Currency B | |||
Cooperation | Non-cooperation | ||
Currency A | Cooperation | A1+θΔV−tc, A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)c |
A1+W−tc−L1, A2+T2−W |
Non-cooperation | A1+T1−W, A2+W−(1−t)c−L2 |
A1, A2 |
The consumption of minimally processed fruit (MPF) has increased over the last decade due to a novel trend in the food market along with the raising consumers demand for fresh, organic, convenient foods and the search for healthier lifestyles. Although represented by one of the most expanded sectors in recent years, the microbiological safety of MPF and its role as an emergent foodborne vehicle has caused great concern to the food industry and public health authorities. Such food products may expose consumers to a risk of foodborne infection as they are not subjected to prior microbial lethal methods to ensure the removal or destruction of pathogens before consumption. A considerable number of foodborne disease cases linked to MPF have been reported and pathogenic strains of Salmonella enterica, Escherichia coli, Listeria monocytogenes, as well as Norovirus accounted for the majority of cases. Microbial spoilage is also an issue of concern as it may result in huge economic losses among the various stakeholders involved in the manufacturing and commercialization of MPF. Contamination can take place at any step of production/manufacturing and identifying the nature and sources of microbial growth in the farm-to-fork chain is crucial to ensure appropriate handling practices for producers, retailers, and consumers. This review aims to summarize information about the microbiological hazards associated with the consumption of MPF and also highlight the importance of establishing effective control measures and developing coordinated strategies in order to enhance their safety.
Citation: Jessie Melo, Célia Quintas. Minimally processed fruits as vehicles for foodborne pathogens[J]. AIMS Microbiology, 2023, 9(1): 1-19. doi: 10.3934/microbiol.2023001
[1] | Xiaochun Chen, Jie Zhao, Yingying Ma, Bo Lv, Xuanjin Du . Tripartite evolutionary game study on coordination information security in prescription circulation. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(12): 21120-21146. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023934 |
[2] | Liurong Zhao, Xiaoxi Yu, Xinyu Zhou . The impact of regulatory mechanisms on vulnerability disclosure behavior during crowdsourcing cybersecurity testing. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(11): 19012-19039. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023841 |
[3] | Yuanyuan Huang, Yiping Hao, Min Wang, Wen Zhou, Zhijun Wu . Optimality and stability of symmetric evolutionary games with applications in genetic selection. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2015, 12(3): 503-523. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2015.12.503 |
[4] | A. Swierniak, M. Krzeslak, D. Borys, M. Kimmel . The role of interventions in the cancer evolution–an evolutionary games approach. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(1): 265-291. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019014 |
[5] | Andrzej Swierniak, Michal Krzeslak . Application of evolutionary games to modeling carcinogenesis. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2013, 10(3): 873-911. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2013.10.873 |
[6] | Fei Wang, Benhai Guo, Zixing Wang, Yuxin Wu . The impact of digital economy on the export competitiveness of China's manufacturing industry. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(4): 7253-7272. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023314 |
[7] | Zheng Liu, Lingling Lang, Lingling Li, Yuanjun Zhao, Lihua Shi . Evolutionary game analysis on the recycling strategy of household medical device enterprises under government dynamic rewards and punishments. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(5): 6434-6451. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021320 |
[8] | Dario Madeo, Chiara Mocenni, Jean Carlo Moraes, Jorge P. Zubelli . The role of self-loops and link removal in evolutionary games on networks. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(5): 5287-5306. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019264 |
[9] | Zhiyan Xing, Yanlong Yang, Zuopeng Hu . Nash equilibrium realization of population games based on social learning processes. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(9): 17116-17137. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023763 |
[10] | Jialing Li, Guiju Zhu, Xinya Hu, Ruqian Fei, Dan Yu, Dong Wang . Study on the evolutionary strategy of upward patient transfer in the loose medical consortia. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(9): 16846-16865. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023751 |
The consumption of minimally processed fruit (MPF) has increased over the last decade due to a novel trend in the food market along with the raising consumers demand for fresh, organic, convenient foods and the search for healthier lifestyles. Although represented by one of the most expanded sectors in recent years, the microbiological safety of MPF and its role as an emergent foodborne vehicle has caused great concern to the food industry and public health authorities. Such food products may expose consumers to a risk of foodborne infection as they are not subjected to prior microbial lethal methods to ensure the removal or destruction of pathogens before consumption. A considerable number of foodborne disease cases linked to MPF have been reported and pathogenic strains of Salmonella enterica, Escherichia coli, Listeria monocytogenes, as well as Norovirus accounted for the majority of cases. Microbial spoilage is also an issue of concern as it may result in huge economic losses among the various stakeholders involved in the manufacturing and commercialization of MPF. Contamination can take place at any step of production/manufacturing and identifying the nature and sources of microbial growth in the farm-to-fork chain is crucial to ensure appropriate handling practices for producers, retailers, and consumers. This review aims to summarize information about the microbiological hazards associated with the consumption of MPF and also highlight the importance of establishing effective control measures and developing coordinated strategies in order to enhance their safety.
The digitization of currency changes the form of money and intensifies market competition. Digital currency is increasingly playing an important role in the economic development of financial services, economic life and international exchanges. In the digital era, various types of currency competition are intensifying from a deeper level and a wider dimension. With the innovative application of digital technology, various forms of digital currency and payment have emerged in an endless stream, from the initial electronic ticket, to electronic card, to mobile payment, and various forms of virtual currency. The digital currency based on blockchain technology has triggered a new upsurge in currency innovation competition and cooperation among countries. At present, there are more than thousands of digital currencies which are in different financial ecosystems, such as Bitcoin, Litecoin, Ethereum, etc. Digitalization has changed the pattern of currency competition, including the competition between digital currency and traditional currency, private digital currency and central bank digital currency, as well as the competition between legal digital currency of various countries. The development of central bank digital currencies in many countries further highlights the importance of research on competition and cooperation in the international digital currency system. Therefore, the innovation competition and regulatory coordination of digital currency is a problem worthy of further study.
Digital currency is a new form of currency driven by fintech innovation, including electronic money, virtual money and legal digital money in a broad sense [1,2]. In the Internet era, the extensive use of information technology in the financial field has promoted a new round of fintech upsurge, and the innovation and application of blockchain technology is currently a hot spot [3,4]. At present, the digital currency based on blockchain technology is different from the electronic form of legal currency, the virtual currency provided by network operators and applied in the virtual space of the network [5,6]. The current electronic currency refers to the digitalization of cash or deposits representing certain wealth through electronic means, and the direct settlement of claims and debts through data trading system, which is essentially the digitalization of legal notes [7,8,9]. The virtual currency mainly refers to the exchange symbol of service value related to real wealth provided by the network virtual space, which can be roughly divided into three categories: game currency, special currency issued by network service providers (such as Tencent Q Coin), and virtual currency used for Internet financial investment (such as Bitcoin and Litecoin) [10,11]. Therefore, the current research on digital currency mainly focuses on the evolution and assumption of specific forms [12,13], mostly using the form of electronic money or virtual money for comparative analysis [14,15].
Digitalization is changing the pattern of currency competition. From the perspective of monetary innovation, the extensive use of science and technology in the financial field has promoted a new round of fintech climax, especially the innovation and application of blockchain technology. In the era of credit money, money itself has no value, but a problem of money credit [16,17]. Under different currency issuing systems, there are great differences in credit guarantee [18,19,20]. At present, from the perspective of attributes, it is mainly divided into public and private issuance, which is essentially the difference between fiat money (national credit) and private money (private credit) [21,22]. Therefore, the competition of digital currency mainly includes: the competition between digital currency and traditional currency, the competition between private digital currencies and central bank digital currencies, and the game of fiat digital currency will become a new focus of international currency competition, and the game around sovereign digital currencies is in full bloom [23,24,25]. It is an inevitable process for currency competition to evolve from private currency to national sovereign currency to super-sovereign currency, or to monopolize with a few sovereign currencies as international currency [26,27,28]. Digital currency competition has reached a consensus. First, competition among virtual currencies. Market results of virtual sales strategy different from traditional real sales strategy (players can only use real currency to purchase payment modules) are analyzed, and users are guided to use more virtual currency [29,30,31]. Second, competition among central bank digital currencies (CBDC). Various competitions have arisen due to central bank digital currencies or synthetic central bank digital currencies, including the competition between global stable currency (GSC) and fiat currency [32,33]. Competition between global stable currencies as well as competition between different central bank digital currencies [34,35].
There is a lot of literature on the analysis of currency competition methods. Based on the method of game theory, the international currency competition is deeply studied. From the interest game relationship between the issuing countries and the using countries of international currency, it is necessary to establish a fair international financial order, balance the interest risks between the issuing countries and the using countries of international currency, analyze the win-win model of currency internationalization and study the quantitative impact [36,37]. It constructs a game theory model in the open economy and analyzes the game process in which the central bank changes agents' expectations by changing exchange rate and monetary policy signals [38]. It analyzed the evolutionary equilibrium of euro and US dollar in a single population network [39]. Then, it extended the evolution of international currency in a single population environment to a multi-population environment, analyzing enterprises' preference for currency, the international usage of currency and the degree of currency internationalization in a multi-population environment [40]. Based on the revenue function of currency issuance and circulation, a two-country currency network model is established and extended to the multi-country model by evolutionary network game simulation [41,42].
At present, most research results and practices on digital currency are based on the evolution of digital currency, and they try to guide the development of digital currency and the design of future sovereign digital currency through technological innovation, promotion and use and financial regulation [43,44,45], while it ignored the competition and cooperation among digital currencies in the multi-currency network. This paper establishes an evolutionary game model among digital currencies without considering external factors to discuss the strategy adopted among different currencies. On this basis, financial supervision coordination is introduced. Under the condition that financial institutions participate in cooperation and provide incentive mechanism, the cooperative evolutionary game process of three-party game model is established and simulated, the countermeasures for the development of digital currency are put forward with the results of mathematical simulation. The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 spontaneous model of digital currency competition. Section 3 evolutionary model of digital currency competition under the financial coordination. Section 4 illustrates and simulates the digital currency competition. Finally, the conclusions and suggestions are given in Section 5.
Digital currency takes technological innovation and use preference as their core competitiveness. The competition among currencies is a game based on currency dominance, which is essentially a series of game processes such as competing for currency market share among digital currencies to build a currency system with the dominant currency as the core. By establishing the digital currency game model, the digital currency participant spontaneous competitive game is carried out. Combined with the dominant and persistent problems in digital currency competition, a competitive game model is constructed to analyze the competition and cooperation strategies of participants, and the optimal behavior in the process of digital currency competition is obtained. Based on the above analysis, the following hypothesis is proposed.
Hypothesis 1: There are traditional electronic currency A (issued by institution A) and new digital currency B (issued by enterprise B), which players of the game are bounded rationality regardless of the external environmental friction. In the multi-currency market, currency A and B have two strategies that they can choose to cooperate or not to cooperate. Cooperation strategies of currencies include information sharing, system compatibility, application channel interaction, etc., while non-cooperation strategies include market barriers, system incompatibility, etc.
Hypothesis 2: The initial income of currency A and B is A1 and A2 respectively. If currency A and B have cooperative intention to become partners, the additional revenue of the cooperation between the two parties is ΔV, where the additional revenue of currency A is θΔV and that of currency B is (1−θ)ΔV, θ(0<θ<1) is the additional distribution coefficient of income. If the cooperation breaks down, the revenue of currency A and B are respectively T1 and T2. Due to the continuity of business development and the asymmetry of countermeasures, the benefits of both parties in the process of termination of cooperation are inconsistent, which the party that actively chooses to withdraw from the cooperation in advance will gain more speculative gains. If both parties have no intention to cooperate, the income of both parties shall be the initial operating income.
Hypothesis 3: Currency A and currency B need to pay certain operating costs in the operation process, and if the two parties cooperate, they also need to pay cooperation costs. The total cooperation cost paid by currency A and B is c, where the cost paid by currency A is tc, the cost paid by currency B is (1−t)c, t(0<t<1) is the ratio coefficient of cost-sharing. If the partnership breaks down, the cost of currency A and B are respectively L1 and L2. While part of the business is still in contact, the exiting party needs to bear default costs W as a certain penalty, and the party who chooses to continue needs to undertake additional loss costs.
The probability of cooperation strategy adopted by currency A is x (0≤ x ≤1), then the probability of non-cooperative strategy is (1- x). The probability of cooperation strategy adopted currency B is y (0≤ y ≤1), then the probability of non-cooperative strategy is (1- y).
The payoff matrix of the game between currency A and B is shown in Table 1 below:
Currency B | |||
Cooperation | Non-cooperation | ||
Currency A | Cooperation | A1+θΔV−tc, A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)c |
A1+W−tc−L1, A2+T2−W |
Non-cooperation | A1+T1−W, A2+W−(1−t)c−L2 |
A1, A2 |
In the competitive process, the phased game strategy chosen by currency A and B may not be stationary and optimal, because the influence of the environment and cognition factors of the monetary institution. They will constantly adjust their strategies according to the growth of currency innovation, and through the adjustment of strategies to obtain a stable strategy for both sides. According to the above assumptions and payoff matrix (Table 1), then the income of cooperation strategy adopted by currency A is U1A, the income of the non-cooperation strategy is U2A and the average income of comprehensive strategy selection is −UA.
The income of cooperation strategy adopted by currency A:
U1A=y(A1+θΔV−tc)+(1−y)(A1+W−tc−L1) | (2.1) |
Benefits of non-cooperative strategy of currency A:
U2A=y(A1+T1−W)+(1−y)A1 | (2.2) |
The average income of combined possible strategies adopted by currency A:
−UA=xU1A+(1−x)U2A | (2.3) |
Then, the replication dynamic equation for currency A:
dxdt=x(1−x)[y(θΔV−T1+L1)+W−tc−L1] | (2.4) |
In the same way, the replication dynamic equation for of currency B:
dydt=y(1−y){x[(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2]+W−(1−t)c−L2} | (2.5) |
According to Eqs (2.4) and (2.5), the two-dimensional dynamical system model of currency A and B is:
{Fx=x(1−x)[y(θΔV−T1+L1)+W−tc−L1]Fy=y(1−y){x[(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2]+W−(1−t)c−L2} | (2.6) |
The local stable equilibrium points of the model are:
(0,0),(0,1),(1,0),(1,1),((1−t)c+L2−W(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2,tc+L1−WθΔV−T1+L1) |
The first-order partial derivatives of x and y of the replication dynamic equation are obtained respectively. The Jacobian matrix is as follows:
J=[(1−2x)[y(θΔV−T1+L1)+W−tc−L1]x(1−x)(θΔV−T1+L1)y(1−y)[(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2](1−2y){x[(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2]+W−(1−t)c−L2}] | (2.7) |
We can judge the local stability in various situations by the eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix and the signs of the trace, and obtain the evolutionary stability strategy. It can be seen from Table 2 that the equilibrium points (0, 0) and (1, 1) is the local stable point, and ((1−t)c+L2−W(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2, tc+L1−WθΔV−T1+L1) is the saddle point. So, the evolutionary stable strategy of spontaneous currencies competition is {cooperation, cooperation} or {no cooperation, no cooperation}.
Equilibrium point | detJ | trJ | Stability |
(0, 0) | + | – | ESS |
(1, 1) | + | – | ESS |
(0, 1) | + | + | Unstable |
(1, 0) | + | + | Unstable |
((1−t)c+L2−W(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2, tc+L1−WθΔV−T1+L1) | – | Saddle point |
According to the evolutionary stability analysis and dynamic replication equation phase diagram of currencies game, the connection between points (0, 0), (1, 0) and saddle point determines each part of the region, which the final strategy of currency A and currency B in the game is affected by the saddle point. When the coordinate value corresponding to the saddle point converges to (0, 0), the area of the upper region is larger, indicating that currency A and B are more likely to choose cooperation strategy. On the contrary, when the coordinate value corresponding to the saddle point converges to (1, 1), the area of the lower region is larger, indicating that currency A and B are more inclined to choose the non-cooperative strategy. In the currency evolutionary game model, the position of saddle point is affected by cooperation income and distribution coefficient, cooperation cost and sharing coefficient, loss cost, liquidated damages and speculative income. When the initial parameters reach a stable state, the cycle of collaborative strategies among digital currencies will become longer, which is conducive to promoting the common development of digital currencies. Therefore, cooperation strategies such as information technology sharing and market opening can promote collaborative innovation among currencies.
Financial regulation coordination is an important external force affecting the innovation and development of digital currencies. The innovative development of digital currency needs not only internal technical support, but also external financial policies and norms. In the innovation and cooperation of digital currency, on the one hand, faced with the upgrade of fintech, emerging currencies at a disadvantage may make traditional currencies fall into difficulties through innovation, and the new mode of one side makes the original operation of the other side difficult to continue. On the other hand, in the face of sudden policies such as financial regulation, both parties may face the risk of failure of the original business. In the wave of fintech innovation, many financial institutions cooperate with third-party payment companies to use new technological tools and products to improve currency business development and realize the interaction of different currencies through technological cooperation. From the perspective of financial regulation, financial coordination and regulation can solve the problem of market participation of digital currency in different growth stages. Based on the above content, financial coordination institution C as a third party is added into the game model of currency A and B for analysis, and the following assumptions are put forward.
Hypothesis 4: Financial regulatory coordination bodies mainly meet the practical needs, financial efficiency and policy security of digital currencies at various stages of regional development. The selection coordination strategy set of financial regulators is {strong participation, weak participation}. Therefore, the three parties involved in the game are bounded rationality and choose the optimal strategy through multiple games.
Hypothesis 5: When the financial coordination institution participates in the development of digital currency, the policies made by financial regulatory coordination can reduce the total cost of currency A and B in the collaborative innovation cooperation process by s, and the distribution coefficient of participation cost remains unchanged. Currency A and B can use their own technology to help financial coordination institutions complete the digital transformation and form a good credit reputation for currencies, and obtain cooperation benefits as R, where the distribution coefficient of cooperation income is a(0<a<1). Then, the income of currency A and B are aR、(1−a)R respectively. If financial coordination institutionsCchoose the strategy of 'strong participation' in the development of digital currencies, their gains are A3. If financial coordination institution C chooses the strategy of "weak participation" which means little or no participation in currency competition regulation, and their gains are bA3, Where b (0<b<1) is the ratio between the income obtained by the financial coordinating institution by choosing the "weak participation" strategy and the income obtained by choosing the "stronger participation" strategy.
Hypothesis 6: When financial regulators participate in the coordination of digital currency innovation and development, they need to supervise the commercial activities of digital currency, and they need to invest corresponding human, material and financial resources. Thus, the total cost incurred by financial regulators is K1. In addition, financial regulators also need to give certain incentives to digital currencies that actively participate in cooperation as K2.
There is a chance that financial regulators will move into co-ordination. The probability that financial regulator C chooses to participate in the coordination strategy is z (0 ≤ z ≤ 1), then the proportion of non-cooperative strategy is (1– z). According to the above six assumptions, the payment matrix of the game between financial coordinating institution and currencies is shown in Tables 3 and 4.
Financial Coordination C | Currency B | ||
Cooperation | Non-cooperation | ||
Currency A | Cooperation | A1+θΔV−t(c−s)+K2+aR, A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)(c−s)+K2 +(1−a)R, A3−K1−2K2 |
A1−t(c−s)−L1+K2+aR+W, A2+T2−W, A3−K1−K2 |
Non-cooperation | A1+T1−W, A2−(1−t)(c−s)−L2+K2+(1−a)R+W, A3−K1−K2 |
A1, A2, A3−K1 |
Financial Coordination C | Currency B | ||
Cooperation | Non-cooperation | ||
Currency A | Cooperation | A1+θΔV−tc, A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)c, bA3 |
A1+W−tc−L1, A2+T2−W, bA3 |
Non-cooperation | A1+T1−W, A2+W−(1−t)c−L2, bA3 |
A1, A2, bA3 |
According to Table 3 and Table 4, the expected benefits of currency A when adopting the strategy of "cooperation" is UA, the expected benefits of currency A when adopting the strategy "non-cooperation" is U1−A, the average income of an integrated situation is −UA.
UA=yz[A1+θΔV−t(c−s)+K2+aR]+(1−y)z[A1−t(c−s)+K2+aR+W−L1] |
+y(1−z)(A1+θΔV−tc)+(1−y)(1−z)(A1+W−tc−L1) | (3.1) |
U1−A=yz(A1+T1−W)+(1−y)zA1+y(1−z)(A1+T1−W)+(1−y)(1−z)A1 | (3.2) |
−UA=xUA+(1−x)U1−A | (3.3) |
The expected benefits of currency B when adopting the strategy of "cooperation" is UB, and the expected return when adopting the strategy of "non-cooperation" is U1−B, and the comprehensive average expected return is −UB.
UB=xz[A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)(c−s)+K2+(1−a)R]+ |
(1−x)z[A2−(1−t)(c−s)+K2+(1−a)R+W−L2]+x(1−z)[A2+(1−θ)ΔV |
−(1−t)c]+(1−x)(1−z)[A2+W−(1−t)c−L2] | (3.4) |
U1−B=xz(A2+T2−W)+(1−x)zA2+x(1−z)(A2+T2−W)+(1−x)(1−z)A2 | (3.5) |
−UB=yUB+(1−y)U1−B | (3.6) |
The expected return of financial coordination institution C when adopting the strategy of "stronger participation" is UC, and the expected return when adopting the strategy of "weak participation" is U1−C, the comprehensive average return is −UC.
UC=xy(A3−K1−2K2)+x(1−y)(A3−K1−K2)+ |
x(1−y)(A3−K1−K2)(1−x)(1−y)(A3−K1) | (3.7) |
U1−C=xybA3+x(1−y)bA3+x(1−y)bA3+(1−x)(1−y)bA3 | (3.8) |
−UC=zUC+(1−z)U1−C | (3.9) |
Thus, the replication dynamic equation of currency A can be written as:
F(x)=dxdt=x(1−x)[z(aR+K2+ts)y(θΔV−T1+L1)+W−tc−L1] | (3.10) |
The replication dynamic equation of currency B is:
F(y)=dydt=y(1−y){z[(1−a)R+K2+(1−t)s]+ |
x[(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2]+W−(1−t)c−L2} | (3.11) |
The replication dynamic equation of financial coordination institution C is:
F(z)=dzdt=z(1−z)[(1−b)A3−K1−(x+y)K2] | (3.12) |
Therefore, the replication dynamic equations of currency A, currency B and financial coordination institution C are established as:
{F(x)=x(1−x)[z(aR+K2+ts)+y(θΔV−T1+L1)+W−tc−L1]F(y)=y(1−y){z[(1−a)R+K2+(1−t)s]+x[(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2]+W−(1−t)c−L2}F(z)=z(1−z)[(1−b)A3−K1−(x+y)K2] | (3.13) |
Proposition 1: The equilibrium points of the dynamic evolutionary game of currency A, B and financial coordination institution C in the same equilibrium state are respectively: E1=(0,0,0), E2=(0,0,0), E3=(0,0,1), E4=(0,1,0), E5=(0,1,1), E6=(1,0,0), E7=(1,1,0), E8=(1,1,1).
Proof: Partial derivatives are obtained for the replication dynamic equations of currency A, currency B and financial coordination institution C, namely, dxdt=0, dydt=0, dzdt=0. It can be concluded that E1=(0,0,0), E2=(0,0,1), E3=(0,1,0), E4=(0,1,1), E5=(1,0,0), E6=(1,0,1), E7=(1,1,0), E8=(1,1,1) are the balance points of the system. So, the proof is completed.
Therefore, the first-order partial derivatives of x, y, and z of the replication dynamic equation are respectively calculated to determine the evolution and stability strategy of the system. The corresponding Jacobian matrix is as follows:
J=[a1x(1−x)(L1+θΔV−T1)x(1−x)(R1+K2+ts)y(1−y)[L2+(1−θ)ΔV−T2]a2y(1−y)[K2+R2+(1−t)s]−z(1−z)K2−z(1−z)K2a3] | (3.14) |
Where, a1=(1−2x)[z(aR+K2+ts)y(θΔV−T1+L1)+W−tc−L1], a2=(1−2y){z[(1−a)R+K2+(1−t)s]+x[(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2]+W−(1−t)c−L2}, a3=(1−2z)[(1−b)A3−K1−(x+y)K2].
The above eight equilibrium points are put into the Jacobian matrix, and the eigenvalues obtained are shown in Table 5.
Equilibrium point | λ1 | λ2 | λ3 |
E1(0,0,0) | W−tc−L1 | W−(1−t)c−L2 | (1−b)A3−K1 |
E2(0,0,1) | K2+aR+W−t(c −s)−L1 |
K2+(1−a)R+W−(1 −t)(c−s)−L2 |
−[(1−b)A3−K1] |
E3(0,1,0) | θΔV+W−T1−tc | −[W−(1−t)c−L2] | (1−b)A3−K1−K2 |
E4(0,1,1) | K2+aR+θΔV+W −t(c−s)−T1 |
−[K2+(1−a)R+W−(1 −t)(c−s)−L2] |
−[(1−b)A3−K1−K2] |
E5(1,0,0) | −(W−tc−L1) | (1−θ)ΔV−T2+W− (1−t)c |
(1−b)A3−K1−K2 |
E6(1,0,1) | −[K2+aR+W−t(c −s)−L1] |
K2+(1−a)R+W−(1−t)(c−s)+(1−θ)ΔV−T2 | −[(1−b)A3−K1−K2] |
E7(1,1,0) | −[θΔV−T1+W−tc] | −[(1−θ)ΔV−T2+ −(1−t)c] |
(1−b)A3−K1−2K2 |
E8(1,1,1) | −[K2+aR+W]−t(c −s)+θΔV−T1 |
−[K2+(1−a)R+W−(1−t)(c−s)+(1−θ)ΔV−T2] | −[(1−b)A3−K1 −2K2] |
The symbols of eigenvalues corresponding to each equilibrium point are analyzed to judge the results of three-party game strategies. According to the realistic feasibility, assuming the participation of financial institutions, the net income of three partner currency A, B and financial coordination institution C is greater than the net income of the three parties without cooperation. That is W−tc−T1>0, W−(1−t)c−T2>0, (1−b)A3−K1−2K2>0. It is necessary to consider the changes in parameters such as costs, cooperation benefits, and incentives paid by various participating entities when financial coordination institutions services digital currencies. The following three propositions is proposed for discussion.
Proposition 2: When K2+aR+W−t(c−s)−L1<0 and K2+(1−a)R+W−(1−t)(c−s)−L2<0, the sum of the rewards and cooperation benefits obtained from the financial institution that the currency A adopts a cooperation strategy is less than the cooperation cost paid by currency A with the participation of financial coordination institution C and the additional payment paid by the counterparty's midway exit. The sum of the loss cost of currency B adopting the cooperation strategy and the return and cooperation income obtained from the financial coordination institution is less than the cooperation cost paid by currency B and the additional loss cost paid by currency B withdrawing from the cooperation strategy when the financial coordination institution participates. In this case, the equilibrium point of the system is E2(0,0,1) and E8(1,1,1), then the evolutionary equilibrium strategy of the system is {no cooperation, no cooperation, participation} or {cooperation, cooperation, participation}.
Proof: According to Lyapunov stability theory, the asymptotic stability at the equilibrium point is judged by analyzing the eigenvalues of Jacobian matrix. When all the eigenvalues are not positive, the equilibrium point is the stable point of the evolutionary game. Therefore, the equilibrium points of proposition 2 is determined, as shown in Table 6.
Equilibrium point | Proposition 2 | Stability | ||
λ1 | λ2 | λ3 | ||
E1(0,0,0) | – | – | + | Unstable |
E2(0,0,1) | – | – | – | ESS |
E3(0,1,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E4(0,1,1) | + | + | – | Unstable |
E5(1,0,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E6(1,0,1) | – | + | – | Unstable |
E7(1,1,0) | – | – | + | Unstable |
E8(1,1,1) | – | – | – | ESS |
Proposition 3: When W−tc−L1>0 or W−(1−t)c−L2>0, the return obtained by currency A by adopting cooperation strategy from financial coordination institution is greater than the sum of the cost paid by currency A when the financial coordination institution C does not participate and the additional loss cost paid by the counterparty's midway exit. Or the return obtained by currency B adopts a cooperative strategy from financial coordinating institution is greater than the sum of the cost paid by currency B when financial coordinating institution C does not participate and the additional loss cost paid by the counterparty's midway exit. At this point, the system game equilibrium point is E8(1,1,1), then the evolution strategy is {cooperation, cooperation, participation}.
Proof: The process as above. The equilibrium points of proposition 3 is determined, as shown in Table 7.
Equilibrium point | Proposition 3 | Stability | ||
λ1 | λ2 | λ3 | ||
E1(0,0,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E2(0,0,1) | + | + | – | Unstable |
E3(0,1,0) | + | – | + | Unstable |
E4(0,1,1) | + | – | – | Unstable |
E5(1,0,0) | – | + | + | Unstable |
E6(1,0,1) | – | + | – | Unstable |
E7(1,1,0) | – | – | + | Unstable |
E8(1,1,1) | – | – | – | ESS |
Proposition 4: When K2+aR+W−t(c−s)−L1>0 and W−tc−L1<0 or K2+(1−a)R+W−(1−t)(c−s)−L2>0 and W−(1−t)c−L2<0, the sum of the return from the financial coordination institution and cooperation income obtained by currency A which adopts a cooperation strategy is greater than the cooperation cost paid by currency A with the participation of financial coordination and the payment of counterparty's exit. The sum of the additional loss cost and the rewards from financial coordination obtained by currency A adopts a cooperative strategy is less than the sum of the cost paid by currency A when the financial coordination institution C does not participate and the additional loss cost paid by the counterparty's exit. Or the sum of cooperation benefits and rewards from financial coordination obtained by currency B adopts a cooperation strategy is greater than the sum of the cooperation cost paid by currency B with the participation of financial coordination and the additional loss cost paid by the other party's company withdrawing midway. The return from financial coordination obtained by currency B adopts a cooperative strategy is less than the sum of the cost paid by currency B when the financial coordination institution does not participate and the additional loss cost paid by the counterparty's currency withdrawing midway. In this case, the system equilibrium point is E8(1,1,1), then the evolution strategy is {cooperation, cooperation, participation}.
Proof: The process as above. The equilibrium points of proposition 4 is determined, as shown in Table 8.
Equilibrium point | Proposition 4 | |||
λ1 | λ2 | λ3 | Stability | |
E1(0,0,0) | - | - | + | Unstable |
E2(0,0,1) | + | + | - | Unstable |
E3(0,1,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E4(0,1,1) | + | - | - | Unstable |
E5(1,0,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E6(1,0,1) | - | + | - | Unstable |
E7(1,1,0) | - | - | + | Unstable |
E8(1,1,1) | - | - | - | ESS |
Many governments have paid more attention to digital currencies and adopted a series of policies and actions to support the development of digital currency, especially those based on blockchain technology. In response to the innovation and coordination of digital currency, more regions centered on the themes of fintech and legal digital currency, and encouraged banks to increase the research and development of payment through diversified fintech policies. Some digital currency competition cases or scenarios are more in-depth and intuitive discussion. The survey selects two types of currency, that is the traditional electronic currency A and a new blockchain digital currency B in the innovation incubator. Financial coordination institution C chooses the right strategy according to the competitive gains of currency A and B. In order to more intuitively determine the evolutionary path of each participant, numerical experiments are used to analyze the influence of currencies and financial coordinating institution's selection strategy and the influence of parameter changes on the evolutionary path. According to the hypothesis and analysis of the previous model, the parameters in the payment matrix should meet W−tc−T1>0, W−(1−t)c−T2>0, (1−b)A3−K1−2K2>0. According to literature and practical experience, assume that the initial value of some parameter in the three-party game is: ΔV = 20, θ=t=a=b= 0.5, A1 = 25, A2 = 30, A3 = 60, W=30,R=16,s=16,c=50, T1 = 5, T2 = 10, L1 = 40, L2 = 45, K1 = 10, K2 = 8. In addition, the initial willingness of currencies A and B and financial coordination institution C to participate is x=y=z=0.5.
According to the above parameter settings, the selection strategy dynamic change and the dynamic equilibrium result of the intention change of financial coordination institution C and currency A and B in the game are simulated. On this basis, it further explores the influence of the distribution coefficient of cooperation income, the reduction in cooperation cost of currencies, the cooperation cost of financial institutions and the changes in incentive parameters on the evolution path of currencies innovation game when financial coordination institutions participate in cooperation.
During the development of digital currencies, the willingness of currency issuing institutions and financial regulatory coordination bodies to participate in cooperation affects the choice of currency competition strategies. With other initial parameters unchanged, the influence of the change of the initial willingness coefficient of financial coordination institution C and currency A and B on the outcome of the game strategy is simulated and analyzed (Figure 1). It is assumed that the initial willingness of the three parties in the game is the same, that is, the initial willingness thresholds of the currency A and B and financial coordinating institution C is between 0.4 and 0.5. When the initial willingness of the three parties to participate in cooperation is less than the critical value 0.4, x and y tend to converge to 0, and z tends to converge to 1, so the final game equilibrium point tends to (0, 0, 1). Meanwhile, it is found that the willingness of well-developed currency B to participate converges faster than that of currency A. When the initial willingness of the three parties to participate in cooperation is greater than the critical value 0.5, x, y, z tends to converge to 1. Therefore, the final game equilibrium point tends to (1, 1, 1). In this case, the larger the initial willingness parameter value of currency A is, the faster its convergence speed will be. When the initial willingness of the three parties to participate in cooperation is at the medium level, as the willingness of financial coordination institutions to participate in cooperation slowly increases, so does the willingness of currency A to participate in cooperation, while that of currency B slowly declines. With the increasing willingness of financial coordination institution C and currency A to participate in cooperation, and the increasing willingness of currency B, both of them finally choose to participate. When the willingness of the three parties to participate in cooperation is high, the willingness of financial coordination institutions and currencies to participate in cooperation will directly increase and eventually converge to the equilibrium point (1, 1, 1). The results show that with the increasing initial willingness of the three parties to participate in cooperation, x and y converge to 1 more quickly, and z converges to 1 more slowly. Finally, the three parties tend to participate in cooperation. In this process, when financial coordination institutions have strong willingness to cooperate and participate, currencies will eventually choose cooperation and reach long-term cooperation with financial coordination institutions, so as to obtain the support of financial authorities and achieve their own stable development.
Whether a currency participates in the cooperation of financial coordination institutions is affected by similar currencies. When other parameters remain unchanged, the influence of the change of the initial willingness of currency A on the strategy of the three-way game is simulated and analyzed (Figure 2). When the initial cooperation willingness of currency B and financial coordination institution C is neutral, the initial cooperation willingness of currency A is between 0.3 and 0.4. When the initial willing value of currency A is less than 0.3, x and y converge to 0 and z converges to 1, and the final game equilibrium point tends to (0, 0, 1). At this time, currency B with higher initial participation willingness is affected by currency A's participation willingness, and its convergence speed is faster. When the initial willing value of currency A is greater than 0.4, x, y and z all converge to 1, and the final game equilibrium tends to (1, 1, 1). In this case, currency A, which has a higher initial willingness value, converges to 1 faster than currency B. When the initial willingness of currency A is less than that of currency B, as the initial willingness of currency A continues to decline, the initial willingness of currency B declines faster, and the willingness to cooperate with financial coordinating institutions slowly rises. When the initial value of the willingness to cooperate with currency A is greater than that of currency B, the willingness to cooperate with currency A continues to increase, while the willingness to cooperate with currency B slowly declines first and then continues to rise. The willingness to cooperate with financial coordinating institutions still rises slowly and finally converges to the equilibrium point (1, 1, 1). The results show that the willingness of currencies to participate in cooperation continues to rise, and the willingness to participate in the same type of currency B and financial coordination will gradually increase. This is because financial coordination provides monetary participants with certain policies and market norms, and whether monetary participants adopt cooperative strategies is largely affected by the participation willingness of peer enterprises. When one party is less willing to participate in cooperation, it will eventually choose non-cooperative strategy.
Whether currency participates in the cooperation of financial coordination institutions is affected by the cooperation willingness of financial coordination institutions. When other parameters remain unchanged, the three parties' willingness to participate in cooperation is simulated and analyzed (Figure 3). Both currency A and currency B are in a neutral state, and the willingness of financial coordination institutions to participate in cooperation is between 0.3 and 0.4. When the cooperation willingness of financial coordination institutions is less than the critical value 0.3, x and y converge to 0, z converges to 1, and the final game equilibrium point tends to (0, 0, 1). At this time, the willingness of currency A and currency B to participate in cooperation is greatly reduced. When the willingness of financial coordination institutions to participate in cooperation is greater than the critical value 0.4, x, y and z all converge to 1, and the final game equilibrium point tends to (1, 1, 1). At this time, the willingness of currency A and currency B to participate in cooperation increases sharply with the increase of the willingness of financial coordination institutions to cooperate, and finally converges to 1. When the willingness of financial coordination institutions to participate in cooperation continued to increase, the willingness of currency to participate in cooperation first dropped sharply, and then rose sharply, and finally reached cooperation with financial coordination. The results show that when the willingness of financial coordination institutions to cooperate is low, the currency is still in a wait-and-see state, and its willingness to cooperate declines sharply over time. The greater the willingness of financial coordinators to cooperate, the greater the willingness of currencies to participate in cooperation. This is because cooperation with currencies can bring the development of fintech and additional cooperation benefits to themselves, and financial institutions will change from low willingness to participate in cooperation to high willingness to cooperate.
When other parameters remain unchanged, the final cooperation strategy of the three parties is simulated and analyzed while the willingness to participate in cooperation changes (Figure 4). When the willingness of currency A and currency B to participate in cooperation is very low, even if the willingness of financial coordination institutions to participate in cooperation is very high, x and y converge to 0, and z converges to 1, currency A and currency B will not adopt cooperation strategy. When the willingness of currency A and currency B to participate in cooperation is high, x and y will converge to 1 and z will converge to 1 even if the willingness of the financial coordination institution to participate in cooperation is low. That is, both currency A and currency B are willing to cooperate with financial coordinator C, and weaker currency A's willingness to cooperate converges faster than currency B.
The change in cost reduction resulting from the cooperation between currencies under the financial coordination will affect the competitive strategies adopted by the currency A and the currency B in their development. When other parameters remain unchanged, a simulation analysis is conducted on the reduction of cooperation cost brought by currencies under the financial regulation coordination (Figure 5). As can be seen from Figure 5, the critical value of cooperation cost reduction S is between 8 and 12. When the cooperation cost reduction S is less than the critical value, x and y tend to converge to 0, and the final game equilibrium point converges to (0, 0, 1). With the continuous increase of S, the convergence speed of x and y slows down, and the cost reduction of currency A is obvious. When the cooperation cost reduction S is greater than the critical value, x and y tend to converge to 1, and the final game equilibrium point converges to (1, 1, 1). With the continuous increase of S, the convergence speed of x and y accelerates, and the convergence speed of currency A is also faster than that of currency B. The results show that when the cooperation cost reduction is not enough to bring more benefits to the cooperation between currencies, it is difficult for monetary parties to reach cooperation under the financial coordination institution. The cost reduction brought about by cooperation under the financial coordination affects whether currencies adopt cooperation strategies, which has a greater impact on the weaker currency A.
The cooperation benefits brought by the coordination of currencies under the financial coordination affect the competitive strategies adopted by currency A and B in the development process. When other parameters remain unchanged, a simulation analysis is carried out on the change of cooperation revenue R brought by monetary parties under the financial regulation coordination (Figure 6). As can be seen from Figure 6, the critical value of cooperation revenue R under the financial coordination in the currency game ranges from 10 to 13. When the cooperation income is lower than the critical value, both x and y converge to 0, and the final game equilibrium point converges to (0, 0, 1). As R increases, the converge of x and y slows down. When the cooperative gain is higher than the critical value, both x and y tend to converge to 1, and the final game equilibrium point converges to (1, 1, 1). As R increases, x and y converge faster, which currencies are more willing to adopt cooperative strategies. The results show that the higher the cooperation benefits brought by the cooperation between currencies under the financial coordination institution, the greater the willingness of currencies to participate in cooperation. This is because currencies cooperation under the financial regulation coordination may introduce positive externalities that are better positioned to grow and develop in the market.
The cooperative cost of financial coordination institutions affects the competitive strategies adopted by currency A, B and financial coordination institution C. With other parameters unchanged, the impact of financial institutions' participation in coordination and cooperation cost changes is simulated and analyzed (Figure 7). As can be seen from Figure 7, the critical value of the cost K1 paid by financial institutions to participate in coordinating cooperation ranges from 10 to 22. When the cost of financial coordination institutions participating in cooperation K1 is less than the critical value, x, y, and z tend to converge to 1, and the final game equilibrium point is (1, 1, 1), which the financial coordination institution is more willing to cooperate with currency A and B. When the cost of financial coordination institution participation in cooperation K1 is greater than the critical value, x, y, and z tend to converge to 0, and the final game equilibrium point is (0, 0, 0), which financial coordination institution and currency A and B are unwilling to cooperate, and the convergence rate of financial coordinating institutions' participation intention is faster than that of currencies A and B. The results show that when the cost of cooperation in financial coordination is high, the cooperation income of financial coordination institution is lower than that of non-cooperative strategies, financial coordination institution will not be willing to cooperate and coordinate, and currencies will not seek help from financial coordination.
The incentive income of financial coordination institution's participation in cooperation affects the competitive strategy adopted by currency A, B and financial coordination institution C. With other parameters unchanged, a simulation analysis is conducted on the influence of change on the incentive income K2 of financial coordination institutions participating in cooperation (Figure 8). It can be seen from figure 8 that the critical value of cooperation incentive K2 given by the financial institution's coordination participation is between 8 and 14. When the incentive income of financial coordination participation is less than the critical value, x and y tend to converge to 0, z converges to 1, And the final game equilibrium point is (0, 0, 1), which currencies are unwilling to adopt the cooperation strategy. When the incentive income of financial coordinating institutions is greater than the critical value, x and y tend to converge to 1, z converges to 0, and the final game equilibrium point converges to (1, 1, 0), which financial coordinating institutions are unwilling to adopt cooperative strategies in this case. When the financial coordination incentive income is between critical values, x, y and z all converge to 1, and the final game equilibrium point is (1, 1, 1). At this point, the three parties are willing to cooperate, and with the continuous increase of K2, the willingness of currency to participate in cooperation converges faster than that of financial coordination institutions. The results show that when the incentive returns of currencies from participating financial coordination is low, the subjective willingness of currencies to participate in cooperation is less, which influenced by the selection of peer firms and market behavior. When the incentive returns reach a certain standard, the currencies will reach a cooperation agreement with the financial coordinating institution. However, once the incentives beyond the financial institutions to bear, the willingness of financial coordination institutions to participate in cooperation will slowly rise, then sharply decline, and finally choose non-cooperation strategy.
The application of digital currencies based on fintech has intensified the competition among currencies. New digital currencies with advanced technology will exert a great influence on the field of currency payment with the increase of application and recognition, thus promoting the improvement of financial efficiency. The technical cooperation and market sharing among digital currencies cannot meet the needs of the late growth of currencies, and will also generate a lot of competition risks. The healthy development of digital currencies needs to seek coordination and legal norms of financial regulatory authorities. Under the coordination of financial regulators, technical standards and legal norms can be formed among digital currencies to promote the orderly development of currencies. Meanwhile, the coordination of financial supervision can break through the technical and market barriers of currency interaction to improve financial efficiency. This paper systematically analyzes the two-party competitive game strategy of currency A, B and the three-party game strategy introduced by financial coordinating institution C by establishing the evolutionary game model between currency A, B and financial coordinating institution C, and analyzes the influence relationship of the changes of main variables by numerical simulation.
The following conclusions can be drawn: first, the willingness of currency A, B and financial coordination institution C to participate in cooperation has different influence on each other's choice of competitive strategy and influence relationship. The strategy adopted by the currency is greatly affected by the willingness of the peer unit to participate in cooperation. The strategies adopted by currencies are also significantly affected by the willingness of financial coordinator to participate in cooperation. Second, the change of monetary cooperation costs and benefits will have a great impact on the strategies adopted by the three parties with the participation of financial coordination institutions. The reduction of the cost of monetary cooperation is greater than the range it can bear, and the willingness of financial coordination institutions to participate in cooperation decreases. The monetary cooperation income with the participation of financial coordination institutions is lower than the expected range, and the willingness of monetary and financial coordination institutions to establish cooperation is reduced. Third, the costs and incentive benefits of financial coordination institutions are more sensitive than those between currencies. Financial coordination institutions are willing to provide support for monetary cooperation when the cost and incentive benefits of participating in cooperation are within a certain range. Once beyond a certain range, the establishment of cooperative relations between financial coordinators may be greatly reduced.
During the growth of digital currency, it learns from the development experience and practice path of technology-leading currency, actively cooperates with technology enterprises to carry out fintech innovation, accelerates the application scenarios of new currency, and learns to seek help from financial regulators. In light of the development needs and characteristics of digital currencies, financial regulators have launched new currency access standards in a timely manner to promote the digital transformation of traditional currencies and improve the level of financial services. In digital currency innovation, in addition to the influence of financial institutions on the development of digital currency, government regulatory policies also have a significant impact on it. At present, governments around the world are actively introducing policies and regulations related to digital currencies, promoting the connection between traditional currencies and new currencies, and realizing cooperation and application coordination among digital currencies. The tripartite dialogue mechanism and docking platform of digital currency provide an effective way for regional financial development. At the same time, it is necessary to strengthen the coordination of financial regulation, avoid mainstream currencies from abusing their dominant market position and harming the rights and interests of consumers, and better realize the healthy development of the digital economy.
Currency digitization and effective supervision are the future trend of financial development. The competition between global legal digital currency and non-legal digital currency is worth further study. Due to the short development history of the new digital currency based on blockchain technology and the fact that the legal digital currency in many countries is still in the research and development and testing stage, there is a lack of complete digital currency operation data and evaluation indicators, and there are certain difficulties in the empirical test of competition. In this paper, the competitive situation of digital currency is analyzed by numerical simulation, and there is a lack of actual data effect support. In the future, we will continue to track the research on digital currency competition, systematically collect various data indicators of digital currency, and better measure the trend of digital currency competition and market efficiency.
The authors are highly grateful to any anonymous referee for their careful reading and insightful comments, and the views and opinions expressed are those of the authors. The work is supported by the Research Project of Philosophy and Society of Universities in Jiangsu Province (No. 2021SJZDA019), Provincial Social Science Foundation of Jiangsu (No. 21EYC013, 22SCC-20).
The authors declare there is no conflict of interest.
[1] |
Septembre-Malaterre A, Remize F, Poucheret P (2018) Fruits and vegetables, as a source of nutritional compounds and phytochemicals: Changes in bioactive compounds during lactic fermentation. Food Res Int 104: 86-99. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodres.2017.09.031 ![]() |
[2] |
Lafarga T, Colás-Medá P, Abadias M, et al. (2019) Strategies to reduce microbial risk and improve quality of fresh and processed strawberries. Inn Food Sci Emer Tech 52: 197-212. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ifset.2018.12.012 ![]() |
[3] |
Siroli LF, Patrignani DI, Serrazanetti F, et al. (2015) Innovative strategies based on the use of bio-control agents to improve the safety, shelf-life and quality of minimally processed fruits and vegetables. Trends Food Sci Tech 46: 302-310. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tifs.2015.04.014 ![]() |
[4] |
Samtiya M, Aluko RE, Dhewa T, et al. (2021) Potential health benefits of food-plant derived bioactive components: An Overview. Foods 10: 839-864. https://doi.org/10.3390/foods10040839 ![]() |
[5] |
Prakash A, Baskaran R, Paramasivam N, et al. (2018) Essential oils based nanoemulsions to improve the microbial quality of minimally processed fruits and vegetables: A review. Food Res Int 111: 509-523. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodres.2018.05.066 ![]() |
[6] |
Corato H (2019) Improving the quality and shelf-life of fresh and minimally processed fruits and vegetables for a modern industry: A comprehensive critical review from the traditional technologies into the most promising advancements. Crit Rev Food Sci Nutr 60: 940-975. https://doi.org/10.1080/10408398.2018.1553025 ![]() |
[7] |
Oliveira M, Abadias M, Usall J, et al. (2015) Application of modified atmosphere packaging as a safety approach to fresh-cut fruits and vegetables – A review. Trends Food Sci Tech 46: 13-26. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tifs.2015.07.017 ![]() |
[8] |
Heaton JC, Jones K (2008) Microbial contamination of fruit and vegetables and the behavior of enteropathogens in the phyllosphere: a review. J Appl Microbiol 104: 613-626. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1365-2672.2007.03587.x ![]() |
[9] |
Olaimat AN, Holley RA (2012) Factors influencing the microbial safety of fresh produce: a review. Food Microbiol 32: 1-19. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fm.2012.04.016 ![]() |
[10] |
Strawn LK, Schneider KR, Danyluk MD (2011) Microbial safety of tropical fruits. Crit Rev Food Sci Nutr 51: 132-145. https://doi.org/10.1080/10408390903502864 ![]() |
[11] |
Pérez-Lavalle L, Carrasco E, Valero A (2020) Strategies for microbial decontamination of fresh blueberries and derived products. Foods 9: 1558. https://doi.org/10.3390/foods9111558 ![]() |
[12] |
McQuiston JR, Waters RJ, Dinsmore BA, et al. (2007) Molecular determination of H antigens of Salmonella by use of microsphere-based liquid array. J Clin Microbiol 49: 565-573. https://doi.org/10.1128/JCM.01323-10 ![]() |
[13] |
Brandl MT, Amundson R (2008) Leaf age as risk factor in contamination of lettuce with Escherichia coli O157:H7 and Salmonella enterica. Appl Environ Microbiol 74: 2298-2306. https://doi.org/10.1128/AEM.02459-07 ![]() |
[14] |
Melotto M, Panchal S, Roy D (2014) Plant innate immunity against human bacterial pathogens. Front Microbiol 5: 411. https://doi.org/10.3389/fmicb.2014.00411 ![]() |
[15] | Wiedemann A, Virlougeux-Payant I, Chaussé A, et al. (2014) Interaction of Salmonella with animals and plants. Front Microbiol 5: 791. https://doi.org/10.3389/fmicb.2014.00791 |
[16] |
Coburn B, Grassi GA, Finlay BB (2007) Salmonella, the host and disease: a brief review. Immun Cell Biol 85: 112-118. https://doi.org/10.1038/sj.icb.7100007 ![]() |
[17] |
Mali-Kale P, Winfree S, Steele-Mortimer O (2012) The bimodal lifestyle of Salmonella in epithelial cells: replication in cytosol obscures defects in vacuolar replication. PLoS One 7: e38732. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0038732 ![]() |
[18] | European Commission Regulation.Commission Regulation (EC) No 2073/2005 on microbiological criteria for foodstuffs. Off J Eur Union L (2005) 338: 1-26. |
[19] |
Strawn LK, Danyluk MD (2010) Fate of Escherichia coli O157:H7 and Salmonella spp. on fresh and frozen cut mangoes and papayas. Int J Food Microbiol 138: 78-84. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2009.12.002 ![]() |
[20] |
Alegre I, Abadias M, Anguera M, et al. (2010) Fate of Escherichia coli O157:H7, Salmonella and Listeria innocua on minimally-processed peaches under different storage conditions. Food Microbiol 27: 862-868. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fm.2010.05.008 ![]() |
[21] |
Ukuku DO, Huang L, Sommers C (2015) Efficacy of sanitizer treatments on survival and growth parameters of Escherichia coli O157:H7, Salmonella, and Listeria monocytogenes on fresh-cut pieces of Cantaloupe during storage. J Food Prot 78: 1288-1295. https://doi.org/10.4315/0362-028X.JFP-14-233 ![]() |
[22] |
Palekar MP, Taylor TM, Maxim JE, et al. (2015) Reduction of Salmonella enterica serotype Poona and background microbiota on fresh-cut cantaloupe by electron beam irradiation. Int J Food Microbiol 202: 66-72. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2015.02.001 ![]() |
[23] |
Graça A, Santo D, Quintas C, et al. (2017) Growth of Escherichia coli, Salmonella enterica and Listeria spp., and their inactivation using ultraviolet energy and electrolyzed water, on ‘Rocha’ fresh-cut pears. Food Control 77: 41-49. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodcont.2017.01.017 ![]() |
[24] |
Yoo BK, Liu Y, Juneja V, et al. (2015) Growth characteristics of Shiga toxin-producing Escherichia coli (STEC) stressed by chlorine, sodium chloride, acid and starvation on lettuce and cantaloupe. Food Control 55: 97-102. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodcont.2015.02.040 ![]() |
[25] |
Berger CN, Sodha SV, Shaw RK, et al. (2010) Fresh fruit and vegetables as vehicles for the transmission of human pathogens. Environ Microbiol 12: 2385-2397. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1462-2920.2010.02297.x ![]() |
[26] |
Croxen MA, Law RJ, Scholz R, et al. (2013) Recent advances in understanding enteric pathogenic Escherichia coli. Clin Microbiol Rev 26: 822-880. https://doi.org/10.1128/CMR.00022-13 ![]() |
[27] |
Solomon EB, Yaron S, Matthews KR (2002) Transmission of Escherichia coli O157:H7 from contaminated manure and irrigation water to lettuce plant tissue and its subsequent internalization. Appl Environ Microbiol 68: 397-400. https://doi.org/10.1128/AEM.68.1.397-400.2002 ![]() |
[28] |
Natvig EE, Ingham SC, Ingham BH, et al. (2002) Salmonella enterica serovar Typhimurium and Escherichia coli contamination of root and leaf vegetables grown in soils with incorporated bovine manure. Appl Environ Microbiol 68: 2737-2744. https://doi.org/10.1128/AEM.68.6.2737-2744.2002 ![]() |
[29] |
Abadias M, Alegre I, Oliveira M, et al. (2012) Growth potential of Escherichia coli on fresh-cut fruits (melon and pineapple) and vegetables (carrot and escarole) stored under different conditions. Food Control 27: 37-44. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodcont.2012.02.032 ![]() |
[30] |
Buchanan RL, Gorris LGM, Heyman MM, et al. (2017) A review of Listeria monocytogenes: An update on outbreaks, virulence, dose response, ecology, and risk assessments. Food Control 75: 1-13. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodcont.2016.12.016 ![]() |
[31] |
NicAogáin K, O'Byrne CP (2016) The role of stress and stress adaptations determining the fate of bacterial pathogen Listeria monocytogenes in the food chain. Front Microbiol 7: 1865. https://doi.org/10.3389/fmicb.2016.01865 ![]() |
[32] |
Ferreira V, Wiedmann M, Teixeira P, et al. (2014) Listeria monocytogenes persistence in food-associated environments: Epidemiology, strain characteristics, and implications for public health. J Food Prot 77: 150-170. https://doi.org/10.4315/0362-028X.JFP-13-150 ![]() |
[33] |
Colagiorgi A, Bruini I, Di Ciccio PA, et al. (2017) Listeria monocytogenes biofilms in the wonderland of food industry. Pathogens 6: 41. https://doi.org/10.3390/pathogens6030041 ![]() |
[34] |
Colás Medà P, Vinas I, Alegre I, et al. (2017) The impact of a cold chain break on the survival of Salmonella enterica and Listeria monocytogenes on minimally processed “Conference” pears during their shelf life. J Sci Food Agric 97: 3077-3080. https://doi.org/10.1002/jsfa.8127 ![]() |
[35] |
Melo J, Andrew PW, Faleiro ML (2015) Listeria monocytogenes in cheese and the dairy environment remains a food safety challenge: The role of stress responses. Food Res Int 67: 75-90. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodres.2014.10.031 ![]() |
[36] | Shamloo E, Hosseini H, Moghadam ZA, et al. (2019) Importance of Listeria monocytogenes in food safety: a review of its prevalence, detection, and antibiotic resistance. Iran J Vet Res 20: 241-254. |
[37] |
Garner D, Kathariou S (2016) Fresh produce-associated listeriosis outbreaks, sources of concern, teachable moments, and insights. J Food Prot 79: 337-344. https://doi.org/10.4315/0362-028X.JFP-15-387 ![]() |
[38] |
Lopez-Valladares G, Danielsson-Tham ML, Tham W (2018) Implicated food products for listeriosis and changes in serovars of Listeria monocytogenes affecting humans for recent decades. Foodborne Pathog Dis 15: 387-397. https://doi.org/10.1089/fpd.2017.2419 ![]() |
[39] |
Gustafson RE, Ryser ET (2017) Thermal inactivation and growth of Listeria monocytogenes during production and storage of caramel apples. Food Control 79: 234-238. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodcont.2017.03.043 ![]() |
[40] | Glass KA, Golden MC, Wanless BJ, et al. (2015) Growth of Listeria monocytogenes within a caramel-coated apple microenvironment. AMS mBio 6: e01232-15. https://doi.org/10.1128/mBio.01232-15 |
[41] |
Ruiz-Llacsahuanga B, Hamilton A, Zaches R, et al. (2016) Utility of rapid tests to assess the prevalence of indicator organisms (aerobic plate count, Enterobacteriaceae, coliforms, Escherichia coli, and Listeria spp.) in apple packinghouses. Int J Food Microbiol 337: 108949. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2020.108949 ![]() |
[42] |
De Jesus AJ, Sheth I, Kwon HJ, et al. (2020) Survival of a serotype 4b strain and a serotype 1/2a strain of Listeria monocytogenes, isolated from a stone fruit outbreak investigation, on whole stone fruit at 4 °C. Int J Food Microbiol 334: 108801. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2020.108801 ![]() |
[43] |
Conway WS, Leverentz B, Saftner RA, et al. (2000) Survival and growth of Listeria monocytogenes on fresh-cut apples slices and its interactions with Glomerella cingulata and Penicillium expansum. Plant Dis 84: 177-181. https://doi.org/10.1094/PDIS.2000.84.2.177 ![]() |
[44] | Ziegler M, Rüegg S, Stephan R, et al. (2018) Growth potential of Listeria monocytogenes in six different RTE fruit products: impact of food matrix, storage temperature and shelf life. Ital J Food Saf 7: 7581. https://doi.org/10.4081/ijfs.2018.7581 |
[45] |
Carpentier B, Cerf O (2011) Review–persistence of Listeria monocytogenes in food industry equipment and premises. Int J Food Microbiol 145: 1-8. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2011.01.005 ![]() |
[46] |
Bosch A, Gkogka E, Le Guyader FS, et al. (2018) Foodborne viruses: Detection, risk assessment, and control options in food processing. Int J Food Microbiol 285: 110-128. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2018.06.001 ![]() |
[47] |
Marsh Z, Shah MP, Wikswo ME (2018) Epidemiology of foodborne norovirus outbreaks -United States, 2009–2015. Food Saf (Tokyo) 6: 58-66. https://doi.org/10.14252/foodsafetyfscj.2017028 ![]() |
[48] |
Butot S, Putallaz T, Sánchez G (2008) Effects of sanitation, freezing and frozen storage on enteric viruses in berries and herbs. Int J Food Microbiol 126: 30-5. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2008.04.033 ![]() |
[49] |
Le Guyader FS, Mittelholzer C, Haugarreau L, et al. (2004) Detection of noroviruses in raspberries associated with a gastroenteritis outbreak. Int J Food Microbiol 97: 179-186. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2004.04.018 ![]() |
[50] |
Quansah JK, Gazula H, Holland R, et al. (2019) Microbial quality of blueberries for the fresh market. Food Control 100: 92-96. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodcont.2018.12.034 ![]() |
[51] |
Bernard H, Faber M, Wilking H, et al. (2014) Large multistate outbreak of norovirus gastroenteritis associated with frozen strawberries, Germany, 2012. Euro Surveill 19: 20719. https://doi.org/10.2807/1560-7917.ES2014.19.8.20719 ![]() |
[52] |
Sarvikivi E, Roivainen M, Maunula L, et al. (2012) Multiple norovirus outbreaks linked to imported frozen raspberries. Epidemiol Infect 140: 260-267. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0950268811000379 ![]() |
[53] |
Warriner K, Ibrahim F, Dickinson M, et al. (2013) Internalization of human pathogens within growing salad vegetables. Biotechnol Genet Eng Rev 20: 117-136. https://doi.org/10.1080/02648725.2003.10648040 ![]() |
[54] |
Lopman B, Gastañaduy P, Park GW, et al. (2012) Environmental transmission of norovirus gastroenteritis. Curr Opin Virol 2: 96-102. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.coviro.2011.11.005 ![]() |
[55] |
Harris LJ, Farber JN, Beuchat LR, et al. (2003) Outbreaks associated with fresh produce: incidence, growth, and survival of pathogens in fresh and fresh-cut produce. Compr Rev Food Sci Food Saf 2: 78-141. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1541-4337.2003.tb00031.x ![]() |
[56] |
Alegbeleye OO, Singleton I, Sant'Ana AS (2018) Sources and contamination routes of microbial pathogens to fresh produce during field cultivation: A review. Food Microbiol 73: 177-208. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fm.2018.01.003 ![]() |
[57] |
Chatziprodromidou IP, Bellou G, Vantarakis G, et al. (2018) Viral outbreaks linked to fresh produce consumption: a systematic review. J Appl Microbiol 124: 932-942. https://doi.org/10.1111/jam.13747 ![]() |
[58] |
Vasickova P, Pavlik I, Verani M, et al. (2010) Issues concerning survival of viruses on surfaces. Food Environ Virol 2: 24-34. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12560-010-9025-6 ![]() |
[59] |
Teunis PFM, Le Guyader FS, Liu P (2020) Noroviruses are highly infectious but there is strong variation in host susceptibility and virus pathogenicity. Epidemics 32: 100401. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.epidem.2020.100401 ![]() |
[60] |
Baert L, Debevere J, Uyttendaele M (2009) The efficacy of preservation methods to inactivate foodborne viruses. Int J Food Microbiol 131: 83-94. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2009.03.007 ![]() |
[61] |
Terio V, Bottaro M, Pavoni E, et al. (2017) Occurrence of hepatitis A and E and norovirus GI and GII in ready-to-eat vegetables in Italy. Int J Food Microbiol 249: 61-65. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2017.03.008 ![]() |
[62] |
D'Souza D, Sair A, Williams K, et al. (2006) Persistence of caliciviruses on environmental surfaces and their transfer to food. Int J Food Microbiol 108: 84-91. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2005.10.024 ![]() |
[63] |
Mattison K, Karthikeyan K, Abebe M, et al. (2007) Survival of calicivirus in foods and on surfaces: experiments with feline calicivirus as a surrogate for norovirus. J Food Prot 70: 500-503. https://doi.org/10.4315/0362-028X-70.2.500 ![]() |
[64] |
Escudero-Abarca B, Rawsthorne H, Gensel C, et al. (2012) Persistence and transferability of Noroviruses on and between common surfaces and foods. J Food Prot 75: 927-35. https://doi.org/10.4315/0362-028x.jfp-11-460 ![]() |
[65] | Gutierrez-Rodrigues E, Adhikari A (2018) Pre-harvesting farming practices impacting quality of fresh produce safety. ASM Microbiol Spectrum 6: 1-20. https://doi.org/10.1128/microbiolspec.PFS-0022-2018 |
[66] |
Yeni F, Alpas H (2017) Vulnerability of global food production to extreme climatic events. Food Res Int 96: 27-39. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodres.2017.03.020 ![]() |
[67] |
Machado-Moreira B, Richards K, Brennan F, et al. (2019) Microbial contamination of fresh produce: What, where and how?. Compr Rev Food Sci Food Saf 18: 1727-1750. https://doi.org/10.1111/1541-4337.12487 ![]() |
[68] |
Gil MI, Selma MV, López-Gálvez F, et al. (2009) Fresh cut product sanitation and wash water disinfection: Problems and solutions. Int J Food Microbiol 134: 37-45. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfoodmicro.2009.05.021 ![]() |
[69] |
Marín A, Tudela JA, Garrido Y, et al. (2020) Chlorinated wash water and pH regulators affect chlorine gas emission and disinfection byproducts. Innov Food Sci Emerg Technol 66: 102533. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ifset.2020.102533 ![]() |
[70] |
Penteado AL, Castro MFPM, Rezende ACB (2014) Salmonella enterica serovar Enteritidis and Listeria monocytogenes in mango (Mangifera indica L.) pulp: growth, survival and cross-contamination. J Sci Food Agric 99: 2746-2751. https://doi.org/10.1002/jsfa.6619 ![]() |
[71] |
Lehto M, Kuisma R, Maatta J, et al. (2011) Hygienic level and surface contamination in fresh-cut vegetable production plants. Food Control 22: 469-475. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodcont.2010.09.029 ![]() |
[72] |
Cunault C, Faille C, Calabozo-Delgado A, et al. (2019) Structure and resistance to mechanical stress and enzymatic cleaning of Pseudomonas fluorescens biofilms formed in fresh-cut ready to eat washing tanks. J Food Eng 262: 154-161. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfoodeng.2019.06.006 ![]() |
[73] |
McCollum JT, Cronquist AB, Silk BJ, et al. (2013) Multistate outbreak of listeriosis associated with cantaloupe. N J Engl J Med 369: 944-953. https://doi.org/10.1056/NEJMoa1215837 ![]() |
[74] |
Corbo MR, Campaniello D, D'Amato D, et al. (2005) Behaviour of Listeria monocytogenes and Escherichia coli O157:H7 in fresh-sliced cactus-pear fruit. J Food Safe 25: 157-172. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-4565.2005.00570.x ![]() |
[75] | Raybaudi-Massilia RM, Mosqueda-Melgar J, Sobrino-Lopez A, et al. (2009) Use of malic acid and other quality stabilizing compounds to assure the safety of fresh-cut “Fuji” apples by inactivation of Listeria monocytogenes, Salmonella Enteritidis and Escherichia coli O157:H7. J Food Safe 29: 239-252. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-4565.2009.00153.x |
[76] |
Erickson MC (2012) Internalization of fresh produce by foodborne pathogens. Annu Rev Food Sci Technol 3: 283-310. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-food-022811-101211 ![]() |
[77] |
Strobel G (2018) The emergence of endophytic microbes and their biological promise. J Fungi 4: 57-76. https://doi.org/10.3390/jof4020057 ![]() |
[78] |
Gibbs DS, Anderson GL, Beuchat LR, et al. (2005) Potential role of Diploscapter sp. strain LKC25, a bacterivorous nematode from soil, as a vector of food-borne pathogenic bacteria to preharvest fruits and vegetables. Appl Environ Microbiol 71: 2433-2437. https://doi.org/10.1128/AEM.71.5.2433-2437.2005 ![]() |
[79] |
Lim JA, Lee DH, Heu S (2014) The interaction of human enteric pathogens with plants. Plant Pathol 30: 109-116. https://doi.org/10.5423/PPJ.RW.04.2014.0036 ![]() |
[80] |
Cools D, Merckx R, Vlassak K, et al. (2001) Survival of E. coli and Enterococcus derived from pig slurry in soils with different texture. Appl Soil Ecol 17: 53-62. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0929-1393(00)00133-5 ![]() |
[81] |
López-Gálvez F, Gil MI, Truchado P, et al. (2010) Cross-contamination of fresh-cut lettuce after a short-term exposure during pre-washing cannot be controlled after subsequent washing with chlorine dioxide or sodium hypochlorite. Food Microbiol 27: 199-204. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fm.2009.09.009 ![]() |
[82] |
Holden N, Pritchard L, Toth I (2009) Colonization out with the colon: plants as an alternative environmental reservoir for human pathogenic enterobacteria. FEMS Microbiol Rev 33: 689-703. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-6976.2008.00153.x ![]() |
[83] |
Deering AJ, Mauer LJR, Pruitt RE (2012) Internalization of E. coli O157:H7 and Salmonella spp. in plants: A review. Food Res Int 45: 567-575. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodres.2011.06.058 ![]() |
[84] |
Gautam D, Dobhal S, Peyton ME, et al. (2014) Surface survival and internalization of Salmonella through natural cracks on developing cantaloupe fruits alone or in the presence of the melon wilt Erwinia tracheiphila. PLoS One 9: e105248. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0105248 ![]() |
[85] |
Chen LQ, Hou B, Lalonde H, et al. (2010) Sugar transporters for intercellular exchange and nutrition of pathogens. Nature 468: 527-532. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature09606 ![]() |
[86] |
Martínez-Vaz BM, Fink RC, Diez-Gonzalez F, et al. (2014) Enteric pathogen-plant interactions: molecular connections leading to colonization and growth and implications for foin od safety. Microbes Environ 29: 123-135. https://doi.org/10.1264/jsme2.ME13139 ![]() |
[87] | Fatima U, Senthil-Kumar M (2015) Plant and pathogen nutrient acquisition strategies. Front Plant Scien 6: 1-12. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpls.2015.00750 |
[88] |
Oms-Oliu G, Rojas-Grau MA, Gonzalez LA, et al. (2010) Recent approaches using chemical treatments to preserve quality of fresh-cut fruit: A review. Postharvest Biol Tech 57: 139-148. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.postharvbio.2010.04.001 ![]() |
[89] |
Luo Y, Nou X, Yang Y, et al. (2011) Determination of free chlorine concentrations needed to prevent Escherichia coli O157:H7 cross-contamination during fresh cut produce wash. J Food Prot 24: 352-358. https://doi.org/10.4315/0362-028X.JFP-10-429 ![]() |
[90] |
Beuchat LR (2002) Ecological factors influencing survival and growth of human pathogens on raw fruits and vegetables. Microbes Infect 4: 413-423. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1286-4579(02)01555-1 ![]() |
1. | Xiaoxiao Zhou, Yongan Zhao, Xin Zhao, Ashfaq Ahmad, Umer Shahzad, Data Regulation and Data-Based Innovation in China: A Four-Group Game Model Using Empirical Testing, 2024, 71, 0018-9391, 7586, 10.1109/TEM.2024.3380257 | |
2. | Tahmina Akhter, Hopf Bifurcation in the Model of Caginalp for the Price of Bitcoin, 2024, 1556-5068, 10.2139/ssrn.4749454 | |
3. | 竞函 桂, The Application and Challenges of Digital Currency in E-Commerce, 2025, 14, 2168-5843, 3482, 10.12677/ecl.2025.141433 | |
4. | Kjell Hausken, Guizhou Wang, A Game-Theoretic Analysis of the Coexistence and Competition Between Hard and Fiat Money, 2025, 13, 2227-7099, 80, 10.3390/economies13030080 |
Currency B | |||
Cooperation | Non-cooperation | ||
Currency A | Cooperation | A1+θΔV−tc, A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)c |
A1+W−tc−L1, A2+T2−W |
Non-cooperation | A1+T1−W, A2+W−(1−t)c−L2 |
A1, A2 |
Equilibrium point | detJ | trJ | Stability |
(0, 0) | + | – | ESS |
(1, 1) | + | – | ESS |
(0, 1) | + | + | Unstable |
(1, 0) | + | + | Unstable |
((1−t)c+L2−W(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2, tc+L1−WθΔV−T1+L1) | – | Saddle point |
Financial Coordination C | Currency B | ||
Cooperation | Non-cooperation | ||
Currency A | Cooperation | A1+θΔV−t(c−s)+K2+aR, A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)(c−s)+K2 +(1−a)R, A3−K1−2K2 |
A1−t(c−s)−L1+K2+aR+W, A2+T2−W, A3−K1−K2 |
Non-cooperation | A1+T1−W, A2−(1−t)(c−s)−L2+K2+(1−a)R+W, A3−K1−K2 |
A1, A2, A3−K1 |
Financial Coordination C | Currency B | ||
Cooperation | Non-cooperation | ||
Currency A | Cooperation | A1+θΔV−tc, A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)c, bA3 |
A1+W−tc−L1, A2+T2−W, bA3 |
Non-cooperation | A1+T1−W, A2+W−(1−t)c−L2, bA3 |
A1, A2, bA3 |
Equilibrium point | λ1 | λ2 | λ3 |
E1(0,0,0) | W−tc−L1 | W−(1−t)c−L2 | (1−b)A3−K1 |
E2(0,0,1) | K2+aR+W−t(c −s)−L1 |
K2+(1−a)R+W−(1 −t)(c−s)−L2 |
−[(1−b)A3−K1] |
E3(0,1,0) | θΔV+W−T1−tc | −[W−(1−t)c−L2] | (1−b)A3−K1−K2 |
E4(0,1,1) | K2+aR+θΔV+W −t(c−s)−T1 |
−[K2+(1−a)R+W−(1 −t)(c−s)−L2] |
−[(1−b)A3−K1−K2] |
E5(1,0,0) | −(W−tc−L1) | (1−θ)ΔV−T2+W− (1−t)c |
(1−b)A3−K1−K2 |
E6(1,0,1) | −[K2+aR+W−t(c −s)−L1] |
K2+(1−a)R+W−(1−t)(c−s)+(1−θ)ΔV−T2 | −[(1−b)A3−K1−K2] |
E7(1,1,0) | −[θΔV−T1+W−tc] | −[(1−θ)ΔV−T2+ −(1−t)c] |
(1−b)A3−K1−2K2 |
E8(1,1,1) | −[K2+aR+W]−t(c −s)+θΔV−T1 |
−[K2+(1−a)R+W−(1−t)(c−s)+(1−θ)ΔV−T2] | −[(1−b)A3−K1 −2K2] |
Equilibrium point | Proposition 2 | Stability | ||
λ1 | λ2 | λ3 | ||
E1(0,0,0) | – | – | + | Unstable |
E2(0,0,1) | – | – | – | ESS |
E3(0,1,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E4(0,1,1) | + | + | – | Unstable |
E5(1,0,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E6(1,0,1) | – | + | – | Unstable |
E7(1,1,0) | – | – | + | Unstable |
E8(1,1,1) | – | – | – | ESS |
Equilibrium point | Proposition 3 | Stability | ||
λ1 | λ2 | λ3 | ||
E1(0,0,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E2(0,0,1) | + | + | – | Unstable |
E3(0,1,0) | + | – | + | Unstable |
E4(0,1,1) | + | – | – | Unstable |
E5(1,0,0) | – | + | + | Unstable |
E6(1,0,1) | – | + | – | Unstable |
E7(1,1,0) | – | – | + | Unstable |
E8(1,1,1) | – | – | – | ESS |
Equilibrium point | Proposition 4 | |||
λ1 | λ2 | λ3 | Stability | |
E1(0,0,0) | - | - | + | Unstable |
E2(0,0,1) | + | + | - | Unstable |
E3(0,1,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E4(0,1,1) | + | - | - | Unstable |
E5(1,0,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E6(1,0,1) | - | + | - | Unstable |
E7(1,1,0) | - | - | + | Unstable |
E8(1,1,1) | - | - | - | ESS |
Currency B | |||
Cooperation | Non-cooperation | ||
Currency A | Cooperation | A1+θΔV−tc, A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)c |
A1+W−tc−L1, A2+T2−W |
Non-cooperation | A1+T1−W, A2+W−(1−t)c−L2 |
A1, A2 |
Equilibrium point | detJ | trJ | Stability |
(0, 0) | + | – | ESS |
(1, 1) | + | – | ESS |
(0, 1) | + | + | Unstable |
(1, 0) | + | + | Unstable |
((1−t)c+L2−W(1−θ)ΔV−T2+L2, tc+L1−WθΔV−T1+L1) | – | Saddle point |
Financial Coordination C | Currency B | ||
Cooperation | Non-cooperation | ||
Currency A | Cooperation | A1+θΔV−t(c−s)+K2+aR, A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)(c−s)+K2 +(1−a)R, A3−K1−2K2 |
A1−t(c−s)−L1+K2+aR+W, A2+T2−W, A3−K1−K2 |
Non-cooperation | A1+T1−W, A2−(1−t)(c−s)−L2+K2+(1−a)R+W, A3−K1−K2 |
A1, A2, A3−K1 |
Financial Coordination C | Currency B | ||
Cooperation | Non-cooperation | ||
Currency A | Cooperation | A1+θΔV−tc, A2+(1−θ)ΔV−(1−t)c, bA3 |
A1+W−tc−L1, A2+T2−W, bA3 |
Non-cooperation | A1+T1−W, A2+W−(1−t)c−L2, bA3 |
A1, A2, bA3 |
Equilibrium point | λ1 | λ2 | λ3 |
E1(0,0,0) | W−tc−L1 | W−(1−t)c−L2 | (1−b)A3−K1 |
E2(0,0,1) | K2+aR+W−t(c −s)−L1 |
K2+(1−a)R+W−(1 −t)(c−s)−L2 |
−[(1−b)A3−K1] |
E3(0,1,0) | θΔV+W−T1−tc | −[W−(1−t)c−L2] | (1−b)A3−K1−K2 |
E4(0,1,1) | K2+aR+θΔV+W −t(c−s)−T1 |
−[K2+(1−a)R+W−(1 −t)(c−s)−L2] |
−[(1−b)A3−K1−K2] |
E5(1,0,0) | −(W−tc−L1) | (1−θ)ΔV−T2+W− (1−t)c |
(1−b)A3−K1−K2 |
E6(1,0,1) | −[K2+aR+W−t(c −s)−L1] |
K2+(1−a)R+W−(1−t)(c−s)+(1−θ)ΔV−T2 | −[(1−b)A3−K1−K2] |
E7(1,1,0) | −[θΔV−T1+W−tc] | −[(1−θ)ΔV−T2+ −(1−t)c] |
(1−b)A3−K1−2K2 |
E8(1,1,1) | −[K2+aR+W]−t(c −s)+θΔV−T1 |
−[K2+(1−a)R+W−(1−t)(c−s)+(1−θ)ΔV−T2] | −[(1−b)A3−K1 −2K2] |
Equilibrium point | Proposition 2 | Stability | ||
λ1 | λ2 | λ3 | ||
E1(0,0,0) | – | – | + | Unstable |
E2(0,0,1) | – | – | – | ESS |
E3(0,1,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E4(0,1,1) | + | + | – | Unstable |
E5(1,0,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E6(1,0,1) | – | + | – | Unstable |
E7(1,1,0) | – | – | + | Unstable |
E8(1,1,1) | – | – | – | ESS |
Equilibrium point | Proposition 3 | Stability | ||
λ1 | λ2 | λ3 | ||
E1(0,0,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E2(0,0,1) | + | + | – | Unstable |
E3(0,1,0) | + | – | + | Unstable |
E4(0,1,1) | + | – | – | Unstable |
E5(1,0,0) | – | + | + | Unstable |
E6(1,0,1) | – | + | – | Unstable |
E7(1,1,0) | – | – | + | Unstable |
E8(1,1,1) | – | – | – | ESS |
Equilibrium point | Proposition 4 | |||
λ1 | λ2 | λ3 | Stability | |
E1(0,0,0) | - | - | + | Unstable |
E2(0,0,1) | + | + | - | Unstable |
E3(0,1,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E4(0,1,1) | + | - | - | Unstable |
E5(1,0,0) | + | + | + | Saddle point |
E6(1,0,1) | - | + | - | Unstable |
E7(1,1,0) | - | - | + | Unstable |
E8(1,1,1) | - | - | - | ESS |