
We obtain an approximation result of the weak solutions to elliptic and parabolic equations with Dirichlet boundary conditions. We show that the weak solution can be obtained with a limit of approximations by regularizing the nonlinearities and approximating the domains.
Citation: Youchan Kim, Seungjin Ryu, Pilsoo Shin. Approximation of elliptic and parabolic equations with Dirichlet boundary conditions[J]. Mathematics in Engineering, 2023, 5(4): 1-43. doi: 10.3934/mine.2023079
[1] | James H. Page, Lorenzo Dorbolò, Marco Pretto, Alessandro Zanon, Pietro Giannattasio, Michele De Gennaro . Sensitivity analysis of mixed analysis-synthesis flight profile reconstruction. Metascience in Aerospace, 2024, 1(4): 401-415. doi: 10.3934/mina.2024019 |
[2] | Grégoire Dannet, Olivier Boucher, Nicolas Bellouin . Features and evolution of civil aviation CO2 emissions based on ADS-B data for the period between 2019–2024. Metascience in Aerospace, 2024, 1(4): 346-370. doi: 10.3934/mina.2024016 |
[3] | Simon Kim, Donghyun Lee, Byunggil Kwak, Myeonghyo Kim . For electrified aircraft propulsion, SiC MOSFET inverter design with power redundancy in both escape event and failure. Metascience in Aerospace, 2025, 2(1): 1-14. doi: 10.3934/mina.2025001 |
[4] | Hui Ying WANG, Némo DECAMPS . Effects of oxygen concentration of oxidizer flow on laminar diffusion flame established over liquid fuel beds at microgravity. Metascience in Aerospace, 2024, 1(2): 159-184. doi: 10.3934/mina.2024007 |
[5] | Wenchao Cai, Yadong Zhou . Preventing aircraft from wildlife strikes using trajectory planning based on the enhanced artificial potential field approach. Metascience in Aerospace, 2024, 1(2): 219-245. doi: 10.3934/mina.2024010 |
[6] | Xu Han, Bin Yu, Hong Liu . Mixing mechanisms in the view of mixing indicators: from passive-scalar mixing to variable-density mixing. Metascience in Aerospace, 2024, 1(1): 1-37. doi: 10.3934/mina.2024001 |
[7] | Jubilee Prasad Rao, Sai Naveen Chimata . Machine learning-based surrogates for eVTOL performance prediction and design optimization. Metascience in Aerospace, 2024, 1(3): 246-267. doi: 10.3934/mina.2024011 |
[8] | Yuan Hu, Zhihao Jiang, Xintai Yuan, Xifan Hua, Wei Liu . Isometric mapping algorithm based GNSS-R sea ice detection. Metascience in Aerospace, 2024, 1(1): 38-52. doi: 10.3934/mina.2024002 |
[9] | Sarker Ashraful Islam, Farhana Kabir Esheta, Md Mahir Shahriar, Dewan Hasan Ahmed . Numerical study of aerodynamic drag reduction of a circular cylinder with an inbuilt nozzle. Metascience in Aerospace, 2024, 1(4): 379-400. doi: 10.3934/mina.2024018 |
[10] | Victor Cánepa, Pablo Servidia . Design and evaluation of INS/GNSS loose and tight coupling applied to launch vehicle integrated navigation. Metascience in Aerospace, 2024, 1(1): 66-109. doi: 10.3934/mina.2024004 |
We obtain an approximation result of the weak solutions to elliptic and parabolic equations with Dirichlet boundary conditions. We show that the weak solution can be obtained with a limit of approximations by regularizing the nonlinearities and approximating the domains.
Analysing and predicting demand-supply dynamics is critical for businesses and governments alike in today's challenging financial scene. The capacity to precisely predict and analyze these dynamics enables decision-makers to optimize production, distribution, and resource allocation, resulting in increased operational efficiency and customer satisfaction. Traditional models, on the other hand, frequently miss a vital factor—collectability—which plays a significant role in determining the effectiveness of demand fulfillment. The concept of the market depends on the demand-supply dynamics. The common commodities like houses observed by Dorofeenko et al. [1], and gasoline by Aleksandrov et al. [2] and Plante [3] exhibit the true dynamics of demand and supply. Gasoline prices drop due to a huge surplus supply [3]. People are affected by the prices of houses and gasoline; thus, it is a must to develop better mathematical models related to the dynamics of demand and supply. Many mathematical tools have been developed in the past to study this concept of demand and supply examined by Heo [4], and Weinrich [5]. In this analysis, the principles of a dynamical system are utilized to examine the intricate dynamics of demand and supply. This approach expands upon the traditional Marshall model, offering a more comprehensive understanding. We focus on a specific item within the global market to investigate the interplay between demand and supply forces. The concept of aggregate demand and aggregate supply is not considered by Karlan et al. [6]. In competitive market product, characteristics are standardized, and buyers and sellers cannot affect the price. Firms can enter or leave the market without any barriers examined by Stone [7]. According to the law of demand, the quantity demanded decreases as the price increases, keeping all the other factors unchanged. According to the law of supply, supply quantity rises as prices rise while all other parameters remain constant. According to Alfred Marshall, the equilibrium price is determined by the intersection of the supply and demand curves (Figure 1). Market is assumed to operate at this price. However, in reality, the factors that are kept constant in the definitions of demand and supply curves are called determinants [7]. The fundamental changes that take place in these factors have a considerable impact on the dynamics of demand and supply, having enormous impacts. It leads to the deviation of the price from the equilibrium point. As per the law of demand and supply, the demand curve and the supply curve are static and are independent of time. It is assumed that the amount of demand and the amount of supply remains stagnant over a period of time. In the proposed demand-supply model, the amounts are dependent on time that is the represent the numbers at that specific moment, not over time; these models are more realistic.
According to the law of supply, supply quantity rises as prices rise while all other parameters remain constant. According to Alfred Marshall, the equilibrium price is determined by the intersection of the supply and demand curves (Figure 1). Market is assumed to operate at this price. However, in reality, the factors that are kept constant in the definitions of demand and supply curves are called determinants [7]. The fundamental changes that take place in these factors have a considerable impact on the dynamics of demand and supply. This leads to the deviation of the price from the equilibrium point. As per the law of demand and supply, the demand curve and the supply curve are static and independent of time. It is assumed that the amount of demand and the amount of supply remains stagnant over a period of time. In the proposed demand-supply model, the amounts are dependent on time, which represent the numbers at that specific moment, not over time; these models are more realistic.
Shananin et al. analyze the impact of consumer financing on home economics in Russia during the COVID-19 epidemic [8]. Ramsey-type models were examined by Gimaltdinov as optimum control issues [9]. Mazloumfard and Glantz studied bank profits under conditions of monopolistic competition and the impact of tax pressure [10]. Tadmon and Njike worked on Okun's law and method for calculating the minimal reservation wage in terms of model parameters [11]. Arabob et al. studied the order of derivatives being reduced from units, causing a delay in the fluctuation of financial assets [12]. Wang et al. explore the dynamics of bank data using a competitive model with encouraging results [13]. Selyutin and Rudenko observed that Savings and capital are two categories of banking services, together with loans and deposits. Holdings and retainage are both types of investments [14]. Comes studied a three-level Lotka-Volterra (TLVR) model, a two-way financial exchange from the Parent Bank to the Subsidiaries Bank, and the reverse is taken into account [15]. Marasco et al. examined the Fokker Planck Kolmogorov stochastic equation solution utilized in the TLVR model to evaluate the equilibrium of the banking sector. It is possible to build custom Lotka-Volterra models for n-level banking [16]. Ruan examined and carefully analyzed the exponential characteristic equation's zeros [17]. By utilizing delay differential equations, demand-supply dynamics with collectability factors are achieved. However, in this case, the process and its signs are unquestionably different. With the help of technological developments, many real world problems have been symbolized using mathematical models [32,33,34,35,36,37,38,39].
We start by providing some background knowledge on mathematical models. The development and redesigned mathematical model are used to undertake a comprehensive numerical examination of the dynamics of bank capital. Additionally, a delay differential equation is used to generalize the model. The impact of the DDE order on the dynamics of banking capital is proven based on the numerical analysis. We conclude by summarizing the findings.
The average price of a product over the global market at time t is denoted as P(t). The complete amount of demand of the product in the global market is denoted as D(t). The complete amount of supply of products in a global market is denoted as S(t). However, the supply of the product is always not immediate, but gets delayed due to the availability of raw material, transportation, complications of production process, etc. This maturation time or production time is incorporated as delay parameters in the term defining amount of supply S(t). The threshold prices of demand and supply are denoted as Pd>0 and Ps>0, respectively. A product is assumed to be collectable when its price becomes very high, such as when an investor is increasingly more likely to buy a stock when it exceeds its fundamental worth. This is denoted by collectability factor Fd>0 and does not depend on the variables (P,D,S). The cost of other commodities, resources, taxes etc. related to supply is denoted as Fd>0. Both Fd and Fs are independent of the three variables (P,D,S). This entire demand-supply dynamic is mathematically represented by the following system of first order non-linear delay differential equations:
DP=α[R−S(t−τ)] | (1) |
DD=β(Pd−P)[1−β1(Pd−P)2]+Fd | (2) |
DS=−γ(Ps−P)+δ[R−S(t−τ)]+Fs | (3) |
where α,β,β1,γ,δ are all positive parameters.
From Eqs (1)−(3).
Let W = P+D+S
dW(t)dt=dP(t)dt+dD(t)dt+dS(t)dt. |
Additoinally, φ=min(α,β,γ,δ,β1,Pd,PS)
dW(t)dt≤φ(P+D+S)+Fd+FS |
0≤φ(P+D+S)+Fd+FS→0,0≤(P+D+S)≤Fd+FSφ. |
As t→∞, and applying comparison theorem
0≤(P+D+S)≤Fd+FSφ. |
Hence, a three-dimensional space contains all of the equations in the systems (1)−(3).
X=[(P,D,S)εR3+:0≤(P+D+S)≤Fd+FSφ] \;as \;t→∞, for all positive initial value {P(0) > 0, D(0) > 0, S(0), S(t−τ)∼S = Const. ∀ tε[−τ,0]}εD⊂R3+, where
φ=min(α,β,γ,δ,β1,Pd,PS). |
Hence, a three-dimensional space contains all of the equations in the systems (1)−(3). X=[(P,D,S)εR3+:0≤(P+D+S)≤Fd+FSφ]ast→∞, for all positive initial value D(0)>0,S(0),S(t−τ)∼S = Const. ∀ tε[−τ,0]}εD⊂R3+, Where
φ=min(α,β,γ,δ,β1,Pd,PS). |
From (3)
dSdt≥−δS |
dSS≥−δdt |
S≥−eδt. |
And similarly, we can calculate for P and D.
From Eq (1)
dP∗dt=0⇒α[D∗−S∗] |
α[D∗−S∗]=0 |
D∗−S∗=0 |
D∗=S∗. |
From Eq (3)
P∗=PS−FSr. |
The dynamic behavior for equilibrium points E∗(P∗,D∗,S∗) of the model given by (1)−(3) is analyses:
dP∗dt=α[D∗−S∗(t−τ)] | (4) |
dD∗dt=β(Pd−P∗)[1−β1(Pd−P∗)2]+Fd | (5) |
dS∗dt=−γ(Ps−P∗)+δ[D−S∗(t−τ)]+Fs. | (6) |
The exponential characteristic equation about equilibrium E* is given by:
λ3+(αββ1(P2d+P2−2PdP)+2αββ1(Pd−P)−αβ)λ+e−λτ(δλ2−αγλ+(αβδ−δαββ1(P2d+P2−2PdP)−αβδ+αδββ1(P2d+P2−2PdP)=0 |
λ3+a1λ+e−λτ(b1λ2−b2λ+b3)=0. | (7) |
Where a1=αββ1(P2d+P2−2PdP)+2αββ1(Pd−P)−αβ
b1=δ,b2=αγ,b3=(αβδ−δαββ1(P2d+P2−2PdP)−αβδ+αδββ1(P2d+P2−2PdP). |
All parameters are a1,b1,b2,b3 positive.
Equation (7) have a solution Iff λ=iω
(iω)3+a1(iω)+e−iωτ(b1(iω)2−b2(iω)+b3)=0. | (8) |
Separating real and imaginary part
−ω3=b2ωsinτω−(b1ω2+b3)cosτω | (9) |
a1ω=b2cosτω+(b1ω2+b3)sinτω. | (10) |
Squaring and adding (9) and (10), we get
ω6−b21ω4+(a21−b2−2b1b3)ω2+b23=0. | (11) |
Put b21=a,(a21−b2−2b1b3)=b,b23=c and ω2=z, we get
z3−az2+bz+c=0. | (12) |
Equation (12) has at least one real positive root if c<0.
Suppose k(z)=z3−az2+bz+c
k(0)=c<0,limz→∞k(z)=∞,∃z0∈(0,∞) |
k(z0)=0, if
Equation (12) has positive at least one positive root iff c≥0.
A=a2−3b≥0 |
k(z)=z3−az2+bz+c |
k'(z)=3z2−2az+b |
k'(z)=0→3z2−2az+b=0 | (13) |
z1,2=2a∓√4a2−12b6=a∓√A3. | (14) |
Equation (13) has doesn't any real root if A<0,k(z) is monotone increasing fuxn in z.
k(z)=c≥0, Eq (11) has no positive root.
Clearly if A≥0, then z1=a+√A3 is least possible of k(z).
If c≥0 then Eq (12) is absolute if z1>0 and k(z1)>0.
Suppose that each of two z1≤0 or z1>0 and k(z1)>0.
If z1≤0,sink(z) is increasing for z≥z1 and k(0)=c≥0.
Consequently, it can be deduced that k(z) does not possess any positive real zeros. If z1>0 and k(z1)>0,sinz2=−a+√A3 is superlative value.
It follows that k(z1)≤k(z2) k(0)=c≥0, k(z) has no positive root.
Lemma 1.
The variable denoted as z1 is determined by the Eq (14).
(1) If c<0, there exists at least one positive real root in Eq (12).
(2) If c≥0 and A=a2−3b<0, If the condition holds, Eq (12) does not possess any positive roots.
(3) If c≥0, then Eq (11) has positive root if z1>0 and k(z1)≤0.
Let's assume that Eq (12) possesses a positive root. Without loss of generality (WLOG), we can consider three positive roots, namely z1,z2,z3. Consequently, Eq (11) will also have three positive roots:
ω1=√z1,ω2=√z2,ω3=√z3. |
From Eq (10)
sinωτ=b1ω−ω3d |
τ=1ω[sin−1(b1ω−ω3)d+2(l−1)π]:l=1,2,3 |
τ(l)m=1ωm[sin−1(b1ω−ω3k)d+2(l−1)π]:m=1,2,3,l=0,1,2…… |
As a result, the roots of Eq (11) would consist of a pair of purely imaginary numbers. When τ=τ(l)m,m=1,2,3;l=0,1,2…..
limj→∞τ(l)m=∞,m=1,2,3,4 |
τ0=τ(l0)m0=min1≤m≤3,l≥1[τ(l)m],ω0=ωm0,y0=ym0. | (15) |
Lemma 2. Suppose that a1≥0,(c1+d),b1(c1−d)>0.
(1) If c≥0 and A=a2−3b<0, then all the roots of Eq (7) will have a negative real part for all τ≥0.
(2) If c<0orc≥0,z1>0 and k(z1)≤0, then all the roots of Eq (7) will have a negative real part for all values of τ in the interval τϵ(0,τ0).
Proof. When τ is equal to zero, Eq (7) transforms into
λ3+(a1+a2)λ2+(b1+b2)λ+(c1+c2)=0. | (16) |
According to Routh-Hurwitz's Criteria:
The condition for all roots of Eq (8) to have a negative real part is if and only if
(c1+c2)≥0,(a1+a2)(b1+b2)−(c1+c2)>0. |
If c≥0 and A=a2−3b<0.
Lemma 1 (2) show that Eq (7) has no roots with zero real part ∀τ≥0.
When c<0orc≥0,z1>0 and k(z1)≤0.
Lemma 1 (1) and (2) implies when τ≠τ(l)m,m=1,2,3,l≥1, Eq (7) does not possess any roots with a zero real part, and the minimum value of τ for which Eq (7) exhibits purely imaginary roots.
We can obtain insight into the system's behavior by analyzing the numerical results. We can see how changes in parameters or beginning circumstances alter the dynamics of demand and supply. Furthermore, we may investigate the implications of the collectability factor on the supply process and its impact on overall system behavior:
α=4,β=0.1,Pd=10,β1=0.01,FD=1,γ=0.01,PS=10,δ=2,FS=1. |
Figure 2 reflects that the supply is delayed below a critical value of τ<3.6999. The demand-supply surplus initial shows fluctuations for these perturbations but becomes stable in the long run. Figure 3 shows the period three market attractor. Figure 4 has same observation of the period three market, which is supported by the phase diagram. Figure 5 shows that whenever τ≥3.6999, the hopf-bifurcation is observed, which means the entire dynamic will be involved into near ending cycles of pick growth recession and flash crash. Figure 6 shows that the attractor will never be at a stable equilibrium for the perturbation τ≥3.6999. Figure 7 explained about the stability of (P, D, S) when the parametric value of β1 varies.
A collection of continuous functions showing a bifurcation phenomenon at the critical value of the positive steady state is created. The bifurcating periodic solutions' course, stability, and periodicity are emphasized. Using the basic approach and several reductions proposed by Hassard et al. [18], a particular formula will be created to investigate the properties of the Hopf-bifurcation at the complex level. The obtained equation will effectively allow the computation of the Hopf-bifurcation characteristics.
Let V1=P−P∗,V2=D−D∗,V3=S−S∗, and the system is altered by t→tτ, to normalize the τ into
dV1dt=αV2+αD∗−αV3(t−1)−αS∗(t−1) |
dV2dt=βPd−2ββ1P2d+6ββ1Pd(V1+P∗)+2ββ1PdV1−4ββ1PdV1P∗ |
−2ββ1P∗2−ββ1V1P2d−ββ1(V1+P∗)3−ββ1P∗P2d |
dV3dt=−γPS+γV1+γP∗+δV2+δD∗−δV3(t−1)−δS∗(t−1). | (17) |
In this stage, we can handle the equation A=A((−1,0),R3+). Without loss of generality, we represent he the critical value τl by τ0. Let τ=τ0+υ, where υ=0 corresponds to the hopf-bifurcation value of the system (13). For simplicity in notation, we rewrite (17) as:
υ'(t)=Eυ(vt)+F(υ,υt). | (18) |
Where υ(t)=(V1(t),V2(t),V3(t))TϵR3,υt(ϕ)ϵA, and defined by υt(ϕ)=υt(t+ϕ)&Eυ:A→R,F:R×D→R is given as:
Eυχ=(τ0+υ)[0α0b00γδ0][χ1(0)χ2(0)χ3(0)]+(τ0+υ)[00α00000δ][χ1(−1)χ2(−1)χ3(−1)]. |
Where b=ββ1(6+Pd(2−Pd)−3V1(V1+2P∗)−P∗(4+3P∗).
And F(υ,ϕ)=(τ0+υ)[F1F2F3].
Where,
F1=αχ21(0)−(1−D∗)χ1(0)χ3(0)+P∗χ2(0)χ3(0)+S∗χ1(0)χ2(0)+χ1(0)χ2(0)χ3(0) |
F2=−χ22(0)−(1−P∗)χ2(0)χ3(0)+D∗χ1(0)χ3(0)+S∗χ1(0)χ2(0)+χ1(0)χ2(0)χ3(0) |
F3=γχ23(0)+δχ1(−1)χ3(0)+δχ2(−1)χ3(0) |
χ(ϕ)=(χ1(ϕ),χ2(ϕ),χ3(ϕ))TϵA(−1,0),R). |
Using the Riesz Representation theorem, ∃ζ(ϕ,υ) of the bounded variation for ϕϵ[−1,0), s.t.
Eυχ=∫0−1dζ(ϕ,0)ϕ(0)forϕϵA. |
We can choose
ζ(ϕ,υ)=(τ0+υ)[0α0b00γδ0]ς(ϕ)+(τ0+υ)[00α00000δ]ς(ϕ+1). |
Here δ is the direct delta function. For χϵA([−1,0],R3+), and calculate
R(υ)χ={dχ(ϕ)dϕ,ϕ∈[−1,0)∫0−1dζ(ϕ,0)χ(ϕ),ϕ=0.andR(υ)χ={0,ϕ∈[−1,0)m(υ,χ)ϕ=0. |
Subsequently, the system (17) holds and equivalence to
υ'(t)=R(υ)χ+R(υ)υt,for | (19) |
η∈A1([−1,0],R+3) |
R∗η(s)={−dη(s)ds,s∈[−1,0)∫0−1dζT(−t,0)η(−t),s=0.. |
Furthermore, the bilinear inner product
<η(s),χ(ϕ)>=¯η(0)χ(0)−∫0−1∫θϱ=ϕ¯η(ϱ−ϕ)dζ(ϕ)χ(ϱ)dϱ. | (20) |
R∗ and R=R(0) and the operators R∗ and iω0 represent the algebraic entities, with iω0 being the eigenvalues of R(0). Consequently, these values serve as coefficient of R∗. Consider the eigen vector r(ϕ)=r(0)eiω0ϕ associated with eigen value iω0. It follows that R(0)=iω0r(ϕ). When ϕ=0, we arrive at the expression
[iω0L−∫0−1dζ(ϕ)eiω0ϕ]r(0)=0,whichoptionr(0)=(1,σ1,ρ1)T |
σ1=(P∗−P∗D∗)D∗S∗+(D∗−P∗D∗)(iω0+αP∗)P∗S∗(D∗−P∗D∗)−(P∗−P∗D∗)(iω0+bD∗) |
ρ1=P∗D∗S∗2−(iω0+αP∗)(iω0+bD∗)P∗S∗(D∗−P∗D∗)−(P∗−P∗D∗)(iω0+bD∗). |
Similarly, it can be calculated that r∗(s)=M(1,σ2,ρ2)eiω0τ0s is the eigen value of R∗ corresponding to −iω0, where
σ2=(P∗−P∗D∗)D∗S∗+(D∗−P∗D∗)(αP∗−iω0)P∗S∗(D∗−P∗D∗)−(P∗−P∗D∗)(bD∗−iω0) |
ρ2=P∗D∗S∗2−(iω0+αP∗)(bD∗−iω0)P∗S∗(D∗−P∗D∗)−(P∗−P∗D∗)(bD∗−iω0). |
In order to assure <r∗(s),r(ϕ)>=1, and we calculate the value of M, from Eq (15),
<r∗(s),r(ϕ)>=¯M(1,¯σ2,¯ρ2,)(1,σ1,ρ1)T−∫0−1∫ϕϱ=ϕ¯M(1,¯σ2,¯ρ2,)e−iω0τ0(ϱ=ϕ)dζ(ϕ)(1,σ1,ρ1)Teiω0τ0dζ=¯M{1+σ1¯σ2+¯ρ1¯ρ2−∫0−1(1,¯σ2,¯ρ2,)ϕeiω0τ0ϕ(1,σ1,ρ1)T}¯M{1+σ1¯σ2+ρ1¯ρ2+τ0¯σ2S∗(Bρ1−gσ1)eiω0τ0}. |
Hence, we choose
¯M=1(1+σ1¯σ2+ρ1¯ρ2+τ0¯σ2S∗(Bρ1−gσ1)eiω0τ0) |
s.t. < r∗(s),r(ϕ)>=1,<r∗(s),¯r(ϕ)>=0. |
We've used the approach suggested by Hassard et al. [18] to figure out the specifics of the central surface. To achieve this, we used the same notations that were described in their work, A0 at υ=0. In particular, we designate the result of Eq (14) as υt, when υ=0.
H(t)=<r∗(s),υt(ϕ)>,W(t,ϕ)=υt(ϕ)−2Re(H(t)r(ϕ)). | (21) |
The center manifold theory A0
W(t,ϕ)=W((r(t),¯r(t),ϕ). |
Where W(r,¯r,ϕ)=W20(ϕ)H22+W11(ϕ)H−H+W02(ϕ)−H22+….
Let rand−r represent the local coordinates associated with the center manifold A0, which is aligned with the directions of r∗ and −r∗, respectively. The parameter W is considered positive when the solution υt is positive. It is important to concentrate only on real solutions. For the specific of the Eq (15), υtϵA0, when υ=0,
H'(t)=iω0τ0H+<−r(ϕ),F(0,W(H,−H,ϕ)+2Re(H(t),r(ϕ))>=iω0τ0H+−r∗(0)F(0,W(H,−H,0)+2Re(H(t)r(t)≅iω0τ0H+−r∗(0)F0(H,−H). |
On rewriting this equation again:
H'(t)≅iω0τ0H(t)+c(H,−H). | (22) |
Where c(H,−H)=−r∗(0)F0(H,−H)
c(H,−H)=c20(ϕ)H22+c11(ϕ)H−H+c21(ϕ)H2−H2+… |
Observing as υt(ϕ)=(V1t,V2t,V3t)=W(t,ϕ)+Hr(ϕ)+¯H¯r(ϕ)
And r(0)=M(1,σ1,ρ1)Teiω0τ0ϕ, we have
V1t(0)=H+−H+W120(0)H22+W111(0)H−H+W102(0)−H22+… |
V2t(0)=σ1H+−σ1H+W220(0)H22+W211(0)H−H+W202(0)−H22+… |
V3t(0)=ρ11H+−ρ11H+W320(0)H22+W311(0)H−H+W302(0)−H22+… |
V1t(−1)=He−iω0τ0+−Heiω0τ0+W120(−1)H22+W111(−1)H−H+W102(−1)−H22+… |
V2t(−1)=σ1He−iω0τ0+−σ1Heiω0τ0+W220(−1)H22+W211(−1)H−H+W202(−1)−H22+… |
Consequently, by comparing coefficients with Eq (21), the following can be derived:
c20=−2τ0−M[α+(1−D∗)ρ1−σ1(P∗ρ1+S∗)+−σ1(bσ21+(1−P∗)σ1ρ1)z−σ1S∗−ρ1D∗)+−σ2σ1(dρ1−δe−iω0τ0−fσ1e−iω0τ0 |
c11==−2τ0−M[+(1−D∗)Re{ρ1}−P∗Re{−ρ1σ1}+S∗Re{ρ1}+−σ2(σ1−ρ1−+(1−P∗)Re{σ1−ρ1}−D∗Re{−ρ1}−S∗Re{σ1})+−ρ2(dρ1−ρ1−δRe{ρ1eiω0τ0}−fRe{−σ1ρ1eiω0τ0})] |
c02=−2τ0−M[α+(1−D∗)−ρ1−−σ1(P∗−ρ1+S∗)+−σ1(b−σ21+(1−P∗)σ1−ρ1−−σ1S∗−−ρ1D∗)+−ρ1−ρ2(d−ρ1−δeiω0τ0−f−σ1e−iω0τ0)] |
c21=−2τ0−M[α(W120(0)+2W111(0))+(1−D∗)(12W120(0)−ρ1+W111(0)ρ1+12W320(0)+W311(0))−(2Re(σ1ρ1)−P∗(12W220(0)−ρ1+12W320(0)−ρ1+W111(0)ρ1+W311(0)ρ1)−S∗(12W220(0)+12W120(0)−σ1+W111(0)σ1+−σ2(−(W220(0)−σ1+2W211(0)σ1)+(1−P∗)(12W220(0)−σ1+W111(0)ρ1+W311(0)−σ1)−(2Re{−ρ1σ1}+ρ1σ1)−D∗(12W120(0)−ρ1+12W320(0)+W111(0)ρ1+W311(0))−S∗(12W220(0)+W120(0)−σ1+W211(0)+W111(0)σ1)+−ρ2(δ(W320(0)−ρ1+2W320(0)ρ1)−δ(W120(−1)−ρ1)+W111(−1)ρ1+12W320(0)eiω0τ0+W311(0)e−iω0τ0)−δ(12W120(−1)−ρ1+W211(−1)ρ1+12W320(0)−σ1eiω0τ0+W311(0)σ1e−iω0τ0))]. |
To determine the value of c21, it is important to compute W20(ϕ)&W11(ϕ) as per Eqs (19) and (21) respectively:
W'=υt−H'r−−H'r={RW−2Re{−r∗(0)F0r(ϕ)},ϕϵ[−1,0)RW−2Re{−r∗(0)F0r(0)}+F0,ϕ=0. |
Let
W'=RW+K. | (23) |
Where,
K(H,−H,ϕ)=K20(ϕ)H22+K11(ϕ)H−H+K02(ϕ)−H22+K21(ϕ)−H2−H2… | (24) |
Alternatively, when considering A0 in the vicinity of the origin,
W'=WHH'+WH−H. |
By expanding the above series and calculating the coefficients, we obtain the following results:
[R−2iω0L]W20(ϕ)=−K20(ϕ),RW11(ϕ)=−K11(ϕ). | (25) |
From Eq (18), we know ϕϵ[−1,0),
K(H,−H,ϕ)=−−r∗(0)−F0r(ϕ)−−r∗(0)−F0r(ϕ)=−cr(ϕ)−−c−r(ϕ). |
Comparing the coefficient with Eq (20), for ϕϵ[−1,0) we get
K20(ϕ)=−c20r(ϕ)−−c02−r(ϕ) |
K11(ϕ)=−c11r(ϕ)−−c11−r(ϕ). |
From Eqs (23) and (25) and definition of R, we get
W20(ϕ)=2iω0τ0W20(ϕ)+c20(ϕ)+−c02−r(ϕ). |
Further examine the W20(ϕ):
W20(ϕ)=ic20ω0τ0r(0)eiω0τ0ϕ+i−c203ω0τ0r(0)e−iω0τ0ϕ+A1e2iω0τ0ϕ. |
Similarly,
W11(ϕ)=ic11ω0τ0r(0)eiω0τ0ϕ+i−c11ω0τ0−r(0)e−iω0τ0ϕ+A2. |
Here A1&A2 repreent three-dimensional vectors, and their values can be computed by substituting ϕ=0 in K. Indeed, as a matter of fact
K(H,−H,ϕ)=2Re{−r∗(0)F0r(0)}+F0. |
We get,
K20(ϕ)=−c20r(ϕ)−−c02−r(ϕ)+FH2 |
K11(ϕ)=−c11r(ϕ)−−c11−r(ϕ)+FH−H. |
Where F0=FH2H22+FH−HH−H+…
With the def. of R,
∫0−1dζ(ϕ)W20(ϕ)=2iω0τ0W20(0)+c20r(0)+−c02−r(0)−FH2. |
Furthermore,
∫0−1dζ(ϕ,)W11(ϕ)=c11r(0)+−c11−r(0)−FH−H |
[iω0τ0L−∫0−1eiω0τ0ϕdζ(ϕ)]r(0)=0and[−iω0τ0L−∫0−1e−iω0τ0ϕdζ(ϕ)]−r(0)=0. |
This shows
[2iω0τ0L−∫0−1e2iω0τ0ϕdζ(ϕ)]A1=FH2and−[∫0−1dζ(ϕ)]A2=FH−H. |
Hence,
[2iω0+αP∗−P∗S∗P∗−P∗D∗−D∗S∗2iω0+bD∗D∗−P∗D∗δS∗e−2iω0τ0−δS∗e−2iω0τ0(2iω0+δS∗)]A1=−2[α+(1−D∗)ρ1−σ1(P∗ρ1+S∗)bσ∗1+(1−P∗)σ1ρ1−σ1S∗−ρ2D∗ρ1(δρ1−δe−iω0τ0−δσ1e−iω0τ0] |
[αP∗−P∗S∗P∗−P∗D∗−D∗S∗−D∗D∗−P∗D∗δS∗−δS∗δS∗]A2=−2[α+(1−D∗)Re{ρ1}−P∗Re{−ρ1σ1}+S∗Re{σ1})−−σ1σ1+(1−P∗)Re{−ρ1σ1}−D∗Re{−ρ1}−S∗Re{σ1}δρ1−ρ1−δRe{ρ1}−δRe{−ρ1σ1}eiω0τ0]. |
Thus, parameter c21 is demonstrate. Upon analyzing the information provided above, each cij can be evaluated using the parameters, leading to the computation of the following values:
J1(0)=i2ω0τ0(c11c20−2|c11|2−|c02|23)+c212,κ2=−Re{J1(0)}Re(λ'(τ0)},ι2=2Re{J1(0)},T2=−Im{J1(0)}+κ2Im{λ'(τ0)}ω0τ0. | (26) |
Theorem 1. The value of κ2 dictates the direction of the Hopf-bifurcation. The Hopf-bifurcation is in a supercritical state when κ2>0 and a subcritical state when κ2<0. As a result, for τ>τ0 and τ<τ0, there are bifurcating periodic solutions, respectively. The value of ι2 determines how stable the bifurcating solutions are. If ι2 and unstable if ι2>0, bifurcating periodic solutions are orbitally asymptotically stable. The value of T2 affects how long the bifurcating periodic solutions last. If T2>0(T2<0), the period grows and vice versa.
To determine the coefficient of generalized sensitivity, Rihan [19], and Thomaseth and Cobelli [20] employ the "direct method". This direct approach involves making the assumption of fixed parameters and subsequently computing the sensitivity coefficient (α,β,β1,γ,δ) through utilization of the sensitivity equation along with the initial solution of Eqs (1)−(3). By focusing on a specific criterion, say γ1, the partial derivatives of the solution (P,D,S) with respect to β1 yield the criteria for the sensitivity Eqs (27)−(29), as presented below:
dS1dt=α[S2−S3(t−τ)] | (27) |
dS2dt=[−β−ββ1(6PdP−P2d+3P2)]S1 | (28) |
dS3dt=−γS1+δS2−δS3(t−τ). | (29) |
Where S1=∂P∂β1,S2=∂D∂β1,S3=∂S∂β1.
By evaluating Eqs (27)−(29) with respect to parameter β1, we were also able to investigate the effects of the systems (1)−(3) on the variables (P,D,S). We kept all other factors constant while performing a sensitivity analysis for the variables (P,D,S) pertaining to β1. It is interesting that the system remained stable throughout this time, even though β1 varied between 0.7 and 0.9.
Similarly, we can calculate the sensitivity analysis (α,β,γ,δ).
The same model is also studied using different fractional derivative operators. In addition, to guarantee that the left and right sides of the ensuing fractional model have the same dimension (time)−η, all the parameters having the dimension (time)−1 are replaced by powers of v, while the other parameters remain unchanged. There is significance associated with various operators of fractional derivatives. Riemann-Liouville proposed the definition with singular kernel [21], which was the first and most widely accepted definition in the field of fractional calculus. The definition of the derivative of fractional order with the non-singular kernel was presented by Caputo [21]. Since this definition is based on the idea of power law, it is inapplicable to issues when the fading memory process is present. Caputo and Fabricio's formulation [22] represent the next advancement in this field, as it addresses processes that display fading memory processes with exponential decay and the Delta-Dirac characteristic. Last, the definition of fractional derivatives and integrals that can easily handle the process by exhibiting a passage from fading memory to power law have been introduced by Atangana [23,26,27,28,29,30,31]. The proposed fractional mathematical model in the context of Caputo and C-F fractional operators is now examined here.
The demand-supply dynamic is mathematically represented by the following system of first order non-linear delay differential equation with conformal operators; where α,β,γ,δ,β1 are all positive parameters and 0<ε≤1. Consider the model in Caputo fractional derivative framework as follows:
bζηtP=αη[D−S],P(0)=P0 | (30) |
bζηtD=βη(Pd−P)[1−βη1(Pd−P)2]+Fd,D(0)=D0 | (31) |
bζηtS=−γη(Ps−P)+δη[D−S]+Fs,S(0)=S0. | (32) |
Here, 'bζηt' denotes the Caputo derivative of fractional order 'η' and for calculating the fractional derivatives, it is assumed that S(t−τ)≈S(t).
Definition 1. Let 'f' be an integrable function on 'R'. If there exists a number 0<η<1, then the fractional Caputo derivative with order 'η' is given by:
bζηtf(t)=1ω(1−η)∫t01(t−φ)ηddφf(φ)dφ | (33) |
where 'bζηt' denotes the Caputo derivative of fractional order η.
Theorem 2. The Cauchy problem with the Caputo derivative allows a unique solution [24] if the following two conditions hold for two positive constants L and −L:
(Ⅰ) Lipchitz condition: |g(t,v1(t))−g(t,v2(t))|≤L|v1−v2| for all v1,v2∈R and for all t∈[t0,T].
(Ⅱ) Linear growth condition: |g(t,v)|2≤−L(1+|v|2).
From (30)−(32) to find the numerical solution [26], consider
0bζηtψ(t)=k(t,ψ(t)),t≥0,ψ(0)=ψ0. | (34) |
Using the fundamental theorem, we can rewrite the above equation as:
ψ(t)=ψ(0)+1ω(η)∫t0(t−φ)η−1k(ψ,φ)dφ. | (35) |
At t=tp+1, we have
ψ(tp+1)=ψ(0)+1ω(η)∫tp+10(tp+1−φ)η−1k(ψ,φ)dφ. | (36) |
At t=tp, we have
ψ(tp)=ψ(0)+1ω(η)∫tp0(tp−φ)η−1k(ψ,φ)dφ. | (37) |
From the above two equations, we have
ψ(tp+1)−ψ(tp)=1ω(η)[∫tp+10(tp+1−φ)η−1k(ψ,φ)dφ−∫tp0(tp−φ)η−1k(ψ,φ)dφ]. | (38) |
The application of the handled scheme with Lagrange polynomial interpolation gives the following numerical iteration formula.
Pp+1=ηhηω(η+2)∑rm=0f1(tm,Pm)[(p−m+1)η(p−m+2+2η)−(p−m)η(p−m+2+2η)]−hηω(η+2)∑rm=0f1(tm−1,Pm−1)[(p−m+1)η+1−(p−m)η(p−m+1+η)]. | (39) |
Where,
f1(t,P)=αη[D−S] | (40) |
Dp+1=ηhηω(η+2)∑rm=0f2(tm,Dm)[(p−m+1)η(p−m+2+2η)−(p−m)η(p−m+2+2η)]−hηω(η+2)∑rm=0f2(tm−1,Dm−1)[(p−m+1)η+1−(p−m)η(p−m+1+η)]. | (41) |
Where,
f2(t,D)=βη(Pd−P)[1−βη1(Pd−P)2]+Fd. | (42) |
Sp+1=ηhηω(η+2)∑rm=0f3(tm,Sm)[(p−m+1)η(p−m+2+2η)−(p−m)η(p−m+2+2η)]−hηω(η+2)∑rm=0f3(tm−1,Sm−1)[(p−m+1)η+1−(p−m)η(p−m+1+η)] | (43) |
where f3(t,S)=−γη(Ps−P)+δη[D−S]+Fs.
We present a mathematical model that describes the dynamics of demand and supply, which genialized the Marshall model and collectability factor. Collectability is seen more often in reality, and many stocks are overvalued. According to the Marshall model, market equilibrium is the only global attractor. When the delay parameter crosses are below the critical value τ<3.6999, the entire demand-supply surplus initial shows fluctuations for these perturbations and when delay parameter cross the critical value (τ≥3.6999), market enters the danger zone i.e., small perturbations lead to regular market fluctuations around market equilibrium, recession, large growth cycles, and flash crash. The caputo operator is used to examine the frcational part of the demand and supply dynamics. The recently proposed model includes a wider variety of market phenomena connected to supply and demand dynamics. Further, the stability of fluctuations around market equilibrium, recession, large growth cycles, and flash crash is also examined. Thus, this model offers insights into the intricacies of real-world markets and their directional analysis to various disturbances by integrating the collectability component and examining the influence of the delay parameter.
The authors declare that they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.
The authors declare no conflict of interest.
[1] |
E. Acerbi, N. Fusco, Regularity for minimizers of nonquadratic functionals: the case 1<p<2, J. Math. Anal. Appl., 140 (1989), 115–135. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-247X(89)90098-X doi: 10.1016/0022-247X(89)90098-X
![]() |
[2] |
E. Acerbi, G. Mingione, Regularity results for a class of functionals with non-standard growth, Arch. Rational Mech. Anal., 156 (2001), 121–140. https://doi.org/10.1007/s002050100117 doi: 10.1007/s002050100117
![]() |
[3] |
E. Acerbi, G. Mingione, Gradient estimates for the p(x)-Laplacean system, J. Reine Angew. Math., 584 (2005), 117–148. https://doi.org/10.1515/crll.2005.2005.584.117 doi: 10.1515/crll.2005.2005.584.117
![]() |
[4] |
E. Acerbi, G. Mingione, Gradient estimates for a class of parabolic systems, Duke Math. J., 136 (2007), 285–320. https://doi.org/10.1215/S0012-7094-07-13623-8 doi: 10.1215/S0012-7094-07-13623-8
![]() |
[5] | R. A. Adams, J. J. F. Fournier, Sobolev spaces, Amsterdam: Elsevier/Academic Press, 2003. |
[6] |
P. Baroni, Lorentz estimates for degenerate and singular evolutionary systems, J. Differ. Equations, 255 (2013), 2927–2951. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jde.2013.07.024 doi: 10.1016/j.jde.2013.07.024
![]() |
[7] |
P. Baroni, Riesz potential estimates for a general class of quasilinear equations, Calc. Var., 53 (2015), 803–846. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00526-014-0768-z doi: 10.1007/s00526-014-0768-z
![]() |
[8] |
P. Baroni, V. Bögelein, Calderón-Zygmund estimates for parabolic p(x,t)-Laplacian systems, Rev. Mat. Iberoam., 30 (2014), 1355–1386. https://doi.org/10.4171/RMI/817 doi: 10.4171/RMI/817
![]() |
[9] |
P. Baroni, M. Colombo, G. Mingione, Regularity for general functionals with double phase, Calc. Var., 57 (2018), 62. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00526-018-1332-z doi: 10.1007/s00526-018-1332-z
![]() |
[10] |
L. Beck, G. Mingione, Lipschitz bounds and nonuniform ellipticity, Commun. Pure Appl. Math., 73 (2020), 944–1034. https://doi.org/10.1002/cpa.21880 doi: 10.1002/cpa.21880
![]() |
[11] |
V. Bögelein, Global Calderón-Zygmund theory for nonlinear parabolic systems, Calc. Var., 51 (2014), 555–596. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00526-013-0687-4 doi: 10.1007/s00526-013-0687-4
![]() |
[12] | H. Brezis, Functional analysis, Sobolev spaces and partial differential equations, New York: Springer, 2011. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-387-70914-7 |
[13] |
M. Bulíček, S.-S. Byun, P. Kaplický, J. Oh, S. Schwarzacher, On global Lq-estimates for systems with p-growth in rough domains, Calc. Var., 58 (2019), 185. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00526-019-1621-1 doi: 10.1007/s00526-019-1621-1
![]() |
[14] |
S.-S. Byun, Y. Kim, Elliptic equations with measurable nonlinearities in nonsmooth domains, Adv. Math., 288 (2016), 152–200. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.aim.2015.10.015 doi: 10.1016/j.aim.2015.10.015
![]() |
[15] |
S.-S. Byun, J. Ok, S. Ryu, Global gradient estimates for general nonlinear parabolic equations in nonsmooth domains, J. Differ. Equations, 254 (2013), 4290–4326. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jde.2013.03.004 doi: 10.1016/j.jde.2013.03.004
![]() |
[16] |
S.-S. Byun, J. Ok, S. Ryu, Global gradient estimates for elliptic equations of p(x)-Laplacian type with BMO nonlinearity, J. Reine Angew. Math., 715 (2016), 1–38. https://doi.org/10.1515/crelle-2014-0004 doi: 10.1515/crelle-2014-0004
![]() |
[17] |
S.-S. Byun, L. Wang, Parabolic equations in time dependent Reifenberg domains, Adv. Math., 212 (2007), 797–818. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.aim.2006.12.002 doi: 10.1016/j.aim.2006.12.002
![]() |
[18] |
I. Chlebicka, A pocket guide to nonlinear differential equations in Musielak-Orlicz spaces, Nonlinear Anal., 175 (2018), 1–27. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.na.2018.05.003 doi: 10.1016/j.na.2018.05.003
![]() |
[19] |
A. Cianchi, V. G. Maz'ya, Global Lipschitz regularity for a class of quasilinear elliptic equations, Commun. Part. Diff. Eq., 36 (2011), 100–133. https://doi.org/10.1080/03605301003657843 doi: 10.1080/03605301003657843
![]() |
[20] |
A. Cianchi, V. G. Maz'ya, Global boundedness of the gradient for a class of nonlinear elliptic systems, Arch. Rational Mech. Anal., 212 (2014), 129–177. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00205-013-0705-x doi: 10.1007/s00205-013-0705-x
![]() |
[21] |
M. Colombo, G. Mingione, Bounded minimisers of double phase variational integrals, Arch. Rational Mech. Anal., 218 (2015), 219–273. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00205-015-0859-9 doi: 10.1007/s00205-015-0859-9
![]() |
[22] |
M. Colombo, G. Mingione, Regularity for double phase variational problems, Arch. Rational Mech. Anal., 215 (2015), 443–496. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00205-014-0785-2 doi: 10.1007/s00205-014-0785-2
![]() |
[23] |
M. Colombo, G. Mingione, Calderón–Zygmund estimates and non-uniformly elliptic operators, J. Funct. Anal., 270 (2016), 1416–1478. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfa.2015.06.022 doi: 10.1016/j.jfa.2015.06.022
![]() |
[24] |
C. De Filippis, G. Mingione, On the regularity of minima of non-autonomous functionals, J. Geom. Anal., 30 (2020), 1584–1626. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12220-019-00225-z doi: 10.1007/s12220-019-00225-z
![]() |
[25] |
C. De Filippis, G. Palatucci, Hölder regularity for nonlocal double phase equations, J. Differ. Equations, 267 (2019), 547–586. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jde.2019.01.017 doi: 10.1016/j.jde.2019.01.017
![]() |
[26] | E. DiBenedetto, Degenerate parabolic equations, New York: Springer, 1993. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4612-0895-2 |
[27] |
L. Diening, B. Stroffolini, A. Verde, Everywhere regularity of functionals with φ-growth, Manuscripta Math., 129 (2009), 449–481. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00229-009-0277-0 doi: 10.1007/s00229-009-0277-0
![]() |
[28] |
F. Duzaar, G. Mingione, Local Lipschitz regularity for degenerate elliptic systems, Ann. Inst. H. Poincaré (C) Anal. Non Linéaire, 27 (2010), 1361–1396. https://doi.org/10.1016/J.ANIHPC.2010.07.002 doi: 10.1016/J.ANIHPC.2010.07.002
![]() |
[29] |
F. Duzaar, G. Mingione, Gradient estimates via non-linear potentials, Amer. J. Math., 133 (2011), 1093–1149. https://doi.org/10.1353/ajm.2011.0023 doi: 10.1353/ajm.2011.0023
![]() |
[30] |
A. H. Erhardt, Existence of solutions to parabolic problems with nonstandard growth and irregular obstacles, Adv. Differential Equations, 21 (2016), 463–504. https://doi.org/10.57262/ade/1457536498 doi: 10.57262/ade/1457536498
![]() |
[31] |
L. Esposito, G. Mingione, Some remarks on the regularity of weak solutions of degenerate elliptic systems, Rev. Mat. Complut., 11 (1998), 203–219. https://doi.org/10.5209/rev_REMA.1998.v11.n1.17325 doi: 10.5209/rev_REMA.1998.v11.n1.17325
![]() |
[32] |
L. Esposito, F. Leonetti, G. Mingione, Regularity results for minimizers of irregular integrals with (p,q) growth, Forum Math., 14 (2002), 245–272. https://doi.org/10.1515/form.2002.011 doi: 10.1515/form.2002.011
![]() |
[33] |
L. Esposito, F. Leonetti, G. Mingione, Sharp regularity for functionals with (p,q) growth, J. Differ. Equations, 204 (2004), 5–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jde.2003.11.007 doi: 10.1016/j.jde.2003.11.007
![]() |
[34] | L. Evans, Partial differential equations, 2 Eds., Providence, RI: American Mathematical Society, 2010. |
[35] |
M. Giaquinta, G. Modica, Remarks on the regularity of the minimizers of certain degenerate functionals, Manuscripta Math., 57 (1986), 55–99. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01172492 doi: 10.1007/BF01172492
![]() |
[36] |
C. Hamburger, Regularity of differential forms minimizing degenerate elliptic functionals, J. Reine Angew. Math., 431 (1992), 7–64. https://doi.org/10.1515/crll.1992.431.7 doi: 10.1515/crll.1992.431.7
![]() |
[37] |
P. Hästö, J. Ok, Maximal regularity for local minimizers of non-autonomous functionals, J. Eur. Math. Soc., 24 (2022), 1285–1334. https://doi.org/10.4171/JEMS/1118 doi: 10.4171/JEMS/1118
![]() |
[38] |
Y. Kim, Gradient estimates for elliptic equations with measurable nonlinearities, J. Math. Pure. Appl. (9), 114 (2018), 118–145. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.matpur.2017.11.003 doi: 10.1016/j.matpur.2017.11.003
![]() |
[39] |
T. Kuusi, G. Mingione, Universal potential estimates, J. Funct. Anal., 262 (2012), 4205–4269. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfa.2012.02.018 doi: 10.1016/j.jfa.2012.02.018
![]() |
[40] |
T. Kuusi, G. Mingione, New perturbation methods for nonlinear parabolic problems, J. Math. Pure Appl. (9), 98 (2012), 390–427. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.matpur.2012.02.004 doi: 10.1016/j.matpur.2012.02.004
![]() |
[41] |
T. Kuusi, G. Mingione, Linear potentials in nonlinear potential theory, Arch. Rational Mech. Anal., 207 (2013), 215–246. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00205-012-0562-z doi: 10.1007/s00205-012-0562-z
![]() |
[42] |
T. Kuusi, G. Mingione, Riesz potentials and nonlinear parabolic equations, Arch. Rational Mech. Anal., 212 (2014), 727–780. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00205-013-0695-8 doi: 10.1007/s00205-013-0695-8
![]() |
[43] |
T. Kuusi, G. Mingione, Guide to nonlinear potential estimates, Bull. Math. Sci., 4 (2014), 1–82. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13373-013-0048-9 doi: 10.1007/s13373-013-0048-9
![]() |
[44] |
T. Kuusi, G. Mingione, Vectorial nonlinear potential theory, J. Eur. Math. Soc., 20 (2018), 929–1004. https://doi.org/10.4171/JEMS/780 doi: 10.4171/JEMS/780
![]() |
[45] | G. Leoni, A first course in Sobolev spaces, Providence, RI: American Mathematical Society, 2009. |
[46] |
P. Marcellini, Regularity of minimizers of integrals of the calculus of variations with nonstandard growth conditions, Arch. Rational Mech. Anal., 105 (1989), 267–284. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00251503 doi: 10.1007/BF00251503
![]() |
[47] |
P. Marcellini, Regularity and existence of solutions of elliptic equations with p, q-growth conditions, J. Differ. Equations, 90 (1991), 1–30. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0396(91)90158-6 doi: 10.1016/0022-0396(91)90158-6
![]() |
[48] | G. Mingione, The Calderón-Zygmund theory for elliptic problems with measure data, Ann. Sc. Norm. Super. Pisa Cl. Sci. (5), 6 (2007), 195–261. |
[49] |
G. Mingione, Gradient potential estimates, J. Eur. Math. Soc., 13 (2011), 459–486. https://doi.org/10.4171/JEMS/258 doi: 10.4171/JEMS/258
![]() |
[50] |
C. Scheven, Existence of localizable solutions to nonlinear parabolic problems with irregular obstacles, Manuscripta Math., 146 (2015), 7–63. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00229-014-0684-8 doi: 10.1007/s00229-014-0684-8
![]() |
[51] | R. E. Showalter, Monotone operators in Banach space and nonlinear partial differential equations, Providence, RI: American Mathematical Society, 1997. |
[52] |
P. Tolksdorf, Regularity for a more general class of quasilinear elliptic equations, J. Differ. Equations, 51 (1984), 126–150. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0396(84)90105-0 doi: 10.1016/0022-0396(84)90105-0
![]() |
[53] |
K. Uhlenbeck, Regularity for a class of non-linear elliptic systems, Acta Math., 138 (1977), 219–240. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02392316 doi: 10.1007/BF02392316
![]() |
[54] | V. V. Zhikov, On some variational problems, Russian J. Math. Phys., 5 (1997), 105–116. |