Processing math: 100%
Research article Special Issues

Financing of the global shift to renewable energy and energy efficiency

  • Received: 01 July 2019 Accepted: 05 August 2019 Published: 14 August 2019
  • JEL Codes: Q56; E60; O11

  • A global shift to low-carbon economies needs five times larger annual investments in renewable energy and energy efficiency compared to the present USD2005 200 billion. The question about how to finance those large investments is discussed with particular attention to the citizens' savings because they are hardly used so far, except a few countries. If good conditions are created, activation of these savings is sufficiently large and it is rewarding regarding the cost-reducing technological change and many civil initiatives. High international prices of fossil fuels create favorable conditions but they are unpredictable whilst the present policy support for energy business and CO2 taxes do not compensate for the low prices. High CO2 taxes could do but meet opposition. Innovations in the USA and EU add value to the energy businesses by USD2005 9.2 billion a year based on average during 2005–2015, which exceeds their R & D on renewable energy and energy efficiency. Innovations in energy business also generate spin-off that exceeds 1% of the global GDP though the spin-off strongly varies across countries. The value addition motivates the supply-oriented and demand-oriented policy support for those energy innovations, in particular subsidies and price guarantees, respectively. Experiences with the subsidies in the USA compared to the price guarantees in the EU show that the latter involved larger expenditures but generated many more new firms and jobs per USD2005. A price guarantee per CO2 would invoke distributed energy systems entailing higher more energy-efficiency and energy security. Innovations generate adaptations when applied on larger scale. Their cost-reduction is function of scale; the projectable cost-reduction reduces the financial risks. Estimates show that the global investments in wind and solar power are efficiently allocated and operations are cost-effective. In addition to the power generation, those renewable energy with storage technologies deliver co-benefits to the energy producers and consumers and business models emerge tuned to the local conditions. The citizens' participations in energy-efficiency and renewable energy would be enhanced if policies guarantee the annual value of the participants' savings. Such guarantee would generate tax returns due to more companies and higher value of assets. The citizens participation with policy support enables the global shift to sustainable energy.

    Citation: Yoram Krozer. Financing of the global shift to renewable energy and energy efficiency[J]. Green Finance, 2019, 1(3): 264-278. doi: 10.3934/GF.2019.3.264

    Related Papers:

    [1] Xianyi Li, Xingming Shao . Flip bifurcation and Neimark-Sacker bifurcation in a discrete predator-prey model with Michaelis-Menten functional response. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(1): 37-57. doi: 10.3934/era.2023003
    [2] Mengxin He, Zhong Li . Dynamic behaviors of a Leslie-Gower predator-prey model with Smith growth and constant-yield harvesting. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(11): 6424-6442. doi: 10.3934/era.2024299
    [3] Jiange Dong, Xianyi Li . Bifurcation of a discrete predator-prey model with increasing functional response and constant-yield prey harvesting. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(10): 3930-3948. doi: 10.3934/era.2022200
    [4] Yichao Shao, Hengguo Yu, Chenglei Jin, Jingzhe Fang, Min Zhao . Dynamics analysis of a predator-prey model with Allee effect and harvesting effort. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(10): 5682-5716. doi: 10.3934/era.2024263
    [5] Yuan Tian, Hua Guo, Wenyu Shen, Xinrui Yan, Jie Zheng, Kaibiao Sun . Dynamic analysis and validation of a prey-predator model based on fish harvesting and discontinuous prey refuge effect in uncertain environments. Electronic Research Archive, 2025, 33(2): 973-994. doi: 10.3934/era.2025044
    [6] Kerioui Nadjah, Abdelouahab Mohammed Salah . Stability and Hopf bifurcation of the coexistence equilibrium for a differential-algebraic biological economic system with predator harvesting. Electronic Research Archive, 2021, 29(1): 1641-1660. doi: 10.3934/era.2020084
    [7] San-Xing Wu, Xin-You Meng . Hopf bifurcation analysis of a multiple delays stage-structure predator-prey model with refuge and cooperation. Electronic Research Archive, 2025, 33(2): 995-1036. doi: 10.3934/era.2025045
    [8] Érika Diz-Pita . Global dynamics of a predator-prey system with immigration in both species. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(2): 762-778. doi: 10.3934/era.2024036
    [9] Yuan Tian, Yang Liu, Kaibiao Sun . Complex dynamics of a predator-prey fishery model: The impact of the Allee effect and bilateral intervention. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(11): 6379-6404. doi: 10.3934/era.2024297
    [10] Jiani Jin, Haokun Qi, Bing Liu . Hopf bifurcation induced by fear: A Leslie-Gower reaction-diffusion predator-prey model. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(12): 6503-6534. doi: 10.3934/era.2024304
  • A global shift to low-carbon economies needs five times larger annual investments in renewable energy and energy efficiency compared to the present USD2005 200 billion. The question about how to finance those large investments is discussed with particular attention to the citizens' savings because they are hardly used so far, except a few countries. If good conditions are created, activation of these savings is sufficiently large and it is rewarding regarding the cost-reducing technological change and many civil initiatives. High international prices of fossil fuels create favorable conditions but they are unpredictable whilst the present policy support for energy business and CO2 taxes do not compensate for the low prices. High CO2 taxes could do but meet opposition. Innovations in the USA and EU add value to the energy businesses by USD2005 9.2 billion a year based on average during 2005–2015, which exceeds their R & D on renewable energy and energy efficiency. Innovations in energy business also generate spin-off that exceeds 1% of the global GDP though the spin-off strongly varies across countries. The value addition motivates the supply-oriented and demand-oriented policy support for those energy innovations, in particular subsidies and price guarantees, respectively. Experiences with the subsidies in the USA compared to the price guarantees in the EU show that the latter involved larger expenditures but generated many more new firms and jobs per USD2005. A price guarantee per CO2 would invoke distributed energy systems entailing higher more energy-efficiency and energy security. Innovations generate adaptations when applied on larger scale. Their cost-reduction is function of scale; the projectable cost-reduction reduces the financial risks. Estimates show that the global investments in wind and solar power are efficiently allocated and operations are cost-effective. In addition to the power generation, those renewable energy with storage technologies deliver co-benefits to the energy producers and consumers and business models emerge tuned to the local conditions. The citizens' participations in energy-efficiency and renewable energy would be enhanced if policies guarantee the annual value of the participants' savings. Such guarantee would generate tax returns due to more companies and higher value of assets. The citizens participation with policy support enables the global shift to sustainable energy.


    The interaction between two or more species has been an important and interesting issue in biology and ecology since the famous Lotka-Volterra model [1,2] was proposed. The interaction between different species will generate rich interesting dynamics of biological species, and exhibit the complexity and diversity [3,4]. Amensalism, as a typical type of interaction between the species, has been intensively considered in the last decades. Amensalism describes a basic biological interaction in nature, where one species inflicts harm on another not affected by the former, which means that it does not receive any costs or benefits to itself. The first pioneer work for the investigations of amensalism model is due to Sun [5], who, in 2003, proposed the following two-species amensalism model:

    {dxdt=r1x(k1xαyk1),dydt=r2y(k2yk2), (1.1)

    where x=x(t) and y=y(t) represent the population densities of two species at time t, respectively; r1 and k1 describe the intrinsic growth rate and the carrying capacity of the first species, respectively; r2 and k2 describe the intrinsic growth rate and the carrying capacity of the second species, respectively; α describes the effect of the second species on the first species. They explored the stability properties of all possible equilibria in system (1.1).

    Setting a11=r1k1, a12=r1αk1 and a22=r2k2, we can see that model (1.1) can be rewritten as

    {dxdt=x(r1a11xa12y),dydt=y(r2a22y), (1.2)

    where all parameters r1, r2, a11, a12, and a22 are positive real numbers.

    Ever since the first amensalism model was presented, the complicated dynamics of amensalism models have been studied extensively (see [6,7,8,9,10,11,12,13,14,15] and the references cited therein). For example, in [6], Guan and Chen considered a two-species amensalism model with Beddington-DeAngelis functional response and gave some comprehensive bifurcation and global dynamics of this system. Recently, Luo et al. [12] proposed an amensalism model with Holling-Ⅱ functional response and weak Allee effect for the first species, and discussed its local dynamics and global structure.

    In the real world, from the point of view of human needs, the management of renewable resources, the exploitation of biological resources, and the harvesting of populations are commonly practiced in forestry, fishery, and wildlife management [16,17,18]. Hence, it is necessary to introduce and to consider the harvesting of species in population models. During the last decade, population models with harvesting and the role of harvesting in the management of renewable resources have received significant attention from the researchers [19,20,21,22,23,24]. Generally speaking, there are three types of harvesting: 1) constant harvesting [25]; 2) linear harvesting [25]; 3) non-linear harvesting [26,27]. As is well known, non-linear harvesting is more realistic from biological and economical points of view [28]. In [26], Clark first proposed the non-linear harvesting term h(E,x)=qExcE+lx, which is called Michaelis-Menten type functional form of catch rate, here q is the catchability coefficient, E is the external effort devoted to harvesting, c and l are constants. After that, many scholars started to focus attention on the influence of the Michaelis-Menten type harvesting on the population systems [28,29,30,31,32,33,34]. For example, a reaction-diffusion predator-prey model with non-local delay and Michaelis-Menten type prey-harvesting was investigated by Zhang et al. [32], they obtained that the discrete and non-local delays are responsible for a stability switch in this system, and a Hopf bifurcation occurs as the delays pass through a critical value. In [33], Hu and Cao discussed a predator-prey system with the nonlinear Michaelis-Menten type predator harvesting and gave a detailed analysis of the stability and bifurcation for this system.

    These studies have shown that harvesting activity has important influence to dynamics of population systems and the harvested models can exhibit richer dynamics compared to the model with no harvesting. However, seldom did scholars consider the dynamical behaviors of an amensalism model with a harvesting term. Accordingly, inspired by the previous works, based on the system (1.2), we now introduce the Michaelis-Menten type harvesting to the second species, then we propose the following amensalism model:

    {dxdt=x(r1a11xa12y),dydt=y(r2a22y)qEycE+ly, (1.3)

    where the parameters r1, r2, a11, a12, and a22 are positive constants, and this term qEycE+ly represents Michaelis-Menten harvesting.

    Setting ¯t=r1t, ¯x=a11r1x, ¯y=a12r1y, α=a12qElr21, δ=r2r1, β=a22a12, γ=a12cElr1, and dropping the bars, then system (1.3) is transformed into

    {dxdt=x(1xy),dydt=y(δβy)αyγ+y. (1.4)

    The layout of this paper is arranged as follows. In the next section, the global dynamics including positivity and boundedness of solutions, number of equilibria, local asymptotical stability, codimension one bifurcations, dynamical behaviors near infinity, closed orbits analysis and global phase portraits are shown for system (1.4). Further, in Section 3, we also obtain the global dynamics of system (1.1) without harvesting term. Numerical simulations and discussions are displayed by Section 4 for demonstrating the theoretical results and the impact of harvesting term. Finally, a brief conclusion is presented in Section 5.

    In this section, we mainly investigate the global dynamics of system (1.4), which include the positivity and boundedness of solutions, the existence and local stability analysis of equilibria, all possible bifurcation behaviors and the global structure of system (1.4).

    Here, we give the positivity and boundedness of the solutions of model (1.4) in the region R2+={(x,y):x0,y0}.

    Lemma 2.1. All solutions of model (1.4) with positive initial value are positive for all t0.

    Proof. Solving model (1.4) with positive initial condition (x(0),y(0)) gives the result:

    x(t)=x(0)[expt0(1x(s)y(s))ds]>0,y(t)=y(0)[expt0(δβy(s)αγ+y(s))ds]>0.

    Therefore, we can easily see that each solution of model (1.4) starting from the positive initial condition (x(0),y(0)) still remains in the first quadrant.

    Lemma 2.2. All solutions of system (1.4) with positive initial value are bounded in region Ω={(x(t),y(t)):0x(t)<1 and 0y(t)<δβ} for the large enough time t.

    Proof. If the initial value is selected in R2+, each solution of model (1.4) remains positive from the above result. One can see

    ˙x<x(1x)

    from the first equation of model (1.4). And a standard comparison theorem shows that

    limtsupx(t)<1.

    Also, the following inequality

    ˙y<βy(δβy)

    is obtained from the second equation of system (1.4). It yields

    limtsupy(t)<δβ.

    Hence, there exists a sufficiently large time T, such that 0x(t)<1 and 0y(t)<δβ for t>T. In summary, all the solutions of system (1.4) are always bounded. Thus we complete the proof.

    Theorem 2.1. System (1.4) always has two boundary equilibria E0(0,0) and E1(1,0) for all positive parameters. For the existence of other equilibria, we have

    1) For the possible positive equilibria:

    i) if α>α, then system (1.4) has no positive equilibria;

    ii) if α=α and 0<δβγ<2β, then there is a unique positive equilibrium E33(1y3,y3);

    iii) if α<α<α, when α<δ+δγββγ and δβγ>0, or α=δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, there is one positive equilibrium E31(1y1,y1); when α>δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, there are two distinct positive equilibria E31(1y1,y1) and E32(1y2,y2);

    iv) if α=α and 0<δβγ<β, then E31 coincides with E1 and there is one positive equilibrium E32(1y2,y2), where y2=δβγβ;

    v) if 0<α<α and α>δ+δγββγ, then there is one positive equilibrium E32(1y2,y2).

    2) For the other possible boundary equilibria:

    i) if α>α, then system (1.4) has no other boundary equilibria; there is one boundary equilibrium E22(0,y2).

    ii) if α=α and δβγ>0, then there is a boundary equilibrium E23(0,y3);

    iii) if α<α<α and δβγ>0, then there are two distinct boundary equilibria E21(0,y1) and E22(0,y2);

    iv) if α=α and δβγ>0, then E21 coincides with E0 and there is one boundary equilibrium E22(0,y2), where y2=δβγβ;

    v) if 0<α<α, then

    Where α=(δ+βγ)24β, α=δγ, y1=δβγ(δ+βγ)24αβ2β, y2=δβγ+(δ+βγ)24αβ2β, and y3=δβγ2β.

    Proof. It is easy to see that system (1.4) always possesses two boundary equilibria given by E0(0,0) and E1(1,0) for all positive parameters.

    1) If x0 and y0, system (1.4) has a positive equilibrium which satisfies

    {x=1y,βy2(δβγ)y+αδγ=0. (2.1)

    For the positive equilibria, y must satisfy 0<y<1. Let Δ denote the discriminant of the second equation of (2.1), namely,

    Δ=(δ+βγ)24αβ, (2.2)

    and let

    α=(δ+βγ)24β. (2.3)

    Obviously, when 0<α<α, the second equation of (2.1) has two roots

    y1=δβγΔ2β  and  y2=δβγ+Δ2β.

    When α=α, the second equation of (2.1) has one root

    y3=δβγ2β.

    Let

    k(y)=βy2(δβγ)y+αδγ,

    and denote by

    α=δγ. (2.4)

    Then we have

    H1) if α>α, then k(0)>0;

    H2) if α=α, then k(0)=0;

    H3) if α<α, then k(0)<0.

    In addition, 0<αα, and α=α if and only if δ=βγ.

    Based on the above analysis, combining with H1), H2) and H3), we can derive that:

    ⅰ) If α>α, then Δ<0 which implies k(y)=0 has no real roots. So system (1.4) has no positive equilibria.

    ⅱ) If α=α, then Δ=0, so k(y)=0 has a unique real roots y3=δβγ2β, combing with the condition 0<y3<1, we get 0<δβγ<2β. In this situation, there exists a unique positive equilibrium E33(1y3,y3).

    ⅲ) If α<α<α, then Δ>0 and k(0)>0, implying k(y)=0 two positive real roots y1 and y2 if δβγ>0. Moreover, when k(1)<0, namely, α<δ+δγββγ, we have 0<y1<1<y2, that is, there is one positive point E31(1y1,y1); when k(1)=0 and the symmetry axis of k(y) is y=δβγ2β<1, namely, α=δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, we have 0<y1<y2=1, which means there is one positive point E31(1y1,y1); when k(1)>0 and the symmetry axis of k(y) is y=δβγ2β<1, namely, α>δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, we have 0<y1<y2<1, that is there are two different positive equilibria E31(1y1,y1) and E32(1y2,y2).

    ⅳ) If α=α, then Δ>0 and k(0)=0, hence k(y)=0 has two real roots y1=0 and 0<y2=δβγβ<1 if 0<δβγ<β, thus E31 coincides with E1 and there is one positive equilibrium E32(1y2,y2).

    ⅴ) If α<α, then Δ>0 and k(0)<0, so there are y1<0 and y2>0. When k(1)>0, i.e., α>δ+δγββγ, we get one positive root 0<y2<1, thus there exits one positive equilibrium E32(1y2,y2).

    The proof of the corresponding boundary equilibria in 2) is similar to that of 1), and hence omitted here. This completes the proof of Theorem 2.1.

    In the following, we focus on the local stability of each equilibrium of system (1.4).

    Theorem 2.2. For the boundary equilibria E0 and E1, the following statements are true.

    1) If 0<α<α, then E0 is a hyperbolic unstable node and E1 is a hyperbolic saddle.

    2) If α>α, then E0 is a hyperbolic saddle and E1 is a hyperbolic stable node.

    3) If α=α, then

    i) when δβγ, E0 and E1 are both saddle-nodes;

    ii) when δ=βγ, E0 is a non-hyperbolic saddle and E1 is a non-hyperbolic stable node.

    Proof. The Jacobian matrix of system (1.4) evaluated at any equilibrium is

    J(x,y)=(2x+1yx0H(x,y)), (2.5)

    where H(x,y)=δ2βyαγ(γ+y)2.

    For the equilibrium E0, the Jacobian matrix is

    J(E0)=(100δαγ), (2.6)

    and the two eigenvalues of J(E0) are λ1(E0)=1>0 and λ2(E0)=δαγ. Obviously, if 0<α<α, then λ2(E0)>0, so E0 is a hyperbolic unstable node. If α>α, then λ2(E0)<0, thus E0 is a hyperbolic saddle. If α=α, then λ2(E0)=0, this means that the equilibrium E0 is non-hyperbolic, so it is hard to directly judge its type from their eigenvalues. We further discuss its stability properties by applying Theorem 7.1 in Chapter 2 in [35].

    In order to change system (1.4) into a standard form, we expand system (1.4) in power series up to the fourth order around the origin

    {dxdt=xx2xyx+P(x,y),dydt=(αγ2β)y2αγ3y3+αγ4y4+Q0(y)Q(x,y), (2.7)

    where Q0(y) represents a power series with the terms yi (i5). From dxdt=0, we obtain that there is a unique implicit function x=φ0(y)=0 such that φ0(y)+P(φ0(y),y)=0 and φ0(0)=φ0(0)=0. Then substituting x=φ0(y)=0 into the second equation of (2.7), we get that

    dydt=(αγ2β)y2αγ3y3+αγ4y4+O(|y|5). (2.8)

    Because α=α=δγ, the coefficient at y2 is δγβ. By Theorem 7.1 in [35], we have when δβγ, the equilibrium E0 is a saddle-node.

    When δ=βγ, (2.8) becomes

    dydt=βγy3+βγ2y4+O(|y|5). (2.9)

    Employing the notations of Theorem 7.1 in Chapter 2 in [35], we have m=3 and am=βγ<0, so the equilibrium E0 is a non-hyperbolic saddle.

    For the equilibrium E1, the Jacobian matrix is

    J(E1)=(110δαγ). (2.10)

    The two eigenvalues of the above matrix J(E1) are λ1(E1)=1<0 and λ2(E1)=δαγ. Clearly, if α<α, then λ2(E1)>0, so E1 is a hyperbolic saddle. If α>α, then λ2(E1)<0, then E1 is a hyperbolic stable node. If α=α, then λ2(E1)=0, the equilibrium E1 is non-hyperbolic and its stability cannot be given directly from the eigenvalues. In order to determinate the stability of E1, we translate E1 to the origin by the translation (¯x,¯y)=(x1,y) and expand system (1.4) in power series up to the fourth order around the origin, which makes system (1.4) to be the following form:

    {d¯xdt=¯x¯y¯x¯y¯x2,d¯ydt=(αγ2β)¯y2αγ3¯y3+αγ4¯y4+Q1(¯y), (2.11)

    where Q1(¯y) represents a power series with terms ¯yi (i5).

    To transform the Jacobian matrix into a standard form, we use the invertible translation

    (uv)=(1101)(¯x¯y), (2.12)

    then system (2.11) becomes

    {dudt=uu2+uv+(αγ2β)v2αγ3v3+αγ4v4+Q1(v),dvdt=(αγ2β)v2αγ3v3+αγ4v4+Q1(v). (2.13)

    By introducing a new time variable τ=t, we get

    {dudτ=u+u2uv(αγ2β)v2+αγ3v3αγ4v4Q1(v)u+P(u,v),dvdτ=(βαγ2)v2+αγ3v3αγ4v4Q1(v)Q(u,v). (2.14)

    Based on the implicit function theorem, from dudτ=0, we can deduce a unique function

    u=φ1(v)=(αγ2β)v2+(αγ2αγ3β)v3+(αγ2αγ3+αγ4β(αγ2β)2)v4+,

    which satisfies φ1(0)=φ1(0)=0 and φ1(v)+P(φ1(v),v)=0. Then substituting it into the second equation of (2.14), we have

    dvdτ=(βαγ2)v2+αγ3v3αγ4v4+O(|v|5). (2.15)

    From α=δγ it follows that the coefficient at v2 is βδγ. Thus, by using Theorem 7.1 in Chapter 2 in [35], we get that when δβγ, the equilibrium E1 is a saddle node.

    When δ=βγ, (2.15) can be written as

    dvdτ=βγv3βγ2v4+O(|v|5).

    By Theorem 7.1 in [35] again, we obtain m=3 and am=βγ>0. Then E0 is a non-hyperbolic unstable node. Hence, E1 is a non-hyperbolic stable node due to that we have used the transformation τ=t. Accordingly, Theorem 2.2 is proved.

    Theorem 2.3. For the boundary equilibria E21, E22 and E23, the following statements are true.

    1) Assume α=α and δβγ>0, then there exists the boundary equilibrium E23(0,y3). Moreover,

    i) If δβγ>2β, then E23 is a saddle-node, which includes a stable parabolic sector.

    ii) If 0<δβγ<2β, then E23 is a saddle-node, which includes an unstable parabolic sector.

    iii) If δβγ=2β, then E23 is non-hyperbolic.

    2) Assume α<α<α and δβγ>0, then there are two boundary equilibria E21(0,y1) and E22(0,y2). Moreover,

    i) If α<δ+δγββγ, then E21 is a hyperbolic unstable node and E22 is a hyperbolic stable node.

    ii) If α>δ+δγββγ and δβγ>2β, then E21 is a hyperbolic saddle and E22 is a hyperbolic stable node.

    iii) If α>δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, then E21 is a hyperbolic unstable node and E22 is a hyperbolic saddle.

    iv) If α=δ+δγββγ and δβγ>2β, then E21 a saddle-node, which includes an unstable parabolic sector and E22 is a hyperbolic stable node.

    v) If α=δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, then E21 a hyperbolic unstable node and E22 is a saddle-node, which includes a stable parabolic sector.

    3) Assume α=α and δβγ>0, then there is one boundary equilibrium E22(0,y2), where y2=δβγβ. Moreover,

    i) If 0<δβγ<β, then E22 is a hyperbolic saddle.

    ii) If δβγ=β, then E22 is a saddle-node, which includes a stable parabolic sector.

    iii) If δβγ>β, then E22 is a hyperbolic stable node.

    4) Assume 0<α<α, then there is one boundary equilibrium E22(0,y2).

    i) If α<δ+δγββγ, then E22 is a hyperbolic stable node.

    ii) If α=δ+δγββγ, then E22 is a saddle-node, which includes a stable parabolic sector.

    iii) If α>δ+δγββγ, then E22 is a hyperbolic saddle.

    Proof. For the equilibrium E2i(i = 1, 2, 3), the Jacobian matrix is

    J(E2i)=(1yi00H(xi,yi)), (2.16)

    where H(xi,yi)=δ2βyiαγ(γ+yi)2. The two eigenvalues of the above matrix J(E2i) are λ1(E2i)=1yi and λ2(E2i)=H(xi,yi).

    Because (xi,yi) satisfies δβyiαγ+yi=0, we can derive

    H(xi,yi)=δ2βyiαγ(γ+yi)2=2βyiγ+yi(yiδβγ2β).

    Then

    λ2(E21)=H(x1,y1)=2βy1(γ+y1)2(y1δβγ2β)=2βy1(γ+y1)2Δ2β>0,
    λ2(E22)=H(x2,y2)=2βy2(γ+y2)2(y2δβγ2β)=2βy2(γ+y2)2Δ2β<0

    and

    λ2(E23)=H(x3,y3)=2βy3(γ+y3)2(y3δβγ2β)=0.

    In addition, for λ1(E2i)=1yi, we discuss it in the following four cases.

    Case 1. α=α and δβγ>0.

    If δβγ>2β, then y3>1, which implies λ1(E23)=1y1<0, so E23 is non-hyperbolic. In order to determinate the stability of the equilibrium E23, we translate E23 to the origin by letting (¯x,¯y)=(x,yy3), and expand the system in power series up to the third order around the origin, under which system (1.4) can be transformed into

    {d¯xdt=(1y3)¯x¯x¯y¯x2,d¯ydt=c0¯y+c1¯y2+c2¯y3+Q2(¯y), (2.17)

    where c0=δ2βy3αγ(γ+y3)2=0, c1=αγ(γ+y3)3β, c2=αγ(γ+y3)4, and Q2(y) represents for a power series with terms ¯yi (i4).

    Then introducing a new time variable τ=(1y3)t, we get

    {d¯xdτ=¯x11y3¯x¯y11y3¯x2¯x+P(¯x,¯y),d¯ydτ=c11y3¯y2+c21y3¯y3+11y3Q2(¯y)Q2(¯x,¯y). (2.18)

    We see that the coefficient at ¯y2 is c11y3>0. Hence, from Theorem 7.1 in Chapter 2 of [35], we have E23 is a saddle-node, which includes a stable parabolic sector and this parabolic sector is on the upper half-plane.

    If δβγ<2β, then y3<1, which means λ1(E23)=1y1>0. Same analysis as the above we can get E23 is also a saddle-node, which includes an unstable parabolic sector and the parabolic sector is on the lower half-plane.

    If δβγ=2β, then y3=1, which means λ1(E23)=1y1=0, so E23 is a non-hyperbolic critical point with two zero eigenvalues.

    Case 2. α<α<α and δβγ>0.

    1) If α<δ+δγββγ, then y1<1<y2, that implies λ1(E21)=1y1>0 and λ1(E22)=1y2<0, so E21 is a hyperbolic unstable node and E22 is a hyperbolic stable node;

    2) If α>δ+δγββγ and δβγ>2β, then 1<y1<y2, implying λ1(E21)=1y1<0 and λ1(E22)=1y2<0, thus E21 is hyperbolic saddle and E22 is hyperbolic stable node;

    3) If α>δ+δγββγ and δβγ<2β, then y1<y2<1, that means λ1(E21)=1y1>0, λ1(E22)=1y2>0, hence E21 is a hyperbolic unstable node and E22 is a hyperbolic saddle;

    4) If α=δ+δγββγ and δβγ>2β, then 1=y1<y2, which means λ1(E21)=1y1=0 and λ1(E22)=1y2<0, so E21 is non-hyperbolic and E22 is a hyperbolic stable node.

    In order to determinate the stability of the equilibrium E21, we translate the equilibrium E21 to the origin by the translation (¯x,¯y)=(x,y1), and expand system (1.4) in power series up to the third order around the origin, which makes system (1.4) to be the following form:

    {d¯xdt=¯x¯y¯x2,d¯ydt=d0¯y+d1¯y2+d2¯y3+Q3(¯y), (2.19)

    where d0=δ2βαγ(γ+1)2, d1=αγ(γ+1)3β, d2=αγ(γ+1)4, and Q3(¯y) represents for a power series with terms ¯yi satisfying i4.

    Then introducing a new time variable τ=d0t, we get

    {d¯xdτ=1d0¯x¯y1d0¯x2Q(¯x,¯y),d¯ydτ=¯y+d1d0¯y2d2d0¯y3+1d0Q3(¯y)¯y+P(¯x,¯y). (2.20)

    From d¯ydτ=0, we can derive a unique implicit function ¯y=ϕ(¯x)=0, which satisfies ϕ(0)=ϕ(0)=0 and ϕ(¯x)+P(¯x,ϕ(¯x))=0. Substituting ¯y=ϕ(¯x)=0 into the first equation of (2.20), we have that

    d¯xdτ=1d0¯x2.

    The coefficient at ¯x2 is

    1d0=γ+1δβγ2β<0.

    By Theorem 7.1 in Chapter 2 of [35], we know E21 is a saddle-node, which includes an unstable parabolic sector and this parabolic sector is on the left half-plane.

    5) If α=δ+δγββγ and δβγ<2β, then y1<y2=1, implying λ1(E21)=1y1>0 and λ1(E22)=1y2=0, therefore E21 a hyperbolic unstable node and E22 is non-hyperbolic. Similarly to the proof of E21 in 4), we can get that E22 is a saddle-node, which includes a stable parabolic sector.

    Case 3. α=α and δβγ>0.

    If δβγ>β, then y2>1, that is λ1(E22)=1y2<0, so E22 is a hyperbolic stable node. If δβγ<β, then y2<1, that is λ1(E22)=1y2>0, thus E22 is a hyperbolic saddle. If δβγ=β, then y2=1, that is λ1(E22)=1y2=0, thus E22 is a non-hyperbolic. Similar to the proof of E21 in 4), we can obtain E22 is a saddle-node, which includes a stable parabolic sector.

    Case 4. α<α.

    If α>δ+δγββγ, then y2<1, which implies λ1(E22)=1y2>0, thus E22 is a hyperbolic saddle. If α<δ+δγββγ, then y2>1, which means λ1(E22)=1y2<0, thus E22 is a hyperbolic stable node. If α=δ+δγββγ, then y2=1, which implies λ1(E22)=1y2=0, thus E22 non-hyperbolic. Similar to the proof of 4) in Case 2, we can derive E22 is a saddle-node, which includes a stable parabolic sector.

    This completes the proof of Theorem 2.3.

    Theorem 2.4. For the positive equilibria E31, E32 and E33, the following statements are true.

    1) If α<α<α, when α<δ+δγββγ and δβγ>0, or α=δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, or α>δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, then E31 is a hyperbolic saddle.

    2) If 0<α<α and α>δ+δγββγ, or α=α and 0<δβγ<β, or α<α<α, α>δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, then E32 is a hyperbolic stable node.

    3) If α=α and 0<δβγ<2β, then E33 is a saddle-node.

    Proof. For the equilibrium E3i(i = 1, 2, 3), the Jacobian matrix is

    J(E3i)=(yi1yi10H(xi,yi)), (2.21)

    where H(xi,yi)=δ2βyiαγ(γ+yi)2. The two eigenvalues of the above matrix J(E3i) are λ1(E3i)=yi1<0 and λ2(E3i)=H(xi,yi). From the analysis of the proof of Theorem 2.3, it follows that λ2(E31)>0, λ2(E32)<0, and λ2(E33)=0.

    Hence, when α<α<α, α<δ+δγββγ and δβγ>0, or α<α<α, α=δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, or α<α<α, α>δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, we have λ1(E31)<0 and λ2(E31)>0, which means E31 is a hyperbolic saddle.

    When 0<α<α and α>δ+δγββγ, or α=α and 0<δβγ<β, or α<α<α, α>δ+δγββγ and 0<δβγ<2β, there exists the positive equilibrium E32 with two eigenvalues λ1(E32)<0 and λ2(E32)<0, hence E32 is a hyperbolic stable node.

    When α=α and 0<δβγ<2β, there exists the positive equilibrium E33 with two eigenvalues λ1(E33)<0 and λ2(E33)=0. Then we further to study the stability of E33 by transforming E33 to the origin by the translation (¯x,¯y)=(xx3,yy3) and expand system (1.4) in power series up to the third order around the origin, which makes system (1.4) to be the following form:

    {d¯xdt=x3¯xx3¯y¯x¯y¯x2,d¯ydt=c0+c1¯y+(αγ(γ+y3)3β)¯y2αγ(γ+y3)4¯y3+Q4(¯y), (2.22)

    where c0=δy3β(y3)2α+αγγ+y3=0, c1=δ2βy3αγ(γ+y3)2=0, and Q4(¯y) stands for a power series with terms ¯yi (i4).

    In order to transform the Jacobian matrix into a standard form, we use the invertible translation

    (uv)=(1101)(¯x¯y), (2.23)

    then system (2.22) can be expressed as

    {dudt=x3u+uvu2+(αγ(γ+y3)3β)v2αγ(γ+y3)4v3+Q4(v),dvdt=(αγ(γ+y3)3β)v2αγ(γ+y3)4v3+Q4(v). (2.24)

    Then introducing a new time variable τ=x3t, we get

    {dudτ=u1x3uv+1x3u21x3(αγ(γ+y3)3β)v2+αγx3(γ+y3)4v31x3Q4(v)    u+P(u,v),dvdτ=1x3(αγ(γ+y3)2β)v2+αγx3(γ+y3)4v31x3Q4(v)Q(u,v). (2.25)

    According to the implicit function theorem, from dudτ=0, we can derive a unique function

    u=φ4(v)=1x3(αγ(γ+y3)3β)v2+1(x3)2(αγ(γ+y3)3β)v2αγx3(γ+y3)4v3+,

    which satisfies φ4(0)=φ4(0)=0 and φ4(v)+P(φ4(v),v)=0. Substituting it into the second equation of (2.25), we have that

    dvdτ=1x3(αγ(γ+y3)2β)v2+αγx3(γ+y3)4v3+O(|v|4).

    The coefficient at the term v2 is

    1x3(βαγ(γ+y3)2)=1x3(β(δβy3)γγ+y3)=β(δβγ)x3(δ+βγ)>0.

    Therefore, on basis of Theorem 7.1 in [35], the equilibrium E33 of system (1.4) is a saddle-node.

    The proof of Theorem 2.4 is finished.

    For readers' convenience, the local dynamical properties of equilibria of system (1.4) are totally summarized in Table 1. It can be clearly seen that the number and stability of equilibria are different according to the value range of the parameters. Therefore, we divide (α,β,γ,δ)R4+ into the following twelve regions.

    R11={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:α=α,δ=βγ, or α=α,δ=βγ or α>α};R12={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:α=α,δ<βγ};R2a={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:0<α<α,αδ+δγββγ};R2b={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:α=α,δβγβ};R22={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:α=α,δβγ2β};R3a={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:0<α<α,α>δ+δγββγ};R3b={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:α=α,0<δβγ<β};R32={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:α<α<α,αδ+δγββγ,δβγ>2β};R33={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:α=α,0<δβγ<2β};R41={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:α<α<α,α<δ+δγββγ,δ>βγ};R42={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:α<α<α,α=δ+δγββγ,0<δβγ<2β};R5={(α,β,γ,δ)R4+:α<α<α,α>δ+δγββγ,0<δβγ<2β}.
    Table 1.  Equilibria of system (1.4) in finite planes.
    Conditions Equilibra
    0<α<α α<δ+δγββγ E0(u),E1(sd),E22(s)
    α=δ+δγββγ E0(u),E1(sd),E22(sn)
    α>δ+δγββγ E0(u),E1(sd),E22(sd),E32(s)
    α=α 0<δβγ<β E0(sn),E1(sn),E22(sd),E32(s)
    δβγ=β E0(sn),E1(sn),E22(sn)
    δβγ>β E0(sn),E1(sn),E22(s)
    δ=βγ E0(sd),E1(s)
    δ<βγ E0(sn),E1(sn)
    α<α<α α<δ+δγββγ δβγ>0 E0(sd),E1(s),E21(u),E22(s),E31(sd)
    α=δ+δγββγ 0<δβγ<2β E0(sd),E1(s),E21(u),E22(sn),E31(sd)
    δβγ>2β E0(sd),E1(s),E21(sn),E22(s)
    α>δ+δγββγ 0<δβγ<2β E0(sd),E1(s),E21(u),E22(sd),E31(sd),E32(s)
    δβγ>2β E0(sd),E1(s),E21(sd),E22(s)
    α=α 0<δβγ<2β E0(sd),E1(s),E23(sn),E33(sn)
    δβγ=2β E0(sd),E1(s),E23(nh)
    δβγ>2β E0(sd),E1(s),E23(sn)
    δβγ=0 E0(sd),E1(s)
    α>α E0(sd),E1(s)
    Note: where "sd", "sn", "u", "s" and 'nh" represent saddle, saddle-node, unstable node, stable node and non-hyperbolic point, respectively.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    For R1=R11R12, system (1.4) possesses two equilibria E0 and E1. In R11, E0 is a saddle and E1 is a stable node. In R12, E0 and E1 represent saddle-nodes. And specifically, in R1, E1 is stable in the first quadrant. Therefore, the qualitative properties of these two equilibria can be seen in Figure 1(a).

    Figure 1.  The qualitative properties of the equilibria for R1, R2, R3, R4 and R5.

    For R2=R21R22, there are three equilibria for system (1.4). In R21=R2aR2b, system (1.4) admits E0 (unstable node or saddle-node), E1 (saddle or saddle-node) and E22 (stable node or saddle-node). In particular, in R21, E0 is unstable and E22 is stable in the first quadrant. In R22, there are E0 (saddle), E1 (stable node) and E23 (non-hyperbolic or saddle-node). The qualitative properties of these equilibria in R2 are displayed by Figure 1(b), (c).

    For R3=R31R32R33, there exist four equilibria for system (1.4). Considering R31=R3aR3b, there are E0 (unstable node or saddle-node which is unstable in the first quadrant), E1 (saddle or saddle-node), E22 (saddle) and E32 (stable node). Considering R32, system (1.4) admits E0 (saddle), E1 (stable node), E21 (saddle or saddle-node) and E22 (stable node). Considering R33, there exist E0, E1, E23 and E33, which are saddle, stable node, saddle-node and saddle-node. The detailed image descriptions of the qualitative properties of the equilibria in R3 are illustrated by Figure 1(d)(f).

    For R4=R41R42, system (1.4) has five equilibria E0 (saddle), E1 (stable node), E21 (unstable node), E22 (stable node or saddle-node) and E31 (saddle). Particularly, E22 is stable in the first quadrant. As shown in Figure 1(g), the qualitative properties of these five equilibria are given.

    For R5, system (1.4) possesses six equilibria E0, E1, E21, E22, E31 and E32, which represent saddle, stable node, unstable node, saddle, saddle and stable node, respectively. Hence, the qualitative properties of these six equilibria are displayed by Figure 1(h).

    In this section, all possible bifurcations of system (1.4) will be found out. Moreover, the feasible conditions for the occurence of those bifurcations will be given.

    Theorem 2.5. System (1.4) undergoes a saddle-node bifurcation at equilibrium E33 when the parameters satisfy the restriction α=αSN=(δ+βγ)24β along with the conditions 0<δβγ<2β and α>δ+δγββγ as given in Theorem 2.1.

    Proof. Now we will verify the transversality condition for the occurrence of a saddle-node bifurcation at α=αSN by utilizing the Sotomayor's theorem [36]. From Section 2.2, we have the two eigenvalues of J(E33) are λ1(E33)<0 and λ2(E33)=0. Denote V and W the eigenvectors corresponding to the eigenvalue λ2(E33) for the matrices J(E33) and J(E33)T, respectively. Simple computations yield

    V=(v1v2)=(11) and W=(w1w2)=(01).

    Furthermore, we can obtain

    Fα(E33;αSN)=(0yγ+y)(E33;αSN)=(0δβγδ+βγ) (2.26)

    and

    D2F(E33;αSN)(V,V)=(2F1x2v21+22F1xyv1v2+2F1y2v222F2x2v21+22F2xyv1v2+2F2y2v22)(E33;αSN)=(02β+2αSNγ(γ+y3)3). (2.27)

    Obviously, when 0<δβγ<2β, the vectors V and W satisfy the transversality conditions

    WTFα(E33;αSN)=δβγδ+βγ0

    and

    WT[D2F(E33;αSN)(V,V)]=2β+2αSNγ(γ+y3)3=2β(βγδ)δ+βγ0.

    Hence, by Sotomayor's theorem, when α=αSN, system (1.4) undergoes a saddle-node bifurcation at non-hyperbolic critical point E33. The number of positive equilibria of system (1.4) changes from zero to two as α passes from the right of α=αSN to the left. Thus, the proof of Theorem 2.5 is completed.

    Theorem 2.6. System (1.4) undergoes a transcritical bifurcation at the boundary equilibrium E1 when the parameters satisfy the conditions α=αTC=δγ and 0<δβγ<2β.

    Proof. Now we also apply Sotomayor's theorem [36] to prove the transversality condition for the occurrence of transcritical bifurcation at E1 as α=αTC. From Section 2.2, we know that λ1(E1)<0 and λ2(E1)=0. Let V and W represent the two eigenvectors corresponding to the zero eigenvalue λ2(E1) of the matrices J(E1) and J(E1)T, respectively, then they are given by

    V=(v1v2)=(11) and W=(w1w2)=(01).

    Furthermore, we can obtain

    Fα(E1;αTC)=(0yγ+y)(E1;αTC)=(00), (2.28)
    DFα(E1;αTC)V=(000γ(γ+y)2)(11)(E1;αTC)=(01γ), (2.29)

    and

    D2F(E1;αTC)(V,V)=(2F1x2v21+22F1xyv1v2+2F1y2v222F2x2v21+22F2xyv1v2+2F2y2v22)(E1;αTC)=(02β+2δγ).

    Clearly, the vectors V and W satisfy the transversality conditions

    WTFα(E1;αTC)=0,WT[DFα(E1;αTC)V]=1γ0

    and

    WT[D2F(E1;αTC)(V,V)]=2β+2δγ0  for 0<δβγ<2β.

    Therefore, by Sotomayor's theorem, if δβγ, system (1.4) experiences a transcritical bifurcation at non-hyperbolic critical point E1 as the parameter α varies through the bifurcation value α=αTC.

    Thus, the proof of Theorem 2.6 is completed.

    In this subsection, we pay some attention to the global structure of the plane nonlinear dynamic system (1.4).

    For the sake of the research of the global dynamics for system (1.4), we have to investigate the qualitative properties of equilibria at infinity, which is important and useful to study the behavior of orbits when |x|+|y| .

    Firstly, using Poincaré transformation of Chapter 5 in [35]:

    x=1z,y=uz,ds=dtz,

    system (1.4) can be transformed into

    {duds=(1β)u2+(δ1)uz+uαuz2u+γz,dzds=uz+zz2. (2.30)

    In the first quadrant of u-z plane, setting z=0, system (2.30) has one boundary equilibrium e(1β1,0) if β>1 and no boundary equilibrium if β1 on the nonnegative u-axis.

    Proceed to the next step, we apply the second type of Poincaré transformation:

    x=vz,y=1z,ds=dtz,

    system (1.4) becomes

    {dvds=v2+(1δ)vz+(β1)v+αvz21+γz,dzds=δz2+βz+αz31+γz. (2.31)

    In the nonnegative cone of v-z plane, there exist two boundary equilibria e1(0,0) and e2(β1,0) if β>1 and only one e1(0,0) if β1 for system (2.31).

    In this paper, of concern is the global dynamics of system (1.4) when β>1. The case β1 is similar, hence, it is omitted.

    Theorem 2.7. In system (2.30), e(1β1,0) is a saddle. In system (2.31), e1(0,0) is an unstable node and e2(β1,0) is a saddle.

    Proof. The Jacobian matrix at e(1β1,0) is evaluated as follows:

    J(e)=(1δ1β10ββ1),

    obviously, which has two eigenvalues λ1(e)=1<0 and λ2(e)=ββ1>0. Hence, e is a saddle in system (2.30).

    Similarly, the corresponding Jacobian matrices of system (2.31) evaluated at e1(0,0) and e2(β1,0) are

    J(e1)=(β100β)  and  J(e2)=(1β(δ1)(β1)0β).

    Clearly, e1 is an unstable node and e2 is a saddle in system (2.31). This proof of Theorem 2.7 is completed.

    From the point of view of Poincaré transformation, we get

    x1z=+, yuz=+, x1v1z1=0,y11z1=+, x2v2z2=+, y21z2=+.

    Consequently, e and e2 are equivalent to an infinite singular point I for system (1.4), e1 is equivalent to an infinite singular point I1 for system (1.4). By combining the Poincaré transformation of Chapter 5 in [35] and Theorem 2.7, we illustrate the dynamical behaviors near infinity of model (1.4) with Figure 2.

    Figure 2.  The dynamics of system (1.4) near infinity.

    We, here, for further research of the global structure of system (1.4), need to discuss the existence of closed orbits in phase space.

    Theorem 2.8. No closed orbit exists for model (1.4) in R2+.

    Proof. On the contrary, assume that model (1.4) exhibits a closed orbit in R2+. From the discussion in Theorem 2.1, we can deduce that all positive equilibria will lie on invariant lines y=δβγΔ2β or y=δβγ+Δ2β. On the basis of Theorem 4.6 of [35], in the interior of the closed orbit, system (1.4) must admit a positive equilibrium. As such, the closed orbit has two points of intersection with y=δβγΔ2β or y=δβγ+Δ2β, which is contrary to the existence and uniqueness of solutions. Therefore, there is no closed orbit for model (1.4). We end the proof of Theorem 2.8.

    System (1.4), according to the aforementioned Theorem 2.7, admits two equilibria I and I1 at infinity, which stand for a saddle and an unstable node, respectively. A step further, we derive that model (1.4) exists no closed orbit in R2+ from the above Theorem 2.8. It now follows that all possible cases of global phase portraits for model (1.4) can be given.

    For the purpose of simplicity, ξI and ω(ξI) are utilized to refer the unstable manifold of I and the ω-limit set of ξI in the nonnegative cone of R2, respectively.

    For (α,β,γ,δ) R1, it is easy to be checked that ω(ξI) is E1. See Figure 3(a) for the global phase portrait of model (1.4) related to the case R1.

    Figure 3.  The global phase portraits of system (1.4).

    For (α,β,γ,δ) R2, we can easily verify that ω(ξI) is E22 in R21 and ω(ξI) is E23 in R22. See Figure 3(b), (c) for the global phase portraits of model (1.4) related to the cases R21 and R22.

    For (α,β,γ,δ) R3, we analyze the global phase portraits of model (1.4) from the three subregions R31, R32 and R33, respectively. When (α,β,γ,δ) R31, we can verify that ω(ξI) is E32. The global phase portraits of model (1.4) related to R31 are given by Figure 3(d), (e). When (α,β,γ,δ) R32, ω(ξI) is E22. The global phase portrait of model (1.4) related to R32 is shown by Figure 3(f). When (α,β,γ,δ) R33, it is clear that ω(ξI) is E33 and the global phase portraits of model (1.4) in this region are shown in Figure 3(g), (h).

    For (α,β,γ,δ) R4, it is clear that ω(ξI) is E22. See Figure 3(i) for the global phase portrait of model (1.4) related to the case R4.

    For (α,β,γ,δ) R5, it is also clear that ω(ξI) is E32. And the global phase portraits of model (1.4) in R5 are shown in Figure 3(j), (k).

    Now, we mainly consider the dynamic properties of all possible equilibria and bifurcation behaviors of model (1.1). More, in R2+, we analyze the global structure of this model and illustrate our analysis with the global phase portraits.

    To facilitate this, system (1.1) takes the following form

    {dxdt=x(1xy),dydt=y(δβy). (3.1)

    On account of the dynamic properties of system (3.1) corresponding to system (1.1), we study the dynamics of system (3.1) in the following.

    As it has been shown in [5], the existence and stability properties of equilibria of system (3.1) are clearly summarized in Table 2. Next, we divide (δ,β)R2+ into two regions as follows.

    G1=G11G12={(δ,β)R2+:0<β<δ}{(δ,β)R2+:δ=β};G2={(δ,β)R2+:0<δ<β}.
    Table 2.  Local dynamical properties of equilibria.
    Equilibrium Existence conditions Type
    E0(0,0) (always exists) unstable node
    E1(1,0) (always exists) saddle
    E2(0,δβ) 0<δ<β saddle
    δ=β non-hyperbolic (stable in R2+)
    0<β<δ stable node
    E3(1δβ,δβ) 0<δ<β stable node

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Consider (δ,β)G1, system (3.1) has three equilibria E0, E1 and E2. Specifically, E0 and E1 represent an unstable node and a saddle. E2 is a stable node in G11 and non-hyperbolic in G12, which is stable in the first quadrant. See Figure 4(a), the qualitative properties of these three equilibria are illustrated.

    Figure 4.  The qualitative properties of the equilibria for G1 and G2.

    Consider (δ,β)G2, system (3.1) admits four equilibria E0, E1, E2 and E3, which are unstable node, saddle, saddle and stable node, respectively. See Figure 4(b), the qualitative properties of these four equilibria are illustrated.

    Here, we will analyze some of all the possible bifurcation scenarios for model (3.1). According to the previous methods applied in Section 2.3, a heuristic discussion similar to the one used by Theorem 2.6 can easily get the conditions for a transcritical bifurcation. Therefore, the following theorem can be directly obtained.

    Theorem 3.1 System (3.1) undergoes a transcritical bifurcation at E2 when the parameters satisfy the condition δ=β.

    In order to investigate the global structure of system (3.1), the methods proposed by Section 2.4 can be extended. By applying Poincaré transformation and analysis of closed orbit, Figure 5(a) describes the existence and stability of the singular points at infinity, as well as all the boundary equilibria. In addition, Figure 5(b)(d) describes minutely the global phase portraits in R2+ similarly.

    Figure 5.  (a) The dynamics of (3.1) near infinity; (b) The global phase portrait of (3.1) in G1; (c) The global phase portrait of (3.1) in G1; (d) The global phase portrait of (3.1) in G2.

    Some numerical examples, in this section, are proposed so as to check the obtained parameter conditions and theoretical results of systems (1.4) and (3.1). Further, we are interested to show the role of harvesting on the local dynamical properties.

    Example 4.1. We consider parameter values as below: α = 2, β = 1.2, γ = 0.8, δ = 2.5. Simple calculations lead to α=α, δβγβ and δ>β, which means both systems (1.4) and (3.1) have three boundary equilibria. The numerical phase portraits related to this case are shown in Figures 6(a) and 7(a). The impact of harvesting is shown by Figure 8.

    Figure 6.  The numerical phase portraits of system (1.4): (a) α = 2, β = 1.2, γ = 0.8, δ = 2.5; (b) α = 1.85, β = 0.3, γ = 2.5, δ = 0.8; (c) α = 0.8, β = 2.5, γ = 0.4, δ = 2.
    Figure 7.  The numerical phase portraits of system (3.1): (a) β = 1.2, δ = 2.5; (b) β = 0.3, δ = 0.8; (c) β = 2.5, δ = 2.
    Figure 8.  The impact of Michaelis-Menten type harvesting on the second species.

    Example 4.2. Some parameter values are taken α = 1.85, β = 0.3, γ = 2.5 and δ = 0.8. In this case, parameters satisfy the conditions 0<α<α and α>δ+δγββγ. Consequently, system (1.4) has a positive equilibrium (global asymptotically stable) and three boundary equilibria. From δ>β, we can effortlessly observe there exists no positive equilibrium for model (3.1). See Figures 6(b) and 7(b), the numerical phase portraits corresponding to this situation are presented. The impact of harvesting is illustrated with curves in Figure 9.

    Figure 9.  The impact of Michaelis-Menten type harvesting on the second species.

    Example 4.3. We select parameter values as follows: α = 0.8, β = 2.5, γ = 0.4, δ = 2. For these parameters, we derive α=α and 0<δβγ<2β. Therefore, system (1.4) possesses the same types of equilibria as the above Example 4.2. Whereas, there is a positive equilibrium (global asymptotically stable) in system (3.1) for δ<β. See Figures 6(c) and 7(c), the corresponding numerical phase portraits are presented. The impact of harvesting is illustrated with curves in Figure 10.

    Figure 10.  The impact of Michaelis-Menten type harvesting on the second species.

    It can be seen that the harvesting effect has a significant role on the population densities. From a biological point of view, the permanence and extinction of species are influenced to differential extent by the harvesting effect on the second species, for instance, greatly slowing the extinction of the first species (Figure 8) or guaranteeing the permanence of the system by preserving the first species from extinction (Figure 9). In addition, both species need much more time to reach their stable coexistence state due to the harvesting effect, which is shown in Figure 10.

    In this article, by combining local and global dynamical analysis, we have investigated the dynamics of the amensalism system with Michaelis-Menten type harvesting for the second species. In order to further explore the influence of harvesting effect, a complete qualitative analysis of the system with no harvesting is also performed. We could show some differences for the model (1.4) with harvesting on the second species and the system (3.1) with no harvesting.

    1) When harvesting is present in the system, it has shown that model (1.4) has more different types of equilibria. System (3.1) has at most four equilibria including one interior point in R2+ and the unique interior point (if it exists) of system (3.1) is globally stable. However, when the Michaelis-Menten type harvesting is on the second species, we shown that the model (1.4) has at most six equilibria including two interior points in R2+ and the interior point E31 is a saddle.

    2) The complex existence of equilibria leads to more bifurcation behaviors of model (1.4). Two kinds of bifurcation, under some parameter restrictions, saddle-node bifurcation and transcritical bifurcation will occur for system (1.4), while there exhibits only one saddle-node bifurcation for the system with no harvesting.

    3) More types of equilibria and more bifurcation behaviors can induce potentially dramatic changes to the dynamics of the system. By the classifications of global phase portraits of model (1.4), we find that more complex dynamics occur for the appearance of harvesting on the second species. Such as, for model (1.4) with harvesting, the first species survives permanently rather than extinction or both species take a lot longer to approach the coexistence state.

    These results reveal that the dynamical properties of system (1.4) get more complicated and richer compared to the system with no harvesting. Furthermore, it would also be interesting to study system (3.1) with both the first species and the second species with harvesting terms since we usually harvest, or would like to harvest, both populations.

    The first author was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No.12001503) and the third author was supported by the Project of Beijing Municipal Commission of Education (KM 202110015001).

    The authors declare there is no conflicts of interest.



    [1] Bertoldi P, Boza-Kiss B (2017) Analysis of barriers and drivers for the development of the ESCO markets in Europe. Energy Policy 107: 345–355. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2017.04.023
    [2] BNEF/Frankfurt School-UNEP Centre (2018) Global Trends in Renewable Energy Investment 2018. Available from: http://www.fs-unep-centre.org (Frankfurt am Main), accessed 5-6-2019.
    [3] Coady D, Parry I, Sears I, et al. (2015) How Large are Global Subsidies, International Monetary Fund, WP15/105, New York, USA.
    [4] Enerdata (2019) Available from: https://www.enerdata.net/publications/executive-briefing/world-energy-expenditures.html, accessed 8-82019.
    [5] Ermen van R (2007) Comparison and Assessment of Funding Schemes for Development of New Activities and Investments in Environmental Technologies, (Fundetec, rapport number 044370).
    [6] EU (2019) Available from: https://www.ise.fraunhofer.de/content/dam/ise/en/documents/publications/studies/EN2018_Fraunhofer-ISE_LCOE_Renewable_Energy_Technologies.pdf (accessed 1--2019).
    [7] Farmer JD, Lafond F (2016) How predictable is technological progress?. Res Policy 45: 647–665. doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2015.11.001
    [8] Grubler A (2012) Energy transitions research: Insights and cautionary tales. Energy Policy 50: 8–16. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2012.02.070
    [9] Grigoli F, Herman A, Schmidt-Hebbel K (2014) World Saving, IMF, WP/14/204, Washington.
    [10] Haas R, Panzer C, Resch G, et al. (2011) A historical review of promotion strategies for electricity from renewable energy sources in EU countries. Renew Sust Energy Rev 15: 1003–1034. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2010.11.015
    [11] Herman R, Ardekanin SA, Ausubel JH (1989) Dematerialization, in Ausubel JH, Sladovich HE (eds.), Technology and Environment, 1st Edition, National Academy Press, Washington DC, 50–69.
    [12] IEA (2017) Emission factors are: 3.80 ton CO2 per ton coal, 2.53 ton CO2 per ton oil and 2.16 ton CO2 per ton oil equivalent of gas based on IEA estimates. Available from: http://www.iea.org/bookshop/729-CO2_Emission_from_Fuel_Combustion, accessed 26-7-2017.
    [13] IEA (2019) databased, International Energy Agency. Available from: https://www.iea.org/classicstats/statisticssearch/.
    [14] IEA/OECD (2019) Available from: https://www.oecd.org/site/tadffss/data/; http://www.iea.org/weo2017.
    [15] India (2019) Available from: https://www.energy.gov/sites/prod/files/2015/08/f25/LCOE.pdf (accessed 1-7-.2019).
    [16] Interreg (2019) Renewable Energy Communities Policy brief Interreg Europe. Available from: https://www.interregeurope.eu/fileadmin/user_upload/plp_uploads/policy_briefs/2018-08-30_Policy_brief_Renewable_Energy_Communities_PB_TO4_final.pdf.
    [17] IRENA (2018) Global Energy Transformation: A roadmap to 2050. Int Renew Energy Agency: Abu Dhabi.
    [18] Jager de D, Klessmann C, Stricker E, et al. (2011) Financing Renewable Energy in the European Energy Market. Report for the European Commission, Directorate-General for Energy.
    [19] Keen M, Parry II, Davies M, et al. (2019) Fiscal policies for Paris Climate Change Strategies-From Principle to Practices, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
    [20] Krlev G, Münscher R, Mülbert K (2013) Social Return on Investment (SROI): State–of-the-art and Perspectives. Centre for Social Investment, University of Heidelberg, Available from: http://www.ub.uni-heidelberg.de/archiv/18758.
    [21] Krozer Y (2008) Innovations and the Environment, Springer, London, Chapter 3.
    [22] Krozer Y (2012) Renewable energy in European regions. Int J Innovation Reg Dev 4: 44–59. doi: 10.1504/IJIRD.2012.045140
    [23] Krozer Y (2015a) Sustainable Investors and Innovators, in Krozer Y., Theories and Practices on Innovating for Sustainable Development, Chapter 10, Springer, Dordrecht-Heidelberg.
    [24] Krozer Y (2015b) Renewable energy business and policy, in Krozer Y., Theories and Practices on Innovating for Sustainable Development, Chapter 12, Springer, Dordrecht-Heidelberg.
    [25] Krozer Y (2019) Valorisation of energy services: essay on the value addition due to renewable energy. Energy Sustainability Society 9: 1–16 doi: 10.1186/s13705-019-0191-6
    [26] Lagarde C, Gaspar V (2019) Getting Real on Meeting Paris Climate Change Commitments, IMF blog May 3, 2019. Available from: https://blogs.imf.org/2019/05/03/getting-real-on-meeting-paris-climate-change-commitments/?utm_medium=email&utm_source=govdelivery.
    [27] Lazard's (2017) Available from: https://www.lazard.com/perspective/levelized-cost-of-energy-2017/ and Lazard's Levelized Cost of Energy Analysis-version 12, Available from: https://www.lazard.com/media/450784/lazards-levelized-cost-of-energy-version-120-vfinal.pdf.
    [28] Mazzucato M, Semaniuk G (2018) Financing renewable energy: Who is financing what and why it matters. Technol Forecasting Social Change 127: 8–22. doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2017.05.021
    [29] McVeigh J, Butraw D, Darmstadter J, et al. (1999) Winner, Loser or Innocent Victim? Has Renewable Energy Performed As Expected, Resources for the Future, Washington.
    [30] Morriss AP, Meiners RE (2016) Competition in Global Oil Markets: A Meta-Analysis and Review. Available from: http://secureenergy.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/02/SAFE_Competition-in-Global-Oil-Markets-A-Meta-Analysis-and-Review.pdf.
    [31] OECD (2019a) Available from: http://www.oecdbetterlifeindex.org/topics/income/.
    [32] OECD (2019b) Available from: https://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?DatasetCode=POP_FIVE_HIST.
    [33] Oji C, Soumonni O, Ojah K (2016) Financing renewable energy projects for sustainable economic development in Africa. Energy Procedia 93: 113–119. doi: 10.1016/j.egypro.2016.07.158
    [34] REN21 (2017) Renewables 2017 Global Status Report, Paris Ren Secretariate.
    [35] Rosenberg N (1973) Innovative responses to material shortages, Am Econ Rev 63: 111–118, reprint in R. Dorfman, N.S. Dorfman (1977) Economics of the Environment, W.W. Norton & Company Inc., New York, 390–399.
    [36] Rubin ES, Azevedo IML, Jaramillo P, et al. (2015) A Review of learning rates for electricity supply technologies. Energy Policy 86: 198–218. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2015.06.011
    [37] Schumpeter JA (1935, 1989) Business Cycles, Porcupine Press, Philadelphia, 59.
    [38] Schumpeter JA (1935) Business Cycles, Porcupine Press, 4th edition, 1989, Philadelphia.
    [39] Sovacool BK (2016) How long will it take, Conceptualizing the temporary dynamics of energy transition. Energy Res Social Sci 13: 202–215. doi: 10.1016/j.erss.2015.12.020
    [40] Shafiee S, Topal E (2010) A long term view on fossil fuel prices. Appl Energy 87: 988–1000. doi: 10.1016/j.apenergy.2009.09.012
    [41] Tyl B, Lizarralde I (2017) The Citizen Funding: an alternative to finance renewable energy projects. Procedia CIRP 64: 199–204. doi: 10.1016/j.procir.2017.03.030
    [42] Yildiz Ö (2014) Financing renewable energy infrastructures via financial citizen participation-The case of Germany. Renew Energy 68: 677–685. doi: 10.1016/j.renene.2014.02.038
    [43] Unit costs (2018) Available from: https://www.irena.org/-/media/Files/IRENA/Agency/Publication/2018/Jan/IRENA_2017_Power_Costs_2018.pdf.
    [44] US (2019) Available from: https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/pdf/electricity_generation.pdf.
    [45] WEC (2019) Available from: https://wec-indicators.enerdata.net/primary-energy-intensity.html.
    [46] World Bank, gross savings based on. Available from: https://data.worldbank.org/indicator.
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Qianqian Li, Ankur Jyoti Kashyap, Qun Zhu, Fengde Chen, Dynamical behaviours of discrete amensalism system with fear effects on first species, 2023, 21, 1551-0018, 832, 10.3934/mbe.2024035
    2. Yajie Sun, Ming Zhao, Yunfei Du, Bifurcations, chaos analysis and control in a discrete predator–prey model with mixed functional responses, 2024, 17, 1793-5245, 10.1142/S1793524523500286
    3. Qun Zhu, Fengde Chen, Zhong Li, Lijuan Chen, Global Dynamics of Two-Species Amensalism Model with Beddington–DeAngelis Functional Response and Fear Effect, 2024, 34, 0218-1274, 10.1142/S0218127424500755
    4. MING ZHAO, YAJIE SUN, YUNFEI DU, COMPLEX DYNAMICAL BEHAVIORS OF A DISCRETE MODIFIED LESLIE–GOWER PREDATOR–PREY MODEL WITH PREY HARVESTING, 2025, 33, 0218-3390, 101, 10.1142/S0218339024500451
    5. Manoj Kumar Singh, Arushi Sharma, 2025, 3283, 0094-243X, 040017, 10.1063/5.0265020
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2019 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(5658) PDF downloads(557) Cited by(15)

Figures and Tables

Tables(3)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog