Mini review Topical Sections

Electrospun ECM macromolecules as biomimetic scaffold for regenerative medicine: challenges for preserving conformation and bioactivity

  • Received: 14 February 2017 Accepted: 16 May 2017 Published: 26 May 2017
  • The extracellular matrix (ECM), the physiological scaffold for cells in vivo, provides structural support to cells and guaranties tissue integrity. At the same time, however, it represents an extremely complex and finely tuned signaling environment that contributes in regulating tissue homeostasis and repair. ECM can bind, release and activate signaling molecules and also modulate cell reaction to soluble factors. Cell-ECM interactions, as a result, are recognized to be critical for physiological wound healing, and consequently in guiding regeneration. Due to its complexity, mimicking ECM chemistry and architecture appears a straightforward strategy to exploit the benefits of a biologically recognizable and cell-instructive environment. As ECM consists primarily of sub-micrometric fibers, electrospinning, a simple and versatile technique, has attracted the majority efforts aimed at reprocessing of biologically occurring molecules. However, the ability to trigger specific cellular behavior is likely to depend on both the chemical and conformational properties of biological molecules. As a consequence, when ECM macromolecules are electrospun, investigating the effect of processing on their structure, and the extent to which their potential in directing cellular behavior is preserved, appears crucial. In this perspective, this review explores the electrospinning of ECM molecules specifically focusing on the effect of processing on polymer structure and on in vitro or in vivo experiments designed to confirm the maintenance of their instructive role.

    Citation: Chiara Emma Campiglio, Chiara Marcolin, Lorenza Draghi. Electrospun ECM macromolecules as biomimetic scaffold for regenerative medicine: challenges for preserving conformation and bioactivity[J]. AIMS Materials Science, 2017, 4(3): 638-669. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2017.3.638

    Related Papers:

    [1] Zhiyan Xing, Yanlong Yang, Zuopeng Hu . Nash equilibrium realization of population games based on social learning processes. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(9): 17116-17137. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023763
    [2] Rui Huang, Hao Xiao, Guoqin Pan . Authority decentralization and air pollution reduction: Evidence from China. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(12): 14212-14231. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022661
    [3] Stephen Tully, Monica-Gabriela Cojocaru, Chris T. Bauch . Multiplayer games and HIV transmission via casual encounters. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2017, 14(2): 359-376. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2017023
    [4] Sharon M. Cameron, Ariel Cintrón-Arias . Prisoner's Dilemma on real social networks: Revisited. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2013, 10(5&6): 1381-1398. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2013.10.1381
    [5] Yueqi Mao, Qiang Mei, Peng Jing, Xingyue Wang, Ying Xue, Ye Zha . Uncovering the behavioral determinants behind private car purchase intention during the new normal of COVID-19: An empirical investigation in China. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(4): 7316-7348. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023318
    [6] Dario Madeo, Chiara Mocenni, Jean Carlo Moraes, Jorge P. Zubelli . The role of self-loops and link removal in evolutionary games on networks. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(5): 5287-5306. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019264
    [7] Yuanyuan Huang, Yiping Hao, Min Wang, Wen Zhou, Zhijun Wu . Optimality and stability of symmetric evolutionary games with applications in genetic selection. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2015, 12(3): 503-523. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2015.12.503
    [8] Jianjun Long, Hui Huang . Stability of equilibrium production-price in a dynamic duopoly Cournot-Bertrand game with asymmetric information and cluster spillovers. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(12): 14056-14073. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022654
    [9] Jiajia Zhang, Yuanhua Qiao, Yan Zhang . Stability analysis and optimal control of COVID-19 with quarantine and media awareness. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(5): 4911-4932. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022230
    [10] Anthony Morciglio, R. K. P. Zia, James M. Hyman, Yi Jiang . Understanding the oscillations of an epidemic due to vaccine hesitancy. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2024, 21(8): 6829-6846. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2024299
  • The extracellular matrix (ECM), the physiological scaffold for cells in vivo, provides structural support to cells and guaranties tissue integrity. At the same time, however, it represents an extremely complex and finely tuned signaling environment that contributes in regulating tissue homeostasis and repair. ECM can bind, release and activate signaling molecules and also modulate cell reaction to soluble factors. Cell-ECM interactions, as a result, are recognized to be critical for physiological wound healing, and consequently in guiding regeneration. Due to its complexity, mimicking ECM chemistry and architecture appears a straightforward strategy to exploit the benefits of a biologically recognizable and cell-instructive environment. As ECM consists primarily of sub-micrometric fibers, electrospinning, a simple and versatile technique, has attracted the majority efforts aimed at reprocessing of biologically occurring molecules. However, the ability to trigger specific cellular behavior is likely to depend on both the chemical and conformational properties of biological molecules. As a consequence, when ECM macromolecules are electrospun, investigating the effect of processing on their structure, and the extent to which their potential in directing cellular behavior is preserved, appears crucial. In this perspective, this review explores the electrospinning of ECM molecules specifically focusing on the effect of processing on polymer structure and on in vitro or in vivo experiments designed to confirm the maintenance of their instructive role.


    Research on human helping behavior focuses on a series of core questions: Why and when do people help? Who does help? How can we reduce apathy and increase helping behavior? How do we improve the chance of successful help-seeking? [1]. These issues are critical to building a harmonious society of mutual assistance.

    Social exchange theory [2,3] proposes that human social behavior results from an exchange process to maximize benefits and minimize costs. This theory suggests that the reasons for helping behaviors include external rewards, internal rewards, and social norms. Among them, internal rewards include alleviating a sense of guilt, happiness from a good mood, and bringing a sense of achievement, etc. Two fundamental concepts related to internal rewards are self-awareness and politeness. These two factors are closely related to the sense of guilt, achievement, and happiness on both sides of the helping behavior. However, existing research rarely touches on the connection of self-awareness and politeness to human help-seeking and help-giving behaviors, especially from the perspective of psychological game theory.

    The conceptualization of self-awareness is complicated [4,5,6,7], and includes both intrapersonal and interpersonal perspectives [4,5,6,7]. Some researchers use the distinction between private and public aspects to describe its intra- and interpersonal aspects [8,9,10]. In these studies, the private aspect involves paying attention to one's inner thoughts and feelings, and the public aspect is the general perception of the self as a social object that influences others [11]. According to Carden et al., "Self-awareness consists of a range of components, which can be developed through focus, evaluation, and feedback, and provides an individual with an awareness of their internal state (emotions, cognitions, physiological responses), that drives their behaviors (beliefs, values, and motivations) and an awareness of how this impacts and influences others" [4]. The self-awareness related to help-seeking and help-giving behavior, applying the self-awareness definition given by Carden et al., includes a range of interpersonal components and intrapersonal components to develop connections between self and helpers or help seekers, it is developed through focus, evaluation, and feedback, and provides an individual with an intrapersonal aspect of self-awareness that drives their behaviors and the interpersonal aspect of self-awareness [4,6]. The interpersonal aspect of self-awareness leads people to pay attention to publicly displayed aspects of the self [12,13]. People pay attention to how others perceive them based on their behavior, etc. [14], and they are more likely to change their minds and behaviors when others are present [15,16,17]. Based on the above discussion, we identified self-awareness as one of the factors influencing helping behavior in this study. That is, helpers with a high level of self-awareness are strongly aware of other people's behavior and reflect on their own behavior when they are asked for help, so they change their behavior. Conversely, helpers with a low level of self-awareness generally are unaware of their own and others' behavior, so they don't change their behavior. In the same way, the above discussion also applies to help seekers [18]. Going a step further, when helpers with a high level of self-awareness are asked for help, they will concern about the help seekers' perceptions. Self-awareness promotes the belief that one has a relatively great personal responsibility for others and tends to increase helpfulness [19,20,21,22,23]. For help seekers, self-awareness is an essential reason for the embarrassment [24]. When help seekers with a high level of self-awareness cannot give back, they will feel belittled because they receive help. Therefore, people with a high level of self-awareness are often reluctant to seek help [25,26,27].

    Politeness refers to people applying good manners or etiquette [28]. An understanding of politeness requires an understanding of its psychosocial underpinnings. At the same time, understanding the corresponding psychosocial phenomena can also be improved by studying the role of politeness in these psychosocial processes [29,30]. Politeness theory proposes that politeness can both indicate and create social distance [29,31,32]. Politeness is relevant to several research areas in social psychology, including person perception and impression management [29]. When people hold prosocial and impression management motivation, they attach importance to two results: helping others and improving their own image [33]. The desire to maintain a good image can stimulate helping behavior [34]. If the level of politeness of helpers is high, they would care more about their image and feel sympathy for help seekers when asked for help, so they would tend to help [35]. For help seekers, if they care about making trouble for others too much, it's hard to seek help [36]. If help-seeking is low yield and high cost to helpers, help seekers would also have negative emotions such as debt and apology [37]. They are afraid they will not be able to repay and are ungrateful. This politeness, as human nature, will affect people's help-seeking behavior.

    Game theory refers to a theoretical framework for envisioning social situations between competing players, which implies optimal decisions for independent and competing players in an environment [38]. As a model of interactive situations between players, the game theory focuses on games where one player's payoff depends on another player's strategy [39]. Games identify players' identities, preferences, and available strategies and focus on the impact of those strategies on outcomes [40]. We establish a psychological game theory model to analyze people's help-seeking and help-giving behavior. According to the Bayesian Nash Equilibrium in this study, given the help seeker and helper characteristics, that is, the probability distribution of self-awareness and politeness, each person will choose the strategy that maximizes his/her expected utility.

    This study aims to link two related social psychology concepts, self-awareness and politeness, with human helping behavior and demonstrate using a game-theory-based Bayesian Nash equilibrium approach. This study is thus expected to make the following potential contributions: First, this study would illustrate the influence of self-awareness and politeness on help-seeking and help-giving when people are in trouble. Second, this study would be able to clarify the relationship between politeness, self-awareness, and the willingness of the help seekers as well as the helpers. Third, this study will compare the results obtained by the method of Bayesian Nash equilibrium based on a psychological game in this study with the results obtained by the method of psychological experiments in previous studies, to verify the conclusion of social psychology about the influence of self-awareness and politeness on helping behavior, through the mathematical method of psychological game theory.

    In this study, we firstly established a game theory model, which was proposed by Harsanyi [41] and adopted by many researchers, such as Myatt and Wallace; Huang and Zhu [42,43].

    The characters on the stage are player A as a help-seeker and player B as a helper. Player A can be people with the low ability signed as L or high ability signed as H. Player B can also be people with low ability or high ability. Low ability and high ability are basic settings in this study. Therefore, the utility function of each player is:

    U=U1+U2+U3

    U1 is the utility of the actual cost paid. U1 is related to the basic cost c and the ability cost of that player, thus, U1=ac; from player A's point of view, if player B does not help him, he/she has to work on it by himself; that is UA1=aAc; If Player B helps, he/she can do it without effort; that is UA1=0; from player B's point of view, if he/she helps player A, he/she has to make his/her own efforts, that is UB1=aBc; If he/she does not help, he/she does not have to make an effort; that is UB1=0. The player with high ability costs less; on the contrary, the player with low ability costs more.

    U2 is the utility of self-awareness, which is related to the degree of self-awareness; represented by α, and the speculation about how others think of himself, represented by E(a). Thus, U2=α[E(a)a]. EB(aASeek) means player B speculates on player A's ability when player A seeks help; EB(aANot seek) means player B speculates on player A's ability when player A does not seek help; EA(aBHelp) means player A speculates on player B's ability when player B helps; EA(aBNot help) means player A speculates on player B's ability when player B does not help. U3 is the effect of politeness, and the degree of politeness β (0 < β < 1) is related to the basic cost and his actual ability, thus, U3=βca.

    Player A's utility in seeking help is:

    UASeek=αA[EB(aASeek)aA]βAcaB

    Player A's utility when he/she does not seek help is:

    UANot seek=aAcαA[EB(aANot seek)aA]

    Player B's utility when he/she helps is:

    UBHelp=aBcαB[EA(aBHelp)aB]

    Player B's utility when he/she does not help is:

    UBNot help=αB[EA(aBNot help)aB]βBcaA

    When the difference between the ability predicted by others and his actual ability is positive, it is α1; and when it is negative, it becomes α2. The relationship between α1 and α2 is 0<α1<α2. The game tree is as follows:

    Figure 1.  Game tree.
    Note: Nature enters twice in this game. In the game tree, N means nature. All the situation happens naturally. A means player A. B means player B. LA means player A's ability is low. PA means the probability when player A's ability is low. HA means player A's ability is high. SOS means player A seeks help while the n means do not seek help. h means player B helps while n means player B does not help. The others are beliefs.

    The probability of LA with high ability is PA; The probability of HA with low ability is (1PA); LA 's probability of seeking help is q; its probability of not seeking help 1q; The probability of HA 's help-seeking is q; Its probability of not seeking help is 1q. Let the probability of LA be PA, the probability of HA be (1PA). Let the probability of LB be PB, the probability of HB be (1PB). The probability of LB giving help is r, its probability of not helping is 1r. The probability of HB giving help is r, its probability of not helping is 1r. Thus, the belief of players A and B at each point is:

    γ=(1PB)qPAqPA(1PB)+q(1PB)(1PA)=qPAqPA+q(1PA);1γ=q(1PA)qPA+q(1PA);ρ=PBqPAqPAPB+qPB(1PA)=qPAqPA+q(1PA);1ρ=q(1PA)qPA+q(1PA);ε=(1PB)qPArqPA(1PB)r+qPBPAr=(1PB)r(1PB)r+PBr;1ε=PBr(1PB)r+PBr;μ=(1PB)(1PA)qrq(1PB)(1PA)r+qPB(1PA)r=(1PB)r(1PB)r+PBr;1μ=PBr(1PB)r+PBr;θ=(1PB)PAq(1r)q(1PB)PA(1r)+qPBPA(1r)=(1PB)(1r)(1PB)(1r)+PB(1r);1θ=PB(1r)(1PB)(1r)+PB(1r);π=(1PB)(1PA)q(1r)q(1PB)(1PA)(1r)+qPB(1PA)(1r)=(1PB)(1r)(1PB)(1r)+PB(1r);1π=PB(1r)(1PB)(1r)+PB(1r);δ=(1q)PA(1PB)(1q)PA(1PB)+(1q)(1PB)(1PA)=(1q)PA(1q)PA+(1q)(1PA);1δ=(1q)(1PB)(1PA)(1q)PA(1PB)+(1q)(1PB)(1PA)=(1q)(1PA)(1q)PA+(1q)(1PA)

    Therefore, if player A seeks help, player B is in two situations: help or not help. Take the utility of player A when player B helps as UAseekO, and the utility of player A when player B does not help A as UAseekX. Thus,

    UASeekO=αA[EB(aASeek)aA]βAcaB
    UASeekX=aAcαA[EB(aASeek)aA]

    Player A's utility is:

    UASeek=PB[rUASeekO+(1r)UASeekX]+
    (1PB)[rUASeekO+(1r)UASeekX]
    UANot seek=aAcαA[EB(aANot seek)aA]

    In the case of HA with high ability:

    [EB(aASeek)HA]=(1PB)[LAγ+HA(1γ)]+PB[LAρ+HA(1ρ)]HA
    =[LAγ+HA(1γ)]HA>0
    [EB(aANot seek)HA]=(1PB)[LAδ+HA(1δ)]+PB[LAσ+HA(1σ)]HA
    =[LAδ+HA(1δ)]HA>0

    Therefore, αA of both parties is αA1. Player A's utility in seeking help is:

    UASeek=PB[rUASeekO+(1r)UASeekX]
    +(1PB)[rUASeekO+(1r)UASeekX]
    =[PBr+(1PB)r]{αA1[[LAγ+HA(1γ)]HA]βAcaB}+[PB(1r)+(1PB)(1r)]{cHAαA1[[LAγ+HA(1γ)]HA]}

    Player A's utility when he/she does not seek help is:

    UANot seek=aAcαA[EB(aANot seek)aA]
    =HAcαA1[[LAδ+HA(1δ)]HA]

    In the case of LA with low ability:

    [EB(aAseek)LA]=(1PB)[LAγ+HA(1γ)]+PB[LAρ+HA(1ρ)]LA
    =[LAγ+HA(1γ)]LA<0
    [EB(aANot seek)HA]=(1PB)[LAδ+HA(1δ)]+PB[LAσ+HA(1σ)]LA
    =[LAδ+HA(1δ)]LA<0

    Therefore, αA of both parties are αA2. When player A seeks help, the utility is:

    UASeek=PB[rUASeekO+(1r)UASeekX]
    +(1PB)[rUASeekO+(1r)UASeekX]
    =[PBr+(1PB)r]{αA2[[LAγ+HA(1γ)]LA]βAcaB}+[PB(1r)+(1PB)(1r)]{cLAαA2[[LAγ+HA(1γ)]LA]}

    Player A's utility when he/she does not seek help is:

    UANot Seek=LAcαA2[[LAδ+HA(1δ)]LA]

    In the case of HB with high ability:

    [EA(aBHelp)aB]=PA[LB(1ε)+HBε]+(1PA)[LB(1μ)+HBμ]HB
    =LB(1ε)+HBεHB>0
    [EA(aBNot help)HB]=PA[LB(1θ)+HBθ]+(1PA)[LB(1π)+HBπ]HB
    =LB(1θ)+HBθHB>0

    Therefore, αB of both parties are αB1. At this time, the utility of player B when he/she helps is:

    UBHelp=HBcαB1[EA(aBHelp)HB]
    =HBcαB1[LB(1ε)+εHBHB]

    The utility of player B when he/she does not help is:

    UBNot help=αB1[EA(aBNot help)HB]βBcaA
    =αB1[LB(1θ)+HBθHB]βBcaA

    In the case of LB :

    [EA(aBhelp)aB]=PA[LB(1ε)+HBε]+(1PA)[LB(1μ)+HBμ]LB
    =LB(1ε)+HBεLB<0
    [EA(aBnot help)aB]=PA[LB(1θ)+HBθ]+(1PA)[LB(1π)+HBπ]LB
    =LB(1θ)+HBθLB<0

    Therefore, αB of both parties are αB1. At this time, the utility of player B when he/she helps is:

    UBHelp=LBcαB2[EA(aBHelp)LB]
    =LBcαB2[LB(1ε)+εHBLB]

    The utility of player B when he/she does not help is:

    UBNot help=αB2[EA(aBNot help)LB]βBcaA
    =αB2[LB(1θ)+HBθLB]βBcaA

    Equilibrium analysis examines what happens when the system reaches equilibrium and the conditions required to achieve equilibrium [44]. Equilibrium analysis is critical in game theory because game equilibrium refers to the realization of the maximum utility of each party in the game, that is, to achieve the satisfaction of each party with the game result so that the actual utility and degree of satisfaction obtained by each party are different. In game equilibrium, such a relatively static state is in which all players do not want to change their strategies [45].

    Bayesian Nash Equilibrium refers to a set of strategies: given the probability distribution of a player's own characteristics and the characteristics of other players, each player chooses a strategy to maximize his expected payoff; that is, no one has the incentive to choose other strategies [46]. This study uses a Bayesian Nash equilibrium to analyze the game between the helper and the help seeker.

    Therefore, the player's decision-making goal is to maximize his/her expected utility given his/her own type and the relationship between the other player's types and strategic choices. Bayesian Nash Equilibrium is a type-dependent strategic combination [47].

    We now start to analyze the equilibrium. When players A and B decide on their strategy, they would select the strategy with larger utility, thus this study should compare the difference in the utility of players' different selections.

    Furthermore, player B with high ability can expect player A's ability as aA=γLA+(1γ)HA.The ability of player B with low ability can expect player A's ability as aA=ρLA+(1ρ)HA. We thus substitute them into the utility function. In addition, Player A with either the high ability or low ability would decide to seek help or not; player B with either the high ability or low ability would decide to help or not. When player A is helped by player B with high ability, r=1; when player B with high ability does not help, r=0; when player B with low ability helps, r=1; when player B with low ability does not help, r=0; when player A with low ability seeks for help, q=1; when player A with low ability does not seek for help, q=0; when player A with high ability seeks for help, q=1, when player A with high ability does not seek for help, q=0. In summary, there are situations including r=1,r=0,r=1,r=0,q=1,q=0,q=1,q=0. As a result, there are 16 combinations. According to calculating, there are nine equilibriums. The following section will discuss these equilibriums. For example, the first equilibrium is stated as follows: HB help; LB not help; LA seek; HA not seek.

    1) r=1,r=0,q=1,q=1

    In the case of HB:

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB1(LBHB)+c(βB[PALA+(1PA)HA]HB)

    In order to meet the condition UBHelpUBNot help>0, there must be:

    βB>αB1(LBHB)c[PALA+(1PA)HA]+HB[PALA+(1PA)HA]

    The relationship between βB and αB1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 2.  βB and αB1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 1).
    Note: The blue textured scheme represents the range of possible values for Player A's self-awareness and politeness. This color scheme also applies to other pictures with a blue color scheme.

    In the case of LB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)+c(βBaALB)

    In order to meet the condition UBhelpUBnot help<0, there must be:

    βB<αB2(LBHB)c[PALA+(1PA)HA]+LBPALA+(1PA)HA

    The relationship between βB and αB2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 3.  βB and αB2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 1).

    Next, let HB = HA,LB = LA,PB = PA,αB1=αA1 = α1,αB2=αA2 = α2,βA=βB. In this case, set the difference between α1 and α2 to ξ. Thus, α2α1=ξ. Because player B must meet the conditions of HB and LB, we thus find the union set of HB and LB. To put the two figures above together, we must distinguish occasions between cLBLBHBξ>cHBLBHB as case 1B and cLBLBHBξ<cHBLBHB as case 2B. At this point:

    Figure 4.  The union set of βB and αB in case 1B in equilibrium 1).

    In the case of HA:

    UASeekUANot seek=αA1(γδ)(LAHA)+(1PB)c(HAβAHB);

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UASeekUANot seek>0, there must be:

    βA<αA1(γδ)(LAHA)cHB(1PB)+HAHB.

    Because there are (γδ)>0 and (γδ)<0, The relationship between βA and αA1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 5.  βA and αA1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 1).
    Note: The pink textured scheme represents the range of possible values for Player B's self-awareness and politeness. This color scheme also applies to other pictures with a pink color scheme.

    In the case of LA:

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(γδ)(LAHA)+(1PB)c(LAβAaB)
    =αA2(γδ)(LAHA)+(1PB)c(LAβAHB])

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UASeekUANot seek>0, there must be:

    βA<αA2(γδ)(LAHA)cHB(1PB)+LAHB

    Because there are (γδ)>0 and (γδ)<0, the relationship between βA and αA2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 6.  βA and αA2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 1).

    Because player B must meet the conditions of HA and LA, we thus find the union set of HA and LA. Owing to ξ>0, cLA(1PB)LAHAξ must be less than cHA(1PB)LAHA. Therefore:

    Figure 7.  The union set of βA and αA in equilibrium 1).

    Players A and B must satisfy all of the conditions of the game equilibrium case 1B or case 2B. Thus, the result that satisfies the conditions of players A and B is 0 < ξ < C. The figure is as follows:

    Figure 8.  The union set of player A and player B in equilibrium 1).
    Note: The yellow textured color scheme represents the range of possible values of self-awareness and politeness shared by Players A and B. This color scheme also applies to other pictures with a yellow color scheme.

    2) r=1,r=0,q=1,q=0

    In the case of HB:

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB1(LBHB)+c(βBLAHB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBhelpUBnot help>0, there must be:

    βB>αB1(LBHB)cLA+HBLA

    The relationship between βB and αB1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 9.  βB and αB1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 2).

    In the case of LB:

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)+c(βBLALB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBhelpUBnot help<0, there must be:

    βB<αB2(LBHB)cLA+LBLA

    The relationship between βB and αB2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 10.  βB and αB2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 2).

    To put the two figures above together, we must distinguish occasions between cLBLBHBξ>cHBLBHB as case 1B and cLBLBHBξ<cHBLBHB as case 2B.

    At this point:

    Figure 11.  The union set of βB and αB in case 1B in equilibrium 2).

    In the case of HA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA1(LAHA)+(1PB)c(HAβAHB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UAseekUAnot seek<0, there must be:

    βA>αA1(LAHA)c(1PB)HB+1

    The relationship between βA and αA1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 12.  βA and αA1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 2).

    In the case of LA:

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(LAHA)+(1PB)c(LAβAHB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UAseekUAnot seek>0, there must be:

    βA<αA2(LAHA)cHB(1PB)+LAHB

    The relationship between βA and αA2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 13.  βA and αA2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 2).

    To put the two figures above together, we must distinguish occasions between cLA(1PB)LAHAξ>cHA(1PB)LAHA as case 1A and cLA(1PB)LAHAξ<cHA(1PB)LAHA as case 2A. At this point:

    Figure 14.  The union set of βA and αA in case 1A in equilibrium 2).

    Player A must satisfy all of the conditions of the game equilibrium case 1A. Player B must satisfy all of the conditions of the game equilibrium case 1B. To satisfy both case 1A and case 1B, there must be 0<ξ<c(1PB). The figure is as follows:

    Figure 15.  The union set of player A and player B in equilibrium 2).

    3) r=1,r=0,q=0,q=0

    In the case of HB:

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB1(LBHB)+c(βB[γLA+(1γ)HA]HB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBHelpUBNot help>0, there must be:

    βB>αB1(LBHB)c[γLA+(1γ)HA]+HBγLA+(1γ)HA

    The relationship between βB and αB1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 16.  βB and αB1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 3).

    In the case of LB:

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)+c(βB[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]LB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBHelpUBNot help<0, there must be:

    βB<αB2(LBHB)c[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]+LBρLA+(1ρ)HA

    The relationship between βB and αB2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 17.  βB and αB2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 3).

    To put the two figures above together, we must distinguish occasions between cLBLBHBξ>cHBLBHB as case 1B and cLBLBHBξ<cHBLBHB as case 2B. At this point:

    Figure 18.  The union set of βB and αB in case 1B in equilibrium 3).

    In the case of HA:

    UASeekUANot seek=αA1(γδ)(LAHA)+(1PB)c(HAβAHB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UASeekUANot seek<0, there must be:

    βA>αA1(γδ)(LAHA)cHB(1PB)+1

    When (γδ)>0 and (γδ)<0, the relationship between βA and αA1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 19.  βA and αA1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 3).

    In the case of LA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(γδ)(LAHA)+(1PB)c(LAβAHB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UASeekUANot seek<0, there must be:

    βA>αA2(γδ)(LAHA)cHB(1PB)+LAHB

    When (γδ)>0 and (γδ)<0, the relationship between βA and αA2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 20.  βA and αA2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 3).

    Owing to:

    α2α1=ξ, cLA(1PB)LAHAξ>cHB(1PB)(LAHA) as case 1A,cLA(1PB)LAHAξ<cHB(1PB)LAHA as case 2A are as follows:

    Figure 21.  The union set of βA and αA in case 1A and case 2A in equilibrium 3).

    Player A must satisfy all of the conditions of the game equilibrium case 1A and player B must satisfy all of the conditions of the game equilibrium case 1B and case 2B. Because case 2B is an empty set, the union set of case 2B and case 1A is also an empty set. To satisfy both case 1B and case 1A, there must be 0<ξ<c(1PB). To satisfy both case 1B and case 2A, there must be c(1PB)<ξ<c. Both of them are shown in the following figure:

    Figure 22.  The union set of player A and player B in equilibrium 3).

    4) r=0,r=0,q=1,q=1

    In the case of HB:

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB1(LBHB)[ε(1PB)]+c(βB[PALA+(1PA)HA]HB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UAHelpUANot help<0, there must be:

    βB<αB1(LBHB)[ε(1PB)]c[PALA+(1PA)LA]+HBPALA+(1PA)LA

    When (εθ)>0 and (εθ)<0, the relationship between βB and αB1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 23.  βB and αB1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 4).

    In the case of LB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)[ε(1PB)]+c{βB[PALA+(1PA)HA]LB}

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBHelpUBNot help<0, there must be:

    βB<αB2(LBHB)[ε(1PB)]c[PALA+(1PA)HA]+LB[PALA+(1PA)HA]

    When (εθ)>0 and (εθ)<0, the relationship between βB and αB2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 24.  βB and αB2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 4).

    Owing to ξ>0, cLBLBHBξ must be less than cHBLBHB. Therefore, the union set is:

    Figure 25.  The union set of βB and αB in equilibrium 4).

    In the case of HA:

    UASeekUANot seek=αA1(PAδ)(LAHA)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UASeekUANot seek>0, there must be: (PAδ)<0. When (γδ)<0, the relationship between βA and αA1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 26.  βA and αA1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 4).

    In the case of LA:

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(γδ)(LAHA)+(r+PBr'PBr)c(LAβAaB)
    =αA2(PAδ)(LAHA)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UASeekUANot seek>0, there must be: (PAδ)<0. When (γδ)<0, the relationship between βA and αA2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 27.  βA and αA2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 4).

    The condition of player B and player A is 0<ξ. As shown in the following figure:

    Figure 28.  The union set of player A and player B in equilibrium 4).

    5) r=0,r=0,q=0,q=0

    In the case of HB:

    UBSeekUBNot seek=αB1(LBHB)[ε(1PB)]+c(βB[γLA+(1γ)HA]HB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBSeekUBNot Seek<0, there must be: (βB<αB1(LBHB)[ε(1PB)]c[γLA+(1γ)HA]+HB[γLA+(1γ)HA], when (εθ)>0 and (εθ)<0, the relationship between βB and αB1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 29.  βB and αB1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 5).

    In the case of LB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)[ε(1PB)]+c{βB[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]LB}

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBHelpUBNot help<0, there must be:

    βB<αB2(LBHB)[ε(1PB)]c[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]+LB[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]

    When (εθ)>0 and (εθ)<0, the relationship between βB and αB2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 30.  βB and αB2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 5).

    Since ξ>0, cLBLBHBξ is always smaller than cHBLBHB. Thus, the union set is:

    Figure 31.  The union set of βB and αB in equilibrium 5).

    In the case of HA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA1(γPA)(LAHA)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UASeekUANot seek<0, there must be: (γPA)>0, when (γδ)>0, the relationship between βA and αA1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 32.  βA and αA1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 5).

    In the case of LA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(γPA)(LAHA)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UASeekUANot seek<0, there must be: (γPA)>0, when (γδ)>0, the relationship between βA and αA2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 33.  βA and αA2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 5).

    Player B's all conditions and player A's all conditions must be met. Thus, the result is 0<ξ. The figure is shown as follows:

    Figure 34.  The union set of player A and player B in equilibrium 5).

    6) r=1,r=1,q=0,q=0

    In the case of HB:

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB1(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]+c(βB[γLA+(1γ)HA]HB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBHelpUBNot help>0, there must be:

    βB<αB1(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]c[γLA+(1γ)HA]+HB[γLA+(1γ)HA]

    When (εθ)>0 and (εθ)<0, the relationship between βB and αB1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 35.  βB and αB1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 6).

    In the case of LB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]+c{βB[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]LB}

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBHelpUBNot help>0, there must be:

    βB<αB2(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]c[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]+LB[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]

    When (εθ)>0 and (εθ)<0, the relationship between βB and αB2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 36.  βB and αB2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 6).

    To combine the two figures above together, we must distinguish occasions between cLBLBHBξ>cHBLBHB as case 1B and cLBLBHBξ<cHBLBHB as case 2B. At this time,

    Figure 37.  The union set of βB and αB in case 1B and case 2B in equilibrium 6).

    In the case of HA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA1(γPA)(LAHA)+c{HAβA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]}

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UAseekUAnot seek<0, there must be:

    βA>αA1(γPA)(LAHA)c[PBLB+(1PB)HB]+HA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]

    When (γδ)>0 and (γδ)<0, the relationship between βA and αA1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 38.  βA and αA1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 6).

    In the case of LA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(γPA)(LAHA)+(r+PBr'PBr)c{LAβA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]}

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UAseekUAnot seek<0, there must be:

    βA>αA2(γPA)(LAHA)c[PBLB+(1PB)HB]+LA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]

    When (γδ)>0 and (γδ)<0, the relationship between βA and αA2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 39.  βA and αA2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 6).

    Owing to α2α1=ξ, there is cLALAHAξ>cHALAHA as case 1A,cLALAHAξ<cHALAHA as case 2A. At this time,

    Figure 40.  The union set of βA and αA in case 1A and case 2A in equilibrium 6).

    Player A must satisfy all of the conditions of the game equilibrium case 1A and 2A. Player B must satisfy all of the conditions of the game equilibrium case 1B and 2B. Thus, the result of the union set of case 1B and case 1A is 0 < ξ < c. It is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 41.  The union set of player A and player B when 0 < ξ < c in equilibrium 6).

    Since the results of the union set of case 1B and case 2A are ξ<c, ξ>c, ξ does not exist. Since the results of the union set of case 2B and case 1A are ξ>c,ξ<c, ξ does not exist. The result of the union set of case 2B and case 2A is ξ>c. The figure is shown as follows:

    Figure 42.  The union set of player A and player B when ξ>c in equilibrium 6).

    7) r=1,r=1,q=1,q=1

    In the case of HB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB1(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]+c(βB[γLA+(1γ)HA]HB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBhelpUBnot help>0, there must be:

    βB<αB1(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]c[γLA+(1γ)HA]+HB[γLA+(1γ)HA]

    When (εθ)>0 and (εθ)<0, the relationship between βB and αB1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 43.  βB and αB1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 7).

    In the case of LB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]+c{βB[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]LB}

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBhelpUBnot help>0, there must be:

    βB<αB2(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]c[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]+LB[ρLA+(1ρ)HA]

    When (εθ)>0 and (εθ)<0, the relationship between βB and αB2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 44.  βB and αB2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 7).

    To put the two figures above together, we must distinguish occasions between cLBLBHBξ>cHBLBHB as case 1B and cLBLBHBξ<cHBLBHB as case 2B. At this point:

    Figure 45.  The union set of βB and αB in case 1B and case 2B in equilibrium 7).

    In the case of HA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA1(PAδ)(LAHA)+c{HAβA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]}

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UAseekUAnot seek>0, there must be:

    βA>αA1(PAδ)(LAHA)c[PBLB+(1PB)HB]+HA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]

    When (γδ)>0 and (γδ)<0, the relationship between βA and αA1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 46.  βA and αA1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 7).

    In the case of LA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(PAδ)(LAHA)+c{LAβA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]}

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UAseekUAnot seek>0, there must be:

    βA<αA2(PAδ)(LAHA)c[PBLB+(1PB)HB]+LA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]

    When (γδ)>0 and (γδ)<0, the relationship between βA and αA2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 47.  βA and αA2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 7).

    Since ξ>0, cLALAHAξ is always smaller than cHALAHA. Thus, the union set is:

    Figure 48.  The union set of βA and αA in equilibrium 7).

    Player B must satisfy all of the conditions of the game equilibrium case 1B or case 2B, so does player A. Thus, the result that satisfies the conditions of players A and B is 0<ξ<c. The figure is:

    Figure 49.  The union set of player A and player B when 0 < ξ < c in equilibrium 7).

    To satisfy case 2B and player A's conditions, the result is 1>ξ>c. The figure is as follows:

    Figure 50.  The union set of player A and player B when ξ>c in equilibrium 7).

    8) r=1,r=1,q=1,q=0

    In the case of HB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB1(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]+c(βBLAHB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBHelpUBNot help>0, there must be:

    βB>αB1(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]cLA+HBLA

    The relationship between βB and αB1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 51.  βB and αB1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 8).

    In the case of LB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]+c(βBLALB)

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UBHelpUBNot help>0, there must be:

    βB>αB2(LBHB)[(1PB)θ]cLA+LBLA

    The relationship between βB and αB2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 52.  βB and αB2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 8).

    To combine the two figures above together, we must distinguish occasions between cLBLBHBξ>cHBLBHB as case 1B and cLBLBHBξ<cHBLBHB as case 2B. At this point,

    Figure 53.  The union set of βB and αB in case 1B and case 2B in equilibrium 8).

    In the case of HA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA1(LAHA)+c{HAβA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]}

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UASeekUANot seek<0, there must be:

    βA>αA1(LAHA)c[PBLB+(1PB)HB]+HA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]

    The relationship between βA and αA1 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 54.  βA and αA1 's range of possible values in equilibrium 8).

    In the case of LA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(LAHA)+c{LAβA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]}

    Therefore, in order to meet the condition UASeekUANot seek>0, there must be:

    βA<αA2(LAHA)c[PBLB+(1PB)HB]+LA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]

    The relationship between βA and αA2 is shown in the following figure:

    Figure 55.  βA and αA2 's range of possible values in equilibrium 8).

    Since α2α1=ξ, there are: cLALAHAξ>cHALAHA as case 1A and cLALAHAξ<cHALAHA as case 2A. At this point,

    Figure 56.  The union set of βA and αA in case 1A in equilibrium 8).

    Player B must satisfy all of the conditions of the game equilibrium case 1B or case 2B, player A must satisfy all of the conditions of the game equilibrium case 1A or case 2A. Because case 2A is an empty set, the union set of case 1B and case 2B is also an empty set. Thus, the result that satisfies both case 1B and case 1A is 0<ξ<c. The figure is as follows:

    Figure 57.  The union set of player A and player B in equilibrium 8).

    Since the result of the union set of case 2B and case 1A is ξ>c, ξ<c, ξ does not exist.

    The above section discusses the eight equilibriums. The next section will discuss why the following eight situations are not equilibrium:

    9) r=0,r=0,q=1,q=0

    In the case of LA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(LAHA)

    Owing to UASeekUANot seek>0 must be satisfied, UASeekUANot seek must be less than 0. It contradicts q=1.

    10) r=0,r=0,q=0,q=1

    In the case of LA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(1)(LAHA)

    Owing to αA2(1)(LAHA) is always positive, UASeekUANot seek must be greater than 0. It contradicts q=0.

    11) r=1,r=0,q=0,q=1

    In the case of LA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(1)(LAHA)+(1PB)c{LAβA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]}

    Owing to αA2(1)(LAHA) and (1PB)c{LAβA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]} are always positive, UASeekUANot seek must be greater than 0. It contradicts q=0.

    12) r=0,r=1,q=1,q=0

    In the case of LB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)(1)+c(βBLALB)

    Owing to αB2(LBHB)(1) and c(βBLALB) are always negative, UBHelpUBNot help must be less than 0. It contradicts r=1.

    13) r=1,r=1,q=0,q=1

    In the case of LA :

    UASeekUANot seek=αA2(1)(LAHA)+c{LAβA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]}

    Owing to αA2(1)(LAHA) and c{LAβA[PBLB+(1PB)HB]} are always positive, UASeekUANot seek must be greater than 0. It contradicts q=0.

    14) r=0,r=1,q=1,q=1

    In the case of LB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)(1)+c(βBLALB)

    Owing to αB2(LBHB)(1) and c(βBLALB) are always negative, UBHelpUBNot help must be less than 0. It contradicts r=1.

    15) r=0,r=1,q=0,q=0

    In the case of LB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)(1)+c(βBLALB)

    Owing to αB2(LBHB)(1) and c(βBLALB) are always negative, UBHelpUBNot help must be less than 0. It contradicts r=1.

    16) r=0,r=1,q=0,q=1

    In the case of LB :

    UBHelpUBNot help=αB2(LBHB)(1)+c(βBHALB)

    Owing to αB2(LBHB)(1) and c(βBHALB) are always negative, UBHelpUBNot help must be less than 0. It contradicts r=1.

    Based on the above equilibrium analysis results, the difference in self-awareness ξ is greatest when it is larger than c, and it becomes equilibriums 6) and 7). It means when the degree of risk aversion of the player is the highest, the helper always helps, regardless of the help-seekers' ability. The reason is that risk aversion helpers care more about being looked down upon than being looked up to by others. Therefore, seeking help from someone with a high level of self-awareness increases the likelihood of getting help. This is consistent with the prior studies based on psychological experiments [19,21,22]. When ξ is slightly smaller, there are equilibriums 1)–3) and 6)–8). At this time, player B, with high ability, would help. Low ability does not necessarily help. In other words, when the difference in self-awareness is medium and slightly smaller, or the degree of risk aversion decreases, only people with high ability will help others. Although people with low ability want to help others, the price of helping others is too high, so they will not help others. Under this condition, self-awareness tends to increase helpfulness. This is consistent with the prior studies based on psychological experiments [19,22,23]. When ξ is the smallest, it is equilibriums 2), 4), 6), 7) and 9). When the difference in self-awareness is minimal, that is, when the degree of risk aversion is small, high-ability help seekers tend not to seek help from others. At this time, although the seeker does not care much about being looked down upon by others, once they seek help from others, the high-ability person will also reduce their utility due to reasons related to politeness, so the high-ability seeker is more inclined to not ask for help. This is consistent with previous literature based on psychological experiments [21].

    Regarding the helper, by equilibriums 4) and 5), if the self-awareness α is large, but the politeness β is very small, neither player B with high ability nor low ability would help. In other words, even if the self-awareness is relatively high, but the degree of politeness is relatively low, both high and low ability people will not help. This is consistent with the previous literature based on psychological experiments [20]. We confirmed that when self-awareness and politeness are within a certain range, people help, as shown in equilibriums 1)–3). Suppose self-awareness α and politeness β are within a specific range; in other words, when self-awareness and politeness are within a specific range. In that case, people with high ability will help, and people with low ability will not help. In equilibriums 6)–8), when self-awareness and politeness are high, the helper will choose to help others regardless of their ability. Helpers with high levels of self-awareness tend to help, consistent with previous research based on psychological experiments [19]. Besides, Helpers with high levels of politeness tend to help, consistent with previous research based on psychological experiments [33,34,35].

    Concerning the help-seeker, in equilibrium 7), If politeness β is small when seeking help, either player A with low or high ability would seek help. It means when viewed from the perspective of the seeker, when the degree of politeness of the seeker is relatively low, no matter the seeker's ability, he/she will seek help from others.

    In equilibriums 2) and 8), if self-awareness α and politeness β are within a specific range, which means the level of self-awareness and politeness are within a certain range, player A with high ability would not seek help. However, player A with low ability would seek help.

    In equilibriums 3) and 6), when self-awareness α and politeness β are both large, either player B with the high ability or low ability would not seek help. It means when self-awareness and politeness are high, the help seeker will not ask for help, regardless of the ability of the seeker. On the one hand, help seekers with high levels of self-awareness tend not to seek help, consistent with previous research based on psychological experiments [25,26,27]. On the other hand, help seekers with high levels of politeness tend not to seek help, consistent with previous research [36,37].

    In situations 12) and 14)–16) where there is no equilibrium, player B with high ability may help. While the psychological effect of self-awareness α and politeness β affect human behavior, it is impossible to force others to do things beyond their abilities.

    In situations 10), 11), 13), and 16), it is unlikely that a player with low abilities would not seek help, and a player with high abilities would seek help.

    To the best of our knowledge, this is the first application of Bayesian Nash equilibrium based on psychological game theory in studying human help-seeking and help-giving behavior. Through this study, we thus extend the generalizability of Bayesian Nash equilibrium based on psychological game theory to the study of human helping behavior.

    Humans grow through mutual help, and society progresses accordingly. However, there are times when people are in deep trouble and are reluctant to ask for help; at other times, people are very hesitant to help others. By establishing a Bayesian Nash Equilibrium analysis, this study analyzes whether people would seek help or help others from two fundamental concepts related to internal rewards: self-awareness and politeness. We also demonstrate the extent to which self-awareness and politeness influence help-seeking and help-giving behaviors, which are regular and predictable. This study thus provides a theoretical understanding of the role of self-awareness and politeness in helping behavior.

    For help-seeking behavior, we can understand why people do not seek help when they are clearly in trouble. Because people have the nature of politeness, it is difficult to ask for help if they are excessively polite and care about their image. Besides, people with an excessively high level of self-awareness often do not ask others for help because they are worried about exposing their flaws and incompetence in front of others [48].

    From the perspective of helpers, we can also understand people tend to help others if they have a high level of self-awareness and politeness. However, it may not be their original intention. For one thing, helpers want to help others to create a positive personal impression and gain praise. For another, politeness, as a basic moral code, advocates the duty of helping others. It also motivates people to help those who are not life-threatening or in desperate need.

    Many of our findings have practical implications for understanding and increasing helping behavior to build a harmonious and mutual aid society finally.

    Based on this study, in the case of knowing the level of self-awareness and politeness of both parties, help seekers can judge whether the other party will help them, and thus decide whether to seek help. Helpers, on the other hand, can judge whether they help or not.

    In terms of help-giving, after realizing that people with high levels of self-awareness tend to help, we can improve people's level of self-awareness to increase helping behavior. Specifically, we can encourage people to read, practice, reflect on themselves more, cultivate their independent awareness and thinking ability, and improve their self-awareness level. Besides, after realizing that people with high levels of politeness tend to help, we can promote the development of etiquette education and improve the level of etiquette cultivation ideologically, to improve the level of politeness. These measures can eventually increase the opportunity to give help. In brief, it is necessary to improve everyone's self-awareness and support and promote the moral code of being polite to others.

    In terms of help-seeking, through this study, we found that individuals with a high level of self-awareness are often reluctant to seek help. So it is crucial to give the person being helped an opportunity to repay the favor. This has also been confirmed in other studies. People are more likely to commit to charities belonging to those who have given them favors [49]. This study suggests individuals with a high level of politeness tend to give up seeking help. Therefore, it is essential to eliminate the guilt of the seeker as much as possible and reduce the bad feeling.

    There are many examples of helping behaviors in everyday life. For example, donation behavior is a typical helping behavior. For instance, in residential communities in China, when someone encounters difficulties such as sudden illness and needs to donate, there are often donation activities similar to love relays. These donation behaviors are influenced by two factors self-awareness and politeness in this study. In this context of donation behavior, people with a high level of self-awareness and politeness are more likely to donate to help those in need who are seriously ill but have no money for treatment. Patients who are short of money and unable to treat their illnesses may tend not to raise funds if their levels of self-awareness and politeness are too high, thus delaying treatment. In such a situation, on the one hand, we need to improve the level of self-awareness and politeness of as many people as possible in our society so that when someone needs help, as many people as possible will lend a helping hand. On the other hand, we can also build channels to provide opportunities for patients who seek help to thank donors so that patients who need help will not miss the opportunity to seek help for their own reasons.

    Although there are extensive studies on human helping behavior in existing literature, prior research emphasized methods of psychological experiments. Besides, studies on human help-seeking and help-giving behaviors rarely study the connection of self-awareness and politeness to human help-seeking and help-giving behaviors, especially from the perspective of psychological game theory. This paper thus links two related social psychology concepts, self-awareness and politeness, with human helping behavior and applies Bayesian Nash equilibrium analysis to compare with the results obtained from psychological experiments in previous studies. We found that a helper with a high level of self-awareness and politeness would help. In contrast, help seekers with a high level of self-awareness and politeness would tend not to seek help. The results obtained in this study through the mathematical method of psychological game theory validate the conclusion of the influence of self-awareness and politeness on helping behavior in social psychology studies based on the research method of psychological experiments.

    Limitations and future directions: To simplify the model, the study has limitations. First, this study does not consider the repaying, in other words, whether the help will be repaid in the future. Second, this study only considered two psychological factors, politeness and self-awareness; other psychological factors could also influence human helping behavior.

    Future studies can consider the act of repaying, and the game theory model can be set as a repeated game. In addition, other psychological factors can be considered in the game theory model to make the theoretical model richer and more realistic to understand human help-seeking and help-giving behavior better.

    We sincerely thank the editors and the anonymous reviewers for their thoughtful reviews and constructive suggestions during the review process. This work was supported by Jiangxi Culture, Art and Science Planning Grant Numbers YG2021184. We also wish to thank Otsuka Toshimi Scholarship Foundation for its generous help.

    The authors declare no conflicts of interest in this paper.

    [1] Flaumenhaft R, Rifkin DB (1991) Extracellular matrix regulation of growth factor and protease activity. Curr Opin Cell Biol 3: 817–823. doi: 10.1016/0955-0674(91)90055-4
    [2] Frantz C, Stewart KM, Weaver VM (2010) The extracellular matrix at a glance. J Cell Sci 123: 4195–4200. doi: 10.1242/jcs.023820
    [3] Bonnans C, Chou J, Werb Z (2014) Remodelling the extracellular matrix in development and disease. Nat Rev Mol Cell Bio 15: 786–801.
    [4] Kim SH, Turnbull J, Guimond S (2011) Extracellular matrix and cell signalling: the dynamic cooperation of integrin, proteoglycan and growth factor receptor. J Endocrinol 209: 139–151. doi: 10.1530/JOE-10-0377
    [5] Schultz GS, Wysocki A (2009) Interactions between extracellular matrix and growth factors in wound healing. Wound Repair Regen 17: 153–162. doi: 10.1111/j.1524-475X.2009.00466.x
    [6] Roskelley CD, Srebrow A, Bissell MJ (1995) A Hierarchy of ECM-Mediated Signaling Regulates Tissue-Specific Gene-Expression. Curr Opin Cell Bio 7: 736–747. doi: 10.1016/0955-0674(95)80117-0
    [7] Altınay S (2016) Is extracellular matrix a castle against to invasion of cancer cells? In: Xu K, Tumor Metastasis, InTech.
    [8] Laurencin CT, Nair LS (2014) Nanotechnology and regenerative engineering: the scaffold, CRC Press.
    [9] Smith LA, Ma PX (2004) Nano-fibrous scaffolds for tissue engineering. Colloid Surface B 39: 125–131. doi: 10.1016/j.colsurfb.2003.12.004
    [10] Khajavi R, Abbasipour M (2012) Electrospinning as a versatile method for fabricating coreshell, hollow and porous nanofibers. Sci Iran 19: 2029–2034. doi: 10.1016/j.scient.2012.10.037
    [11] Fessler JH (1974) Self-assembly of collagen. J Supramol Struct 2: 99–102. doi: 10.1002/jss.400020204
    [12] Bellingham CM, Keeley FW (2004) Self-ordered polymerization of elastin-based biomaterials. Curr Opin Solid ST M 8: 135–139. doi: 10.1016/j.cossms.2004.01.007
    [13] Zhu X, Cui W, Li X, et al. (2008) Electrospun fibrous mats with high porosity as potential scaffolds for skin tissue engineering. Biomacromolecules 9: 1795–1801. doi: 10.1021/bm800476u
    [14] Lee SJ, Yoo JJ, Lim GJ, et al. (2007) In vitro evaluation of electrospun nanofiber scaffolds for vascular graft application. J Biomed Mater Res A 83: 999–1008.
    [15] Holzwarth JM, Ma PX (2011) Biomimetic nanofibrous scaffolds for bone tissue engineering. Biomaterials 32: 9622–9629. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2011.09.009
    [16] Xie J, MacEwan MR, Schwartz AG, et al. (2010) Electrospun nanofibers for neural tissue engineering. Nanoscale 2: 35–44. doi: 10.1039/B9NR00243J
    [17] Li WJ, Tuli R, Okafor C, et al. (2005) A three-dimensional nanofibrous scaffold for cartilage tissue engineering using human mesenchymal stem cells. Biomaterials 26: 599–609. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2004.03.005
    [18] Mogoşanu GD, Grumezescu AM (2014) Natural and synthetic polymers for wounds and burns dressing. Int J Pharm 463: 127–136. doi: 10.1016/j.ijpharm.2013.12.015
    [19] Sell SA, Wolfe PS, Garg K, et al. (2010) The use of natural polymers in tissue engineering: a focus on electrospun extracellular matrix analogues. Polymers 2: 522–553. doi: 10.3390/polym2040522
    [20] Gomes SR, Rodrigues G, Martins GG, et al. (2015) In vitro and in vivo evaluation of electrospun nanofibers of PCL, chitosan and gelatin: A comparative study. Mater Sci Eng C 46: 348–358. doi: 10.1016/j.msec.2014.10.051
    [21] Herskovits TT, Gadegbeku B, Jaillet H (1970) On the structural stability and solvent denaturation of proteins I. Denaturation by the alcohols and glycols. J Biol Chem 245: 2588–2598.
    [22] Freedman KJ, Haq SR, Edel JB, et al. (2013) Single molecule unfolding and stretching of protein domains inside a solid-state nanopore by electric field. Sci Rep-UK 3: 1638. doi: 10.1038/srep01638
    [23] Ingavle GC, Leach JK (2013) Advancements in electrospinning of polymeric nanofibrous scaffolds for tissue engineering. Tissue Eng B 20: 277–293.
    [24] Tan SH, Inai R, Kotaki M, et al. (2005) Systematic parameter study for ultra-fine fiber fabrication via electrospinning process. Polymer 46: 6128–6134. doi: 10.1016/j.polymer.2005.05.068
    [25] Yarin A (2011) Coaxial electrospinning and emulsion electrospinning of core-shell fibers. Polym Advan Technol 22: 310–317. doi: 10.1002/pat.1781
    [26] Xu C, Inai R, Kotaki M, et al. (2004) Aligned biodegradable nanofibrous structure: a potential scaffold for blood vessel engineering. Biomaterials 25: 877–886. doi: 10.1016/S0142-9612(03)00593-3
    [27] Ding B, Kimura E, Sato T, et al. (2004) Fabrication of blend biodegradable nanofibrous nonwoven mats via multi-jet electrospinning. Polymer 45: 1895–1902. doi: 10.1016/j.polymer.2004.01.026
    [28] Del Gaudio C, Bianco A, Grigioni M (2007) Electrospun bioresorbable trileaflet heart valve prosthesis for tissue engineering: in vitro functional assessment of a pulmonary cardiac valve design. Annali dell'Istituto superiore di sanita 44: 178–186.
    [29] Bhardwaj N, Kundu SC (2010) Electrospinning: a fascinating fiber fabrication technique. Biotechnol Adv 28: 325–347. doi: 10.1016/j.biotechadv.2010.01.004
    [30] Pham QP, Sharma U, Mikos AG (2006) Electrospinning of polymeric nanofibers for tissue engineering applications: a review. Tissue Eng 12: 1197–1211. doi: 10.1089/ten.2006.12.1197
    [31] Ferreira JL, Gomes S, Henriques C, et al. (2014) Electrospinning polycaprolactone dissolved in glacial acetic acid: Fiber production, nonwoven characterization, and in vitro evaluation. J Appl Polym Sci 131.
    [32] Gupta RK, Kennel E, Kim KJ (2009) Polymer nanocomposites handbook, CRC press.
    [33] Patel H, Bonde M, Srinivasan G (2011) Biodegradable polymer scaffold for tissue engineering. Trends Biomater Artif Organs 25: 20–29.
    [34] Powell S (2010) Langevin Dynamics Study of Water Diffusion in Model Articular Cartilage [Master's Thesis], Queensland University of Technology Brisbane, Brisbane, Australia.
    [35] Chew SY, Mi R, Hoke A, et al. (2008) The effect of the alignment of electrospun fibrous scaffolds on Schwann cell maturation. Biomaterials 29: 653–661. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2007.10.025
    [36] Gunatillake PA, Adhikari R (2003) Biodegradable synthetic polymers for tissue engineering. Eur Cells Mater 5: 1–16.
    [37] Hu X, Liu S, Zhou G, et al. (2014) Electrospinning of polymeric nanofibers for drug delivery applications. J Control Release 185: 12–21. doi: 10.1016/j.jconrel.2014.04.018
    [38] Bürck J, Heissler S, Geckle U, et al. (2013) Resemblance of electrospun collagen nanofibers to their native structure. Langmuir 29: 1562–1572. doi: 10.1021/la3033258
    [39] Gugutkov D, Gustavsson J, Ginebra MP, et al. (2013) Fibrinogen nanofibers for guiding endothelial cell behavior. Biomater Sci-UK 1: 1065–1073. doi: 10.1039/c3bm60124b
    [40] Rnjak J, Li Z, Maitz PK, et al. (2009) Primary human dermal fibroblast interactions with open weave three-dimensional scaffolds prepared from synthetic human elastin. Biomaterials 30: 6469–6477. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2009.08.017
    [41] Li M, Mondrinos MJ, Gandhi MR, et al. (2005) Electrospun protein fibers as matrices for tissue engineering. Biomaterials 26: 5999–6008. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2005.03.030
    [42] Khadka DB, Haynie DT (2012) Protein-and peptide-based electrospun nanofibers in medical biomaterials. Nanomed-Nanotechnol 8: 1242–1262. doi: 10.1016/j.nano.2012.02.013
    [43] Malafaya PB, Silva GA, Reis RL (2007) Natural-origin polymers as carriers and scaffolds for biomolecules and cell delivery in tissue engineering applications. Adv Drug Deliver Rev 59: 207–233. doi: 10.1016/j.addr.2007.03.012
    [44] Badylak SF (2005) Regenerative medicine and developmental biology: the role of the extracellular matrix. Anat Rec Part B 287: 36–41.
    [45] Matthews JA, Wnek GE, Simpson DG, et al. (2002) Electrospinning of collagen nanofibers. Biomacromolecules 3: 232–238. doi: 10.1021/bm015533u
    [46] Matthews JA, Boland ED, Wnek GE, et al. (2003) Electrospinning of collagen type II: a feasibility study. J Bioact Compat Pol 18: 125–134. doi: 10.1177/0883911503018002003
    [47] Shields KJ, Beckman MJ, Bowlin GL, et al. (2004) Mechanical properties and cellular proliferation of electrospun collagen type II. Tissue Eng 10: 1510–1517. doi: 10.1089/ten.2004.10.1510
    [48] Jha BS, Ayres CE, Bowman JR, et al. (2011) Electrospun collagen: a tissue engineering scaffold with unique functional properties in a wide variety of applications. J Nanomater 2011: 7.
    [49] Zeugolis DI, Khew ST, Yew ES, et al. (2008) Electro-spinning of pure collagen nano-fibres-just an expensive way to make gelatin? Biomaterials 29: 2293–2305. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2008.02.009
    [50] Yang L, Fitie CF, van der Werf KO, et al. (2008) Mechanical properties of single electrospun collagen type I fibers. Biomaterials 29: 955–962. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2007.10.058
    [51] Lannutti J, Reneker D, Ma T, et al. (2007) Electrospinning for tissue engineering scaffolds. Mater Sci Eng C 27: 504–509. doi: 10.1016/j.msec.2006.05.019
    [52] Liu T, Teng WK, Chan BP, et al. (2010) Photochemical crosslinked electrospun collagen nanofibers: synthesis, characterization and neural stem cell interactions. J Biomed Mater Res A 95: 276–282.
    [53] Jiang Q, Reddy N, Zhang S, et al. (2013) Water‐stable electrospun collagen fibers from a non‐toxic solvent and crosslinking system. J Biomed Mater Res A 101: 1237-1247.
    [54] Kazanci M (2014) Solvent and temperature effects on folding of electrospun collagen nanofibers. Mater Lett 130: 223–226. doi: 10.1016/j.matlet.2014.05.114
    [55] Fiorani A, Gualandi C, Panseri S, et al. (2014) Comparative performance of collagen nanofibers electrospun from different solvents and stabilized by different crosslinkers. J Mater Sci-Mater M 25: 2313–2321. doi: 10.1007/s10856-014-5196-2
    [56] Dong Z, Wu Y, Clark RL (2011) Thermodynamic modeling and investigation of the formation of electrospun collagen fibers. Langmuir 27: 12417–12422. doi: 10.1021/la201859c
    [57] Meimandi-Parizi A, Oryan A, Moshiri A (2013) Role of tissue engineered collagen based tridimensional implant on the healing response of the experimentally induced large Achilles tendon defect model in rabbits: a long term study with high clinical relevance. J Biomed Sci 20: 28. doi: 10.1186/1423-0127-20-28
    [58] Rho KS, Jeong L, Lee G, et al. (2006) Electrospinning of collagen nanofibers: effects on the behavior of normal human keratinocytes and early-stage wound healing. Biomaterials 27: 1452–1461. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2005.08.004
    [59] Liu T, Houle JD, Xu J, et al. (2012) Nanofibrous collagen nerve conduits for spinal cord repair. Tissue Eng A 18: 1057–1066. doi: 10.1089/ten.tea.2011.0430
    [60] Kidoaki S, Kwon IK, Matsuda T (2005) Mesoscopic spatial designs of nano-and microfiber meshes for tissue-engineering matrix and scaffold based on newly devised multilayering and mixing electrospinning techniques. Biomaterials 26: 37–46. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2004.01.063
    [61] Telemeco T, Ayres C, Bowlin G, et al. (2005) Regulation of cellular infiltration into tissue engineering scaffolds composed of submicron diameter fibrils produced by electrospinning. Acta Biomater 1: 377–385. doi: 10.1016/j.actbio.2005.04.006
    [62] Zhong SP, Teo WE, Zhu X, et al. (2007) Development of a novel collagen–GAG nanofibrous scaffold via electrospinning. Mater Sci Eng C 27: 262–266. doi: 10.1016/j.msec.2006.05.010
    [63] Casper CL, Yang W, Farach-Carson MC, et al. (2007) Coating electrospun collagen and gelatin fibers with perlecan domain I for increased growth factor binding. Biomacromolecules 8: 1116–1123. doi: 10.1021/bm061003s
    [64] Barnes CP, Pemble IV CW, Brand DD, et al. (2007) Cross-linking electrospun type II collagen tissue engineering scaffolds with carbodiimide in ethanol. Tissue Eng 13: 1593–1605. doi: 10.1089/ten.2006.0292
    [65] Foltran I, Foresti E, Parma B, et al. (2008) Novel biologically inspired collagen nanofibers reconstituted by electrospinning method. Macromol Symp 269: 111–118. doi: 10.1002/masy.200850914
    [66] Dong B, Arnoult O, Smith ME, et al. (2009) Electrospinning of collagen nanofiber scaffolds from benign solvents. Macromol Rapid Comm 30: 539–542. doi: 10.1002/marc.200800634
    [67] Timnak A, Gharebaghi FY, Shariati RP, et al. (2011) Fabrication of nano-structured electrospun collagen scaffold intended for nerve tissue engineering. J Mater Sci-Mater M 22: 1555–1567. doi: 10.1007/s10856-011-4316-5
    [68] Wang Y, Yao M, Zhou J, et al. (2011) The promotion of neural progenitor cells proliferation by aligned and randomly oriented collagen nanofibers through β1 integrin/MAPK signaling pathway. Biomaterials 32: 6737–6744. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2011.05.075
    [69] Meng L, Arnoult O, Smith M, et al. (2012) Electrospinning of in situ crosslinked collagen nanofibers. J Mater Chem 22: 19412–19417. doi: 10.1039/c2jm31618h
    [70] Gorgieva S, Kokol V (2011) Collagen-vs. gelatine-based biomaterials and their biocompatibility: review and perspectives, INTECH open access publisher Croatia.
    [71] Heydarkhan-Hagvall S, Schenke-Layland K, Dhanasopon AP, et al. (2008) Three-dimensional electrospun ECM-based hybrid scaffolds for cardiovascular tissue engineering. Biomaterials 29: 2907–2914.
    [72] Ratanavaraporn J, Rangkupan R, Jeeratawatchai H, et al. (2010) Influences of physical and chemical crosslinking techniques on electrospun type A and B gelatin fiber mats. Int J Biol Macromol 47: 431–438.
    [73] Masutani EM, Kinoshita CK, Tanaka TT, et al. (2014) Increasing thermal stability of gelatin by UV-induced cross-linking with glucose. Int J Biomater 2014.
    [74] Zhang Y, Venugopal J, Huang ZM, et al. (2006) Crosslinking of the electrospun gelatin nanofibers. Polymer 47: 2911–2917. doi: 10.1016/j.polymer.2006.02.046
    [75] Panzavolta S, Gioffrè M, Focarete ML, et al. (2011) Electrospun gelatin nanofibers: optimization of genipin cross-linking to preserve fiber morphology after exposure to water. Acta Biomater 7: 1702–1709. doi: 10.1016/j.actbio.2010.11.021
    [76] Sisson K, Zhang C, Farach-Carson MC, et al. (2009) Evaluation of cross-linking methods for electrospun gelatin on cell growth and viability. Biomacromolecules 10: 1675–1680. doi: 10.1021/bm900036s
    [77] Madaghiele M, Piccinno A, Saponaro M, et al. (2009) Collagen-and gelatine-based films sealing vascular prostheses: evaluation of the degree of crosslinking for optimal blood impermeability. J Mater Sci-Mater M 20: 1979–1989. doi: 10.1007/s10856-009-3778-1
    [78] Ki CS, Baek DH, Gang KD, et al. (2005) Characterization of gelatin nanofiber prepared from gelatin–formic acid solution. Polymer 46: 5094–5102. doi: 10.1016/j.polymer.2005.04.040
    [79] Powell H, Boyce S (2008) Fiber density of electrospun gelatin scaffolds regulates morphogenesis of dermal–epidermal skin substitutes. J Biomed Mater Res A 84: 1078–1086.
    [80] Okutan N, Terzi P, Altay F (2014) Affecting parameters on electrospinning process and characterization of electrospun gelatin nanofibers. Food Hydrocolloid 39: 19–26. doi: 10.1016/j.foodhyd.2013.12.022
    [81] Yao R, He J, Meng G, et al. (2016) Electrospun PCL/Gelatin composite fibrous scaffolds: mechanical properties and cellular responses. J Biomat Sci-Polym E 27: 824–838. doi: 10.1080/09205063.2016.1160560
    [82] Ghasemi-Mobarakeh L, Prabhakaran MP, Morshed M, et al. (2008) Electrospun poly (ɛ-caprolactone)/gelatin nanofibrous scaffolds for nerve tissue engineering. Biomaterials 29: 4532–4539.
    [83] Dubský M, Kubinová Š, Širc J, et al. (2012) Nanofibers prepared by needleless electrospinning technology as scaffolds for wound healing. J Mater Sci-Mater M 23: 931–941. doi: 10.1007/s10856-012-4577-7
    [84] Huang ZM, Zhang Y, Ramakrishna S, et al. (2004) Electrospinning and mechanical characterization of gelatin nanofibers. Polymer 45: 5361–5368. doi: 10.1016/j.polymer.2004.04.005
    [85] Zhang Y, Ouyang H, Lim CT, et al. (2005) Electrospinning of gelatin fibers and gelatin/PCL composite fibrous scaffolds. J Biomed Mater Res B 72: 156–165.
    [86] Choktaweesap N, Arayanarakul K, Aht-Ong D, et al. (2007) Electrospun gelatin fibers: effect of solvent system on morphology and fiber diameters. Polym J 39: 622.
    [87] Song JH, Kim HE, Kim HW (2008) Production of electrospun gelatin nanofiber by water-based co-solvent approach. J Mater Sci-Mater M 19: 95–102. doi: 10.1007/s10856-007-3169-4
    [88] Zhang S, Huang Y, Yang X, et al. (2009) Gelatin nanofibrous membrane fabricated by electrospinning of aqueous gelatin solution for guided tissue regeneration. J Biomed Mater Res A 90: 671–679.
    [89] Chen HC, Jao WC, Yang MC (2009) Characterization of gelatin nanofibers electrospun using ethanol/formic acid/water as a solvent. Polym Advan Technol 20: 98–103.
    [90] Sisson K, Zhang C, Farach‐Carson MC, et al. (2010) Fiber diameters control osteoblastic cell migration and differentiation in electrospun gelatin. J Biomed Mater Res A 94: 1312-1320.
    [91] Martin SL, Vrhovski B, Weiss AS (1995) Total synthesis and expression in Escherichia coli of a gene encoding human tropoelastin. Gene 154: 159–166. doi: 10.1016/0378-1119(94)00848-M
    [92] Yeo GC, Aghaei-Ghareh-Bolagh B, Brackenreg EP, et al. (2015) Fabricated Elastin. Adv Healthc Mater 4: 2530–2556.
    [93] Nivison‐Smith L, Weiss AS (2012) Alignment of human vascular smooth muscle cells on parallel electrospun synthetic elastin fibers. J Biomed Mater Res A 100: 155-161.
    [94] Nivison-Smith L, Rnjak J, Weiss AS (2010) Synthetic human elastin microfibers: stable cross-linked tropoelastin and cell interactive constructs for tissue engineering applications. Acta Biomater 6: 354–359. doi: 10.1016/j.actbio.2009.08.011
    [95] Rnjak-Kovacina J, Wise SG, Li Z, et al. (2011) Tailoring the porosity and pore size of electrospun synthetic human elastin scaffolds for dermal tissue engineering. Biomaterials 32: 6729–6736. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2011.05.065
    [96] Boland ED, Matthews JA, Pawlowski KJ, et al. (2004) Electrospinning collagen and elastin: preliminary vascular tissue engineering. Front Biosci 9: e32. doi: 10.2741/1204
    [97] McKenna KA, Hinds MT, Sarao RC, et al. (2012) Mechanical property characterization of electrospun recombinant human tropoelastin for vascular graft biomaterials. Acta Biomater 8: 225–233. doi: 10.1016/j.actbio.2011.08.001
    [98] McKenna KA, Gregory KW, Sarao RC, et al. (2012) Structural and cellular characterization of electrospun recombinant human tropoelastin biomaterials. J Biomater Appl 27: 219–230. doi: 10.1177/0885328211399480
    [99] Lee KY, Jeong L, Kang YO, et al. (2009) Electrospinning of polysaccharides for regenerative medicine. Adv Drug Deliver Rev 61: 1020–1032. doi: 10.1016/j.addr.2009.07.006
    [100] Li J, He A, Han CC, et al. (2006) Electrospinning of hyaluronic acid (HA) and HA/gelatin blends. Macromol Rapid Comm 27: 114–120. doi: 10.1002/marc.200500726
    [101] Schiffman JD, Schauer CL (2008) A review: electrospinning of biopolymer nanofibers and their applications. Polym Rev 48: 317–352. doi: 10.1080/15583720802022182
    [102] Um IC, Fang D, Hsiao BS, et al. (2004) Electro-spinning and electro-blowing of hyaluronic acid. Biomacromolecules 5: 1428–1436. doi: 10.1021/bm034539b
    [103] Brenner EK, Schiffman JD, Toth LJ, et al. (2013) Phosphate salts facilitate the electrospinning of hyaluronic acid fiber mats. J Mater Sci 48: 7805–7811.
    [104] Brenner EK, Schiffman JD, Thompson EA, et al. (2012) Electrospinning of hyaluronic acid nanofibers from aqueous ammonium solutions. Carbohyd Polym 87: 926–929. doi: 10.1016/j.carbpol.2011.07.033
    [105] Liu Y, Ma G, Fang D, et al. (2011) Effects of solution properties and electric field on the electrospinning of hyaluronic acid. Carbohyd Polym 83: 1011–1015. doi: 10.1016/j.carbpol.2010.08.061
    [106] Xu S, Li J, He A, et al. (2009) Chemical crosslinking and biophysical properties of electrospun hyaluronic acid based ultra-thin fibrous membranes. Polymer 50: 3762–3769. doi: 10.1016/j.polymer.2009.06.009
    [107] Yao S, Wang X, Liu X, et al. (2013) Effects of ambient relative humidity and solvent properties on the electrospinning of pure hyaluronic acid nanofibers. J Nanosci Nanotechno 13: 4752–4758. doi: 10.1166/jnn.2013.7197
    [108] Wang X, Um IC, Fang D, et al. (2005) Formation of water-resistant hyaluronic acid nanofibers by blowing-assisted electro-spinning and non-toxic post treatments. Polymer 46: 4853–4867. doi: 10.1016/j.polymer.2005.03.058
    [109] Hsu FY, Hung YS, Liou HM, et al. (2010) Electrospun hyaluronate–collagen nanofibrous matrix and the effects of varying the concentration of hyaluronate on the characteristics of foreskin fibroblast cells. Acta Biomater 6: 2140–2147. doi: 10.1016/j.actbio.2009.12.023
    [110] Uppal R, Ramaswamy GN, Arnold C, et al. (2011) Hyaluronic acid nanofiber wound dressing-production, characterization, and in vivo behavior. J Biomed Mater Res B 97: 20–29.
    [111] Ahmed Z, Underwood S, Brown R (2000) Low concentrations of fibrinogen increase cell migration speed on fibronectin/fibrinogen composite cables. Cytoskeleton 46: 6–16. doi: 10.1002/(SICI)1097-0169(200005)46:1<6::AID-CM2>3.0.CO;2-Z
    [112] Ye Q, Zünd G, Benedikt P, et al. (2000) Fibrin gel as a three dimensional matrix in cardiovascular tissue engineering. Eur J Cardio-Thorac 17: 587–591. doi: 10.1016/S1010-7940(00)00373-0
    [113] Sell SA, Francis MP, Garg K, et al. (2008) Cross-linking methods of electrospun fibrinogen scaffolds for tissue engineering applications. Biomed Mater 3: 045001. doi: 10.1088/1748-6041/3/4/045001
    [114] Wnek GE, Carr ME, Simpson DG, et al. (2003) Electrospinning of nanofiber fibrinogen structures. Nano Lett 3: 213–216.
    [115] Sell S, Barnes C, Simpson D, et al. (2008) Scaffold permeability as a means to determine fiber diameter and pore size of electrospun fibrinogen. J Biomed Mater Res A 85: 115–126.
    [116] Carlisle CR, Coulais C, Namboothiry M, et al. (2009) The mechanical properties of individual, electrospun fibrinogen fibers. Biomaterials 30: 1205–1213. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2008.11.006
    [117] McManus M, Boland E, Sell S, et al. (2007) Electrospun nanofibre fibrinogen for urinary tract tissue reconstruction. Biomed Mater 2: 257. doi: 10.1088/1748-6041/2/4/008
    [118] McManus MC, Boland ED, Simpson DG, et al. (2007) Electrospun fibrinogen: feasibility as a tissue engineering scaffold in a rat cell culture model. J Biomed Mater Res A 81: 299–309.
    [119] Guadiz G, Sporn LA, Simpson-Haidaris PJ (1997) Thrombin cleavage-independent deposition of fibrinogen in extracellular matrices. Blood 90: 2644–2653.
    [120] Stitzel J, Liu J, Lee SJ, et al. (2006) Controlled fabrication of a biological vascular substitute. Biomaterials 27: 1088–1094. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2005.07.048
    [121] Schnell E, Klinkhammer K, Balzer S, et al. (2007) Guidance of glial cell migration and axonal growth on electrospun nanofibers of poly-ε-caprolactone and a collagen/poly-ε-caprolactone blend. Biomaterials 28: 3012–3025. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2007.03.009
    [122] López-Calzada G, Hernandez-Martínez AR, Cruz-Soto M, et al. (2016) Development of meniscus substitutes using a mixture of biocompatible polymers and extra cellular matrix components by electrospinning. Mater Sci Eng C 61: 893–905.
    [123] Koh HS, Yong T, Chan CK, et al. (2008) Enhancement of neurite outgrowth using nano-structured scaffolds coupled with laminin. Biomaterials 29: 3574–3582. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2008.05.014
    [124] Zhu Y, Leong MF, Ong WF, et al. (2007) Esophageal epithelium regeneration on fibronectin grafted poly(L-lactide-co-caprolactone) (PLLC) nanofiber scaffold. Biomaterials 28: 861–868. doi: 10.1016/j.biomaterials.2006.09.051
    [125] Cheng Y, Ramos D, Lee P, et al. (2014) Collagen functionalized bioactive nanofiber matrices for osteogenic differentiation of mesenchymal stem cells: bone tissue engineering. J Biomed Nanotechnol 10: 287–298. doi: 10.1166/jbn.2014.1753
    [126] Yeo IS, Oh JE, Jeong L, et al. (2008) Collagen-based biomimetic nanofibrous scaffolds: preparation and characterization of collagen/silk fibroin bicomponent nanofibrous structures. Biomacromolecules 9: 1106–1116. doi: 10.1021/bm700875a
    [127] Dhandayuthapani B, Krishnan UM, Sethuraman S (2010) Fabrication and characterization of chitosan–gelatin blend nanofibers for skin tissue engineering. J Biomed Mater Res B 94: 264–272.
    [128] Altman GH, Diaz F, Jakuba C, et al. (2003) Silk-based biomaterials. Biomaterials 24: 401–416. doi: 10.1016/S0142-9612(02)00353-8
    [129] Plowman JE, Deb-Choudhury S, Dyer JM (2013) Fibrous protein nanofibers, In: Gerrard JA, Protein Nanotechnology: Protocols, Instrumentation, and Applications, 2nd Eds, Humana Press, 61–76.
    [130] Kim IY, Seo SJ, Moon HS, et al. (2008) Chitosan and its derivatives for tissue engineering applications. Biotechnol Adv 26: 1–21. doi: 10.1016/j.biotechadv.2007.07.009
    [131] Wen X, Wang Y, Guo Z, et al. (2014) Cauda Equina-Derived Extracellular Matrix for Fabrication of Nanostructured Hybrid Scaffolds Applied to Neural Tissue Engineering. Tissue Eng A 21: 1095–1105.
    [132] McManus MC, Boland ED, Koo HP, et al. (2006) Mechanical properties of electrospun fibrinogen structures. Acta Biomater 2: 19–28. doi: 10.1016/j.actbio.2005.09.008
    [133] Baker S, Sigley J, Helms CC, et al. (2012) The mechanical properties of dry, electrospun fibrinogen fibers. Mater Sci Eng C 32: 215–221. doi: 10.1016/j.msec.2011.10.021
    [134] Wan C, Frydrych M, Chen B (2011) Strong and bioactive gelatin–graphene oxide nanocomposites. Soft Matter 7: 6159–6166. doi: 10.1039/c1sm05321c
    [135] Nadeem D, Kiamehr M, Yang X, et al. (2013) Fabrication and in vitro evaluation of a sponge-like bioactive-glass/gelatin composite scaffold for bone tissue engineering. Mater Sci Eng C 33: 2669–2678. doi: 10.1016/j.msec.2013.02.021
    [136] Merkle VM, Zeng L, Slepian MJ, et al. (2014) Core‐shell nanofibers: Integrating the bioactivity of gelatin and the mechanical property of polyvinyl alcohol. Biopolymers 101: 336–346. doi: 10.1002/bip.22367
    [137] Hersel U, Dahmen C, Kessler H (2003) RGD modified polymers: biomaterials for stimulated cell adhesion and beyond. Biomaterials 24: 4385–4415. doi: 10.1016/S0142-9612(03)00343-0
    [138] Paletta JRJ, Bockelmann S, Walz A, et al. (2010) RGD-functionalisation of PLLA nanofibers by surface coupling using plasma treatment: influence on stem cell differentiation. J Mater Sci-Mater M 21: 1363–1369. doi: 10.1007/s10856-009-3947-2
    [139] Nomizu M, Utani A, Shiraishi N, et al. (1992) The all-D-configuration segment containing the IKVAV sequence of laminin A chain has similar activities to the all-L-peptide in vitro and in vivo. J Biol Chem 267: 14118–14121.
    [140] Lodish H, Zipursky SL (2001) Molecular cell biology. Biochem Mol Biol Edu 29: 126–133.
    [141] Peh P, Lim NSJ, Blocki A, et al. (2015) Simultaneous delivery of highly diverse bioactive compounds from blend electrospun fibers for skin wound healing. Bioconjugate Chem 26: 1348–1358. doi: 10.1021/acs.bioconjchem.5b00123
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. 琦 张, A Corpus-Based Study on the Application of Politeness Principle in Business English Letters, 2023, 11, 2330-1708, 4580, 10.12677/ML.2023.1110614
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2017 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(8624) PDF downloads(1418) Cited by(20)

Figures and Tables

Figures(4)  /  Tables(5)

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog