In order to study the impact of the incubation periods of humans and vectors on diseases transmission, a novel vector-borne diseases model with two time delays on bipartite networks is proposed. The formula of the basic reproduction number R0 is given, which is dependent on time delays. Moreover, the globally asymptotic stability of the disease-free equilibrium and the endemic equilibrium is proved by constructing appropriate Lyapunov functions. Finally, numerical simulations are carried out to verify the analysis results and reveal the influence of the structure of bipartite networks on the basic reproduction number.
Citation: Rundong Zhao, Qiming Liu, Huazong Zhang. Dynamical behaviors of a vector-borne diseases model with two time delays on bipartite networks[J]. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(4): 3073-3091. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021154
[1] | Alessandro Didonna, Federico Benetti . Post-translational modifications in neurodegeneration. AIMS Biophysics, 2016, 3(1): 27-49. doi: 10.3934/biophy.2016.1.27 |
[2] | Hisao Moriya . The expression level and cytotoxicity of green fluorescent protein are modulated by an additional N-terminal sequence. AIMS Biophysics, 2020, 7(2): 121-132. doi: 10.3934/biophy.2020010 |
[3] | Ivana Sirangelo, Margherita Borriello, Gaetano Irace, Clara Iannuzzi . Intrinsic blue-green fluorescence in amyloyd fibrils. AIMS Biophysics, 2018, 5(2): 155-165. doi: 10.3934/biophy.2018.2.155 |
[4] | Yu-Ting Huang, Hui-Fen Liao, Shun-Li Wang, Shan-Yang Lin . Glycation and secondary conformational changes of human serum albumin: study of the FTIR spectroscopic curve-fitting technique. AIMS Biophysics, 2016, 3(2): 247-260. doi: 10.3934/biophy.2016.2.247 |
[5] | Mostean Bahreinipour, Hajar Zarei, Fariba Dashtestani, Jamal Rashidiani, Khadijeh Eskandari, Seyed Ali Moussavi Zarandi, Susan Kabudanian Ardestani, Hiroshi Watabe . Radioprotective effect of nanoceria and magnetic flower-like iron oxide microparticles on gamma radiation-induced damage in BSA protein. AIMS Biophysics, 2021, 8(2): 124-142. doi: 10.3934/biophy.2021010 |
[6] | Timothy Jan Bergmann, Giorgia Brambilla Pisoni, Maurizio Molinari . Quality control mechanisms of protein biogenesis: proteostasis dies hard. AIMS Biophysics, 2016, 3(4): 456-478. doi: 10.3934/biophy.2016.4.456 |
[7] | Marek K. Korzeniowski, Barbara Baird, David Holowka . STIM1 activation is regulated by a 14 amino acid sequence adjacent to the CRAC activation domain. AIMS Biophysics, 2016, 3(1): 99-118. doi: 10.3934/biophy.2016.1.99 |
[8] | Larisa A. Krasnobaeva, Ludmila V. Yakushevich . DNA kinks behavior in the potential pit-trap. AIMS Biophysics, 2022, 9(2): 130-146. doi: 10.3934/biophy.2022012 |
[9] | Judit Faus-Garriga, Isabel Novoa, Andrés Ozaita . mTOR signaling in proteostasis and its relevance to autism spectrum disorders. AIMS Biophysics, 2017, 4(1): 63-89. doi: 10.3934/biophy.2017.1.63 |
[10] | Wei Zhang, Sheng Cao, Jessica L. Martin, Joachim D. Mueller, Louis M. Mansky . Morphology and ultrastructure of retrovirus particles. AIMS Biophysics, 2015, 2(3): 343-369. doi: 10.3934/biophy.2015.3.343 |
In order to study the impact of the incubation periods of humans and vectors on diseases transmission, a novel vector-borne diseases model with two time delays on bipartite networks is proposed. The formula of the basic reproduction number R0 is given, which is dependent on time delays. Moreover, the globally asymptotic stability of the disease-free equilibrium and the endemic equilibrium is proved by constructing appropriate Lyapunov functions. Finally, numerical simulations are carried out to verify the analysis results and reveal the influence of the structure of bipartite networks on the basic reproduction number.
Funds have been raised globally to help the fight for HIV and AIDS epidemics in low-and middle-income countries. In the year 2014 alone USD 19.2 billion was made available globally to finance the response to AIDS in such countries. Out of this, USD 8.5 billion was handled by the global organizations like The Global Fund to fight AIDS, Tuberculosis and Malaria, and UNITAID [1,14,25]. The type and intensity of response may vary from region to region and from country to country depending on the type of risk groups, rate of prevalence, social make-ups and economic conditions they have.
Globally over 36.7 million people are leaving with HIV and of these cases about 70.5% live in Sub-Saharan Africa, 13.8% live in Asia, 4.6% in Latin America, and around 3% live in Eastern Europe and central Asia. More than 1.8 million children under the age of 15 live with HIV/AIDS globally and among them more than 83 percent live in Sub-Sahara African region. A further 2.1 million people were infected in the year 2015 [24]. Every day over 5,700 new HIV infections occur worldwide. Out of these more than 95 percent occur in low-and middle-income countries and above 600 new cases per day are among children under 15 [24]. It is estimated that more than 90% of infant infection is caused by mother-to-child transmission which could have been prevented. In general global HIV prevalence (proportion of people with HIV) is remaining at the same level, although the global number of people with HIV is rising because of new infections and longer survival times, and continuously growing global total population.
In the absence of a curing medicine and a working vaccination, the investment to control the HIV epidemics is mainly to reduce the total number of new infections and the rate of progression to AIDS.
Untreated HIV progress to AIDS and death in most individuals. The antiretroviral (ARV) therapy to HIV infected people limits the viral replication allowing either immune preservation (at the earlier course of the infection) or immune reconstruction, resulting in durable, life-saving effects. The ARV treatment has two fold advantages: an advantage to the infected person as a treatment to increase the healthy life of the infected individual and an advantage to the society at large in decreasing the rate of infectiousness of the infected individual. The use of ART can significantly reduce the plasma viral load (by up to six orders of magnitude [16]) which decreases the rate of infectiousness of a treated person.
The other outcome of the ART intervention both to the individual and the society is that it reduces the costs of illness which may include hospitalization and the use of other expensive therapies. However, only about 17 million people worldwide received ART at the end of 2015 [24] and this amounts to only 46% of the total.
The intervention to reduce, and eventually eliminate the Mother-to-Child Transmission (MTCT), which is also called a vertical transmission, is through the use of ARVs during pregnancy and delivery and to the infants following births and the use of replacement infant feeding [4]. It is known that potent viral suppression greatly reduces perinatal HIV transmission.
To finance the interventions, the fund raised globally is very limited. It is only up to 70% of the required amount even at its pick stage [15,25] (see Fig. 1).
Due to economic difficulties or political reasons international aid may fluctuate significantly and hence the investment on health care could be highly affected, in particular in low-and middle-income countries. Therefore, the scarce resources have to be allocated optimally to get better and tangible achievements, in epidemic terms.
Health economics theory states that allocating resources to medical interventions in increasing order of their cost-effectiveness ratios until the available budget has been exhausted will result in the optimal allocation of funds [6,27]. Actually this leads to a Give-it-all or nothing strategy. Moreover, to establish the Cost-Effectiveness criteria one needs to collect adequate data on the population distribution and generate cost-effectiveness data for individual and community-level interventions. Even in the perfect information case, 'Allocation by Cost-Effectiveness' (ACE) does not allow for several important factors such as, increasing or diminishing marginal returns to scale, mutual exclusivity of programmes, and interaction of program outcomes, which are necessary to be taken into consideration [18].
Therefore, several researchers have proposed the method of operations research in allocating resources for HIV interventions (see for instance [2,3,7,8,30,31] and the references therein). However, all of them use one level-optimization procedures, which assume that resources are allocated by the same country where the programs are implemented. Such models may work well for resource allocation decisions in developed countries, where the fund is raised only from within the country itself.
A two level resource allocation model has been proposed in [18]. However, this model assumes that the lower level problem has a unique solution, which is not normally the case, especially when the production functions used are not linear (which is true even with the model formulation of the same paper). Therefore, it could be difficult to apply the proposed method in practical situations. Moreover, the effect of ART in reducing new infections was not considered in the model.
In this work a simplified epidemic model with the inclusion of the effect of ART will be used to formulate a global resource allocation model for HIV control. The paper shall concentrate on developing and analyzing the model where the decision for resource allocation passes through various levels. Such levels could be two or more depending on the organizational structure of the global financing agencies and on the mechanism they allocate resources to developing countries.
The remaining part of this paper is organized as follows: the resource allocation problem and the structure of the levels have been formulated and analyzed separately in Section 2, while Section 3 is devoted for the analysis of the model in its entirety. The paper is concluded with a discussion in Section 4.
The decision for international fund allocation for HIV prevention programs to low-and middle-income countries usually passes through various stages, with all of them aiming in controlling the epidemics and reducing human sufferings. We assume that major decision points in allocating funds can be classified into three hierarchical groupings; the upper level can be taken as the International funding organization, the middle level can be the Regional representatives and the lower level being the Country representatives. Due to the variation in prevalence, the main factors in the transmission mode of the disease, the economic condition and their social set-up, etc. countries with closer features (in addition to their geographic proximities) are classified by many international funding agencies in to some regions, like the Sub-Sahara Africa, Latin America, the Middle East and North Africa, Asia, etc. We take these regional forms as a middle level decision points in the resource allocation process. The diagram in Fig. 2 indicates the structure of the model under study.
At each stage of the resource allocation process indicated in Fig. 2, the final common goal of investment, which is assumed to be controlling the epidemics and improving the quality of healthy life of the society, will be checked. That means, the investment is targeted to positively affect the dynamics of the epidemics. There are several models in literature which try to describe the dynamics of the HIV infection and spread in the population with ARV treatment. The schematic diagram in Fig. 3 indicates one of such models where interventions have impact on the disease dynamics.
The dynamical system representing the schematic diagram in Fig. 3 will be given by the following set of differential equations.
dVdt=mβ(I+ε2T)−(γρ+μ+δV)VdSdt=π−λS(I+ε1T)Q−μSdIdt=λS(I+ε1T)Q−(ρ+σ+μ)IdTdt=ρ(γV+I)−(α+μ)TdAdt=σI+αT−(μ+δA)A S(0)+V(0)+I(0)+T(0)+A(0)=1, |
where
If we assume that the interventions have direct effect on some of the parameters in the system, allocation of resources should yield in decreasing the rate of infection (
dVdt=ϕm(y1)β(I+ε2T)−(γϕρ(y3)+μ+δV)V | (1) |
dSdt=π−ϕλ(y2)S(I+ε1T)Q−μS | (2) |
dIdt=ϕλ(y2)S(I+ε1T)Q−(ρ+σ+μ)I | (3) |
dTdt=ϕρ(y3)(γV+I)−(ϕα(y4)+μ)T | (4) |
dAdt=σI+ϕα(y4)T−(μ+δA)A | (5) |
S(0)+V(0)+I(0)+T(0)+A(0)=1 | (6) |
If
Since non-treated children with HIV have a 10 times higher mortality rate compared to those of other children [21], it is assumed that they will not become sexually active in the population (especially in low-income countries where child mortality rate is significantly high). However, those who are getting proper ARV treatment may mature to adulthood at a rate of
Assume that there are
The goal of the interventions program is mainly to minimize the total number of individuals who become newly infected, both in the category of the newly born children with an infected status (
The objective function of the resource optimization problem at the lower level is, therefore, simply taking the total sum of the contribution of the incidence of the newborns and the incidence of adults due to sexual contacts in the given period of time in all the community groups of a country, which is a function of the investment variables.
If a total of
fkj(ykji)=Mj∑i=1∫τ0e−rt{(ϕλi(y2kji)Si(t)[Ii(t)+ε1Ti(t)Qi(t)]) +ϕmi(y1kji)β(Ii(t)+ε2Ti(t))}dt, | (7) |
where
T(t+δt)=T(t)+[ϕρ(y3)(γV(t)+I(t))−(ϕα(y4)+μ)T(t)]δt =ϕρ(y3)[γV(t)+I(t)]δt−[(ϕα(y4)+μ)δt−1]T(t) |
By reformulating this last equation we can get the value of
T(t)=ϕρ(y3)[γV(t−δt)+I(t−δt)]δt−[(ϕα(y4)+μ)δt−1]T(t−δt), | (8) |
where,
fkj(ykji)=Mj∑i=1∫τ0e−rt{ϕλi(y2kji)Si(t)Qi(t)[Ii(t) +ε1(ϕρi(y3kji)[γVi(t−δt)+Ii(t−δt)]δt −[(ϕαi(y4kji)+μ)δt−1]Ti(t−δt))] +ϕmi(y1kji)β[Ii(t)+ε2(ϕρi(y3kji)[γVi(t−δt)+Ii(t−δt)]δt −[(ϕαi(y4kji)+μ)δt−1]Ti(t−δt))]}dt, | (9) |
which is a nonlinear (non-convex) function of the investment variables. Even in the cases when the cost functions
In determining the value of
In the expression above, the variable vectors
If the planning time horizon
Therefore, the resource allocation problem at the lower decision point will be given by a non convex optimization problem:
minykjiNjfkj(ykji)Subject to Mj∑i=1(y1kji+y2kji+y3kji+y4kji)≤xkj | (10) |
Here, the constraint reflects that the total investment in country
The solution
On the other hand the Middle-Level decision maker (region
maxxk1,…,xkNn Fk=hk1xk1+hk2xk2+⋯+hkNnxkNn Subject to xk1+xk2+⋯+xkNn≤vk | (11) |
where
One possible way of estimating the values of
hkj=w1r1kj×e1kjNkj×c1kj+w2r2kj×e2kjNkj×c2kj, |
where,
The coefficients
If a solution
Fk(vk)=hk1x∗k1(vk)+hk2x∗k2(vk)+⋯+hkNkx∗kNk(vk) | (12) |
The upper level problem will then be finding an optimal allocation
maxv1,…,vn n∑kFk(vk)Subject to v1+v2+⋯+vn≤B xkj≥dkjvk for each k=1 to n Mj∑i=1yℓkji≥zℓkjvk for each ℓ=1,2,3,4, | (13) |
where,
When we combine all the three problems described in the previous section in sequential order the general resource allocation problem takes the form,
maxv1,…,vn n∑kFk(vk) Subject to v1+v2+⋯+vn≤B xkj≥dkjvk for each k=1ton Mj∑i=1yℓkji≥zℓkjvk for each ℓ=1,2,3,4, where xkj,ylkji solvemaxxk1,…,xkNn Fk=hk1xk1+hk2xk2+⋯+hkNnxkNnSubject toxk1+xk2+⋯+xkNn≤vk where, ykji solves minykjiNjfkj(ykji) Subject to Mj∑i=1(y1kji+y2kji+y3kji+y4kji)≤xkj | (14) |
where all the variables are nonnegative. i.e.,
Given a total budget
Accepting the values
Therefore, the optimization problem solved at each stage is a (multi-)parametric problem, where the parameters are decision variables at other decision levels. Moreover, the decision process is hierarchical as the global planner should declare its optimal allocation of funds first for the middle level to act. However, a one level solution procedures may not help to arrive at the optimal solution of such kind of problems as the parameters need to be rechecked again for their agreement with the optimality requirements at each other levels. That means, we need to apply solution techniques for multilevel programming problems to eventually arrive at the optimal allocation of resources for HIV interventions. The techniques that we may choose to solve the problem, however, depend on the types of the production functions for investment of each of the 4 types of the interventions.
Since all the constraints in problem (14) are linear inequalities in investment variables at all levels, the constraint set is polyhedral. But since the objective function of the lower level problem is non-convex, even when all the production functions are chosen to be linear, unique solutions may not be obtained at lower levels and we do not also expect that only full utilization of funds give optimal solutions. Proper definition of the production functions for each of the intervention types requires a closer study on the nature of the investment and its impact on the corresponding parameter values. Although linear functions are easy to work with, such linear approximations may not take important behaviors of the parameters into consideration. Therefore, it is advisable to use a combination of models depending on the nature of interventions.
In some of the intervention programs each incremental unit of money spent may produce the same incremental reduction or upsurge in epidemic component. In such type of programs the production function could be taken to be linear as a function of investment variables [2,3]. In our model, for example, to formulate the proportion of investment in increasing the rate of recruitment for treatment (
On the other hand, production functions that are related to a change in the risky behavior of group of individuals, an incremental investment in such programs may not usually produce the same incremental reduction in the risky behavior of individuals [12]. This is because, as the program expands the individuals reached are increasingly less likely to change their risky behavior. In such cases we may better model the corresponding production function by a function which is convex with respect to the investment variables. In our model, the investment in reducing the rate of infection due to unsafe sexual contacts (
ϕλ(y)={λmin, if 0≤y≤F;λmin(a+bec(F−y)), if y>F, |
where
Once the model is properly formulated the next step will be to choose the best solution procedure that can give us an optimal solution. Since, all the constraint sets are polyhedral in investment variables, the solution approach depends on the type of definition of the production functions which appear in the objective function of the lower level problem. If all the production functions are twice continuously differentiable functions,
To show the procedure for solving the global resource allocation problem using a tri-level hierarchical model, we formulated a hypothetical example. In this situation, assume there are 3 regions globally and a total of
1In this example, the allocated budget
For the formulation of the upper level (global) and the middle level (regional) resource allocation problems, the following parameters values are used.
hkj=(0.20.30.310.390.250.4), dkj=(20%25%30%15%25%20%), |
where, the rows represent the regions and the columns represent the countries. The entries in the matrix
In the lower level problem there are various parameters to be used. Some of them are disease parameters that remain constant across the glob and some others are country or risk group specific. They are summarized in Tables 1 and 2. (Some of these parameters are from [5,13,19,23,26,28] and the rest are estimated.)
Parameter value | Description |
mortality rate for infected children | |
additional death rate due to AIDS | |
rate of progression to AIDS, if not treated | |
preferential rate of recruitment for children to receive ART | |
transmission probability | |
factor of reduction on rate of disease transmission due to ART | |
factor of reduction on rate of MTCT due to treatment |
Parameter values | Description (each is for the 6 countries) |
Birth rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Death rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for high risk groups | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for high risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of defaulting in the use of ART-assumed to be the same for both risk groups in each of the countries | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in High risk groups | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in Low risk groups |
Initial size for the Low Risk population group in the 6 countries is assumed to be as in the table below,
Pop. Size | R1C1 | R1C2 | R2C1 | R2C2 | R3C1 | R3C2 | |
S(0) | 15652504 | 870885.6 | 35863200 | 7341600 | 28122000 | 16815000 | , |
V(0) | 87640 | 12854.4 | 652800 | 151200 | 548250 | 285000 | |
I(0) | 1016624 | 107120 | 1632000 | 361200 | 1322250 | 627000 | |
T(0) | 438200 | 47132.8 | 1836000 | 411600 | 1451250 | 855000 | |
A(0) | 333032 | 33207.2 | 816000 | 134400 | 806250 | 418000 |
and the initial size for High Risk population group in the 6 countries is taken to be as in the following table.
Pop. Size | R1C1 | R1C2 | R2C1 | R2C2 | R3C1 | R3C2 |
S(0) | 11706200 | 611078.4 | 13785600 | 2656800 | 7998000 | 4512000 |
V(0) | 110176 | 25708.8 | 499200 | 57600 | 193500 | 90000 |
I(0) | 1170620 | 208636.8 | 2515200 | 417600 | 1236250 | 666000 |
T(0) | 454476 | 84048 | 1632000 | 342000 | 1053500 | 600000 |
A(0) | 330528 | 59328 | 768000 | 126000 | 268750 | 132000 |
The production functions for the model are chosen to be
ϕmi(y1)=m(1+a2y1), ϕλi(y2)=λ(1+e−(c1y2))ϕρi(y3)=ρ(1+a1y3), ϕαi(y4)=α(1+e−(c2y4)), |
with
Then, given the leader's variable
In choosing a solution approach, it is considered that since the lower level objective of the problem is defined in terms of an integral form, it will be expensive to calculate the first and second order derivatives. Hence, the algorithm in [29] is used to get the solution. After reformulation and running the SEAMSP algorithm [29] for the above tri-level problem, we obtain the solutions as in Table 3. The values in this table are given in millions of USD.
Low Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
125.46 | 234.63 | 310.64 | 107.62 | 172.46 | 423.69 | |||
89.14 | 193.46 | 154.29 | 98.947 | 193.42 | 244.36 | |||
97.432 | 102.46 | 196.98 | 69.442 | 207.16 | 219.80 | |||
49.864 | 299.87 | 130.26 | 124.67 | 154.32 | 501.64 | |||
High Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
28.808 | 125.01 | 120.09 | 77.004 | 124.50 | 142.29 | |||
65.128 | 166.29 | 276.41 | 85.677 | 103.49 | 321.64 | |||
56.836 | 257.30 | 233.75 | 115.18 | 89.809 | 346.20 | |||
104.41 | 60.049 | 300.46 | 59.954 | 142.64 | 64.384 |
When these optimal investment values are used in the dynamical system it can be seen from the simulation graphs (Fig. 4 - 6) that the prevalence of the disease decreases significantly in each of the countries in the region.
In this paper a hierarchical model for global resource allocation of the funds that are raised to fight HIV/AIDS is formulated and analyzed. It has been shown that when the effect of treatment in the aversion of new infection is employed in the model, the objective function of the lower level decision making structure is neither convex nor concave in the allocation variables even if all the production functions are assumed to be linear. This made the resulting multilevel optimization problem difficult to solve with classical operations research methods.
Here, it is assumed that there are three levels of decisions in the global allocation of resources. However, a two level decision system can also be analyzed using a similar approach by simply merging the middle level with the upper level decision making structure. Since the main difficulty (in terms of solution approaches) arises due to the properties of the lower level objective function, the two level version of the problem also requires the same solution techniques recommended in this paper. On the other hand if the number of levels (or hierarchies) is increased from 3 to any possible number in the formulation of the model, the analysis of the model again follows a similar argument and structure. The solution techniques of any such multilevel problems also depend on the type of constraints and criteria functions formulated at each level of decision. The effectiveness of this model is not yet proved by taking actual data from the field. Nonetheless, unlike the conclusion in [18] (which recommends the use of equity -optimal approach), the author recommends the use of optimal -optimal approach over the other possible decision approaches between the levels as equity parameters are already included in the model constraints.
This study considered the allocation of resources to control the HIV epidemic in a multiple but independent communities of the population in any country. Though the model relies upon the epidemic behavior of HIV/AIDS, the model structure and the analysis given in this paper are likely to be applied to other types of diseases provided some of the interventions also result in reducing the infectiousness of the infected individuals. Moreover, one can also use a similar model to allocate resources to control multiple diseases in the same population (like, for example, Tuberculosis (TB) and Malaria) if the epidemics are assumed to be independent. But since some infections are not independent, one need to apply a different modeling structure for non-independent diseases (like, for example, HIV and TB, HIV and other sexually transmitted diseases) because the same intervention may have an impact on the incidence of the other diseases as well.
In this paper it is also assumed that countries within a region, or regions within the global settings do not compete each other to receive higher resources from higher level resource allocation body for any of the intervention programs. If the resource allocation structure allows for such a competition, then one has to apply a multi-level multi-follower method to get an optimal solution. However, such techniques are not well developed yet to handle various formulations of lower level problems. Therefore, this requires a further research especially when the objective functions of the lower level decision makers (in our case the country level resource allocation structure) need to solve non-convex and non-concave problems with resources are shared among them.
This work is partly supported by the Swedish International Science Program (ISP), through the project at the Department of Mathematics, Addis Ababa University.
[1] | S. M. Lemon, P. F. Sparling, M. A. Hamburg, D. A. Relman, E. R. Choffnes, Vector-borne diseases: Understanding the environmental, human health, and ecological connections. Workshop summary, National Academies Press, 2008. |
[2] | Changes in the incidence of vector-borne disease attributable to climate change, CIESIN, 2007. Available from: http://www.ciesin.columbia.edu/TG/HH/veclev2. |
[3] | R. Ross, The prevention of malaria, John Murray, 1911. |
[4] |
A. Traoré, Analysis of a vector-borne disease model with human and vectors immigration, J. Appl. Math. Comput., 64 (2020), 411–428. doi: 10.1007/s12190-020-01361-4
![]() |
[5] | R. Nyang'inja, G. Lawi, M. Okongo, A. Orwa, Stability analysis of Rotavirus-malaria co-epidemic model with vaccination, Dyn. Syst. Appl., 28 (2019), 371–407. |
[6] | A. Abiodun, P. Witbooi, K. O. Okosun, Modelling the impact of climatic variables on malaria transmission, Hacet. J. Math. Stat., 47 (2018), 219–235. |
[7] |
A. L. Barabási, R. Albert, Emergence of scaling in random networks, Science, 286 (1999), 509–512. doi: 10.1126/science.286.5439.509
![]() |
[8] |
S. Boccaletti, V. Latora, Y. Moreno, M. Chavez, D. U. Hwang, Complex networks: Structure and dynamics, Phys. Rep., 424 (2006), 175–308. doi: 10.1016/j.physrep.2005.10.009
![]() |
[9] |
S. Eubank, H. Guclu, V. S. Anil Kumar, M. V. Marathe, A. Srinivasan, Z. Toroczkai et al., Modelling disease outbreaks in realistic urban social networks, Nature, 429 (2004), 180–184. doi: 10.1038/nature02541
![]() |
[10] |
N. Masuda, N. Konno, Multi-state epidemic processes on complex networks, J. Theor. Biol., 243 (2006), 64–75. doi: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2006.06.010
![]() |
[11] |
H. Shi, Z. Duan, G. Chen, An SIS model with infective medium on complex networks, Phys. A, 387 (2008), 2133–2144. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2007.11.048
![]() |
[12] |
M. E. Woolhouse, C. Dye, J.-F. Etard, T. Smith, J. Charlwood, G. Garnett, et al., Heterogeneities in the transmission of infectious agents: Implications for the design of control programs, Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A., 94 (1997), 338–342. doi: 10.1073/pnas.94.1.338
![]() |
[13] |
M. Yang, G. Chen, X. Fu, A modfied SIS model with an infective medium on complex networks and its global stability, Phys. A, 390 (2011), 2408–2413. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2011.02.007
![]() |
[14] |
Y. Wang, Z. Jin, Z. Yang, Z. Zhang, T. Zhou, G. Sun, Global analysis of an SIS model with an infective vector on complex networks, Nonlinear Anal.-Real World Appl., 13 (2012), 543–557. doi: 10.1016/j.nonrwa.2011.07.033
![]() |
[15] |
X. Wang, J. Yang, Dynamical analysis of a mean-field vector-borne diseases model on complex networks: An edge based compartmental approach, Chaos, 30 (2020), 013103. doi: 10.1063/1.5116209
![]() |
[16] |
R. Zhang, Global dynamic analysis of a model for vector-borne diseases on bipartite networks, Phys. A, 545 (2020), 123813. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2019.123813
![]() |
[17] |
R. Bray, P. Garnham, The life-cycle of primate malaria parasites, Br. Med. Bull., 38 (1982), 117–122. doi: 10.1093/oxfordjournals.bmb.a071746
![]() |
[18] | D. M. Claborn, P. M. Masuoka, T. A. Klein, T. Hooper, A. Lee, R. G. Andre, A cost comparison of two malaria control methods in Kyunggi province, Republic of Korea, using remote sensing and geographic information systems. Am. J. Trop. Med. Hyg., 66 (2002), 680–685. |
[19] | R. Zhang, D. Li, Z. Jin, Dynamic analysis of a delayed model for vector-borne diseases on bipartite networks, Appl. Math. Comput., 263 (2015), 342–352. |
[20] |
C. Li, C. Tsai, S. Yang, Analysis of epidemic spreading of an SIRS model in complex heterogeneous networks, Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simul., 19 (2014), 1042–1054. doi: 10.1016/j.cnsns.2013.08.033
![]() |
[21] |
J. Liu, T. Zhang, Epidemic spreading of an SEIRS model in scale-free networks, Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simul., 16 (2011), 3375–3384. doi: 10.1016/j.cnsns.2010.11.019
![]() |
[22] |
H. Zhang, X. Fu, Spreading of epidemics on scale-free networks with nonlinear infectivity, Nonlinear Anal.-Theory Methods Appl., 70 (2009), 3273–3278. doi: 10.1016/j.na.2008.04.031
![]() |
[23] | J. K. Hale, S. M. V. Lunel, L. S. Verduyn, S. M. V. Lunel, Introduction to Functional Differential Equations, vol. 99, Springer Science & Business Media1 1993. |
[24] | J. P. La Salle, The Stability of Dynamical Systems, SIAM, 1976. |
[25] |
L. L. Shapiro, S. A. Whitehead, M. B. Thomas, Quantifying the effects of temperature on mosquito and parasite traits that determine the transmission potential of human malaria, PLoS. Biol., 15 (2017), e2003489. doi: 10.1371/journal.pbio.2003489
![]() |
[26] |
S. Ruan, D. Xiao, J. C. Beier, On the delayed Ross-Macdonald model for malaria transmission, Bull. Math. Biol., 70 (2008), 1098–1114. doi: 10.1007/s11538-007-9292-z
![]() |
[27] | Global health estimates: Life expectancy and leading causes of death and disability, W. H. Organization, 2021. Available from: https://www.who.int/data/gho/data/indicators/indicator-details/GHO/gho-ghe-halehealthy-life-expectancy-at-birth. |
[28] | Malaria, W. H. Organization, 2021. Available from: https://www.who.int/health-topics/malaria#tab=tab_1. |
1. | Christopher Eric Bragança, Daniel Adam Kraut, Mode of targeting to the proteasome determines GFP fate, 2020, 295, 00219258, 15892, 10.1074/jbc.RA120.015235 | |
2. | Alessandra Porcu, Anna Nilsson, Sathwik Booreddy, Samuel A. Barnes, David K. Welsh, Davide Dulcis, Seasonal changes in day length induce multisynaptic neurotransmitter switching to regulate hypothalamic network activity and behavior, 2022, 8, 2375-2548, 10.1126/sciadv.abn9867 | |
3. | Luca Mantovanelli, Bauke F. Gaastra, Bert Poolman, 2021, 88, 9780323911146, 1, 10.1016/bs.ctm.2021.10.002 | |
4. | Jia Jun Fung, Karla Blöcher-Juárez, Anton Khmelinskii, 2022, Chapter 6, 978-1-0716-1731-1, 85, 10.1007/978-1-0716-1732-8_6 | |
5. | Magdalena Surdyka, Ewelina Jesion, Anna Niewiadomska-Cimicka, Yvon Trottier, Żaneta Kalinowska-Pośka, Maciej Figiel, Selective transduction of cerebellar Purkinje and granule neurons using delivery of AAV-PHP.eB and AAVrh10 vectors at axonal terminal locations, 2022, 15, 1662-5099, 10.3389/fnmol.2022.947490 | |
6. | Elisabet Navarro-Tapia, Roberto Pérez-Torrado, 2022, Chapter 3, 978-1-0716-1731-1, 31, 10.1007/978-1-0716-1732-8_3 | |
7. | Hongtao Zhang, Eric Linster, Markus Wirtz, Frederica L. Theodoulou, 2023, Chapter 14, 978-1-0716-2783-9, 201, 10.1007/978-1-0716-2784-6_14 | |
8. | Hans S. Bell, John Tower, In vivo assay and modelling of protein and mitochondrial turnover during aging, 2021, 15, 1933-6934, 60, 10.1080/19336934.2021.1911286 | |
9. | Jingyu Pan, Yongsheng Tang, Jia Liu, Cong Gao, Wei Song, Jing Wu, Liming Liu, Xiulai Chen, Reprogramming protein stability in Escherichia coli to improve four-carbon dicarboxylic acids production, 2024, 493, 13858947, 152893, 10.1016/j.cej.2024.152893 | |
10. | Xuelian Zhou, Lu Miao, Yonghui Chen, Jinjing Shi, Qinglong Qiao, Zhaochao Xu, Naphthalimide-derived fluorogenic SNAP probe for real-time monitoring of protein degradation, 2025, 1359-7345, 10.1039/D5CC00459D | |
11. | Sang-ah Park, Ji Min Lee, Deubiquitinase dynamics: methodologies for understanding substrate interactions, 2025, 58, 1976-670X, 191, 10.5483/BMBRep.2025-0011 | |
12. | Katherine S. Bell, Sebastian Ko, Sam Ali, Brett Bognar, Michael Khmelkov, Nick Rau, Oscar K. Peng, Mavi Eyuboglu, John Paine, Andy Tong, Anuj Saria, Siddharth Agrawal, Kelvin J. A. Davies, John Tower, Tissue-Specific Fluorescent Protein Turnover in Free-Moving Flies, 2025, 16, 2075-4450, 583, 10.3390/insects16060583 |
Parameter value | Description |
mortality rate for infected children | |
additional death rate due to AIDS | |
rate of progression to AIDS, if not treated | |
preferential rate of recruitment for children to receive ART | |
transmission probability | |
factor of reduction on rate of disease transmission due to ART | |
factor of reduction on rate of MTCT due to treatment |
Parameter values | Description (each is for the 6 countries) |
Birth rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Death rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for high risk groups | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for high risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of defaulting in the use of ART-assumed to be the same for both risk groups in each of the countries | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in High risk groups | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in Low risk groups |
Low Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
125.46 | 234.63 | 310.64 | 107.62 | 172.46 | 423.69 | |||
89.14 | 193.46 | 154.29 | 98.947 | 193.42 | 244.36 | |||
97.432 | 102.46 | 196.98 | 69.442 | 207.16 | 219.80 | |||
49.864 | 299.87 | 130.26 | 124.67 | 154.32 | 501.64 | |||
High Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
28.808 | 125.01 | 120.09 | 77.004 | 124.50 | 142.29 | |||
65.128 | 166.29 | 276.41 | 85.677 | 103.49 | 321.64 | |||
56.836 | 257.30 | 233.75 | 115.18 | 89.809 | 346.20 | |||
104.41 | 60.049 | 300.46 | 59.954 | 142.64 | 64.384 |
Parameter value | Description |
mortality rate for infected children | |
additional death rate due to AIDS | |
rate of progression to AIDS, if not treated | |
preferential rate of recruitment for children to receive ART | |
transmission probability | |
factor of reduction on rate of disease transmission due to ART | |
factor of reduction on rate of MTCT due to treatment |
Parameter values | Description (each is for the 6 countries) |
Birth rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Death rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for high risk groups | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for high risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of defaulting in the use of ART-assumed to be the same for both risk groups in each of the countries | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in High risk groups | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in Low risk groups |
Low Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
125.46 | 234.63 | 310.64 | 107.62 | 172.46 | 423.69 | |||
89.14 | 193.46 | 154.29 | 98.947 | 193.42 | 244.36 | |||
97.432 | 102.46 | 196.98 | 69.442 | 207.16 | 219.80 | |||
49.864 | 299.87 | 130.26 | 124.67 | 154.32 | 501.64 | |||
High Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
28.808 | 125.01 | 120.09 | 77.004 | 124.50 | 142.29 | |||
65.128 | 166.29 | 276.41 | 85.677 | 103.49 | 321.64 | |||
56.836 | 257.30 | 233.75 | 115.18 | 89.809 | 346.20 | |||
104.41 | 60.049 | 300.46 | 59.954 | 142.64 | 64.384 |