on energy consumption in the case of Kazakhstan. J Appl Econ 23: 75-88. https://doi.org/10.1080/15140326.2019.1709690 doi: 10.1080/15140326.2019.1709690
![]() |
[52] |
Nduhuura P, Garschagen M, Zerga A (2020) Mapping and Spatial Analysis of Electricity Load Shedding Experiences: A Case Study of Communities. Energies 13: 1-26. https://doi.org/10.3390/en13174280 doi: 10.3390/en13174280
![]() |
[53] |
Nduhuura P, Garschagen M, Zerga A (2021) Impacts of Electricity Outages in Urban Households in Developing Countries: A Case of Accra, Ghana. Energies 14: 1-26. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14123676 doi: 10.3390/en14123676
![]() |
[54] | Omisakin AO (2009) Economic growth and environmental quality in Nigeria: Does environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis hold? Environ Res J 3: 14-18. |
[55] |
Onisanwa ID, Adaji MO (2020) Electricity consumption and its determinants in Nigeria. J Econ Manage 41: 87-104. https://doi.org/10.22367/jem.2020.41.05 doi: 10.22367/jem.2020.41.05
![]() |
[56] |
Osobajo OA, Otitoju A, Otitoju MA, et L. (2020) The impact of energy consumption and economic growth on carbon dioxide emissions. Sustainability 12: 1-16. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12197965 doi: 10.3390/su12197965
![]() |
[57] |
Ozcan B, Ozturk I (2019) Renewable energy consumption-economic growth nexus in emerging countries: A bootstrap panel causality test. Renew Sust Energ Rev 104: 30-37. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2019.01.020 doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2019.01.020
![]() |
[58] |
Peñalvo-López E, Pérez-Navarro Á, Hurtado E, et al. (2019) Comprehensive methodology for sustainable power supply in emerging countries. Sustainability 11: 2-22. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11195398 doi: 10.3390/su11195398
![]() |
[59] | Pesaran MH, Shin Y, Smith RJ (2001) Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of level relationships. J Appl Econ 16: 289-326. |
[60] | Quartey J, Ametorwotia WD (2017) Assessing the total economic value of electricity in Ghana: A step toward energizing economic growth. |
[61] |
Rafindadi AA, Ozturk I (2016) Effects of financial development, economic growth and trade on electricity consumption: Evidence from post-Fukushima Japan. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 54: 1073-1084. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2015.10.023 doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2015.10.023
![]() |
[62] |
Rehman A, Rauf A, Ahmad M, et al. (2019) The effect of carbon dioxide emission and the consumption of electrical energy, fossil fuel energy, and renewable energy, on economic performance: evidence from Pakistan. Environ Sci Pollut Res 26: 21760-21773. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-019-05550-y doi: 10.1007/s11356-019-05550-y
![]() |
[63] |
Sbia R, Shahbaz M, Ozturk I (2017) Economic growth, financial development, urbanisation and electricity consumption nexus in UAE. Econ Res-Ekon Istraž 30: 527-549. https://doi.org/10.1080/1331677X.2017.1305792 doi: 10.1080/1331677X.2017.1305792
![]() |
[64] |
Sekantsi LP, Thamae RI, Mohatonyane LE (2016) Electricity Consumption in Lesotho: The Role of Financial Development, Industrialisation and Urbanisation. J Int Bus Econ 4: 19-28. https://doi.org/10.15640/jibe.v4n1a2 doi: 10.15640/jibe.v4n1a2
![]() |
[65] |
Shahbaz M, Hye QMA, Tiwari AK, et al. (2013) Economic growth, energy consumption, financial development, international trade and CO2 emissions in Indonesia. Renew Sustain Energ Rev 25: 109-121. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2013.04.009 doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2013.04.009
![]() |
[66] |
Shahbaz M, Lean H (2012) Does financial development increase energy consumption? The role of industrialization and urbanization in Tunisia. Energy Policy 40: 473-479. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2011.10.050 doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2011.10.050
![]() |
[67] | Sichone YM, Mulenga P, Phiri C, et al. (2016) Electricity Load Shedding: An Econometric Analysis of the Productivity of Firms in the Manufacturing Sector in Lusaka. Int J Commer Manage Res 2: 151-157. |
[68] |
Solarin SA, Shahbaz M, Khan H, et al. (2021) ICT, Financial Development, Economic Growth and Electricity Consumption: New Evidence from Malaysia. Glob Bus Rev 22: 941-962. https://doi.org/10.1177/0972150918816899 doi: 10.1177/0972150918816899
![]() |
[69] |
Toda HY, Yamamoto T (1995) Statistical Inference in Vector Autoregressions with Possibly Integrated Processes. J Econom 66: 225-250. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01616-8 doi: 10.1016/0304-4076(94)01616-8
![]() |
[70] | Williams A, Porter S (2006) Comparison of hydropower options for developing countries with regard to the environmental, social and economic aspects. Small 1. |
[71] | World Bank (2021) World Development Indicators 2021, Washington DC. Available from https://databank.worldbank.org/source/world-development-indicators#. |
[72] |
Xia XH, Hu Y (2012) Determinants of electricity consumption intensity in China: analysis of cities at subprovince and prefecture levels in 2009. Energy Econ Policy 2012. https://doi.org/10.1100/2012/496341 doi: 10.1100/2012/496341
![]() |
[73] |
Zalengera C, Blanchard RE, Eames PC, et al. (2014) Overview of the Malawi energy situation and A PESTLE analysis for sustainable development of renewable energy. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 38: 335-347. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2014.05.050 doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2014.05.050
![]() |
1. | Bangxin Jiang, Yijun Lou, Jianquan Lu, Input-to-state stability of delayed systems with bounded-delay impulses, 2022, 2, 2767-8946, 44, 10.3934/mmc.2022006 | |
2. | Zhifeng Lu, Fei Wang, Yujuan Tian, Yaping Li, Lag synchronization of complex-valued interval neural networks via distributed delayed impulsive control, 2022, 8, 2473-6988, 5502, 10.3934/math.2023277 | |
3. | Ramalingam Sakthivel, Palanisamy Selvaraj, Yeong-Jae Kim, Dong-Hoon Lee, Oh-Min Kwon, Rathinasamy Sakthivel, Robust H∞ resilient event-triggered control design for T-S fuzzy systems, 2022, 15, 1937-1632, 3297, 10.3934/dcdss.2022028 | |
4. | Zhaoxia Duan, Jinling Liang, Zhengrong Xiang, Filter design for continuous-discrete Takagi-Sugeno fuzzy system with finite frequency specifications, 2023, 3, 2767-8946, 387, 10.3934/mmc.2023031 |