Research article

A survey comparative analysis of cartesian and complexity science frameworks adoption in financial risk management of Zimbabwean banks

  • Received: 06 May 2022 Revised: 11 June 2022 Accepted: 17 June 2022 Published: 21 June 2022
  • JEL Codes: G15, G23, F36

  • Traditionally, financial risk management is examined with cartesian and interpretivist frameworks. However, the emergence of complexity science provides a different perspective. Using a structured questionnaire completed by 120 Risk Managers, this paper pioneers a comparative analysis of cartesian and complexity science theoretical frameworks adoption in sixteen Zimbabwean banks, in unique settings of a developing country. Data are analysed with descriptive statistics. The paper finds that overally banks in Zimbabwe are adopting cartesian and complexity science theories regardless of bank size, in the same direction and trajectory. However, adoption of cartesian modeling is more comprehensive and deeper than complexity science. Furthermore, due to information asymmetries, there is diverging modeling priorities between the regulator and supervisor. The regulator places strategic thrust on Knightian risks modeling whereas banks prioritise ontological, ambiguous and Knightian uncertainty measurement. Finally, it is found that complexity science and cartesianism intersect on market discipline. From these findings, it is concluded that complexity science provides an additional dimension to quantitative risk management, hence an integration of these two perspectives is beneficial. This paper makes three contributions to knowledge. First, it adds valuable insights to theoretical perspectives on Quantitative Risk Management. Second, it provides empirical evidence on adoption of two theories from developing country perspective. Third, it offers recommendations to improve Quantitative Risk Management policy formulation and practice.

    Citation: Gilbert Tepetepe, Easton Simenti-Phiri, Danny Morton. A survey comparative analysis of cartesian and complexity science frameworks adoption in financial risk management of Zimbabwean banks[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(2): 359-384. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022016

    Related Papers:

    [1] David Kuo Chuen Lee, Chia Mei Shih, Jincheng Zheng . Asian CBDCs on the rise: An in-depth analysis of developments and implications. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(4): 665-696. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023032
    [2] Dilvin Taşkın, Görkem Sarıyer . Use of derivatives, financial stability and performance in Turkish banking sector. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(2): 252-273. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020012
    [3] Larysa Dokiienko, Nataliya Hrynyuk, Igor Britchenko, Viktor Trynchuk, Valentyna Levchenko . Determinants of enterprise's financial security. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(1): 52-74. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024003
    [4] Tram Thi Xuan Huong, Tran Thi Thanh Nga, Tran Thi Kim Oanh . Liquidity risk and bank performance in Southeast Asian countries: a dynamic panel approach. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(1): 111-133. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021006
    [5] Raymond J. Hawkins, Hengyu Kuang . Lending Sociodynamics and Drivers of the Financial Business Cycle. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(3): 219-252. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.3.219
    [6] Dimitra Loukia Kolia, Simeon Papadopoulos . The levels of bank capital, risk and efficiency in the Eurozone and the U.S. in the aftermath of the financial crisis. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(1): 66-90. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020004
    [7] Iuliana Matei . Is financial development good for economic growth? Empirical insights from emerging European countries. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(4): 653-678. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020030
    [8] Oleg Sukharev, Ekaterina Voronchikhina . Financial and non-financial investments: comparative econometric analysis of the impact on economic dynamics. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(3): 382-411. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020018
    [9] Mohammed Yaw Broni, Mosharrof Hosen, Mansur Masih . Does a country’s external debt level affect its Islamic banking sector development? Evidence from Malaysia based on Quantile regression and Markov regime-switching. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2019, 3(2): 366-389. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2019.2.366
    [10] Md Qamruzzaman, Wei Jianguo . Investigation of the asymmetric relationship between financial innovation, banking sector development, and economic growth. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(4): 952-980. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.4.952
  • Traditionally, financial risk management is examined with cartesian and interpretivist frameworks. However, the emergence of complexity science provides a different perspective. Using a structured questionnaire completed by 120 Risk Managers, this paper pioneers a comparative analysis of cartesian and complexity science theoretical frameworks adoption in sixteen Zimbabwean banks, in unique settings of a developing country. Data are analysed with descriptive statistics. The paper finds that overally banks in Zimbabwe are adopting cartesian and complexity science theories regardless of bank size, in the same direction and trajectory. However, adoption of cartesian modeling is more comprehensive and deeper than complexity science. Furthermore, due to information asymmetries, there is diverging modeling priorities between the regulator and supervisor. The regulator places strategic thrust on Knightian risks modeling whereas banks prioritise ontological, ambiguous and Knightian uncertainty measurement. Finally, it is found that complexity science and cartesianism intersect on market discipline. From these findings, it is concluded that complexity science provides an additional dimension to quantitative risk management, hence an integration of these two perspectives is beneficial. This paper makes three contributions to knowledge. First, it adds valuable insights to theoretical perspectives on Quantitative Risk Management. Second, it provides empirical evidence on adoption of two theories from developing country perspective. Third, it offers recommendations to improve Quantitative Risk Management policy formulation and practice.



    This study focuses on comparing the adoption of cartesian and complexity science frameworks in quantitative risk management of Zimbabwean banks. Precisely this research pioneers a comparison of traditional and modern theoretical perspectives of financial risk management in the unique settings of Zimbabwe, a developing country contrary to extant studies that focus on developed economies. First the study advances the theory of cartesianism emanating from classical science and finance theories such as Efficient Market Hypothesis (Fama, 1970), Modern Portfolio Theory (Markowitz, 1952), Capital Asset Pricing Model (Sharpe, 1964), Option Pricing Theory (Black and Scholes, 1973; Merton, 1974) and Arbitrage Pricing Theory (Ross, 1976). Second it advances complexity economics theory following Knight (1921), Hayek (1964), Diebold et al, (2010), Ganegoda and Evans (2014), Haldane, (2016); Flage and Aven (2015), Aven (2017), Mazri (2017) and Tepetepe et al., (2021). The objectives of this paper are to test and compare the adoption of these two theories using a survey. The paper answers these research questions: (a) What are the theoretical perspectives for quantitative financial risk management? (b) What are static and complexity science frameworks? (c) What are the similarities and differences in the adoption of cartesian and complexity science theoretical frameworks in financial risk management of Zimbabwean banks? (d) Is there any point of intersection and complementarity for these two theories? The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 focuses on the literature review focusing on cartesian, interpretivist and complexity science theories. Section 3 documents the survey research methodology that was applied. Section 4 provides the comparative analysis of survey results, discussion, and recommendations. Section 5 provides the conclusion and areas of further research.

    This section provides a literature review on three theoretical frameworks namely cartesian, interpretivist and complexity science that influence the definition of risk, practice, and policy formulation for quantitative risk management in banks.

    Cartesian or traditional financial risk management is founded on bedrock of classical science and neoclassical financial economics theories. Its basis are assumptions of closed systems, stability, rational expectations, ordered states, Gaussian normality, independence, homogeneity, optimisation, equilibrium, and absence of information asymmetries (Muth, 1961; Arthur, 2013; Ganegoda and Evans, 2014; Hull, 2018; Plosser and Santos, 2018). Under this view risk is the magnitude of deviation from the target, measurable with objective probabilities (Knight, 1921; Keynes, 1921; Gebizlioglu and Dhaene, 2009; Sweeting, 2011; McNeil et al., 2015; Pichler, 2017). Thus, it is possible to manage risks with linear and reductionist "best practices" based on laws of probability and available historical data (Ganegoda and Evans, 2014; Aven, 2017).

    According to cartesian theory the whole is the sum of its parts (Arthur, 2021). As such to understand closed systems, one needs to decompose them into components which are studied in isolation. The aggregation of these components forms the whole. Cartesianism is identified with nomenclatures such as positivism, post positivism, conventional economics, reductionism, conventional science, and scientific objectivism (Arthur, 2021). Proponents of cartesianism believe that risks are factual and measurable. Hence, they uphold a scientific constructivism claim of the existence of standard solutions for risk management problems (Dowd and Hutchinson, 2014). To them quantitative risk management is essentially founded on mechanistic Newtonian science and classical financial theories such as Efficient Market Hypothesis (Fama, 1970), Modern Portfolio Theory (Markowitz, 1952), Capital Asset Pricing Model (Sharpe, 1964), Option Pricing Theory (Black and Scholes, 1973; Merton, 1974) and Arbitrage Pricing Theory (Ross, 1976).

    The cartesian belief is the reason for the proliferation of static frameworks, books and financial regulations that tries to offer standard solutions and practices on bank risk management (Sweeting, 2011; McNeil, et al., 2015). These static frameworks focus on specified resilience modeling and silo risk analysis (Sweeting, 2011; Morin, 2014; Cavallo, 2014; McNeil et al., 2015). In general, these frameworks are founded on principles of establishing context, risk assessment, risk identification, risk analysis, evaluation, monitoring, communication, and consultation (Sweeting, 2011; Cavallo, 2014). Three types of static frameworks exist (Sweeting, 2011). First, advisory risk management frameworks are neither compulsory nor legislative but provides generic guidelines of capital management for example, Risk Analysis and Management for Projects (RAMP), the COSO ERM Integrated Framework, the Treasury Board of Canada Integrated Risk Management Framework, the Orange Book, etc. Second, proprietary risk management frameworks are provided by credit rating agencies for instance the Fitch's Standard and Poor & Moody's for the institution's debtholders and investors. Third, mandatory risk management frameworks are compulsory and regulatory for example Basel Ⅲ in banks and Solvency Ⅱ in insurance.

    Static frameworks promote linear, and fact-based risk management principally based on the doctrine of Gaussian distribution Value at Risk modeling (Dowd and Hutchison, 2014). Therefore, by applying these frameworks present cartesian risk management in banks focuses predominantly on Knightian risks which are less severe in magnitude. However, in the real financial world, standard solutions do not exist because sometimes risks are emergent and unknown (Dowd and Hutchison, 2014). Hence the elegant modeling methods offered by static frameworks are not applicable to complex systems where standard solutions do not exist (Sornette, 2003; Helbing, 2013; Cavallo, 2014, Bolton et al., 2020). Arthur (2021) criticise cartesian risk management for producing elegant but unrealistic financial engineering models based on deductive logic which ignores other uncertainties. Several studies highlight that, cartesian risk management also suffers from the illusion of risk control, treating risk preferences as exogenous events, and omitting ethics (Taleb, 2007; Allan et al., 2013; Motet and Bieder, 2017; Righi et al., 2019). Dowd et al., (2011) argues that the cartesian paradigm failed practically during the 2008 great financial crisis where banks that had adopted Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ flimsy Value at risk doctrine of quantitative finance in Europe and United States of America were hit the most. Farmer et al., (2012) and Arthur (2021) highlights that cartesian paradigm offers no solution to current challenges that violate rational expectation theory and those emanating from emerging operational risks such as climate, technological, geopolitical, societal, health and economic risks. As such some authors are demanding for a new paradigm to complement standard finance and risk management (Sornette, 2003; Blume and Durlauf, 2006; Hellbing, 2013; Cavallo, 2014; Battiston, et al., 2016a; Arthur, 2021). These argue that financial risk management will be effective if static and dynamic frameworks are integrated. Strong critics of cartesianism are calling for its radical elimination in favour of either laissez faire banking or complexity science (Haldane, 2009; Dowd et al., 2011; Farmer, et al., 2012; Dowd and Hutchison, 2014). They argue that a laissez faire banking system through competition promotes higher capital ratios, better risk management and financial stability.

    To find the state of cartesian frameworks adoption, this paper focuses more on Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ than other frameworks because it is mandatory in Zimbabwean banks and provides straightforward quantitative risk management methods under Pillar 1. Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ provides various risk weighted asset modeling approaches divided into two types. First, the simple standardised approaches where the key parameters are fixed and given by supervisor (Zimbabwe Basel Ⅱ Technical Guidelines, 2011). These include the modified standardised approach (MSA) for assessing credit risk, alternative standardised approach (ASA) for operational risk and standardised approach (SA) for market risk. The simpler approaches are designed specifically for smaller banks with simpler financial models. Currently, Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ proposes the replacement of Value at Risk methods for market risk with expected shortfall (BCBS, 2017). Second, the internal modeling approaches where banks are conditionally allowed to determine their own parameters. There are two internal rating-based approaches for credit risk modeling. Under the foundation internal ratings-based approach (FIRB) approach banks estimate probabilities of default for each borrower but are given other parameters by supervisor, while under the advanced internal ratings-based approach (AIRB) banks also estimate other parameters, such as loss given default and exposure at default on their own. The asset correlation is provided by the supervisor in all cases. Operational risk is calculated with the advanced measurement approach (AMA) and market risk is forecasted with internal models' approach (IMA). The latest method for operational risk modeling is the standardised measurement approach (SMA). Adoption of internal modeling is theoretically supposed to result in the convergence of regulatory and economic capital thus reducing regulatory arbitrage and promoting financial stability (BCB, 2006; Zimbabwe Basel Ⅱ Technical Guidelines, 2011)

    Interpretivists view risk as the subjective perception of individuals based on their personal experience, social beliefs, subjective notions, and culture. Thus, risk is qualitative and can be quantified by subjective or Bayesian probabilities (Bayes and Price, 1763; Ramsey, 1926; Shackle, 1949; Savage, 1954; Aven, 2017; Righi et al., 2019). Interpretivists reject notions of objectivity, certainty in knowledge, rational expectations, subject centred reasoning, and referential use of language (Beck, 1992; Cavallo, 2014; Morin, 2014). Policy makers prefer qualitative risk management because it is more accessible, easily understood, and requires no mathematical competence. Interpretivism explains the proliferation of qualitative frameworks and books on bank risk management (Sweeting, 2011). Table 1 shows the differences between cartesian, interpretivist risk and complexity science risk management.

    Table 1.  Cartesian, interpretivist and complexity science risk management.
    Dimension of contrast Traditional Modern Neo-modernism
    Philosophy Cartesianism/Reductionism Interpretivism Complexity science/Holism
    Epistemology Risk is an event analysed primarily at individual levels in silos or elements Risk is a social and subjective phenomenon Risk is holistic phenomenon analysed as a whole
    Expectations Rational expectations Irrational Irrational, adaptive, and evolutionary expectations
    Logic Deduction Induction Abductive (Induction & deduction)
    Risk preferences They are given and unexplained Risk preferences, perceptions and responses are learned Risk preferences are learned and adaptive
    Risk quantification Risk is objectively quantifiable Risk is subjectively quantifiable Risk is both objectively and subjectively quantifiable
    System Stable and closed Any type of system Dynamic and open system
    Risk Responses Mitigate negative events Probe, sense and respond qualitatively to mitigate negative events Probe, sense and respond Build safe operating space
    Ethics Ethics are omitted Ethics are integral to risk management Ethics are integral to risk management
    Modeling tools Quantitative (Basis is Central Limit Theorem) Qualitative Complexity science / algorithmic modeling

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Table 1 provides brief descriptions on the similarities and differences of cartesian, interpretivist and complexity science financial risk management. The descriptions are obtained from analysis of Cavallo, (2014); Righi et al., (2019); and Arthur, (2021).

    Complexity science is part of neo-modernism which provides an opportunity to understand non-linear, evolutionary, dynamic, and self-organising systems (Zimmerman, 1999). Neo-modernism combines cartesian and interpretivists' views of risk management (Althaus, 2005; Righi, et al., 2019). Risk is hence an integration of definitions from multiple disciplines such as mathematics, science, economics, finance, engineering, medicine, arts, humanities, philosophy, and information technology (Althaus, 2005). Complexity science is an interdisciplinary approach providing a pluralistic view of the world (Newman, 2011; Mitchell, 2009; Arthur, 2013; Farmer, 2015; Haldane, 2016; Li et al., 2018; Li and Evans, 2019; Tepetepe et al., 2021). It is an epistemological position where the whole is not the sum of its parts dating back to Aristotle's views. Decomposing a complex system into individual components destroys the system's properties (Bruno et al., 2016).

    In physics, biology, chemistry, medicine, and engineering sciences complexity science is used to examine complex adaptive systems such as condensed matter, natural ecosystems, immune systems, internet of things, nervous systems, and ant colonies. In economics complexity science is rooted in Adam Smith's laissez faire and Pareto's laws (Anderson, 1972; Arthur, 2013). It is used to examine economies, financial systems, and organisations. In most social sciences the approach is used to analyse culture, organisational behaviour, crowds, society, and population dynamics. Complexity science is a multidisciplinary approach, framework, theory, and philosophy (Mitleton-Kelly, 2003). Researchers term it the "new economic thinking", "new scientific way", "new discipline", "new world view" and "complexity economics." It is an abductive approach providing an alternative and challenge to classical economics and science (Senge, 1990; Mitleton-Kelly, 2003; Haldane, 2009; Famer, 2012; Morin, 2014; Cavallo, 2014; Allan et al., 2013; Bolton et al., 2020).

    There is no universal definition for complex systems. Holmes (2021) define complex systems on basis of two characteristics (a) heterogeneity and (b) non-linearity. Heterogeneity means that many interconnected agents interact in a complex system. Non-linearities leads into multiple equilibria and as such small changes at micro level amplifies and lead to critical transitions or tipping points at macro-level. A complex adaptive system is an open, living, and dynamic system characterised by heterogenous agents, no central control and simple rules of operation that give rise to collective behaviour, sophisticated information processing, and adaptation via learning or evolution (Mitleton-Kelly, 2003; Mitchell, 2009; Baranger, 2010; Newman, 2011). According to Arthur (2013) complexity science is the study of the consequences of interactions; patterns, or structures, or phenomena, that emerge from interactions among elements-particles, or cells, or dipoles, or agents, or firms.

    Fundamentally, economics answers the problems of allocation and formation (Arthur, 2013). Classical financial modeling whether it uses Newtonian science or traditional economics theories; focuses on the allocation problem (Arthur, 2021). However, these traditional models work poorly in providing solutions to questions of formation, exploration, adaptation, and qualitative change which are complex systems (Tabb, 1999). This is because problems of formation are "hard to predict" and, in many cases, unpredictable due to emergence, chaos, and creative destruction (Schumpeter, 1912; Arthur, 2021). According to Allan et al., (2013) complexity science is (a) a discipline of seeing wholes, (b) a framework for seeing interrelationships, patterns, and networks; and (c) a methodology to see both the forest and trees. Recent empirical studies affirm that financial risks are complex adaptive systems (Allan et al, 2013; Farmer et al., 2012; Corrigan et al., 2013; Li and Evans, 2019). However, most of these empirical studies concentrate on risks in banking and insurance companies of developed economies such as United States, Europe, and Australia. This paper concentrates on the unique settings of a developing country.

    Complexity economists assume that financial risks are complex systems characterised by heterogenous agents, self-organisation, emergence, adaptation, non-linearity, far from equilibrium, space of possibilities, co-evolution, historicity and time, path dependence and creation of new order (Mitleton-Kelly, 2003; Gros, 2011; Corrigan et al., 2013; Turner and Baker, 2019). Heterogenous agents in the financial system exist in form of multiple banks, regulators, insurance companies, asset managers, stock markets, pensions, and employees (Li and Evans, 2019). These agents are learning, evolving, and adapting to changing beliefs, norms, culture, perceptions, history, and physiology of the system leading to feedback processes such as tipping points, self-fulfilling processes, and creation of new order.

    Broadly speaking, financial risks emanate, exist, and evolve in complex systems. First, many researchers argue that the economic systems out of which risks emanate are complex systems (Hommes, 2001; Blume and Durlauf, 2006; Haldane and May, 2011; Haldane, 2012; Farmer, 2012; Arthur, 2013; Battiston et al., 2016a; Li, 2017). Second, many studies reveal that institutions such as banks, and insurance companies are both economic and social organisations classified as complex adaptive systems (Allan et al., 2013; Mitchell, 2009; Kremer, 2012; Battiston et al., 2016b). Third, risks in banks are managed by human beings, who are influenced by cultural perceptions of organisations and individuals. Organisations and culture are regarded as complex adaptive systems (Mitleton-Kelly, 2003; Ingram and Thompson, 2011; Thompson, 2018).

    Financial risks exist in multiple states. This refers to space of possibilities implying that unpredictability is due to intertwined and non-linear relationships. Additionally, financial risks are multidimensional. The classification of risks into four realms is testament to multidimensional existence. All the dimensions of financial risks interact and influence each other. Non-linearity means small changes emanating from interrelationships, networks, interconnections, and feedback loops among heterogenous agents have larger effects on the system. Financial risks are non-linear, interrelated, networked and systemic as shown by difficulties in delineating boundaries between Basel Ⅲ market, credit, and operational risks (Corrigan et al., 2013, Battiston et al., 2016a; BCBS, 2017).

    One key assumption is that financial risks display emergent and evolutionary behaviour. Emergence is the "unpredictable surprise" emanating from random behaviour and interaction of agents. Evolution implies that there are always novel risks whose impact are highly catastrophic. This leads into unforeseen, new, and unexpected behaviours whose "causes and effects" cannot be understood by analysing the system's components (Pagel et al., 2007; Aven, 2017). Historicity and time imply that there is path dependence and unique histories for each risk and bank. This means that agents take context specific decisions that violates best practice and "one size fit all" treatments such as those proposed by cartesian frameworks for example Basel Ⅲ (Li, 2017). Path dependence is also called sensitivity to initial conditions. Simply, this means a small difference in starting values can result in significantly different trajectories. New risks are always emerging disrupting existing patterns. Banks have structure and hierarchy but few leverage points such that risks self-organise. Given these properties of financial risks, complexity science theory provides a robust framework to understand financial risk management in a hyperconnected world (Farmer, 2012; Allan et al., 2013; Battiston et al., 2016b). According to Gross (2011) complexity science is the best method of integrating and combining the language of uncertainty, positivist, and interpretivist views of risk.

    Having outlined the complexity adaptive nature of financial risks, this section proposes a holistic dynamic four realm risk classification framework. The proposed framework is based on Knight (1921), Hayek (1964), Diebold et al, (2010), Ganegoda and Evans (2014), Flage and Aven (2015), Aven (2017), Mazri (2017) and Tepetepe et al., (2021) theory of risk and uncertainty. The foundation of this theoretical direction is Knight (1921)'s distinction between risk and uncertainty. According to Knight (1921) risk is measurable uncertainty where the probability and future outcomes are known whereas Knightian uncertainty is the immeasurable risk where there is either limited or no knowledge about the events but depends on intuition, judgement, and experience. Ellseberg (1961), in support classifies random variables into known (certain) and unknown (uncertain) probability distributions. The four realms are Knightian risk, Knightian Uncertainty, Ambiguous Uncertainty and Ontological Uncertainty. These realms are interconnected and overlaid upon each other (Ganegoda and Evans, 2014). Quantitative Risk Managers and executives can use this framework to classify risks for strategic modeling and decision-making purposes.

    Knightian risk is the state of familiar or fully emerged risks (Mazri, 2017). Risks in this realm are well known by risks managers hence are quantifiable with cartesian theoretical frameworks because there is adequate knowledge of probability distributions and future outcomes. Traditional statistical modeling and Newtonian mechanistic approaches are suitable due to the existence of adequate theory, models, and data (Ganegoda and Evans, 2014; Fadina and Schmidt, 2019). Gaussian distributions through random walks or martingale theories are normally used to estimate these risks (Hull, 2018). According to Mikes (2005) themes for Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ capital modeling such as Silo and Integrated Risk Management draw heavily from the concept of Knightian risk. Furthermore, standard solutions and best practice are used to deal with this realm (Snowden and Boone, 2007).

    Knightian uncertainty is the realm of epistemic uncertainty where objective probabilities are difficult or impossible to compute. While risk managers have the knowledge about possible future states, they cannot measure their underlying probabilities with accuracy because of insufficient data, lack of well-developed theory and models, wild randomness, and presence of high degree unique events (Mandelbrot and Taleb, 2007; Ganegoda and Evans, 2014; Mousavi and Gigerenzer, 2014; Beissner and Riedel, 2016; Burzoni et al., 2021). Mazri (2017) calls Knightian uncertainty the realm of scientifically controversial risks. To deal with this realm Quantitative Risk Managers should employ novel practice such as investing in knowledge, fractal market hypothesis, scenario analysis and stress testing, and complexity science (Mandelbrot and Hudson, 2004; Allan et al., 2013; Ganegoda and Evans, 2014; Haldane, 2016).

    Ambiguous uncertainty refers to risks that emanate from psychological reactions of human participants that operate the financial systems. Ganegoda and Evans (2014) argue that in environments governed by human beings, possible future states are vaguely defined. This ambiguity emanates from free-will, irrational behaviour, adaptive and cognitive biases. This psychological behaviour, termed "animal spirits" is manifested in selfish, greed, and inhumane acts that leads to incomplete information and unpredictability (Keynes, 1921; Shefrin and Statman, 1985; De Bondt and Thaler, 1985; Shefrin, 2010). Contrary to the Efficient Market Hypothesis, ambiguity imply that financial markets are imperfect (Burzoni et al., 2017; Fadina and Schmidt, 2019). Hence the formation of asset bubbles, liquidity market crashes, scams, depressions, and long-term mispricing of assets which culminates into financial crises is attributed to human cognitive biases or neuroeconomics (Sornette and Quillon, 2012). Quantitative Risk Managers can deal with this realm by applying behavioural economics and finance, heuristics, nudging and game theory (Ganegoda and Evans, 2014; Haldane, 2016; Thaler and Sunstein, 2008).

    Ontological uncertainty is the realm of the unknown-unknowns or hidden risks (Taleb, 2007; Ganegoda and Evans, 2014; Mazri, 2017). Risks in this realm are still unknown or very novel because there is absence of knowledge, data, probability distributions and future outcomes. In some cases, the future outcomes are undefined (Bronk, 2011). To deal with this realm Quantitative Risk Managers should humble themselves, acknowledge their limitations and admit ignorance (Ganegoda and Evans, 2014). They should sense, respond, and act with emergent modeling practice and pattern- based management (Snowden, 2003; Turner and Baker, 2019). To do so they utilise a balanced mix of precaution, regular stress testing, scenario analysis, crisis management, early warning models, investing in research and knowledge, and complexity science (Allan, et al., 2013; Ganegoda and Evans, 2014; Aven, 2015; Haldane, 2017).

    This section briefly reviews complex systems modeling methods from a practitioner and strategic quantitative risk management perspective. A complete and detailed review can be found in Allan et al., (2013). Modeling techniques for complex systems are quite different from those used in cartesianism (Farmer et al., 2012). Quantitative Risk Managers can employ heuristics, behavioural economics, concept mapping, theory of critical phenomena, data mining, systems dynamic modeling, chaos theory, fuzzy set theory, possibility theory, neural networks, Bayesian networks, agent-based computation, network theory, ant colony optimisation, cellular automata, and genetic algorithms to measure and manage financial risks in banks.

    Heuristics are accurate and robust rules of thumb used to solve problems, make inferences, and learn in complex systems (Girgerenzer, 2007; Shefrin, 2010; Haldane, 2015). By using experience, gut feelings, educated guesses, intuitive judgement, stereotyping, profiling and common-sense, animals and humans solve complex problems of finding a nesting position, mate, and strategic decisions (Gigerenzer et al., 2011; Katsikopoulos, 2011; Haldane, 2015). For example, Haldane (2012) argues that dogs catch the frisbee using simpler rules of thumb than aerodynamic and complicated PhD formulae. In support empirical studies by Mousavi and Gigerenzer (2014) and Aikman et al. (2014) indicate that simple heuristics outperform complex models in uncertainty environments where there is little data and small sample sizes. Specifically, Aikman et al. (2014) compares fast frugal trees for stress testing, and Basel Ⅱ simple versus advanced credit risk modeling methods. They find that (a) simple methods outperform complex modeling methods for calculating capital requirements where there is limited data and fat tailed distributions, (b) simple indicators outperformed complex metrics for in bank failure prediction during the great financial crisis (c) fast frugal decision trees perform better than information-intensive regression techniques in bank failure prediction. Haldane (2017) thus propose the replacement of Basel Ⅲ with heuristics capital regulation based on the doctrine "less information is more" contrary to traditional quantitative finance doctrine "more information is better".

    Behavioural economics and finance provide frameworks for modeling decision making that is influenced by "animal spirits", heterogenous expectations and psychological behaviours of market agents (Farmer et al., 2012; Battiston et al., 2016b; Virigineni and Rao, 2017). To behavioural scientists' classical theories (e.g., Efficient Market Hypothesis) do not represent real world financial markets because they exclude irrational behaviour, adaptation, learning and dynamism of human agents (Lo, 2011). The adaptive market hypothesis provided by Hommes (2011) and Lo (2012) offers a theoretical framework for behavioural modeling. The theory postulates that financial markets behave like biological systems. Its assumptions are individuals in financial markets have self-interest, make mistakes, learn, and adapt (Farmer and Lo, 1999; Farmer, 2002; Lo, 2004; Lo, 2012). Competition in banks drive adaptation and innovation. Evolutionary principles such as competition, natural selection, adaptation, reproduction, and interactions control financial markets. Therefore, quantitative risk managers that pay attention to heuristic and prospect theory biases such as overconfidence, anchoring, herding, framing, availability, representativeness, hindsight bias, mental accounting, loss aversion, and so on provide better predictions of risk and capital (Shefrin, 2010; Thaler, 2015; Barberis, 2017).

    Concept mapping is the qualitative and non-numerical representation of situations in form of mental, naïve, or folk theories that explore different aspects of a matter. Concept maps are imaged, dynamic, and outcome-based simulations used in everyday life to understand the world. Concept mapping enables the visualisation of complex and non-linear relationships between different ideas and concepts (Allan et al., 2013). Abstract or concrete concepts are denoted as nodes and their interrelationships as links. Systems dynamic modeling is causal prediction of nonlinear relationships of underlying structures of flows, delays, and feedback loops (Forrester, 1969; Bharathy and McShane, 2014). It is based on laws of motion and change, termed calculus in mathematics and mechanics in physics. Once a model is established, the system can simulate future scenarios using deterministic rules as well as random values.

    Fractal market hypothesis (FMH) provides a framework for modeling turbulence, feedback loops, jumps, discontinuity, irrational behaviour, butterfly effects, and non-periodicity that truly characterise real world financial markets (Mandelbrot, 1963; Peters, 1991; Peters, 1994; Liu and Song, 2012; Anderson and Noss, 2013; Karp and Van Vuuren, 2019). FMH provides the theoretical basis for modeling variables with wild randomness and mean reversion such as market crashes, bubbles, and natural disasters (Joshi, 2014). It is also called chaos theory. Adoption of fractal market theory demands big data and complete elimination of some current cartesian frameworks such as Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ (Ganegoda and Evans, 2014; Klioutchnikov et al., 2017). However, chaos theory is complicated because it requires significant mathematical programming (Allan et al., 2013).

    Fuzzy set theory deals with circumstances where there is ambiguous and vague information (Chaudhuri and Ghosh, 2016). Set theory, the foundation of probability theory is converted into fuzzy sets and all subsequent applications are updated to enable them to incorporate vagueness (Georgescu, 2012; Allan et al., 2013; Chaudhuri and Ghosh, 2016). When using fuzzy logic, people's qualitative descriptions and quantitative estimations are elaborated to maximise utility. Possibility theory by Zadeh(1965, 1978) is an extension of fuzzy theory. It is a subjective measure applicable in situations where there are small sample sizes, vague data, fuzzy or imprecise data, subjective elements, conflicting data, and linguistic information (Georgescu, 2012; Georgescu and Kinnunen, 2016). Chaudhuri and Ghosh (2016) apply possibility theory in operational risk modeling in a mining environment and they conclude that it calculates capital charges better than probability theory.

    Neural networks are computational methods inspired by the brain's structure, processing method, and learning abilities. A neural network or artificial neural network (ANN) is an automated nonlinear regression process (Allan et al., 2013). Bayesian Networks allow the system to perform inference and learning. Virtually a BN is a hierarchy structure with nodes cascading in layers, allowing users to visually understand the logical relationships among variables (Allan et al., 2013). Agent based modeling examines a collection of autonomous decision-making entities called agents (Bonabeau, 2002; Farmer and Foley, 2009; Haldane, 2016). It is used to model non-linear relationships, scenario analysis, feedback loops, local interactions, and externalities because they can reproduce emergent phenomena, dynamic equilibria and non-linear properties represented in complex systems (Kremer, 2012; Haldane, 2016). ABM outputs are very sensitive to initial conditions, often producing a vast space of possible outcomes which can only be understood through rigorous statistical scrutiny (Macal et al., 2013). Agent based modeling is well known for simulating agent's behaviour in four areas: flow, organisational, market, and diffusion (Bonabeau, 2002; Macal et al., 2013, Chan-Lau, 2017).

    Network theory originates from Leonhard Euler's paper on "Seven Bridges of Konigsberg", published in 1736. Network theory is based on the proposition that to some extent everything is somehow connected (Ellinas et al., 2018; Petrone and Latora, 2018). Mitchell (2006) states that under network theory an object is conceptualised as a node (or vertex) and its relationships with others as edges. A network (or graph) is simply a collection of nodes(vertices) and links (edges). The links can be directed or undirected, and weighted or unweighted. Network theory has applications in macroprudential regulation, systemic risk, measuring contagion, emerging risks, credit risks, liquidity risks and stress testing (Eisenberg and Noe, 2001; Haldane and May, 2011; Glasserman and Young, 2015; Gao et al., 2018; Soramaki and Cook, 2018; Battiston et al., 2016b; Ellinas et al., 2018).

    Ant colony optimisation (ACO) is a technique for solving combinatorial optimisation problems using ant behaviour (Dorigo et al., 1996; Dorigo, 2007). Ant colony optimization mimics techniques employed by ants when establishing the short route to a food source. An ACO algorithm consists of several cycles (iterations) of constructing a solution. During each iteration several ants (which is a parameter) construct complete solutions using heuristic information and the collected experiences of previous groups of ants. These collected experiences are represented by a digital analogue of trail pheromone which is deposited on the constituent elements of a solution. The ACO method is applicable in situations where there is self-organisation. This technique is applicable to derivatives pricing, credit risk modeling and bankruptcy prediction (Marten et al., 2010). Martens et al., (2010) applies ACO in credit risk under Basel Ⅱ, but the method is still limited to academia.

    Genetic algorithms are methods for solving both constrained and unconstrained optimisation processes based on laws of natural selection and genetics evolution (Mitchell, 2006). They are applicable where the objective function is stochastic, nonlinear, discontinuous, and non-differentiable (Holland, 2002). Genetic algorithms replicate natural evolution processes and population growth under the "survival of the fittest" principle. Risks are modelled following biological principles of selection, reproduction, and mutation of a population. This method is potentially applicable in credit scoring, stock selection, bankruptcy predictions (Allan, et al., 2013).

    Cellular automata refer to spatial modeling that explores discrete behaviour of interacting elements in a complex system using simple rules (Mitchell, 2006). The method allows analysis of emergence, diffusive, transportive and dissipative effect of risks with a bottom-up approach (Mitchell, 2006). This method is commonly applied where data is low and severity high such as natural hazard modeling of earthquakes, hurricanes, fires, terrorism, nuclear and hazardous material incidents. Phylogenetic theory is simply the theory of evolution in systematic biology. It propagates the belief that all organisms on earth descended from one common ancestor (Allan et al., 2013, Evans et al., 2017). Hence, organisms' historical patterns of descent, path dependence and evolutionary relationships can be evaluated with phylogenetic or cladistic trees using molecular, physiological, and morphological data (Allan et al., 2013). A phylogenetic tree is essentially a connected graph that shows historical pattern of ancestry, divergence, and descent. It is composed of nodes and branches which does not contain any closed structures. The nodes symbolise the organisms under investigation, whereas branches that connect all nodes represent the relationships among different organisms, in terms of their ancestry and descent relationships. This theory can be used to model history, evolution, and emergence of risks.

    This section provides an outline of the research methodology which was used for data collection and analysis. As in Tepetepe et al., (2021), a structured questionnaire was employed to collect primary data from sixteen Zimbabwean banks. The structured questionnaire was adopted because it provided factual, standard responses, and measurable data from a large sample (Zikmund, 2003; Fellegi, 2010; Babbie 2011; Saunders et al., 2019). The primary purpose for employing the survey was to obtain descriptive generalisable information and facilitate independent objective analysis (Babbie, 2011; Ponto, 2015). The questionnaire was designed to collect categorical data with a mixture of Likert scale and "yes/no" questions. The questions were designed by researchers based on theoretical constructs from cartesian and complexity science theory (Collis and Hussey, 2009; Fellegi, 2010; Saunders, et al., 2012; Easterby-Smith et al., 2015). The state of adoption was examined with level of static frameworks, four realms of uncertainty, and modeling method adoption.

    The objective of sampling in a survey strategy is to obtain a sample representative of the population (Ponto, 2015). In this study banks were divided into four strata by bank size and ownership structure into International, Pan African, Private owned and Government owned indigenous banks. The sample size was determined at 95% confidence interval using Krejcie and Morgan's (1970) table as in Sekaran (2003), Yamane's (1967), and Saunders et al. (2012) formulae. These formulae provide samples of 132,133 and 132 respectively. This led to the distribution of 160 self-administered questionnaires out of a population of 200 Risk Managers. To reduce non-response bias, questionnaires were distributed beyond those recommended by the three techniques and a follow up mail was used. 131 questionnaires were collected, representing a 75% active response rate. 120 adequately completed questionnaires were used for data analysis.

    The structured questionnaire was piloted using Babbie and Quinlan (2011)'s two stage procedure. First, academics selected from the University of Bolton and second, ten Risk Managers chosen by stratified random sampling reviewed the questionnaire for correctness and feasibility for the study (Saunders et al., 2012; Hussey and Collins, 2010). Ten risk managers were employed following Brace (2008), who states that pilot testing is successful in identifying the needed changes if few individuals up to ten are willing to complete and provide suggestions.

    Data was collected for a period of six months. The data was analysed with descriptive statistics on Statistical Package for Social Sciences (SPSS). Following Tukey (1977)'s exploratory data analysis method, the data was presented in form of form of frequency tables and bar charts (Field, 2009; Saunders et al., 2012; Hair et al., 2014).

    Validity and reliability of the structured questionnaire were measured by content validity and Cronbach's alpha. Content validity was establishing by ensuring the structured questionnaire was reviewed by academic experts from the University of Bolton and ten risk managers who participated in the pilot study (Fink, 1995; Kimberlin and Winterstein, 2008; Pallant, 2010; Mohajan, 2017). The Cronbach alpha was 0.813 which is acceptable. Hence results are regarded as valid and reliable.

    Ethical considerations in this study cover permission to conduct survey, informed consent, data privacy and confidentiality. Permission to conduct survey were obtained from the University of Bolton. Participants completed the questionnaire from informed consent where they had a right to withdraw their participation. The purpose of the research was explained to the participants by the researcher on the cover letter attached to questionnaire. The study ensured data privacy on two matters. Firstly, no reference is made to names of banks where questionnaires were distributed. Secondly, no reference is made to any individual or bank on data analysis, presentation, and discussion of outcomes.

    This section reports findings of the comparative analysis of cartesian and complexity science theoretical frameworks adoption in quantitative risk management of Zimbabwean banks. The structured questionnaire was completed by 26 percent Quantitative Risk Managers, 24 percent Credit Risk Managers, 22 percent Operational Risk Managers and 13 percent Market Risk Managers. 77 percent of the Risk Managers who participated in the survey had above three years' experience in risk management.

    A comparison of results shows that banks in Zimbabwe have adopted both cartesian and complexity science theories with the same speed and in the same direction regardless of size but under varying strengths. The strengths of adoption are higher for cartesian than complexity science frameworks adoption. In summary Figure 1 shows that Pan African, international, and local banks are moving at the same pace in adopting the four types of frameworks.

    Figure 1.  Cartesian and complexity science framework adoption.

    Particularly Figure 1 shows that Zimbabwean banks have adopted mandatory frameworks (100 percent), proprietary frameworks (89 percent), advisory frameworks (89 percent) and complexity science frameworks (40 percent). This initial assessment reveal that Quantitative Risk Management in Zimbabwean banks is predominantly cartesian in nature complying to specified resilience modeling and fact-based risk management within established standards of practice (Sweeting, 2011; Morin, 2014; Cavallo, 2014). We perform further analysis on the adoption of complexity science using four realms: Knightian risk, Knightian Uncertainty, Ambiguous Uncertainty and Ontological Uncertainty

    Table 2 shows that regardless of bank size there is significant adoption of the four-realm complexity science framework. On average 97 percent respondents show that risk managers classify risks as Knightian risks, 88 percent as ontological uncertainty, 87 percent as ambiguous uncertainty and 73 percent as Knightian uncertainty. Our conclusion is that banks in Zimbabwe are adopting both cartesian and complexity science approaches in the same direction and trajectory regardless of their size. However, cartesianism predominates the new paradigm of complexity science.

    Table 2.  Bank size and complexity science four realms of uncertainty adoption.
    Question 4 Do you utilise the below classification in quantitative risk management
    Uncertainty Realm International Pan African Private Indigenous Government indigenous
    Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No
    Ontological Uncertainty 90% 10% 89% 11% 93% 7% 80% 20%
    Ambiguous Uncertainty 93% 7% 89% 11% 90% 10% 74% 26%
    Knightian uncertainty 57% 43% 84% 16% 91% 9% 61% 39%
    Knightian risks 98% 2% 95% 5% 96% 4% 97% 3%
    Note: This table provides descriptive statistics on complexity science realms adoption in relation to bank size.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The study finds the adoption of Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ modelling methods to be more comprehensive and deeper than complexity science methods. First, the paper performs an analysis of cartesian framework adoption using Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ. The results reveal deep and comprehensive Eurocentric adoption of Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ financial engineering methods in both large (Pan African, international) and smaller domestic banks. Hence banks are adopting all types of Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ capital modeling methods regardless of size. As summarised by Table 3 the adoption of various Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ modeling methods is high. These results confirm postulations by Jones and Knaack (2019) that low-income countries sometimes adopt Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ methods to a greater extent even if they are ill-suited for them to enhance their perceived international competitive standing. On average, first, banks are compliant to credit risk modeling methods as 97 percent Modified Standardised Approach (MSA), 83 percent Advanced Internal Ratings Based Approach (AIRB), and 62 percent Foundation Internal Rating Based Approach (FIRB). Second banks are compliant to operational risk modeling methods as 88 percent Alternative Standardised Approach (ASA), 85 percent Advanced Measurement Approach (AMA), 0 percent Standardised Measurement Approach (SMA). Third banks are compliant to market risks as 100 percent standardised approach (SA) and 98 percent internal models' approach.

    Table 3.  Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ financial engineering methods adoption.
    Question 3 To what extent have you have implemented the following Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ methods for capital modeling. Choose the methods that best apply to your bank from the list below.
    Risk Type Modeling Method Level of adoption by bank type (frequencies)
    Indigenous Private Indigenous Government Owned International Pan African
    Credit MSA 100% 100% 87% 92%
    AIRB 76% 77% 67% 53%
    FIRB 40% 71% 33% 25%
    Operational ASA 90% 100% 93% 78%
    AMA 77% 74% 60% 56%
    SMA - - - -
    Market SA 68% 61% 73% 61%
    IMA 76% 87% 80% 67%
    Note: This table reports descriptive statistics on the adoption of Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ modeling methods in relation to bank size.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Second, we carry an analysis of complexity science modeling adoption. Figure, 2 shows low adoption of complexity science modeling methods. However behavioural economics & finance (90 percent), heuristics (71 percent) and concept mapping (30 percent) are adopted to a greater extent.

    Figure 2.  Complexity science modeling methods adoption.

    A comparison of the results indicates that the rate of Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ capital modeling methods adoption is higher than that of complexity science modeling methods.

    As shown in Table 4 this study empirically discovers diverging capital modeling priorities between banks and their regulator. While Zimbabwean banks place strategic thrust on general resilience modeling and pattern-based management for immeasurable and hard to predict risks in ontological, ambiguous and Knightian uncertainty realms, the regulator does the contrary. Rather the regulator prioritises specified resilience modeling and fact-based management where the modeling of Knightian risks is more important than other realms of uncertainty.

    Table 4.  Diverging modeling priorities between banks and their supervisor.
    Realm Banks' ranking Supervisor's ranking
    Ontological Uncertainty 1 4
    Ambiguous Uncertainty 2 3
    Knightian Uncertainty 3 2
    Knightian Risk 4 1
    Note: This table provides an analysis of divergence in modeling priorities between supervisor and banks.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    These divergent capital modeling views are a result of information asymmetries between banks and supervisor. Given different modeling priorities, achieving regulatory capital adequacy with cartesianism alone in Zimbabwean banks may not be possible. Thus, clinging to the cartesian paradigm might increase the probability of banks reporting overestimated or underestimated capital adequacy figures to impress and comply to supervisory demands because of peer pressure.

    Finally, the study finds that complexity science and cartesian frameworks intersect on market discipline. Hence enhancing market discipline will possibly improve financial risk management in banks.

    As previously mentioned, this study finds that both cartesian and complexity science frameworks adoption in Zimbabwean banks is moving in the same direction regardless of bank size. However, the adoption of Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ modeling methods is more comprehensive and deeper than complexity science. Furthermore, due to information asymmetries between regulator and banks, the strategic thrusts for financial risk management are different. The regulator focuses on Knightian risk modeling whereas banks prioritise ontological, ambiguous and Knightian uncertainty respectively. Lastly, the study shows that complexity science and cartesianism converges on market discipline. These results confirm Blume and Durlauf (2006), Farmer et al. (2012), Battiston et al. (2016b), Haldane (2017), Li and Evans (2019) and Arthur (2021) that complexity science provides an additional dimension to the study of quantitative risk management and its integration into mainstream financial risk management will provide possible solutions to some of the pertinent current non- Gaussian distribution challenges. Examples of current challenges are financial stability, climate risk modeling, sustainable banking, systemic risk, emerging risks, and interconnected risks. The study argues for an inclusion of uncertainty in the practice of Quantitative Risk Management.

    Based on this study's findings we propose three optional policy recommendations to improve Quantitative Risk Management in Zimbabwean banks. The first proposal entails the integration of cartesian and complexity science in financial regulation and modeling methods. It should be noted that an integration of complexity science and cartesianism, in this case is not aimed at achieving equilibrium, but obtaining maximum benefits, paradigm shift in policy making, complementary and different viewpoints from these two schools and application to suitable situations. We propose that financial modeling regulation such as Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ should be reduced to heuristic simplicity. Our recommendation is strongly inclined to laissez faire and complexity science economists who argue that "less is more". Less was more, historically in the free banking era where with few simple rules banks had higher capital adequacy of above 50 percent (Dowd and Hutchison, 2014). Currently there are more rulebooks with more pages, but capital adequacy is slightly above 12 percent. This recommendation challenges the predominantly upheld doctrine of quantitative finance "more is better" culminating in less useful excessive cartesian rulebooks for instance Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ as noted by Dowd and Hutchison (2014). Instead of providing a cure these rulebooks are characterised by "too many pages of detailed technical modeling" which perpetrate herding behaviour, regulatory gaming, complicated "geek" mathematical models, poor risk management and financial crises. Furthermore, in our view, regulation that will improve quantitative finance should embrace the ideology of nudging rather than coercion, self-regulation, and simplicity, rather than excessive complex rules. Nudges are defined as any aspect of choice architecture that alters people's behaviour in a predictable way without forbidding any options or significantly changing their economic incentives (Thaler and Sunstein, 2008, p.6). The second option is enhancing market discipline since complexity science and cartesianism intersect on market discipline. The third option is for central bank to curtail information asymmetries by accelerating its speed in embracing new standards and models of risk management.

    Traditionally, the examination of financial risk management is done with cartesian and interpretivist theories. However, the emergence of complexity science offers a different perspective. Complexity economists argue that financial risks are complex adaptive systems characterised by emergence, evolution, non-linearity, interconnectedness, chaos, irrational expectations, adaptive behaviour, and heterogeneous agents. Hence traditional methods of quantitative finance fail when assumptions of rational expectations, perfect markets, independence, perfect information, and homogeneity are violated. This paper pioneers a comparative analysis of cartesian and complexity science adoption in Zimbabwean banks, in settings of a developing country. A structured questionnaire was employed for data collection.

    First, the results suggests that both cartesian and complexity science frameworks are adopted in the same direction and at same pace by both large and domestic banks. However financial risk management is still predominantly cartesian based. Furthermore, there is evidence of deeper and comprehensive compliance to Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ modeling than complex science modeling techniques. Second, the study reveals diverging modeling priorities between the regulator and banks due to information asymmetries. Third, complexity science and cartesian frameworks converge on market discipline. Finally, this paper provides recommendations to improve Quantitative Risk Management practices and policy formulation in Zimbabwean banks. Future research should look on these two issues: (a) an examination of the impact of integrating complexity science and Basel Ⅱ/Ⅲ, and (b) analysis of the factors that enhance market discipline in Zimbabwean banks.

    Special thanks to participants in the survey and anonymous reviewers of this work.

    All authors declare no conflicts of interests in this article.



    [1] Aikman D, Galesic M, Gigerenzer G, et al. (2014) Taking uncertainty seriously: simplicity versus complexity in financial regulation. Ind Corp Change 30: 317–345. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dtaa024 doi: 10.1093/icc/dtaa024
    [2] Allan N, Cantle N, Godfrey P (2013) A review of the use of complex systems applied to risk appetite and emerging risks in ERM practice: Recommendations for practical tools to help risk professionals tackle the problem of risk appetite and emerging risks. Brit Actuar J 18: 163–234. https://doi.org/10.1017/S135732171200030X doi: 10.1017/S135732171200030X
    [3] Allen F, Gale D (2000) Financial Contagion. J Polit Econ 108: 1–33. https://doi.org/10.1086/262109 doi: 10.1086/262109
    [4] Althaus CE (2005) A disciplinary perspective on the epistemological status of risk. Risk Anal 25: 567–588. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1539-6924.2005.00625.x doi: 10.1111/j.1539-6924.2005.00625.x
    [5] Anagnostou I, Sourabh S, Kandhai D (2018) Incorporating Contagion in Portfolio Credit Risk Models using Network Theory. Complexity 2018. https://doi.org/10.1155/2018/6076173 doi: 10.1155/2018/6076173
    [6] Anderson N, Noss J (2013) The Fractal Market Hypothesis and its implications for the stability of financial markets. Available from: https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/-/media/boe/files/financial-stability-paper/2013/the-fractal-market-hypothesis-and-its-implications-for-the-stability-of-financial-markets.pdf?la=en&hash=D096065EA97BE61902BDE5CC022D1E6EA38AAC49.
    [7] Anderson PW (1972) More is different. Science 177: 393–396. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.177.4047.393 doi: 10.1126/science.177.4047.393
    [8] Arthur WB (2021) Foundations of Complexity. Nat Rev Phys 3: 136–145. https://doi.org/10.1038/s42254-020-00273-3 doi: 10.1038/s42254-020-00273-3
    [9] Arthur WB (2013) Complexity Economics: A Different Framework for Economic Thought. Complexity Economics, Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.2469/dig.v43.n4.70
    [10] Arthur WB (1999) Complexity and the economy. Science 284: 107–09. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.284.5411.107 doi: 10.1126/science.284.5411.107
    [11] Aven T (2017) A Conceptual Foundation for Assessing and Managing Risk, Surprises and Black Swans. In: Motet, G., Bieder, C., The Illusion of Risk Control, Springer Briefs in Applied Sciences and Technology. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-32939-0_3
    [12] Aven T (2013) On how to deal with deep uncertainties in risk assessment and management context. Risk Anal 33: 2082–2091. https://doi.org/10.1111/risa.12067 doi: 10.1111/risa.12067
    [13] Aven T, Flage R (2015) Emerging risk – Conceptual definition and a relation to black swan type of events. Reliab Eng Syst Safe 144: 61–67. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ress.2015.07.008 doi: 10.1016/j.ress.2015.07.008
    [14] Aven T, Krohn BS (2014) A new perspective on how to understand, assess and manage risk and the unforeseen. Reliab Eng Syst Safe 121: 1–10. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ress.2013.07.005 doi: 10.1016/j.ress.2013.07.005
    [15] Babbie ER (2011) The Practice of Social Science Research. South African Ed. Cape Town. Oxford University Press.
    [16] Baranger M (2010) Chaos, Complexity, and Entropy. A Physics Talk for Non-Physicists. Report in New England Complex Systems Institute, Cambridge.
    [17] Barberis N (2017) Behavioural Finance: Asset Prices and Investor Behaviour. Available from: https://www.aeaweb.org/content/file?id=2978.
    [18] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2017) Basel Ⅲ: Finalising Post-Crisis Reforms. Available from: https://www.bis.org/bcbs/publ/d424.htm.
    [19] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2013) Fundamental Review of the Trading Book: A Revised Market Risk Framework. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs265.pdf.
    [20] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2006) Basel Ⅱ International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards: A Revised Framework-Comprehensive Version. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs128.pdf.
    [21] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (1996) Amendment to the Capital Accord to Incorporate Market Risks. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs24.pdf.
    [22] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) (1988) International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs107.pdf.
    [23] Battiston S, Caldarelli G, May R, et al. (2016a) The Price of Complexity in Financial Networks. P Natl A Sci 113: 10031–10036. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1521573113. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1521573113
    [24] Battiston S, Farmer JD, Flache A, et al. (2016b) Complexity theory and financial regulation: Economic policy needs interdisciplinary network analysis and behavioural modelling. Science 351: 818–819. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aad0299 doi: 10.1126/science.aad0299
    [25] Bayes T, Price R (1763) An Essay towards Solving a Problem in the Doctrine of Chances. Philos T R Soc London 53: 370–418. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstl.1763.0053 doi: 10.1098/rstl.1763.0053
    [26] Beck U (1992) Risk society: towards a new modernity. Sage London.
    [27] Beissner P, Riedel F (2016) Knight-Walras Equilibria. Centre for Mathematical Economics Working Paper 558.
    [28] Bharathy GK, McShane MK (2014) Applying a Systems Model to Enterprise Risk Management. Eng Manag J 26: 38–46. https://doi.org/10.1080/10429247.2014.11432027 doi: 10.1080/10429247.2014.11432027
    [29] Black F, Scholes M (1973) The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. J Polit Econ 29: 449–470.
    [30] Blume L, Durlauf (2006) The Economy as an Evolving Complex System Ⅲ: current perspectives and future directios. https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195162592.001.0001
    [31] Bolton P, Despres M, Pereira da Silva L, et al. (2020) The green swan: central banking and financial stability in the age of climate change. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/othp31.pdf.
    [32] Bonabeau E (2002) Agent-Based Modeling: Methods and Techniques for Simulating Human Systems. Natl Acad Sci 99: 7280–7287. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.082080899 doi: 10.1073/pnas.082080899
    [33] Brace I (2008) Questionnaire Design: How to Plan, Structure, and Write Survey Material for Effective Market Research, 2 Eds., London: Kogan Page. https://doi.org/10.5860/choice.42-3520
    [34] Bronk R (2011) Uncertainty, modeling monocultures and the financial crisis. Bus Econ 42: 5–18.
    [35] Bruno B, Faggini M, Parziale A (2016) Complexity Modeling in Economics: the state of the Art. Econ Thought 5: 29–43.
    [36] Burzoni M, Riedel F, Soner MH (2021) Viability and arbitrage under Knightian uncertainty. Econometrica 89: 1207–1234. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA16535 doi: 10.3982/ECTA16535
    [37] Chan-Lau JA (2017) An Agent Based Model of the Banking System. IMF Working Paper. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781484300688.001
    [38] Chaudhuri A, Ghosh SK (2016) Quantitative Modeling of Operational Risk in Finance and Banking Using Possibility Theory, Springer International Publishing Switzerland. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-26039-6
    [39] Collis J, Hussey R (2009) Business Research: a practical guide for undergraduate and postgraduate students, 3rd ed., New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
    [40] Corrigan J, Luraschi P, Cantle N (2013) Operational Risk Modeling Framework. Milliman Research Report. Available from: https://web.actuaries.ie/sites/default/files/erm-resources/operational_risk_modelling_framework.pdf.
    [41] De Bondt W, Thaler R (1985) Does the stock market overact? J Financ 40: 793–808. https://doi.org/10.2307/2327804 doi: 10.2307/2327804
    [42] Diebold FX, Doherty NA, Herring RJ (2010) The Known, Unknown, and the Unknowable. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
    [43] Dorigo M (2007) Editorial. Swarm Intell 1: 1–2. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11721-007-0003-z doi: 10.1007/s11721-007-0003-z
    [44] Dorigo M, Maniezzo V, Colorni A (1996) Ant system: optimisation by a colony cooperating agents. IEEE T Syst Man Cy B 26: 29–41. https://doi.org/10.1109/3477.484436 doi: 10.1109/3477.484436
    [45] Dowd K (1996) The case for financial Laissez-faire. Econ J 106: 679–687. https://doi.org/10.2307/2235576 doi: 10.2307/2235576
    [46] Dowd K, Hutchinson M (2014) How should financial markets be regulated? Cato J 34: 353–388.
    [47] Dowd K, Hutchinson M, Ashby S, et al. (2011) Capital Inadequacies the Dismal Failure of the Basel Regime of Bank Capital Regulation. Banking & Insurance Journal.
    [48] Easterby-Smith M, Thorpe R, Jackson PR (2015) Management and Business Research, 5 Eds., London: Sage.
    [49] Ellinas C, Allan N, Combe C (2018) Evaluating the role of risk networks on risk identification, classification, and emergence. J Network Theory Financ 3: 1–24. https://doi.org/10.21314/JNTF.2017.032 doi: 10.21314/JNTF.2017.032
    [50] Ellsberg D (1961) Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axioms. Q J Econ 75: 643–669. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884324 doi: 10.2307/1884324
    [51] Evans JR, Allan N, Cantle N (2017) A New Insight into the World Economic Forum Global Risks. Econ Pap 36. https://doi.org/10.1111/1759-3441.12172 doi: 10.1111/1759-3441.12172
    [52] Fadina T, Schmidt T (2019) Default Ambiguity. Risks 7: 64. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks7020064 doi: 10.3390/risks7020064
    [53] Fama EF (1970) Efficient Capital Markets: A review of Theory and Empirical Work. J Financ 25: 383–417. https://doi.org/10.2307/2325486 doi: 10.2307/2325486
    [54] Farmer JD (2012) Economics needs to treat the economy as a complex system. Institute for New Economic Thinking at Oxford Martin School. Working Paper.
    [55] Farmer D (2002) Market force, ecology, and evolution. Ind Corp Change 11: 895–953. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/11.5.895 doi: 10.1093/icc/11.5.895
    [56] Farmer D, Lo A (1999) Fronties of finance: Evolution and efficient markets. Pro Nat Acad Sci 96: 9991–9992. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.96.18.99 doi: 10.1073/pnas.96.18.99
    [57] Farmer JD, Gallegati C, Hommes C, et al. (2012) A complex systems approach to constructing better models for financial markets and the economy. Eur Phys J-Spec Top 214: 295–324. https://link.springer.com/article/10.1140/epjst/e2012-01696-9
    [58] Farmer JD, Foley D (2009) The economy needs agent-based modeling. Nature 460: 685–686. https://www.nature.com/articles/460685a
    [59] Fellegi IP (2010) Survey Methods and Practices, Available from: https://unstats.un.org/wiki/download/attachments/101354131/12-587-x2003001-eng.pdf?api=v2.
    [60] Field A (2009) Discovering Statistics Using SPSS, 3 eds., London: Sage.
    [61] Fink A (2009) How to Conduct Surveys, 4 eds., Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
    [62] Fink A (1995) How to Measure Survey Reliability and Validity, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
    [63] Forrester JW (1969) Urban Dynamics. Cambridge Mass M.I.T Press.
    [64] Ganegoda A, Evans J (2014) A framework to manage the measurable, immeasurable and the unidentifiable financial risk. Aust J Manage 39: 5–34. https://doi.org/10.1177/0312896212461033 doi: 10.1177/0312896212461033
    [65] Gao Q, Fan H, Shen J (2018) The Stability of Banking System Based on Network Structure: An Overview. J Math Financ 8: 517–526. 10.4236/jmf.2018.83032 doi: 10.4236/jmf.2018.83032
    [66] Gebizlioglu OL, Dhaene J (2009) Risk Measures and Solvency-Special Issue. J Comput Appl Math 233: 1–2. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cam.2009.07.030 doi: 10.1016/j.cam.2009.07.030
    [67] Gigerenzer G (2007) Gut feelings: The Intelligence of the unconscious. New York: Viking Press.
    [68] Gigerenzer G, Hertwig R, Pachur T (Eds) (2011) Heuristics: The foundations of adaptive behaviour, New York: Oxford University Press.
    [69] Glasserman P, Young HP (2015) How likely is contagion in financial networks? J Bank Financ 50: 383–399. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.02.006 doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.02.006
    [70] Gros S (2011) Complex systems and risk management. IEEE Eng Manag Rev 39: 61–72.
    [71] Hair J, Black W, Babin B, et al (2014) Multivariate Data Analysis, 7 eds., Pearson Prentice Hall, Auflage.
    [72] Haldane AG (2017) Rethinking Financial Stability. Available from: https://www.bis.org/review/r171013f.pdf.
    [73] Haldane AG (2016) The dappled world. Available from: https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/-/media/boe/files/speech/2016/the-dappled-world.pdf.
    [74] Haldane AG (2012) The Dog and the Frisbee. Available from: https://www.bis.org/review/r120905a.pdf.
    [75] Haldane AG (2009) Rethinking the financial network. Available from: https://www.bis.org/review/r090505e.pdf.
    [76] Haldane AG, May RM (2011) Systemic risk in banking ecosystems. Available from: https://www.nature.com/articles/nature09659.
    [77] Hayek FA (1964) The theory of complex phenomena. The critical approach to science and philosophy, 332–349. https://doi.org/10.4324/9781351313087-22
    [78] Helbing D (2013) Globally network risks and how to respond. Nature 497: 51–59. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature12047 doi: 10.1038/nature12047
    [79] Holland JH (2002) Complex adaptive systems and spontaneous emergence. In Curzio, A.Q., Fortis, M., Complexity and Industrial Clusters: Dynamics and Models in Theory and Practice, New York: Physica-Verlag, 25–34. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-50007-7_3
    [80] Hommes C (2011) The heterogeneous expectations hypothesis: Some evidence from the lab. J Econ Dyn Control 35: 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2010.10.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2010.10.003
    [81] Hommes C (2001) Financial markets as nonlinear adaptive evolutionary systems. Quant Financ 1: 149–167. https://doi.org/10.1080/713665542 doi: 10.1080/713665542
    [82] Hull J (2018) Risk Management and Financial Institutions, 5 eds., John Wiley.
    [83] Ingram D, Thompson M (2011) Changing seasons of risk attitudes. Actuary 8: 20–24.
    [84] Joshi D (2014) Fractals, liquidity, and a trading model. European Investment Strategy, BCA Research.
    [85] Karp A, van Vuuren G (2019) Investment's implications of the Fractal Market Hypothesis. Ann Financ Econ 14: 1–27. https://doi.org/10.1142/S2010495219500015 doi: 10.1142/S2010495219500015
    [86] Katsikopoulos KV (2011) Psychological Heuristics for Making Inferences: Definition, Performance, and the Emerging Theory and Practice. Decis Anal 8: 10–29. https://doi.org/10.1287/deca.1100.0191 doi: 10.1287/deca.1100.0191
    [87] Keynes JM (1921) A Treatise on Probability, London: Macmillan.
    [88] Kimberlin CL, Winterstein AG (2008) Validity and Reliability of Measurement Instruments in Research. Am J Health Syst Pharma 65: 2276–2284. https://doi.org/10.2146/ajhp070364. doi: 10.2146/ajhp070364
    [89] Kirman A (2006) Heterogeneity in economics. J Econ Interact Co-ordination 1: 89–117. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-006-0005-8 doi: 10.1007/s11403-006-0005-8
    [90] Kirman A (2017) The Economy as a Complex System. In: Aruka, Y., Kirman, A., Economic Foundations for Social Complexity Science. Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-5705-2_1
    [91] Klioutchnikova I, Sigovaa M, Beizerova N (2017) Chaos Theory in Finance. Procedia Comput Sci 119: 368–375. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.procs.2017.11.196 doi: 10.1016/j.procs.2017.11.196
    [92] Knight FH (1921) Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, Boston and New York: Houghton Mifflin Company.
    [93] Krejcie RV, Morgan DW (1970) Determining the sample size for research activities. Educ Psychol Meas 30: 607–610.
    [94] Kremer E (2012) Modeling and Simulation of Electrical Energy Systems though a Complex Systems Approach using Agent Based Models, Kit Scientific Publishing.
    [95] Kurtz CF, Snowden DJ (2003) The new dynamics of strategy: Sense-making in a complex and complicated world. IBM Syst J 42: 462–483. https://doi.org/10.1147/sj.423.0462 doi: 10.1147/sj.423.0462
    [96] Li Y (2017) A non-linear analysis of operational risk and operational risk management in banking industry, PhD Thesis, School of Accounting, Economics and Finance, University of Wollongong. Australia.
    [97] Li Y, Allan N, Evans J (2018) An analysis of the feasibility of an extreme operational risk pool for banks. Ann Actuar Sci 13: 295–307. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1748499518000222 doi: 10.1017/S1748499518000222
    [98] Li Y, Allan N, Evans J (2017) An analysis of operational risk events in US and European banks 2008–2014. Ann Actuar Sci 11: 315–342. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1748499517000021 doi: 10.1017/S1748499517000021
    [99] Li Y, Allan N, Evans J (2017) A nonlinear analysis of operational risk events in Australian banks. J Oper Risk 12: 1–22. https://doi.org/10.21314/JOP.2017.185 doi: 10.21314/JOP.2017.185
    [100] Li Y, Evans J (2019) Analysis of financial events under an assumption of complexity. Ann Actuar Sci 13: 360–377. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1748499518000337 doi: 10.1017/S1748499518000337
    [101] Li Y, Shi L, Allan N, et al. (2019) An Analysis of power law distributions and tipping points during the global financial crisis. Ann Actuar Sci 13: 80–91. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1748499518000088 doi: 10.1017/S1748499518000088
    [102] Liu G, Song G (2012) EMH and FMH: Origin, evolution, and tendency. 2012 Fifth International Workshop on Chaos-fractals Theories and Applications. https://doi.org/10.1109/IWCFTA.2012.71
    [103] Lo A (2004) The adaptive markets hypothesis: Market efficiency from an evolutionary perspective. J Portfolio Manage 30: 15–29. https://doi.org/10.3905/jpm.2004.442611 doi: 10.3905/jpm.2004.442611
    [104] Lo A (2012) Adaptive markets and the new world order. Financ Anal J 68: 18–29. https://doi.org/10.2469/faj.v68.n2.6 doi: 10.2469/faj.v68.n2.6
    [105] Macal CM, North MJ, Samuelson MJ (2013) Agent-Based Simulation. In: Gass, S.I., Fu M.C., Encyclopaedia of Operations Research and Management Science, Springer, Boston MA.
    [106] Mandelbrot B (1963) The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices. J Bus 36: 394–419. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2350970
    [107] Mandelbrot B, Hudson RL (2004) The (Mis) behaviour of Markets: A Fractal View of Risk, Ruin, and Reward, Basic Books: Cambridge.
    [108] Mandelbrot B, Taleb N (2007) Mild vs. wild randomness: Focusing on risks that matter. In: Diebold, F.X., Doherty, N.A., Herring, R.J., The Known, the Unknown, and the Unknowable in Financial Risk Management: Measurement and Theory Advancing Practice, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 47–58.
    [109] Markowitz HM (1952) Portfolio Selection. J Financ 7: 77–91. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1952.tb01525.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1952.tb01525.x
    [110] Martens D, Van Gestel T, De Backer M, et al. (2010) Credit rating prediction using Ant Colony Optimisation. J Oper Res Soc 61: 561–573.
    [111] Mazri C (2017) (Re)Defining Emerging Risk. Risk Anal 37: 2053–2065. https://doi.org/10.1111/risa.12759 doi: 10.1111/risa.12759
    [112] McNeil AJ, Frey R, Embrechts P (2015) Quantitative Risk Management (2nd ed): Concepts, Techniques and Tools, Princeton University Press. Princeton.
    [113] Merton RC (1974) On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rate. J Financ 29: 637–654. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1974.tb03058.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1974.tb03058.x
    [114] Mikes A (2005) Enterprise Risk Management in Action. Available from: https://etheses.lse.ac.uk/2924/.
    [115] Mitchell M (2006) Complex systems: Network thinking. Artif Intell 170: 1194–1212. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.artint.2006.10.002 doi: 10.1016/j.artint.2006.10.002
    [116] Mitchell M (2009) Complexity: A Guided Tour. Oxford University Press.
    [117] Mitleton-Kelly E (2003) Complex systems and evolutionary perspectives on organisations: the application of complexity theory to organisations. Oxford: Pergamon.
    [118] Mohajan H (2017) Two Criteria for Good Measurements in Research: Validity and Reliability. Annals of Spiru Haret University 17: 58–82.
    [119] Mohajan HK (2018) Qualitative Research Methodology in Social Sciences and Related Subjects. J Econ Dev Environ Peopl 7: 23–48.
    [120] Morin E (2014) Complex Thinking for a Complex World-About Reductionism, Disjunction and Systemism. Systema 2: 14–22.
    [121] Morin E (1992) From the concept of system to the paradigm of complexity. J Soc Evol Sys 15: 371–385. https://doi.org/10.1016/1061-7361(92)90024-8 doi: 10.1016/1061-7361(92)90024-8
    [122] Motet G, Bieder C (2017) The Illusion of Risk Control, Springer Briefs in Applied Sciences and Technology. Springer, Cham.
    [123] Mousavi S, Gigerenzer G (2014) Risk, Uncertainty and Heuristics. J Bus Res 67: 1671–1678. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2014.02.013 doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2014.02.013
    [124] Muth JF (1961) Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements. Econometrica 29: 315–35.
    [125] Newman MJ (2011) Complex systems: A survey. Am J Phy 79: 800–810. https://doi.org/10.1119/1.3590372 doi: 10.1119/1.3590372
    [126] Pagel M, Atkinson Q, Meade A (2007) Frequency of word-use predicts rates of lexical evolution throughout Indo-European history. Nature 449: 717–720.
    [127] Pallant J (2010) SPSS Survival Manual: A Step-by-Step Guide to Data Analysis using SPSS for Windows, Maidenhead: Open University Press.
    [128] Peters E (1991) Fractal Market Analysis: Applying Chaos Theory to Investment and Economics. London: Wiley Finance. John Wiley Science.
    [129] Peters E (1994) Fractal Market Analysis: Applying Chaos Theory to Investment and Economics. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
    [130] Pichler A (2017) A quantitative comparison of risk measures. Ann Oper Res 254: 1–2. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-017-2397-3 doi: 10.1007/s10479-017-2397-3
    [131] Plosser M, Santos J (2018) The Cost of Bank Regulatory Capital. Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Staff Report Number 853.
    [132] Ponto J 2015) Understanding and Evaluatin Survey Research. J Adv Pract Oncol 6: 66–171. https://doi.org/10.6004/jadpro.2015.6.2.9 doi: 10.6004/jadpro.2015.6.2.9
    [133] Quinlan C (2011) Business Research Methods. South Westen Cengage Learning.
    [134] Ramsey FP (1926) Truth and Probability. In Ramsey 1931, The Foundations of Mathematics and Other Logical Essays, Chapter Ⅶ, 156–198, edited by R.B. Braithwaite, London: Kegan, Paul, Trench, Trubner and Co., New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company.
    [135] Righi BM, Muller FM, da Silveira VG, et al. (2019) The effect of organisational studies on financial risk measures estimation. Rev Bus Manage 21: 103–117. https://doi.org/10.7819/rbgn.v0i0.3953 doi: 10.7819/rbgn.v0i0.3953
    [136] Ross SA (1976) The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. J Econ Theory 13: 341–360. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(76)90046-6 doi: 10.1016/0022-0531(76)90046-6
    [137] Saunders M, Lewis P, Thornhill A (2019) Research Methods for Business Students, New York Pearson Publishers.
    [138] Saunders M, Lewis P, Thornhill A (2012) Research Methods, Pearson Publishers.
    [139] Savage LJ (1954) The Foundations of Statistics. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
    [140] Sekaran U (2003) Research Methods for Business (4th ed.), Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley &Sons. Shane, S. and Cable.
    [141] Senge P (1990) The Fifth Discipline- The Art and Practice of the Learning Organisation. New York, Currency Doubleday.
    [142] Shackle GLS (1949) Expectations in Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    [143] Shackle GLS (1949) Probability and uncertainty. Metroeconomica 1: 161–173. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-999X.1949.tb00040.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-999X.1949.tb00040.x
    [144] Sharpe WF (1964) Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk. J Financ 19: 425–442. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1964.tb02865.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1964.tb02865.x
    [145] Shefrin H (2010) Behaviouralising Finance. Found Trends Financ 4: 1–184. http://dx.doi.org/10.1561/0500000030 doi: 10.1561/0500000030
    [146] Shefrin H, Statman M (1985) The disposition to sell winners to early and ride loses too long: Theory and evidence. J Financ 40: 777–790. https://doi.org/10.2307/2327802 doi: 10.2307/2327802
    [147] Snowden D, Boone M (2007) A leader's framework for decision making. Harvard Bus Rev 85: 68–76.
    [148] Soramaki K, Cook S (2018) Network Theory and Financial Risk, Riskbooks.
    [149] Sornette D (2003) Why Stock Markets Crash: Critical Events in Complex Financial Systems, Princeton University Press.
    [150] Sornette D, Ouillon G (2012) Dragon-kings: mechanisms, statistical methods, and empirical evidence. Eur Phys J Spec Topics 205: 1–26. https://doi.org/10.1140/epjst/e2012-01559-5 doi: 10.1140/epjst/e2012-01559-5
    [151] Sweeting P (2011) Financial Enterprise Risk Management. Cambridge University Press.
    [152] Tepetepe G, Simenti-Phiri E, Morton D (2021) Survey on Complexity Science Adoption in Emerging Risks Management of Zimbabwean Banks. J Global Bus Technol 17: 41–60
    [153] Thaler RH (2015) Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioural Economics. New York: W. W. Norton and Company.
    [154] Thompson M (2018) How banks and other financial institutions. Brit Actuar J 23: 1–16.
    [155] Tukey JW (1977) Exploratory Data Analysis, MA: Addison-Wesley.
    [156] Turner RJ, Baker MR (2019) Complexity Theory: An Overview with Potential Applications for the Social Sciences. Sys Rev 7: 1–22. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems7010004 doi: 10.3390/systems7010004
    [157] Virigineni M, Rao MB (2017) Contemporary Developments in Behavioural Finance. Int J Econ Financ Issues 7: 448–459.
    [158] Yamane T (1967) Statistics: An Introductory Analysis (2nd ed), New York: Harper and Row.
    [159] Zadeh LA (1965) Fuzzy sets. Inf Control 8: 335–338. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0019-9958(65)90241-X doi: 10.1016/S0019-9958(65)90241-X
    [160] Zadeh LA (1978) Fuzzy sets as basis for a theory of possibility. Fuzzy Set Syst 1: 3–28. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-0114(78)90029-5 doi: 10.1016/0165-0114(78)90029-5
    [161] Zikmund W (2003) Business Research Methods, 7th Ed, Mason, OH. and Great Britain, Thomson/South-Western.
    [162] Zimbabwe (2011) Technical Guidance on the Implementation of the Revised Adequacy Framework in Zimbabwe. Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe.
    [163] Zimmerman B (1999) Complexity science: A route through hard times and uncertainty. Health Forum J 42: 42–46.
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Cletos Garatsa, Leo Mataruka, Christopher Zishiri, Service Provider Migration and Bank Switching Behaviour: Factors Influencing Customer Retention in Harare's Banking Sector, 2025, 6, 2958-2326, 10, 10.59413/ajocs/v6.i.1.2
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2022 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(2926) PDF downloads(113) Cited by(1)

Figures and Tables

Figures(2)  /  Tables(4)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog