Processing math: 100%
Research article

Investor sentiment and the interdependence structure of GIIPS stock market returns: A multiscale approach

  • The GIIPS economies are noted to suffer the most consequences of systemic crises. Regardless of their bad performance in crisis periods, their role(s) in asset allocation and portfolio management cannot go unnoticed. For effective portfolio management across divergent timescales, cross-market interdependencies cannot be side-lined. This study examines the conditional and unconditional co-movements of stock market returns of GIIPS economies incorporating investor fear in their time-frequency connectedness. As a result, the bi-, partial, and multiple wavelet approaches are employed. Our findings explicate that the high interdependencies between the stock market returns of GIIPS across all time scales are partly driven by investor fear, implying that extreme investor sentiment could influence stock market prices in GIIPS. The lagging role of Spanish stock market returns manifests at zero lags at high (lower) and medium frequencies (scales). At lower frequencies (higher scales), particularly quarterly-to-biannual and biannual-to-annual, Spanish and Irish stock markets, respectively, lag all other markets. Although portfolio diversification and safe haven benefits are minimal with GIIPS stocks, their volatilities could be hedged against by investing in the US VIX. Intriguing inferences for international portfolio and risk management are offered by our findings.

    Citation: Samuel Kwaku Agyei, Ahmed Bossman. Investor sentiment and the interdependence structure of GIIPS stock market returns: A multiscale approach[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(1): 87-116. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023005

    Related Papers:

    [1] Yue Cao . Blow-up criterion for the 3D viscous polytropic fluids with degenerate viscosities. Electronic Research Archive, 2020, 28(1): 27-46. doi: 10.3934/era.2020003
    [2] Jie Zhang, Gaoli Huang, Fan Wu . Energy equality in the isentropic compressible Navier-Stokes-Maxwell equations. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(10): 6412-6424. doi: 10.3934/era.2023324
    [3] Jianxia He, Qingyan Li . On the global well-posedness and exponential stability of 3D heat conducting incompressible Navier-Stokes equations with temperature-dependent coefficients and vacuum. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(9): 5451-5477. doi: 10.3934/era.2024253
    [4] Yazhou Wang, Yuzhu Wang . Regularity criterion of three dimensional magneto-micropolar fluid equations with fractional dissipation. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(7): 4416-4432. doi: 10.3934/era.2024199
    [5] Guochun Wu, Han Wang, Yinghui Zhang . Optimal time-decay rates of the compressible Navier–Stokes–Poisson system in $ \mathbb R^3 $. Electronic Research Archive, 2021, 29(6): 3889-3908. doi: 10.3934/era.2021067
    [6] Jie Qi, Weike Wang . Global solutions to the Cauchy problem of BNSP equations in some classes of large data. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(9): 5496-5541. doi: 10.3934/era.2024255
    [7] Hui Yang, Futao Ma, Wenjie Gao, Yuzhu Han . Blow-up properties of solutions to a class of $ p $-Kirchhoff evolution equations. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(7): 2663-2680. doi: 10.3934/era.2022136
    [8] Yang Cao, Qiuting Zhao . Initial boundary value problem of a class of mixed pseudo-parabolic Kirchhoff equations. Electronic Research Archive, 2021, 29(6): 3833-3851. doi: 10.3934/era.2021064
    [9] José Luis Díaz Palencia, Saeed Ur Rahman, Saman Hanif . Regularity criteria for a two dimensional Erying-Powell fluid flowing in a MHD porous medium. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(11): 3949-3976. doi: 10.3934/era.2022201
    [10] Zhonghua Qiao, Xuguang Yang . A multiple-relaxation-time lattice Boltzmann method with Beam-Warming scheme for a coupled chemotaxis-fluid model. Electronic Research Archive, 2020, 28(3): 1207-1225. doi: 10.3934/era.2020066
  • The GIIPS economies are noted to suffer the most consequences of systemic crises. Regardless of their bad performance in crisis periods, their role(s) in asset allocation and portfolio management cannot go unnoticed. For effective portfolio management across divergent timescales, cross-market interdependencies cannot be side-lined. This study examines the conditional and unconditional co-movements of stock market returns of GIIPS economies incorporating investor fear in their time-frequency connectedness. As a result, the bi-, partial, and multiple wavelet approaches are employed. Our findings explicate that the high interdependencies between the stock market returns of GIIPS across all time scales are partly driven by investor fear, implying that extreme investor sentiment could influence stock market prices in GIIPS. The lagging role of Spanish stock market returns manifests at zero lags at high (lower) and medium frequencies (scales). At lower frequencies (higher scales), particularly quarterly-to-biannual and biannual-to-annual, Spanish and Irish stock markets, respectively, lag all other markets. Although portfolio diversification and safe haven benefits are minimal with GIIPS stocks, their volatilities could be hedged against by investing in the US VIX. Intriguing inferences for international portfolio and risk management are offered by our findings.



    We consider the compressible isentropic Navier-Stokes equations with degenerate viscosities in R3, which gives the conservation laws of mass and momentum of fluids. This model comes from the Boltzmann equations through the Chapman-Enskog expansion to the second order, and the viscosities depend on the density ρ0 by the laws of Boyle and Gay-Lussac for ideal gas. This system can be written as

    {ρt+div(ρu)=0,(ρu)t+div(ρuu)+P=divT, (1)

    where xR3 is the spatial coordinate; t0 is the time; ρ is the density of the fluid; u=(u(1),u(2),u(3))R3 is the velocity of the fluid; P is the pressure, and for the polytropic fluid

    P=Aργ,γ>1, (2)

    where A is a positive constant, γ is the adiabatic index; T is the stress tensor given by

    T=μ(ρ)(u+(u))+λ(ρ)divuI3, (3)

    where I3 is the 3×3 unit matrix, μ(ρ) is the shear viscosity, λ(ρ) is the second viscosity, and

    μ(ρ)=αρ,λ(ρ)=βρ, (4)

    where the constants α and β satisfy

    α>0,2α+3β0.

    Here, the initial data are given by

    (ρ,u)|t=0=(ρ0,u0)(x),xR3, (5)

    and the far field behavior is given by

    (ρ,u)(0,0)as |x|,t0. (6)

    The aim of this paper is to prove a blow-up criterion for the regular solution to the Cauchy problem (1) with (5)-(6).

    Throughout the paper, we adopt the following simplified notations for the standard homogeneous and inhomogeneous Sobolev space:

    Dk,r={fL1loc(R3):|f|Dk,r=|kf|Lr<+},Dk=Dk,2(k2),D1={fL6(R3):|f|D1=|f|L2<},fXY=fX+fY,fs=fHs(R3),|f|p=fLp(R3),|f|Dk=fDk(R3).

    A detailed study of homogeneous Sobolev space can be found in [5].

    The compressible isentropic Navier-Stokes system is a well-known mathematical model, which has attracted great attention from the researchers, and some significant processes have been made in the well-posedness for this system.

    When (μ,λ) are both constants, with the assumption that there is no vacuum, the local existence of the classical solutions to system (1) follows from a standard Banach fixed point argument. For the existence results with vacuum and general data, the main breakthrough is due to Lions [16]. He established the global existence of weak solutions in R3, periodic domains or bounded domains, under the homogenous Dirichlet boundary conditions and the restriction γ>9/5. Later, the restriction on γ was improved to γ>3/2 by Feireisl-Novotný-Petzeltová [4]. Recently, Cho-Choe-Kim [2] introduced the following initial layer compatibility condition

    divT0+P(ρ0)=ρ0g

    for some gL2 to deal with the vacuum. They proved the local existence of the strong solutions in R3 or bounded domains with homogenous Dirichlet boundary conditions. Moreover, Huang-Li-Xin proved the global existence of the classical solutions to the Cauchy problem of the isentropic system with small energy and vacuum in [8].

    When (μ,λ) depend on density in the following form

    μ(ρ)=αρδ1,λ(ρ)=βρδ2, (7)

    where δ1>0, δ20, α>0 and β are all real constants, system (1) has received a lot of attention. However, except for the 1D problems, there are few results on the strong solutions for the multi-dimensional problems, since the possible degeneracy of the Lamˊe operator caused by initial vacuum. This degeneracy gives rise to some difficulties in the regularity estimates because of the less regularizing effect of the viscosity on the solutions. Recently, Li-Pan-Zhu [11] have obtained the local existence of the classical solutions to system (1) in 2D space under

    δ1=1,δ2=0 or 1,α>0,α+β0, (8)

    and (6), where the vacuum cannot appear in any local point. They [12] also prove the same existence result in 3D space under

    (ρ,u)(ˉρ,0)as|x|, (9)

    with initial vacuum appearing in some open set or the far field, the constant ˉρ0 and

    1<δ1=δ2min(3,γ+12),α>0,α+β0. (10)

    We also refer readers to [3], [6], [10], [13], [18], [26] and references therein for other interesting progress for this compressible degenerate system, corresponding radiation hydrodynamic equations and magnetohydrodynamic equations.

    It should be noted that one should not always expect the global existence of solutions with better regularities or general initial data because of Xin's results [23] and Rozanova's results [20]. It was proved that there is no global smooth solutions to (1), if the initial density has nontrivial compact support (1D) or the solutions are highly decreasing at infinity(dD, d1). These motivate us to find the blow-up mechanisms and singularity structures of the solutions.

    For constant viscosity, Beale-Kato-Majda [1] first proved that the maximum norm of the vorticity controls the blow-up of the smooth solutions to 3D incompressible Euler equations

    limTTT0|curlu|dt=, (11)

    where T is the maximum existence time. Later, for the same problem, Ponce [19] proved that the maximum norm of the deformation tensor controls the blow-up of the smooth solutions

    limTTT0|D(u)|dt=, (12)

    where the deformation tensor D(u)=12(u+(u)). Huang-Li-Xin [7] proved that the criterion (12) holds for the strong solutions to the system (1). Sun-Wang-Zhang [22] proved that the upper bound of the density controls the blowup of the strong solution to the system (1). There are some other interesting results about infinite time blowup and finite time blowup results on the nonlinear wave equation with different initial energy levels, refer to [14], [15], [24] and references therein for detailed study.

    When the viscosities depend on density in the form of (4), S. Zhu [25] introduced the regular solutions, which can be defined as

    Definition 1.1. [25] Let T>0 be a finite constant, (ρ,u) is called a regular solution to the Cauchy problem (1) with (5)-(6) on [0,T]×R3 if (ρ,u) satisfies

    (A)(ρ,u)  in [0,T]×R3  satisfies the Cauchy problem (1)with (5)(6)in the sense of distributions;(B)ρ0,ργ12C([0,T];H2), (ργ12)tC([0,T];H1);(C)logρC([0,T];D1), (logρ)tC([0,T];L2);(D)uC([0,T];H2)L2([0,T];D3), utC([0,T];L2)L2([0,T];D1).

    The local existence of the regular solutions has been obtained by Zhu [25].

    Theorem 1.2. [25] Let 1<γ2 or γ=3. If the initial data (ρ0,u0) satisfies the regularity conditions

    ργ1200,(ργ120,u0)H2,logρ0D1, (13)

    then there exist a small time T and a unique regular solution (ρ,u) to the Cauchy problem (1) with (5)-(6). Moreover, we also have ρ(t,x)C([0,T]×R3) and

    ρC([0,T];H2),ρtC([0,T];H1).

    Based on Theorem 1.2, we establish the blow-up criterion for the regular solution in terms of logρ and the deformation tensor D(u), which is similar to the Beale-Kato-Majda criterion for the ideal incompressible Euler equations and the compressible Navier-Stokes equations.

    Theorem 1.3. Let (ρ,u) be a regular solution obtained in Theorem 1.2. Then if ¯T<+ is the maximal existence time, one has both

    limT¯T(sup0tT|logρ|6+T0|D(u)| dt)=+, (14)

    and

    limsupT¯TT0D(u)LD1,6 dt=+. (15)

    The rest of the paper can be organized as follows. In Section 2, we will give the proof for the criterion (14). Section 3 is an appendix which will present some important lemmas which are frequently used in our proof, and also give the detail derivation for the desired system used in our following proof.

    In this section, we give the proof for Theorem 1.3. We use a contradiction argument to prove (14), let (ρ,u) be the unique regular solution to the Cauchy problem (1) with (5)-(6) and the maximal existence time ¯T. We assume that ¯T<+ and

    limT¯T(sup0tT|logρ|6+T0|D(u)|dt)=C0<+ (16)

    for some constant 0<C0<. If we prove that under assumption (16), ¯T is actually not the maximal existence time for the regular solution, there will be a contradiction, thus (14) holds.

    Notice that, one can also prove (15) by contradiction argument. Assume that

    limsupT¯TT0D(u)LD1,6 dt=C0<+ (17)

    for some constant 0<C0<. Combing (17) with the mass equation, we know that

    limT¯Tsup0tT|logρ|6CC0,

    which implies that under assumption (17), we have (16). Thus, if we prove that (14) holds, then (15) holds immediately.

    In the rest part of this section, based on the assumption (16), we will prove that ˉT is not the maximal existence time for the regular solution.

    From the definition of the regular solution, we know for

    ϕ=ργ12,ψ=2γ1logϕ, (18)

    (ϕ,ψ,u) satisfies

    {ϕt+uϕ+γ12ϕdivu=0,ψt+(uψ)+divu=0,ut+uu+2θϕϕ+Lu=ψQ(u), (19)

    where L is the so-called Lamˊe operator given by

    Lu=div(α(u+(u))+βdivuI3), (20)

    and terms (Q(u),θ) are given by

    Q(u)=α(u+(u))+βdivuI3,θ=Aγγ1. (21)

    See our appendix for the detailed process of the reformulation.

    For (19)2, we have the equivalent form

    ψt+3l=1Allψ+Bψ+divu=0. (22)

    Here Al=(a(l)ij)3×3 (i,j,l=1,2,3) are symmetric with a(l)ij=u(l) when i=j; and a(l)ij=0, otherwise. B=(u), so (22) is a positive symmetric hyperbolic system. By direct computation, one knows

    ψ=2γ1ϕϕ=2γ1ργ12ργ12=ρρ=logρ, (23)

    combing this with (16), one has ψL([0,T];L6).

    Under (16) and (19), we first show that the density ρ is uniformly bounded.

    Lemma 2.1. Let (ρ,u) be the unique regular solution to the Cauchy problem (1) with (5)-(6) on [0,¯T)×R3 satisfying (16). Then

    ρL([0,T]×R3)+ϕL([0,T];Lq)C,0T<¯T,

    where C>0 depends on C0, constant q[2,+] and ¯T.

    Proof. First, it is obvious that ϕ can be represented by

    ϕ(t,x)=ϕ0(W(0,t,x))exp(γ12t0divu(s,W(s,t,x))ds), (24)

    where WC1([0,T]×[0,T]×R3) is the solution to the initial value problem

    {ddtW(t,s,x)=u(t,W(t,s,x)),0tT,W(s,s,x)=x, 0sT, xR3.

    Then it is clear that

    ϕL([0,T]×R3)|ϕ0|exp(CC0)C. (25)

    Similarly,

    ρL([0,T]×R3)C. (26)

    Next, multiplying (19)1 by 2ϕ and integrating over R3, we get

    ddt|ϕ|22C|divu||ϕ|22, (27)

    from (16), (27) and the Gronwall's inequality, we immediately obtain

    ϕL([0,T];L2)C. (28)

    Combing (25)-(28) together, one has

    ϕL([0,T];Lq)C,q[2,+].

    We complete the proof of this lemma.

    Before go further, notice that

    |ϕ|6=|ϕlogϕ|6=2γ1|ϕlogρ|6C|ϕ||logρ|6C, (29)

    where we have used (16) and Lemma 2.1. Next, we give the basic energy estimates on u.

    Lemma 2.2. Let (ρ,u) be the unique regular solution to the Cauchy problem (1) with (5)-(6) on [0,¯T)×R3 satisfying (16). Then

    sup0tT|u(t)|22+T0|u(t)|22dtC,0T<¯T,

    where C only depends on C0 and ¯T.

    Proof. Multiplying (19)3 by 2u and integrating over R3, we have

    ddt|u|22+2R3(α|u|2+(α+β)(divu)2)dx=R32(uuuθϕ2u+ψQ(u)u)dx:L1+L2+L3. (30)

    The right-hand side terms can be estimated as follows.

    L1=R32uuudxC|divu||u|22,L2=2R3θϕ2divudxC|ϕ|22|divu|C|divu|,L3=R32ψQ(u)udxC|ψ|6|u|2|u|3C|u|2|u|122|u|122α2|u|22+C|u|2|u|2α|u|22+C|u|22, (31)

    where we have used (16), (23) and the facts

    |u|3C|u|122|u|122. (32)

    Thus (30) and (31) yield

    ddt|u|22+α|u|22C(|divu|+1)|u|22+C|divu|. (33)

    By the Gronwall's inequality, (16) and (33), we have

    |u(t)|22+t0|u(s)|22dsC,0tT. (34)

    This completes the proof of this lemma.

    The next lemma provides the key estimates on ϕ and u.

    Lemma 2.3. Let (ρ,u) be the unique regular solution to the Cauchy problem (1) with (5)-(6) on [0,¯T)×R3 satisfying (16). Then

    sup0tT(|u(t)|22+|ϕ(t)|22)+T0(|2u|22+|ut|22)dtC,0T<¯T,

    where C only depends on C0 and ¯T.

    Proof. Multiplying (19)3 by Luθϕ2 and integrating over R3, we have

    12ddtR3(α|u|2+(α+β)|divu|2)dx+R3(Luθϕ2)2 dx=αR3(uu)×curlu dx+R3(2α+β)(uu)divu dx+θR3(ψQ(u))ϕ2dxθR3(uu)ϕ2 dx+R3(ψQ(u))Lu dxθR3utϕ2 dx≡:9i=4Li, (35)

    where we have used the fact that

    u+divu=curl(curlu)=×curlu.

    First, from the standard elliptic estimate shown in Lemma 3.3, we have

    |2u|22C|θϕ2|22C|div(α(u+(u))+βdivuI3)|22C|θϕ2|22C|div(α(u+(u))+βdivuI3)θϕ2|22=CR3(Luθϕ2)2dx. (36)

    Second, we estimate the right-hand side of (35) term by term. According to

    {u×curlu=12(|u|2)uu,×(a×b)=(b)a(a)b+(divb)a(diva)b,

    Hölder's inequality, Young's inequality, (16), (23), (29), Lemma 2.2, Lemma 3.1 and (19)1, one can obtain that

    |L4|=α|R3(u)u×curlu dx|=α|R3(curlu×((u)u))dx|=α|R3(curlu×(u×curlu))dx|=α|R3(12|curlu|2divucurluD(u)curlu)dx|C|u||u|22,|L5|=|R3(2α+β)(u)udivu dx||R3(2α+β)(u:udivu+12(divu)3)dx|+C|ϕ|6|u|3|u|2|divu|C(|u|22|divu|+|u|122|u|122|u|2|divu|)C(|u|22+|u|2|u|2)|divu|C|divu|(|u|22+1),L6=θR3(ψQ(u))ϕ2 dxC|ψ|6|u|3|ϕ2|2C|u|122|2u|122|ϕ|2|ϕ|C|ϕ|22+C(ϵ)|u|22+ϵ|2u|22,|L7|=θ|R3(uu)ϕ2dx|=θ|R3u:(u)ϕ2dxR3ϕ2u(divu)dx| (37)
    =θ|R3u:(u)ϕ2dx+R3(divu)2ϕ2dx+R2uϕ2divu dx|C(|u|22|ϕ2|+|u|2|ϕ|2|ϕ||divu|)C(|u|22+|divu||ϕ|2)C(|u|22+|divu|+|divu||ϕ|22),L8=R3(ψQ(u))Lu dxC|ψ|6|u|3|2u|2C|2u|322|u|122C(ϵ)|u|22+ϵ|2u|22,L9=θR3utϕ2dx=θR3ϕ2divut dx=θddtR3ϕ2divu dxθR3(ϕ2)tdivu dx=θddtR3ϕ2divu dxθR32ϕϕtdivu dx=θddtR3ϕ2divu dx+θR3uϕ2divu dx+θ(γ1)R3ϕ2(divu)2dxθddtR3ϕ2divu dx+C(|u|2|ϕ|2|ϕ||divu|+|u|22|ϕ2|)θddtR3ϕ2divu dx+C(|ϕ|2|divu|+|u|22)θddtR3ϕ2divu dx+C(|u|22+|divu|+|divu||ϕ|22), (38)

    where ϵ>0 is a sufficiently small constant. Thus (35)-(38) imply

    12ddtR3(α|u|2+(α+β)|divu|22θϕ2divu)dx+C|2u|22C((|u|22+|ϕ|22)(|divu|+1)+|divu|). (39)

    Third, applying to (19)1 and multiplying by (ϕ), we have

    (|ϕ|2)t+div(|ϕ|2u)+(γ2)|ϕ|2divu=2(ϕ)u(ϕ)(γ1)ϕϕdivu=2(ϕ)D(u)(ϕ)(γ1)ϕϕdivu. (40)

    Integrating (40) over R3, we get

    ddt|ϕ|22C(ϵ)(|D(u)|+1)|ϕ|22+ϵ|2u|22. (41)

    Adding (41) to (39), from the Gronwall's inequality and (16), we immediately obtain

    α|u(t)|222θR3ϕ2divu dx+C|ϕ(t)|22+t0|2u(s)|22dsC,

    that is

    α|u(t)|22+C|ϕ(t)|22+t0|2u(s)|22dsC+2θR3ϕ2divu dxC(1+|u|2|ϕ|2|ϕ|)C+α4|u(t)|22,

    which implies

    |u(t)|22+|ϕ(t)|22+t0|2u(s)|22dsC,0tT.

    Finally, due to ut=Luuu2θϕϕ+ψQ(u), we deduce that

    t0|ut|22dsCt0(|2u|22+|u|23|u|26+|ϕ|2|ϕ|22+|u|23|ψ|26)dsC.

    Thus we complete the proof of this lemma.

    Next, we proceed to improve the regularity of ϕ, ψ and u. First, we start with the estimates on the velocity.

    Lemma 2.4. Let (ρ,u) be the unique regular solution to the Cauchy problem (1) with (5)-(6) on [0,¯T)×R3 satisfying (16). Then

    sup0tT(|ut(t)|22+|u(t)|D2)+T0|ut|22dtC,0T<¯T, (42)

    where C only depends on C0 and ¯T.

    Proof. From the standard elliptic estimate shown in Lemma 3.3 and

    Lu=utuu2θϕϕ+ψQ(u), (43)

    one has

    |u|D2C(|ut|2+|uu|2+|ϕϕ|2+|ψQ(u)|2)C(|ut|2+|u|6|u|3+|ϕ|3|ϕ|6+|ψ|6|u|3)C(1+|ut|2+|u|6|u|122|2u|122+|u|122|2u|122)C(1+|ut|2+|2u|122)C(1+|ut|2)+12|u|D2, (44)

    where we have used Sobolev inequalities, (16), (23), (29) and Lemmas 2.1-2.3. Then we immediately obtain that

    |u|D2C(1+|ut|2). (45)

    Next, differentiating (19)3 with respect to t, it reads

    utt+Lut=(uu)t2θ(ϕϕ)t+(ψQ(u))t. (46)

    Multiplying (46) by ut and integrating over R3, one has

    12ddt|ut|22+α|ut|2212ddt|ut|22+R3(α|ut|2+(α+β)|divut|2)dx=R3((uu)tut+(ψQ(u))tut2θ(ϕϕ)tut)dx:12i=10Li. (47)

    Similarly, based on (16), (23), (29) and Lemmas 2.1-2.3, we estimate the right-hand side of (47) term by term as follows.

    L10=R3(uu)tut dx=R3((utu)ut+(uut)ut)dx=R3(utD(u)ut12(ut)2divu)dxC|D(u)||ut|22,L11=R3(ψQ(u))tut dx=R3ψQ(u)tut dx+R3ψtQ(u)ut dx=R3ψQ(u)tut dxR3divuQ(u)ut dx+R3uψdiv(Q(u)ut)dxC(|ψ|6|ut|2|ut|3+|2u|2|Q(u)||ut|2+|ψ|6|u|6|2u|2|ut|6+|ψ|6|u|6|Q(u)|6|ut|2)C(|ut|2|ut|122|ut|122+|2u|2|Q(u)||ut|2+|u|6|ut|2+|2u|2|ut|2)α8|ut|22+C(1+|D(u)|)(|ut|22+|u|2D2),L12=R32θ(ϕϕ)tut dx=θR3(ϕ2)tdivutdx=2θR3ϕϕtdivutdx=2θR3ϕ(uϕ+γ12ϕdivu)divutdx=θR3(uϕ2+(γ1)ϕ2divu)divutdx (48)
    =θ(γ1)2R3ϕ2(divu)2tdxθR3uϕ2divutdx=θ(γ1)2ddtR3ϕ2(divu)2dx+θ(γ1)R3uϕϕt(divu)2dxθR3uϕ2divutdx=θ(γ1)2ddtR3ϕ2(divu)2dxθ(γ1)R3uϕ(uϕ)(divu)2dxθ(γ1)22R3uϕ2(divu)3dxθR3uϕ2divutdx=θ(γ1)2ddtR3ϕ2(divu)2dx+θ(γ1)2R3uϕ2(divu)2dx+θ(γ1)(3γ)2R3ϕ2(divu)3dxθR3uϕ2divutdxθ(γ1)2ddtR3ϕ2(divu)2dx+C(|u||ϕ|2|u|2|2u|2+|ϕ|2|D(u)||u|22+|ϕ||ϕ|2|u||ut|2)θ(γ1)2ddtR3ϕ2(divu)2dx+C(|u|||2u|2+|D(u)|+|u||ut|2) (49)
    θ(γ1)2ddtR3ϕ2(divu)2dx+α4|ut|22+C(1+|D(u)|+|u|2D2), (50)

    where we also used Hölder's inequality, Young's inequality and

    |u|C|u|W1,3C(|u|122|u|122+|u|12|2u|12). (51)

    It is clear from (47)-(50) and (45) that

    ddt(|ut|22+|ϕdivu|22)+|ut|22C(1+|2u|2+|D(u)|)|ut|22. (52)

    Integrating (52) over (τ,t) (τ(0,t)), we have

    |ut(t)|22+|ϕdivu(t)|22+tτ|ut(s)|22ds|ut(τ)|22+|ϕdivu(τ)|22+Ctτ((1+|2u|2+|D(u)|)|ut|22)(s)ds. (53)

    From the momentum equations (19)3, we obtain

    |ut(τ)|2C(|uu|2+|ϕϕ|2+|Lu|2+|ψQ(u)|2)(τ)C(|u||u|2+|ϕ||ϕ|2+|u|D2+|ψ|6|u|3)(τ), (54)

    which, together with the definition of regular solution, gives

    limsupτ0|ut(τ)|2C(|u0||u0|2+|ϕ0||ϕ0|2+|u0|D2+|ψ0|6|u0|3)C0. (55)

    Letting τ0 in (53), applying the Gronwall's inequality, (16) and Lemma 2.3, we arrive at

    |ut(t)|22+|u(t)|2D2+t0|ut(s)|22dsC,0tT. (56)

    This completes the proof of this lemma.

    The following lemma gives bounds of ϕ and 2u.

    Lemma 2.5. Let (ρ,u) be the unique regular solution to the Cauchy problem (1) with (5)-(6) on [0,¯T)×R3 satisfying (16). Then

    sup0tT(ϕ(t)W1,6+|ϕt(t)|6)+T0|u(t)|2D2,6dtC,0T<¯T, (57)

    where C only depends on C0 and ¯T.

    Proof. First, taking q=6 in Lemma 2.1, combing with (29) we have

    sup0tTϕ(t)W1,6C,0T<¯T.

    Second, one has

    |ϕt|6=|uϕ+γ12ϕdivu|6C(|ϕ|6|u|+|ϕ||divu|6)C, (58)

    where we have used Lemmas 2.3-2.4 and (29).

    Third, according to

    Lu=utuu2θϕϕ+ψQ(u), (59)

    and the standard elliptic estimate shown in Lemma 3.3, one has

    |2u|6C(|ut|6+|uu|6+|ϕϕ|6+|ψQ(u)|6)C(|ut|2+|u||u|6+|ϕ||ϕ|6+|ψ|6|Q(u)|)C(1+|ut|2+|D(u)|142|D(u)|346)C(1+|ut|2+|2u|346)C(1+|ut|2)+12|2u|6, (60)

    where we have used (16), (23), (29), Lemmas 2.1-2.4 and

    |divu|C|D(u)|,|D(u)|C|D(u)|142|D(u)|346. (61)

    Thus, (60) implies that

    |2u|6C(1+|ut|2). (62)

    Combing (62) with Lemma 2.4, one has

    t0|u(s)|2D2,6dsCt0(1+|ut(s)|22)dsC,0tT. (63)

    The proof of this lemma is completed.

    Lemma 2.5 implies that

    t0|u(,s)|dsC, (64)

    for any t[0,¯T) with C>0 a finite number. Noting that (19) is essentially a parabolic-hyperbolic system, it is then standard to derive other higher order estimates for the regularity of the regular solutions. We will show this fact in the following lemma.

    Lemma 2.6. Let (ρ,u) be the unique regular solution to the Cauchy problem (1) with (5)-(6) on [0,¯T)×R3 satisfying (16). Then

    sup0tT(|ϕ(t)|2D2+|ψ(t)|2D1+ϕt(t)21+|ψt(t)|22)+T0(|u(t)|2D3+|ϕtt(t)|22)dtC,0T<¯T,

    where C only depends on C0 and ¯T.

    Proof. From (19)3 and Lemma 3.3, we have

    |u|D3C(|ut|D1+|uu|D1+|ϕϕ|D1+|ψQ(u)|D1)C(|ut|D1+|u||2u|2+|u|6|u|3+|ψ|6|2u|3+|ϕ|6|ϕ|3+|ϕ||2ϕ|2+|ψ|2|D(u)|)C(1+|ut|D1+|ϕ|D2+|u|12D3+|ψ|D1|D(u)|)C(1+|ut|D1+|ϕ|D2+|ψ|D1|D(u)|)+12|u|D3, (65)

    where we have used Young's inequality, Lemma 2.5, (16), (23), (29) and (61). Thus (65) offers that

    |u|D3C(1+|ut|D1+|ϕ|D2+|D(u)||ψ|D1). (66)

    Next, applying i (i=1,2,3) to (19)2 with respect to x, we obtain

    (iψ)t+3l=1Alliψ+Biψ+idivu=(i(Bψ)+Biψ)+3l=1(i(Al)lψ). (67)

    Multiplying (67) by 2(iψ), integrating over R3, and then summing over i, noting that Al (l=1,2,3) are symmetric, it is not difficult to show that

    ddt|ψ|22CR3(|divA||ψ|2+|3u||ψ|+|ψ|2|u|+|i(Bψ)Biψ||ψ|)dxC(|divA||ψ|22+|3u|2|ψ|2+|ψ|22|u|+|i(Bψ)Biψ|2|ψ|2), (68)

    where divA=3l=1lAl. When |ζ|=1, choosing r=2, a=3, b=6 in (83), we have

    |i(Bψ)Biψ|2=|Dζ(Bψ)BDζψ|2C|2u|3|ψ|6C|2u|122|3u|122C|3u|122. (69)

    Thus

    ddt|ψ|22C(|u||ψ|22+|3u|2|ψ|2+|3u|122|ψ|2). (70)

    Combining (70) with (66) and Lemma 3.1, we have

    ddt|ψ|2D1C(1+|u|)|ψ|2D1+C(1+|3u|2)|ψ|D1C(1+|u|)|ψ|2D1+C(1+|ϕ|2D2+|ut|22). (71)

    On the other hand, let ϕ=G=(G(1),G(2),G(3)). Applying 2 to (19)1, we have

    0=(G)t+(uG)+(Gu)+γ12(Gdivu+ϕdivu), (72)

    similarly to the previous step, we multiply (72) by 2G and integrate it over R3 to derive

    ddt|G|2D1CR3(|2u||G|+|u||G|+|ϕ||2u|+|ϕ||3u|)|G|dxC(|G|6|2u|3+|u||G|2+|ϕ||3u|2)|G|2C(|2u|122|3u|122+|u||G|D1+|u|D3)|G|D1C(|u|12D3+|u|D3)|G|D1+C|u||G|2D1C(1+|u|D3)|G|D1+C|u||G|2D1C(1+|ut|D1+|ϕ|D2+|D(u)||ψ|2)|G|D1+C|u||G|2D1C(1+|ut|D1+|u||ψ|D1)|G|D1+C(1+|u|)|G|2D1C(1+|u|)(|G|2D1+|ψ|2D1)+C(1+|ut|22), (73)

    where we have used the Young's inequality, (29) and (66). This estimate, together with (71), gives that

    ddt(|G|2D1+|ψ|2D1)C(1+|u|)(|G|2D1+|ψ|2D1)+C(1+|ut|22). (74)

    Then the Gronwall's inequality, (42), (64) and (74) imply

    |ϕ(t)|2D2+|ψ(t)|2D1C,0tT. (75)

    Combing (75) with (66) and Lemma 2.4, one has

    t0|u(s)|2D3dsCt0(1+|ut(s)|22)dsC,0tT. (76)

    Finally, using the following relations

    ψt=(uψ)divu,   ϕt=uϕγ12ϕdivu,ϕtt=utϕuϕtγ12ϕtdivuγ12ϕdivut, (77)

    according to Hölder's inequality, (16), (29), Lemmas 2.1-2.5, one has

    |ψt|2C(|uψ|2+|uψ|2+|divu|2)C(|u|3|ψ|6+|u||ψ|2+|2u|2)C,|ϕt|2C(|uϕ|2+|ϕdivu|2)C(|u||ϕ|2+|ϕ||u|2)C,|ϕt|2C(|(uϕ)|2+|(ϕdivu)|2)C(|uϕ|2+|2ϕu|2+|ϕdivu|2+|ϕdivu|2)C(|u|3|ϕ|6+|u||2ϕ|2+|ϕ|6|u|3+|ϕ||2u|2)C,|ϕtt|2C(|utϕ|2+|uϕt|2+|ϕtdivu|2+|ϕdivut|2)C(|ut|6|ϕ|3+|u||ϕt|2+|ϕt|6|u|3+|ϕ||ut|2)C(1+|ut|2). (78)

    Thus

    sup0tT(ϕt(t)21+|ψt(t)|22)C,

    and according to (42), one has

    T0|ϕtt(t)|22dtT0(1+|ut(t)|22)dtC.

    The proof of this lemma is completed.

    Now we know from Lemmas 2.1-2.6 that, if the regular solution (ρ,u)(x,t) exists up to the time ¯T>0, with the maximal time ¯T<+ such that the assumption (16) holds, then

    (ργ12,logρ,u)|t=¯T=limt¯T(ργ12,logρ,u)

    satisfies the conditions imposed on the initial data (13). If we solve the system (1) with the initial time ¯T, then Theorem 1.1 ensures that (ρ,u)(x,t) extends beyond ¯T as the unique regular solution. This contradicts to the fact that ¯T is the maximal existence time. We thus complete the proof of Theorem 1.3.

    In this subsection, we present some important lemmas which are frequently used in our previous proof. The first one is the well-known Gagliardo-Nirenberg inequality, which can be found in [9].

    Lemma 3.1. [9] Let r(1,+) and  hW1,p(R3)Lr(R3). Then the following inequality holds for some constant C(c,p,r)

    |h|qC|h|cp|h|1cr, (79)

    where

    c=(1r1q)(1r1p+13)1,0c1. (80)

    If p<3, then q[r,3p3p] when r<3p3p; and q[3p3p,r] when r3p3p. If p=3, then q[r,+). If p>3, then q[r,+].

    Some common versions of this inequality can be written as

    |f|3C|f|122|f|122,|f|6C|f|2,|f|C|f|142|f|346, (81)

    which have be used frequently in our previous proof.

    The second one can be found in Majda [17], and we omit its proof.

    Lemma 3.2. [17] Let positive constants r, a and b satisfy the relation

    1r=1a+1b

    and 1a, b, r+. s1, if f,gWs,a(R3)Ws,b(R3), then we have

    |Ds(fg)fDsg|rCs(|f|a|Ds1g|b+|Dsf|b|g|a), (82)
    |Ds(fg)fDsg|rCs(|f|a|Ds1g|b+|Dsf|a|g|b), (83)

    where Cs>0 is a constant depending only on s, and sf means that the set of all elements of ζf with |ζ|=s.

    The third one is on the regularity estimates for Lamˊe operator. For the elliptic problem

    {αΔu(α+β)divu=f,u0as |x|+, (84)

    one has

    Lemma 3.3. [21] If uDk,q with 1<q<+ is a weak solution to the problem (84), then

    |u|Dk+2,qC|f|Dk,q, (85)

    where k is an integer and the constant C>0 depend on α,β and q. Moreover, if uDk,q is a weak solution to the following problem

    Δu=f,u0as |x|+, (86)

    then (85) holds and if f=divg, we also have

    |u|D1,qC|g|Lq. (87)

    The proof can be obtained via the classical estimates from harmonic analysis, which can be found in [21] or [22]. We omit it here.

    Now we show that, via introducing new variables

    ϕ=ργ12,ψ=logρ=2γ1ϕ/ϕ, (88)

    the system (1) can be rewritten as

    {ϕt+γ12ϕdivu+uϕ=0,ψt+(uψ)+divu=0,ut+uu+2θϕϕ+Lu=ψQ(u). (89)

    Proof. First, from the momentum equation, one has

    ρut+ρuu+Pρdiv(α(u+u)+βdivuI3)=ρ[α(u+u)+βdivuI3],

    where P=Aργ, divide both side by ρ, one has

    ut+uu+Aγργ2ρdiv(α(u+u)+βdivuI3)=ρρ[α(u+u)+βdivuI3].

    Denote

    Lu=div(α(u+u)+βdivuI3),Q(u)=α(u+u)+βdivuI3,θ=Aγγ1,

    we have

    ut+uu+2θϕϕ+Lu=ψQ(u). (90)

    Second, for ψ=logρ, one has

    ψt=(logρ)t=(logρ)t=(ρtρ)=(div(ρu)ρ)=(ρuρdivuρ)=(logρu+divu)=divuu(logρ)logρu=divuuψψu=divu(uψ). (91)

    Third, for ϕ=ργ12, one has

    ϕt=(ργ12)t=γ12ργ32ρt=γ12ργ12ρtρ=γ12ργ12div(ρu)ρ=γ12ϕρdivuρuρ=γ12ϕdivuuϕ. (92)

    Combing (90)-(92) together, we complete the proof of the transformation.

    The author sincerely appreciates Dr. Shengguo Zhu for his very helpful suggestions and discussions on the problem solved in this paper. The research of Y. Cao was supported in part by China Scholarship Council 201806230126 and National Natural Science Foundation of China under Grants 11571232.

    Conflict of Interest: The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.



    [1] Adam AM (2020) Susceptibility of stock market returns to international economic policy: Evidence from effective transfer entropy of Africa with the implication for open innovation. J Open Innov Technol Mark Complex 6: 71. https://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc6030071 doi: 10.3390/joitmc6030071
    [2] Agyei SK (2022) Diversification benefits between stock returns from Ghana and Jamaica: Insights from time-frequency and VMD-based asymmetric quantile-on-quantile analysis. Math Probl Eng 2022: 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1155/2022/9375170 doi: 10.1155/2022/9375170
    [3] Agyei SK (2023) Emerging markets equities' response to geopolitical risk: Time-frequency evidence from the Russian-Ukrainian conflict era. Heliyon 9: e13319. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2023.e13319 doi: 10.1016/j.heliyon.2023.e13319
    [4] Agyei SK, Adam AM, Bossman A, et al. (2022a) Does volatility in cryptocurrencies drive the interconnectedness between the cryptocurrencies market? Insights from wavelets. Cogent Econ Financ 10: 2061682. https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2022.2061682 doi: 10.1080/23322039.2022.2061682
    [5] Agyei SK, Isshaq Z, Frimpong S, et al. (2021) COVID‐19 and food prices in sub‐Saharan Africa. Afr Dev Rev 33: S102-S113. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8268.12525 doi: 10.1111/1467-8268.12525
    [6] Agyei SK, Owusu Junior P, Bossman A, et al. (2022b). Spillovers and contagion between BRIC and G7 markets: New evidence from time-frequency analysis. PLoS ONE 17: e0271088. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0271088 doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0271088
    [7] Aharon DY, Umar Z, Vo XV (2021) Dynamic spillovers between the term structure of interest rates, bitcoin, and safe‑haven currencies. Financ Innov 7: 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-021-00274-w doi: 10.1186/s40854-021-00274-w
    [8] Ahmad AH, Aworinde OB (2021) Fiscal and external deficits nexus in GIIPS countries: Evidence from parametric and nonparametric causality tests. Int Adv Econ Res 27: 171–184. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11294-021-09829-0 doi: 10.1007/s11294-021-09829-0
    [9] Algieri B (2013) An empirical analysis of the nexus between external balance and government budget balance: The case of the GIIPS countries. Econ Syst 37: 233–253. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecosys.2012.11.002 doi: 10.1016/j.ecosys.2012.11.002
    [10] Algieri B (2014) Drivers of export demand: A focus on the GIIPS countries. World Econ 37: 1454–1482. https://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12153 doi: 10.1111/twec.12153
    [11] Andreas K (2020) Twitter and traditional news media effect on Eurozone's stock market. International Hellenic University.
    [12] Andrikopoulos A, Samitas A, Kougepsakis K (2014) Volatility transmission across currencies and stock markets: GIIPS in crisis. Appl Financ Econ 24: 1261–1283. https://doi.org/10.1080/09603107.2014.925054 doi: 10.1080/09603107.2014.925054
    [13] Apergis N, Chi M, Lau K, et al. (2016) Media sentiment and CDS spread spillovers: Evidence from the GIIPS countries. Int Rev Financ Anal 47: 50–59. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2016.06.010 doi: 10.1016/j.irfa.2016.06.010
    [14] Armah M, Amewu G, Bossman A (2022) Time-frequency analysis of financial stress and global commodities prices: Insights from wavelet-based approaches. Cogent Econ Financ 10: 2114161. https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2022.2114161 doi: 10.1080/23322039.2022.2114161
    [15] Asafo-Adjei E, Adam AM, Darkwa P (2021) Can crude oil price returns drive stock returns of oil producing countries in Africa? Evidence from bivariate and multiple wavelet. Macroecon Financ Emerg Mark Econ, 1–19. https://doi.org/10.1080/17520843.2021.1953864 doi: 10.1080/17520843.2021.1953864
    [16] Asafo-Adjei E, Agyapong D, Agyei SK, et al. (2020) Economic policy uncertainty and stock returns of Africa: A wavelet coherence analysis. Discrete Dyn Nat Soc 2020: 1–8. https://doi.org/10.1155/2020/8846507 doi: 10.1155/2020/8846507
    [17] Asafo-Adjei E, Bossman A, Boateng E, et al. (2022) A nonlinear approach to quantifying investor fear in stock markets of BRIC. Math Probl Eng 2022: 1–20. https://doi.org/10.1155/2022/9296973 doi: 10.1155/2022/9296973
    [18] Baur DG, Lucey BM (2010) Is gold a hedge or a safe haven? An analysis of stocks, bonds and gold. Financ Rev 45: 217–229. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6288.2010.00244.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6288.2010.00244.x
    [19] Beetsma R, Giuliodori M, de Jong F, et al. (2013) Spread the news: The impact of news on the European sovereign bond markets during the crisis. J Int Money Financ 34: 83–101. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2012.11.005 doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2012.11.005
    [20] Bossman A (2021) Information flow from COVID-19 pandemic to Islamic and conventional equities: An ICEEMDAN-induced transfer entropy analysis. Complexity 2021: 1–20. https://doi.org/10.1155/2021/4917051 doi: 10.1155/2021/4917051
    [21] Bossman A, Adam AM, Owusu Junior P, et al. (2022a) Assessing interdependence and contagion effects on the bond yield and stock returns nexus in Sub-Saharan Africa: Evidence from wavelet analysis. Sci Afr 16: e01232. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.sciaf.2022.e01232 doi: 10.1016/j.sciaf.2022.e01232
    [22] Bossman A, Agyei SK (2022a) ICEEMDAN-based transfer entropy between global commodity classes and African equities. Math Probl Eng 2022: 1–28. https://doi.org/10.1155/2022/8964989 doi: 10.1155/2022/8964989
    [23] Bossman A, Agyei SK (2022b) Interdependence structure of global commodity classes and African equity markets: A vector wavelet coherence analysis. Resour Policy 79: 103039. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2022.103039 doi: 10.1016/j.resourpol.2022.103039
    [24] Bossman A, Agyei SK, Owusu Junior P, et al. (2022b) Flights-to-and-from-quality with Islamic and conventional bonds in the COVID-19 pandemic era: ICEEMDAN-based transfer entropy. Complexity 2022: 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1155/2022/1027495 doi: 10.1155/2022/1027495
    [25] Bossman A, Agyei SK, Umar Z, et al. (2023) The impact of the US yield curve on sub-Saharan African equities. Financ Res Letters, 103636. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.frl.2023.103636 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2023.103636
    [26] Bossman A, Owusu Junior P, Tiwari AK (2022c) Dynamic connectedness and spillovers between Islamic and conventional stock markets: time- and frequency-domain approach in COVID-19 era. Heliyon 8: e09215. https://doi.org/10.1016/J.HELIYON.2022.E09215 doi: 10.1016/J.HELIYON.2022.E09215
    [27] Bossman A, Teplova T, Umar Z (2022d) Do local and world COVID-19 media coverage drive stock markets? Time-frequency analysis of BRICS. Complexity 2022: 2249581. https://doi.org/10.1155/2022/2249581 doi: 10.1155/2022/2249581
    [28] Bossman A, Umar Z, Agyei SK, et al. (2022e) A new ICEEMDAN-based transfer entropy quantifying information flow between real estate and policy uncertainty. Res Econ, 189–205. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rie.2022.07.002 doi: 10.1016/j.rie.2022.07.002
    [29] Bouri E, Lien D, Roubaud D, et al. (2018) Fear linkages between the US and BRICS stock markets: A frequency-domain causality. Int J Econ Bus 25: 441–454.
    [30] Chiang S, Liu W, Suardi S, et al. (2021) United we stand divided we fall: The time-varying factors driving European Union stock returns. J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 71: 101316. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intfin.2021.101316 doi: 10.1016/j.intfin.2021.101316
    [31] de Vries T, de Haan J (2016) Credit ratings and bond spreads of the GIIPS. Appl Econ Lett 23: 107–111. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2015.1054063 doi: 10.1080/13504851.2015.1054063
    [32] Dergiades T, Milas C, Panagiotidis T (2015) Tweets, Google trends, and sovereign spreads in the GIIPS. Oxford Econ Pap 67: 406–432. https://doi.org/10.1093/oep/gpu046 doi: 10.1093/oep/gpu046
    [33] Ewaida HYM (2017) The impact of sovereign debt on growth: An empirical study on GIIPS versus JUUSD countries. Eur Res Stud J 20: 607–633.
    [34] Fama EF (1970) Efficient Market Hypothesis: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work. J Financ 25: 383–417.
    [35] Fernández-Macho J (2012) Wavelet multiple correlation and cross-correlation: A multiscale analysis of Eurozone stock markets. Phys A 391: 1097–1104. https://doi.org/10.1016/J.PHYSA.2011.11.002 doi: 10.1016/J.PHYSA.2011.11.002
    [36] Flavin TJ, Lagoa-varela D (2019) On the stability of stock-bond comovements across market conditions in the Eurozone periphery. Global Financ J December 2018: 100491. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gfj.2019.100491 doi: 10.1016/j.gfj.2019.100491
    [37] Forbes KJ, Rigobon R (2001) Measuring contagion: conceptual and empirical issues. Int Financ Contagion, 43–66. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4757-3314-3_3 doi: 10.1007/978-1-4757-3314-3_3
    [38] Forbes KJ, Rigobon R (2002) No contagion, only interdependence: Measuring stock market comovements. J Financ 57: 2223–2261. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00494 doi: 10.1111/0022-1082.00494
    [39] Frimpong S, Gyamfi EN, Ishaq Z, et al. (2021) Can global economic policy uncertainty drive the interdependence of agricultural commodity prices? Evidence from partial wavelet coherence analysis. Complexity. https://doi.org/10.1155/2021/8848424 doi: 10.1155/2021/8848424
    [40] He X, Gokmenoglu KK, Kirikkaleli D, et al. (2021) Co-movement of foreign exchange rate returns and stock market returns in an emerging market: Evidence from the wavelet coherence approach. Int J Financ Econ 2020: 1–12. https://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.2522 doi: 10.1002/ijfe.2522
    [41] Heryán T, Ziegelbauer J (2016) Volatility of yields of government bonds among GIIPS countries during the sovereign debt crisis in the Euro area. Q J Econ Econ Policy 11: 62–74.
    [42] Islam R, Volkov V (2021) Contagion or interdependence? Comparing spillover indices. Empir Econ 63: 1403–1455. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-021-02169-2 doi: 10.1007/s00181-021-02169-2
    [43] Kamaludin K, Sundarasen S, Ibrahim I (2021) Covid-19, Dow Jones and equity market movement in ASEAN-5 countries: evidence from wavelet analyses. Heliyon 7: e05851.
    [44] Karanasos M, Yfanti S, Hunter J (2022) Emerging stock market volatility and economic fundamentals: the importance of US uncertainty spillovers, financial and health crises. Ann Oper Res 313: 1077–1116. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-021-04042-y doi: 10.1007/s10479-021-04042-y
    [45] Kenourgios D, Umar Z, Lemonidi P (2020) On the effect of credit rating announcements on sovereign bonds: International evidence. Int Econ 163: 58–71. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.inteco.2020.04.006 doi: 10.1016/j.inteco.2020.04.006
    [46] Lee H (2021) Time-varying comovement of stock and treasury bond markets in Europe: A quantile regression approach. Int Rev Econ Financ 75: 1–20. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2021.03.020 doi: 10.1016/j.iref.2021.03.020
    [47] Lo AW (2004) The adaptive markets hypothesis. J Portf Manage 30: 15–29.
    [48] Magnus N, Blikstad D (2018) The GIIPS crisis in the context of the European Monetary Union: a political economy approach. Brazilian Keynesian Rev 4: 224–249.
    [49] Morlet J, Arens G, Fourgeau E, et al. (1982) Wave propagation and sampling theory - Part Ⅰ: Complex signal and scattering in multilayered media. Geophysics 47: 203–221. https://doi.org/10.1190/1.1441328 doi: 10.1190/1.1441328
    [50] Muller UA, Dacorogna MM, Dav RD, et al. (1997) Volatilities of different time resolutions - Analyzing the dynamics of market components. J Empir Financ 4: 213–239.
    [51] Nazlioglu S, Altuntas M, Kilic E, et al. (2021) Purchasing power parity in GIIPS countries: evidence from unit root tests with breaks and non-linearity. Appl Econ Anal 30: 176–195. https://doi.org/10.1108/AEA-10-2020-0146 doi: 10.1108/AEA-10-2020-0146
    [52] Owusu Junior P, Adam AM, Asafo-Adjei E, et al. (2021) Time-frequency domain analysis of investor fear and expectations in stock markets of BRIC economies. Heliyon 7: e08211. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2021.e08211 doi: 10.1016/j.heliyon.2021.e08211
    [53] Owusu Junior P, Frimpong S, Adam AM, et al. (2021) COVID-19 as information transmitter to global equity markets: Evidence from CEEMDAN-based transfer entropy approach. Math Probl Eng 2021: 1–19. https://doi.org/10.1155/2021/8258778 doi: 10.1155/2021/8258778
    [54] Rapach DE, Strauss JK, Zhou G (2013) International stock return predictability: what is the role of the United States? J Financ 68: 1633–1662.
    [55] Reichlin P (2020) The GIIPS Countries in the Great Recession: Was it a Failure of the Monetary Union? Luiss School of European Political Economy.
    [56] Riaz Y, Shehzad CT, Umar Z (2020) The sovereign yield curve and credit ratings in GIIPS. Int Rev Financ 21: 895–916. https://doi.org/10.1111/irfi.12306 doi: 10.1111/irfi.12306
    [57] Rua A, Nunes LC (2009) International comovement of stock market returns: A wavelet analysis. J Empir Financ 16: 632–639. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jempfin.2009.02.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jempfin.2009.02.002
    [58] Sarwar G, Khan W (2017) The effect of US stock market uncertainty on emerging market returns. Emerg Mark Financ Trade 53: 1796–1811.
    [59] Shahzad SJH, Bouri E, et al. (2022) The hedge asset for BRICS stock markets: Bitcoin, gold or VIX. World Econ 45: 292–316. https://doi.org/10.1111/TWEC.13138 doi: 10.1111/TWEC.13138
    [60] Silva N (2021) Information transmission between stock and bond markets during the Eurozone debt crisis: evidence from industry returns. Spanish J Financ Account 50: 381–394. https://doi.org/10.1080/02102412.2020.1829422 doi: 10.1080/02102412.2020.1829422
    [61] Torrence C, Compo GP (1998) A Practical Guide to Wavelet Analysis. Bull Am Meteorol Soc 79: 61–78. https://doi.org/10.1175/1520-0477 doi: 10.1175/1520-0477
    [62] Torrence C, Webster PJ (1999) Interdecadal changes in the ENSO-Monsoon system. J Clim 12: 2679–2690. https://doi.org/10.1175/1520-0442(1999)012<2679:ICITEM>2.0.CO;2 doi: 10.1175/1520-0442(1999)012<2679:ICITEM>2.0.CO;2
    [63] Umar Z, Bossman A, Choi S, et al. (2023) The relationship between global risk aversion and returns from safe-haven assets. Financ Res Lett 51: 103444. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2022.103444 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2022.103444
    [64] Umar Z, Bossman A, Choi S, et al. (2022a) Are short stocks susceptible to geopolitical shocks? Time-Frequency evidence from the Russian-Ukrainian conflict. Financ Res Lett, 103388. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2022.103388 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2022.103388
    [65] Umar Z, Gubareva M, Teplova T, et al. (2022b) Oil price shocks and the term structure of the US yield curve: a time-frequency analysis of spillovers and risk transmission. Ann Oper Res, 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-022-04786-1 doi: 10.1007/s10479-022-04786-1
    [66] Umar Z, Gubareva M, Yousaf I, et al. (2021) A tale of company fundamentals vs sentiment driven pricing: The case of GameStop. J Behav Exp Financ 30: 100501. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2021.100501 doi: 10.1016/j.jbef.2021.100501
  • QFE-07-01-005-s001.pdf
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Xiaoqiang Dai, Wenke Li, Non-global solution for visco-elastic dynamical system with nonlinear source term in control problem, 2021, 29, 2688-1594, 4087, 10.3934/era.2021073
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(2110) PDF downloads(159) Cited by(7)

Figures and Tables

Figures(6)  /  Tables(3)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog