As a knowledge-intensive financial enterprise, intellectual capital can play a significant driving role in enhancing the value of financial enterprises. Especially in the current unstable and complex international financial market, it is necessary for financial enterprises to actively consider the advantages of intellectual capital to shape their competitive edge and maximize profit value. However, it is also important to consider the issue of asymmetric information within the financial system, particularly the attitudes and behaviors in the strategic interactions between governments and financial enterprises. Therefore, this paper took the strict logical structure and analytical method of game theory as an effective analytical tool to solve the problem of asymmetric information in the economy and to use the asymmetric information game method to construct a mathematical model of intellectual capital in order to cope with the mistrust in the game process. Based on game theory, this paper systematically analyzed the factors influencing intellectual capital and constructed mathematical models of game theory for adverse selection ex-ante and moral hazard ex-post, analyzing strategic behavior. The research results indicated that, from the perspectives of market reactions and financing constraints, there is an issue of information asymmetry between the government and financial enterprises. The paper also presents viable strategic recommendations for alleviating information asymmetry and achieving coordinated allocation of information resources between government and enterprises.
Citation: Bei Yuan. Mathematical modeling of intellectual capital asymmetric information game in financial enterprises[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(3): 5708-5721. doi: 10.3934/math.2024277
[1] | Ahmad Mohammed Alghamdi, Sadek Gala, Maria Alessandra Ragusa . A regularity criterion of weak solutions to the 3D Boussinesq equations. AIMS Mathematics, 2017, 2(3): 451-457. doi: 10.3934/Math.2017.2.451 |
[2] | Wei Zhang . A priori estimates for the free boundary problem of incompressible inviscid Boussinesq and MHD-Boussinesq equations without heat diffusion. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(3): 6074-6094. doi: 10.3934/math.2023307 |
[3] | Zhaoyang Shang . Osgood type blow-up criterion for the 3D Boussinesq equations with partial viscosity. AIMS Mathematics, 2018, 3(1): 1-11. doi: 10.3934/Math.2018.1.1 |
[4] | Sadek Gala, Maria Alessandra Ragusa . A logarithmically improved regularity criterion for the 3D MHD equations in Morrey-Campanato space. AIMS Mathematics, 2017, 2(1): 16-23. doi: 10.3934/Math.2017.1.16 |
[5] | Xinli Wang, Haiyang Yu, Tianfeng Wu . Global well-posedness and optimal decay rates for the n-D incompressible Boussinesq equations with fractional dissipation and thermal diffusion. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(12): 34863-34885. doi: 10.3934/math.20241660 |
[6] | Feng Cheng . On the dissipative solutions for the inviscid Boussinesq equations. AIMS Mathematics, 2020, 5(4): 2869-2876. doi: 10.3934/math.2020184 |
[7] | Ahmad Mohammad Alghamdi, Sadek Gala, Jae-Myoung Kim, Maria Alessandra Ragusa . The anisotropic integrability logarithmic regularity criterion to the 3D micropolar fluid equations. AIMS Mathematics, 2020, 5(1): 359-375. doi: 10.3934/math.2020024 |
[8] | Xuemin Xue, Xiangtuan Xiong, Yuanxiang Zhang . Two fractional regularization methods for identifying the radiogenic source of the Helium production-diffusion equation. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(10): 11425-11448. doi: 10.3934/math.2021662 |
[9] | Oussama Melkemi, Mohammed S. Abdo, Wafa Shammakh, Hadeel Z. Alzumi . Yudovich type solution for the two dimensional Euler-Boussinesq system with critical dissipation and general source term. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(8): 18566-18580. doi: 10.3934/math.2023944 |
[10] | Ailing Ban . Asymptotic behavior of non-autonomous stochastic Boussinesq lattice system. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(1): 839-857. doi: 10.3934/math.2025040 |
As a knowledge-intensive financial enterprise, intellectual capital can play a significant driving role in enhancing the value of financial enterprises. Especially in the current unstable and complex international financial market, it is necessary for financial enterprises to actively consider the advantages of intellectual capital to shape their competitive edge and maximize profit value. However, it is also important to consider the issue of asymmetric information within the financial system, particularly the attitudes and behaviors in the strategic interactions between governments and financial enterprises. Therefore, this paper took the strict logical structure and analytical method of game theory as an effective analytical tool to solve the problem of asymmetric information in the economy and to use the asymmetric information game method to construct a mathematical model of intellectual capital in order to cope with the mistrust in the game process. Based on game theory, this paper systematically analyzed the factors influencing intellectual capital and constructed mathematical models of game theory for adverse selection ex-ante and moral hazard ex-post, analyzing strategic behavior. The research results indicated that, from the perspectives of market reactions and financing constraints, there is an issue of information asymmetry between the government and financial enterprises. The paper also presents viable strategic recommendations for alleviating information asymmetry and achieving coordinated allocation of information resources between government and enterprises.
This paper is concerned with the regularity criterion of the 3D Boussinesq equations with the incompressibility condition :
{∂tu+u⋅∇u−Δu+∇π=θe3,∂tθ+u⋅∇θ−Δθ=0,∇⋅u=0,(u,θ)(x,0)=(u0,θ0)(x),x∈R3, | (1.1) |
where u=u(x,t) and θ=θ(x,t) denote the unknown velocity vector field and the scalar function temperature, while u0, θ0 with ∇⋅u0=0 in the sense of distribution are given initial data. e3=(0,0,1)T. π=π(x,t) the pressure of fluid at the point (x,t)∈R3×(0,∞). The Boussinesq equation is one of important subjects for researches in nonlinear sciences [14]. There are a huge literatures on the incompressible Boussinesq equations such as [1,2,3,4,6,8,9,10,17,19,20,21,22] and the references therein.
When θ=0, (1.1) reduces to the well-known incompressible Navier-Stokes equations and many results are available. Besides their physical applications, the Navier-Stokes equations are also mathematically significant. From that time on, much effort has been devoted to establish the global existence and uniqueness of smooth solutions to the Navier-Stokes equations.
However, similar to the classic Navier-Stokes equations, the question of global regularity of the weak solutions of the 3D Boussinesq equations still remains a big open problem and the system (1.1) has received many studies. Based on some analysis technique, some regularity criteria via the velocity of weak solutions in the Lebesgue spaces, multiplier spaces and Besov spaces have been obtained in [5,17,19,20,22,23].
More recently, the authors of the present paper [7] showed that the weak solution becomes regular if
∫T0‖u(⋅,t)‖21−r.B−r∞,∞+‖θ(⋅,t)‖21−r.B−r∞,∞1+log(e+‖u(⋅,t)‖Hs+‖θ(⋅,t)‖Hs)dt<∞ for some 0≤r<1 and s≥12, | (1.2) |
where .B−r∞,∞ denotes the homogeneous Besov space. Definitions and basic properties of the Sobolev spaces and the Besov spaces can be find in [18]. For concision, we omit them here.
The purpose of this paper is to improve the regularity criterion (1.2) in the following form.
Theorem 1.1. Let (u,θ) be a smooth solution to (1.1) in [0,T) with the initial data (u0,θ0)∈H3(R3)×H3(R3) with divu0=0 in R3. Suppose that the solution (u,θ) satisfies
∫T0‖u(⋅,t)‖21−r.B−r∞,∞log(e+‖u(⋅,t)‖.B−r∞,∞)dt<∞ for some r with 0≤r<1. | (1.3) |
Then it holds
sup0≤t≤T(‖u(⋅,t)‖2H3+‖θ(⋅,t)‖2H3)<∞. |
That is, the solution (u,θ) can be smoothly extended after time t=T. In other word, if T∗ is the maximal time existence of the solution, then
∫T∗0‖u(⋅,t)‖21−r.B−r∞,∞log(e+‖u(⋅,t)‖.B−r∞,∞)dt<∞. |
Then the solution can be smoothly extended after t=T.
Remark 1.1. The condition (1.3) can be regarded as a logarithmically improved version of the assumption
∫T0‖u(⋅,t)‖21−r.B−r∞,∞dt<∞ for some r with 0≤r<1. |
For the case r=1, we have the following result.
Theorem 1.2. Let (u,θ) be a smooth solution to (1.1) in [0,T) with the initial data (u0,θ0)∈H3(R3)×H3(R3) with divu0=0 in R3. Suppose that there exists a small positive constant η such that
‖u(⋅,t)‖L∞(0,T;.B−1∞,∞(R3))≤η, | (1.4) |
then solution (u,θ) can be smoothly extended after time t=T.
Remark 1.2. Theorem 1.2 can be regarded as improvements and limiting cases of those in [7]. It is worth to point out all conditions are valid for the usual Navier-Stokes equations. We refer to a recent work [7] and references therein.
Remark 1.3. For the case r=0, see [23].
In this section, we will prove Theorem 1.1 by the standard energy method.
Let T>0 be a given fixed time. The existence and uniqueness of local smooth solutions can be obtained as in the case of the Navier-Stokes equations. Hence, for all T>0 we assume that (u,θ) is a smooth solution to (1.1) on [0,T) and we will establish a priori bounds that will allow us to extend (u,θ) beyond time T under the condition (1.3).
Owing to (1.3) holds, one can deduce that for any small ϵ>0, there exists T0=T0(ϵ)<T such that
∫TT0‖u(⋅,t)‖21−r.B−r∞,∞log(e+‖u(⋅,t)‖.B−r∞,∞) dt≤ϵ<<1. | (2.1) |
Thanks to the divergence-free condition ∇⋅u=0, from (1.1)2, we get immediately the global a priori bound for θ in any Lebesgue space
‖θ(⋅,t)‖Lq≤C‖θ0‖Lq for all q∈[2,∞] and all t∈[0,T]. |
Now, multiplying (1.1)2 by θ and using integration by parts, we get
12ddt‖θ‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2=0. |
Hence, we obtain
θ∈L∞(0,T;L2(R3))∩L2(0,T;H1(R3)). | (2.2) |
Next, multiplying (1.1)1 by u, we have after integration by part,
12ddt‖u‖2L2+‖∇u‖2L2=∫R3(θe3)⋅udx≤‖θ‖L2‖u‖L2≤C‖u‖L2, |
which yields
u∈L∞(0,T;L2(R3))∩L2(0,T;H1(R3)), | (2.3) |
where we used (2.2) and
∫R3(u⋅∇u)⋅udx=12∫R3(u⋅∇)u2dx=−12∫R3(∇⋅u)u2dx=0 |
by incompressibility of u, that is, ∇⋅u=0.
Now, apply ∇ operator to the equation of (1.1)1 and (1.1)2, then taking the inner product with ∇u and ∇θ, respectively and using integration by parts, we get
12ddt(‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2)+‖Δu‖2L2+‖Δθ‖2L2=−∫R3∇(u⋅∇)u⋅∇udx+∫R3∇(θe3)⋅∇udx−∫R3∇(u⋅∇)θ⋅∇θdx=I1+I2+I3. | (2.4) |
Employing the Hölder and Young inequalities, we derive the estimation of the first term I1 as
I1=∫R3(u⋅∇)u⋅Δudx≤‖∇⋅(u⊗u)‖L2‖Δu‖L2≤C‖u‖.B−r∞,∞‖∇u‖⋅Hr‖Δu‖L2≤C‖u‖.B−r∞,∞‖∇u‖1−rL2‖Δu‖1+rL2≤12‖Δu‖2L2+C‖u‖21−r.B−r∞,∞‖∇u‖2L2≤12‖Δu‖2L2+C‖u‖21−r.B−r∞,∞(‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2), |
where we have used the inequality due to [16] :
‖u⊗u‖⋅H1≤C‖u‖.B−r∞,∞‖∇u‖⋅Hr |
and the interpolation inequality
‖w‖.Hs=‖|ξ|sˆw‖L2≤‖w‖1−sL2‖∇w‖sL2 for all 0≤s≤1. |
The term I3 can be estimated as
I3≤C‖∇u‖L2‖∇θ‖2L4≤C‖∇u‖L2‖∇θ‖.B−1∞,∞‖Δθ‖L2≤C‖∇u‖L2‖θ‖.B0∞,∞‖Δθ‖L2≤12‖Δθ‖2L2+C‖θ‖2L∞‖∇u‖2L2≤12‖Δθ‖2L2+C‖θ‖2L∞(‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2), |
where we have used
‖∇θ‖.B−1∞,∞≤C‖θ‖.B0∞,∞≤C‖θ‖L∞. |
The term I2 can be estimated as
I2≤‖∇u‖L2‖∇θ‖L2≤12(‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2). |
Plugging all the estimates into (2.4) yields that
ddt(‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2)+‖Δu‖2L2+‖Δθ‖2L2≤C(12+‖u‖21−r.B−r∞,∞+‖θ‖2L∞)(‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2). |
Hence, we obtain
ddt(‖∇u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖∇θ(⋅,t)‖2L2)+‖Δu‖2L2+‖Δθ‖2L2≤C[12+‖u‖21−r.B−r∞,∞+‖θ‖2L∞log(e+‖u‖.B−r∞,∞)](‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2)log(e+‖u‖.B−r∞,∞)≤C[12+‖u‖21−r.B−r∞,∞+‖θ‖2L∞log(e+‖u‖.B−r∞,∞)](‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2)log(e+‖u‖H3+‖θ‖H3)≤C[12+‖u‖21−r.B−r∞,∞+‖θ‖2L∞log(e+‖u‖.B−r∞,∞)](‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2)log(e+κ(t)) |
where κ(t) is defined by
κ(t)=supT0≤τ≤t(‖u(⋅,τ)‖H3+‖θ(⋅,τ)‖H3)forallT0<t<T. |
It should be noted that the function κ(t) is nondecreasing. Moreover, we have used the following fact :
‖u‖.B−r∞,∞≤C‖u‖H3. |
Integrating the above inequality over [T0,t] and applying Gronwall's inequality, we have
‖∇u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖∇θ(⋅,t)‖2L2+∫tT∗‖Δu(⋅,τ)‖2L2+‖Δθ(⋅,τ)‖2L2dτ≤(‖∇u(⋅,T0)‖2L2+‖∇θ(⋅,T0)‖2L2)×exp(C∫tT0‖u‖21−r.B−r∞,∞log(e+‖u(⋅,τ)‖.B−r∞,∞)log(e+κ(τ))dτ)≤(‖∇u(⋅,T0)‖2L2+‖∇θ(⋅,T0)‖2L2)×exp(Clog(e+κ(t))∫tT0‖u‖21−r.B−r∞,∞log(e+‖u(⋅,τ)‖.B−r∞,∞)dτ)≤˜Cexp(Cϵlog(e+κ(t)))=˜C(e+κ(t))Cϵ | (2.5) |
where ˜C is a positive constant depending on ‖∇u(⋅,T0)‖2L2, ‖∇θ(⋅,T0)‖2L2, T0, T and θ0.
H3−norm. Next, we start to obtain the H3−estimates under the above estimate (2.5). Applying Λ3=(−Δ)32 to (1.1)1, then taking L2 inner product of the resulting equation with Λ3u, and using integration by parts, we obtain
12ddt‖Λ3u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Λ4u(⋅,t)‖2L2=−∫R3Λ3(u⋅∇u)⋅Λ3udx+∫R3Λ3(θe3)⋅Λ3udx | (2.6) |
Similarly, applying Λ3=(−Δ)32 to (1.1)2, then taking L2 inner product of the resulting equation with Λ3θ, and using integration by parts, we obtain
12ddt‖Λ3θ(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Λ4θ(⋅,t)‖2L2=−∫R3Λ3(u⋅∇θ)⋅Λ3θdx, | (2.7) |
Using ∇⋅u=0, we deduce that
12ddt(‖Λ3u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Λ3θ(⋅,t)‖2L2)+‖Λ4u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Λ4θ(⋅,t)‖2L2=−∫R3[Λ3(u⋅∇u)−u⋅Λ3∇u]⋅Λ3udx+∫R3Λ3(θe3)⋅Λ3udx−∫3R3[Λ3(u⋅∇θ)−u⋅Λ3∇θ]⋅Λ3θdx=Π1+Π2+Π3. | (2.8) |
To bound Π1, we recall the following commutator estimate due to [12]:
‖Λα(fg)−fΛαg‖Lp≤C(‖Λα−1g‖Lq1‖∇f‖Lp1+‖Λαf‖Lp2‖g‖Lq2), | (2.9) |
for α>1, and 1p=1p1+1q1=1p2+1q2. Hence Π1 can be estimated as
Π1≤C‖∇u‖L3‖Λ3u‖2L3≤C‖∇u‖34L2‖Λ3u‖14L2‖∇u‖13L2‖Λ4u‖53L2≤16‖Λ4u‖2L2+C‖∇u‖132L2‖Λ3u‖32L2, | (2.10) |
where we used (2.9) with α=3,p=32, p1=q1=p2=q2=3, and the following Gagliardo-Nirenberg inequalities
{‖∇u‖L3≤C‖∇u‖34L2‖Λ3u‖14L2,‖Λ3u‖L3≤C‖∇u‖16L2‖Λ4u‖56L2. | (2.11) |
If we use the existing estimate (2.1) for T0≤t<T, (2.10) reduces to
Π1≤12‖Λ4u‖2L2+˜C(e+κ(t))32+132Cϵ. | (2.12) |
Using (2.11) again, we get
Π3≤C(‖∇u‖L3‖Λ3θ‖L3+‖∇θ‖L3‖Λ3u‖L3)‖Λ3θ‖L3≤C(‖∇u‖L3+‖∇θ‖L3)(‖Λ3u‖2L3+‖Λ3θ‖2L3)≤16(‖Λ4u‖2L2+‖Λ4θ‖2L2)+˜C(e+κ(t))32+132Cϵ. |
For Π2, we have
Π2≤12(‖Λ3u‖2L2+‖Λ3θ‖2L2)≤˜C(e+κ(t))2. |
Inserting all the inequalities into (2.8) and absorbing the dissipative terms, one finds
ddt(‖Λ3u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Λ3θ(⋅,t)‖2L2)≤˜C(e+κ(t))32+132Cϵ+˜C(e+κ(t))2, | (2.13) |
with together with the basic energy (2.2)-([2.3]) yields
ddt(‖u(⋅,t)‖2H3+‖θ(⋅,t)‖2H3)≤˜C(e+κ(t))32+132Cϵ+˜C(e+κ(t))2, | (2.14) |
Choosing ϵ sufficiently small provided that 132Cϵ<12 and applying the Gronwall inequality to (2.14), we derive that
supT0≤τ≤t(‖u(⋅,τ)‖2H3+‖θ(⋅,τ)‖2H3)≤˜C<∞, | (2.15) |
where ˜C depends on ‖∇u(⋅,T0)‖2L2 and ‖∇θ(⋅,T0)‖2L2.
Noting that the right-hand side of (2.15) is independent of t for , we know that (u(⋅,T),θ(⋅,T))∈H3(R3)×H3(R3). Consequently, (u,θ) can be extended smoothly beyond t=T. This completes the proof of Theorem 1.1.
In order to prove Theorem 1.2, we first recall the following local existence theorem of the three-dimensional Boussinesq equations.
Lemma 3.1. Suppose (u,θ)∈Lα(R3), for some α≥3 and ∇⋅u=0. Then, there exists T0>0 and a unique solution of (1.1) on [0,T0) such that
(u,θ)∈BC([0,T0);Lα(R3))∩Ls([0,T0);Lr(R3)),t1su∈BC([0,T0);Lα(R3)) | (3.1) |
Moreover, let (0,T∗) be the maximal interval such that (u,θ) solves (1.1) in C((0,T∗);Lα(R3)), α>3. Then for any t∈(0,T∗)
‖u(⋅,t)‖Lα≥C(T∗−t)α−32α and ‖θ(⋅,t)‖Lα≥C(T∗−t)α−32α, |
with the constant C independent of T∗ and α.
Let (u,θ) be a strong solution satisfying
(u,θ)∈Lα((0,T);Lβ(R3)) for 2α+3β=1 and β>3. |
Then (u,θ) belongs to C∞(R3×(0,T)).
Proof. For all T>0, we assume that (u,θ) is a smooth solution to (1.1) on [0,T) and we will establish a priori bounds that will allow us to extend (u,θ) beyond time T under the condition (1.4).
Similar to the proof of Theorem 1.1, we can show that
(u,θ)∈L∞(0,T;L2(R3))∩L2(0,T;H1(R3)). | (3.2) |
The proof of Theorem 1.2 is divided into steps.
Step Ⅰ. H1−estimation. In order to get the H1−estimates, we apply ∇ operator to the equation of (1.1)1 and (1.1)2, multiply by ∇u and ∇θ, respectively to obtain
12ddt(‖∇u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖∇θ(⋅,t)‖2L2)+‖Δu(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Δθ(⋅,t)‖2L2=−∫R3∇(u⋅∇)u⋅∇udx+∫R3∇(θe3)⋅∇udx−∫R3∇(u⋅∇)θ⋅∇θdx=I1+I2+I3. | (3.3) |
Next we estimate I1,I2 and I3 in another way. Hence,
I1≤‖∇u‖3L3≤C‖∇u‖.B−2∞,∞‖Δu‖2L2≤C‖u‖.B−1∞,∞‖Δu‖2L2, |
where we have used the following interpolation inequality due to [16] :
‖w‖L3≤C‖∇w‖23L2‖w‖13.B−2∞,∞. |
By means of the Hölder and Young inequalities, the term I3 can be estimated as
I3≤C‖∇u‖L2‖∇θ‖2L4≤C‖∇u‖L2‖∇θ‖.B−1∞,∞‖Δθ‖L2≤C‖θ‖2.B0∞,∞‖Δθ‖2L2+C‖∇u‖2L2≤C‖θ‖2L∞‖Δθ‖2L2+C‖∇u‖2L2, |
where we have used the following interpolation inequality due to [16] :
‖∇θ‖2L4≤C‖∇θ‖.B−1∞,∞‖Δθ‖L2. |
The term I2 can be estimated as
I2≤‖∇u‖L2‖∇θ‖L2≤12(‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2). |
Plugging all the estimates into (3.3) yields that
12ddt(‖∇u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖∇θ(⋅,t)‖2L2)+‖Δu(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Δθ(⋅,t)‖2L2≤C‖u‖.B−1∞,∞‖Δu‖2L2+C‖θ‖2L∞‖Δθ‖2L2+C(‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2). |
Under the assumption (1.4), we choose η small enough so that
C‖u‖.B−1∞,∞≤12 . |
Hence, we find that
ddt(‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2)+‖Δu‖2L2+‖Δθ‖2L2≤C(‖∇u‖2L2+‖∇θ‖2L2). |
Integrating in time and applying the Gronwall inequality, we infer that
‖∇u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖∇θ(⋅,t)‖2L2+∫T0(‖Δu(⋅,τ)‖2L2+‖Δθ(⋅,τ)‖2L2)dτ≤C. | (3.4) |
Step Ⅱ. H2−estimation. Next, we start to obtain the H2−estimates under the above estimate (3.4). Applying Δ to (1.1)1, then taking L2 inner product of the resulting equation with Δu, and using integration by parts, we obtain
12ddt‖Δu(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Λ3u(⋅,t)‖2L2=−∫R3Δ(u⋅∇u)⋅Δudx+∫R3Δ(θe3)⋅Δudx | (3.5) |
Similarly, applying Δ to (1.1)2, then taking L2 inner product of the resulting equation with Δθ, and using integration by parts, we obtain
12ddt‖Δθ(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Λ3θ(⋅,t)‖2L2=−∫R3Δ(u⋅∇θ)⋅Δθdx. | (3.6) |
Adding (3.5) and (3.6), we deduce that
12ddt(‖Δu(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Δθ(⋅,t)‖2L2)+‖Λ3u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Λ3θ(⋅,t)‖2L2=−∫R3Δ(u⋅∇u)⋅Δudx+∫R3Δ(θe3)⋅Δudx−∫R3Δ(u⋅∇θ)⋅Δθdx=K1+K2+K3. | (3.7) |
Using Hölder's inequality and Young's inequality, K1 can be estimated as
K1=∫R3Δ(u⊗u)⋅Δ∇udx≤‖Δ(u⊗u)‖L2‖Δ∇u‖L2≤C‖u‖L∞‖Δu‖L2‖Λ3u‖L2≤12‖Λ3u‖2L2+C‖u‖2L∞‖Δu‖2L2. |
Here we have used the bilinear estimates due to Kato-Ponce [12] and Kenig-Ponce-Vega [13]:
‖Λα(fg)‖Lp≤C(‖Λαg‖Lq1‖f‖Lp1+‖Λαf‖Lp2‖g‖Lq2), |
for α>0, and 1p=1p1+1q1=1+1q2.
From the incompressibility condition, Hölder's inequality and Young's inequality, one has
K3=∫R3Δ(uθ)⋅Δ∇θdx≤‖Δ(uθ)‖L2‖Δ∇θ‖L2≤C(‖u‖L∞‖Δθ‖L2+‖θ‖L∞‖Δu‖L2)‖Λ3θ‖L2≤12‖Λ3θ‖2L2+C(‖u‖2L∞+‖θ‖2L∞)(‖Δu‖2L2+‖Δθ‖2L2). |
For K2, we have
K2≤12(‖Δu‖2L2+‖Δθ‖2L2) |
Inserting all the inequalities into (3.7) and absorbing the dissipative terms, one finds
ddt(‖Δu(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Δθ(⋅,t)‖2L2)+‖Λ3u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Λ3θ(⋅,t)‖2L2≤C(‖u‖2L∞+‖θ‖2L∞)(‖Δu‖2L2+‖Δθ‖2L2). | (3.8) |
Using the following interpolation inequality
‖f‖L∞≤C‖f‖14L2‖Δf‖34L2, |
together with the key estimate (3.4) yield that
∫T0(‖u(⋅,τ)‖2L∞+‖θ(⋅,τ)‖2L∞)dτ≤C<∞. |
Applying the Gronwall inequality to (3.8), we derive that
‖Δu(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Δθ(⋅,t)‖2L2+∫T0(‖Λ3u(⋅,t)‖2L2+‖Λ3θ(⋅,t)‖2L2)dt≤C. | (3.9) |
By estimates (3.4) and (3.9) as well as the following Gagliardo-Nirenberg's inequality
‖f‖L6≤C‖f‖12L2‖Δf‖12L2, |
it is easy to see that
(u,θ)∈L4(0,T;L6(R3)), |
from which and Lemma 3.1 the smoothness of (u,θ) follows immediately. This completes the proof of Theorem 1.2.
Part of the work was carried out while the first author was long term visitor at University of Catania. The hospitality and support of Catania University are graciously acknowledged.
All authors would like to thank Professor Bo-Qing Dong for helpful discussion and constant encouragement. They also would like to thank the anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments and suggestions to improve the quality of the paper.
All authors declare no conflicts of interest in this paper.
[1] | P. Nesegil, The effect of intellectual capital efficiency on financial performance: a research on participation banks, J. Life Econ., 8 (2021), 281-287. |
[2] |
D. T. Nguyen, T. D. Q. Le, S. H. Tran, The moderating role of income diversification on the relationship between intellectual capital and bank performance evidence from Viet Nam, Cogent Bus. Manag., 10 (2023), 2182621. https://doi.org/10.1080/23311975.2023.2182621 doi: 10.1080/23311975.2023.2182621
![]() |
[3] | J. Bananuka, Intellectual capital, isomorphic forces and internet financial reporting: evidence from Uganda's financial services firms, J. Econ. Adm. Sci., 36 (2019), 110-133. https://doi.org/10.1108/JEAS-03-2018-0042 |
[4] | K. C. T. Duho, Intangibles, intellectual capital, and the performance of listed non-financial services firms in West Africa: a cross-country analysis, Merits, 2 (2022), 101-125. https://doi.org/10.3390/merits2030009 |
[5] |
P. N. Tran, D. H. Vo, Do banks accumulate a higher level of intellectual capital? Evidence from an emerging market, J. Intellec. Cap., 23 (2020), 439-457. https://doi.org/10.1108/JIC-03-2020-0097 doi: 10.1108/JIC-03-2020-0097
![]() |
[6] |
M. T. H. Majumder, I. J. Ruma, A. Akter, Does intellectual capital affect bank performance? Evidence from Bangladesh, LBS J. Manag. Res., 21 (2023), 171-185. https://doi.org/10.1108/LBSJMR-05-2022-0016 doi: 10.1108/LBSJMR-05-2022-0016
![]() |
[7] |
P. Prasojo, W. Yadiati, T. Fitrijanti, M. Sueb, Exploring the relationship between intellectual capital and maqasid sharia-based performance: the moderating role of sharia governance, J. Islamic Mark., 14 (2023), 2130-2146. https://doi.org/10.1108/JIMA-07-2021-0226 doi: 10.1108/JIMA-07-2021-0226
![]() |
[8] |
P. N. Githaiga, Income diversification and bank risk-taking: the moderating role of intellectual capital, Cogent Bus. Manag., 9 (2022), 2149142. https://doi.org/10.1080/23311975.2022.2149142 doi: 10.1080/23311975.2022.2149142
![]() |
[9] |
M. A. S. Mollah, M. A. Rouf, The impact of intellectual capital on commercial banks' performance: evidence from Bangladesh, J. Money Bus., 2 (2022), 82-93. https://doi.org/10.1108/JMB-07-2021-0024 doi: 10.1108/JMB-07-2021-0024
![]() |
[10] | N. Niccolò, Intellectual capital: the missing link in the corporate social responsibility-financial performance relationship, J. Intellect. Cap., 23 (2022), 420-438. https://doi.org/10.1108/jic-02-2020-0038 |
[11] |
L. A. M. Chowdhury, T. Rana, M. Akter, H. Mahfuzul, Impact of intellectual capital on financial performance: evidence from the Bangladeshi textile sector, J. Account. Organ. Chan., 14 (2018), 429-454. https://doi.org/10.1108/JAOC-11-2017-0109 doi: 10.1108/JAOC-11-2017-0109
![]() |
[12] |
D. B. Tran, D. H. Vo, Should bankers be concerned with Intellectual capital? A study of the Thai banking sector, J. Intellect. Cap., 19 (2018), 897-914. https://doi.org/10.1108/JIC-12-2017-0185 doi: 10.1108/JIC-12-2017-0185
![]() |
[13] |
H. S. Mohammad, I. Bujang, Performance of Malaysian financial firms: an intellectual capital perspective using MVAIC model, Asian Econ. Financ. Rev., 9 (2019), 752-765. https://doi.org/10.18488/journal.aefr.2019.97.752.765 doi: 10.18488/journal.aefr.2019.97.752.765
![]() |
[14] |
Y. Yang, Do aggressive pro forma earnings-reporting firms have difficulty disclosing intellectual capital? Australian evidence, J. Intellect. Cap., 19 (2018), 875-896. https://doi.org/10.1108/JIC-03-2017-0051 doi: 10.1108/JIC-03-2017-0051
![]() |
[15] |
G. Ginesti, A. Caldarelli, A. Zampella, Exploring the impact of intellectual capital on company reputation and performance, J. Intellect. Cap., 19 (2018), 915-934. https://doi.org/10.1108/JIC-01-2018-0012 doi: 10.1108/JIC-01-2018-0012
![]() |
[16] | M. A. Ibarra Cisneros, F. Hernandez-Perlines, Intellectual capital and Organization performance in the manufacturing sector of Mexico, Manag. Decis., 56 (2018), 1818-1834. https://doi.org/10.1108/MD-10-2017-0946 |
[17] | F. Bertani, L. Ponta, M. Raberto, A. Teglio, Silvano Cincotti, The complexity of the intangible digital economy: an agent-based model, J. Bus. Res., 129 (2021), 527-540. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.03.041 |
[18] |
S. U. Rehman, H. Elrehail, A. Alsaad, A. Bhatti, Intellectual capital and innovative performance: a mediation-moderation perspective, J. Intellect. Cap., 23 (2021), 998-1024. https://doi.org/10.1108/JIC-04-2020-0109 doi: 10.1108/JIC-04-2020-0109
![]() |
[19] | H. Hong, J. D. Kubik, J. A. Scheinkman, Financial constraints on corporate goodness, NBER Working Paper, 2012. |
[20] |
T. Garanina, J. Dumay, Forward-looking intellectual capital disclosure in IPOs: implications for intellectual capital and integrated reporting, J. Intellect. Cap., 18 (2017), 128-148. https://doi.org/10.1108/JIC-05-2016-0054 doi: 10.1108/JIC-05-2016-0054
![]() |
[21] |
F. Caputo, M. D. Giudice, F. Evangelista, G. Russo, Corporate disclosure and intellectual capital: the light side of information asymmetry, Int. J. Manag. Financ. Account., 8 (2016), 75-81. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJMFA.2016.076668 doi: 10.1504/IJMFA.2016.076668
![]() |
[22] | W. Widarjo, R. Rahmawati, B. Bandi, A. K. Widagd, Underwriter reputation, intellectual capital disclosure, and underpricing, Int. J. Biol. Sci., 18 (2017), 227-244. https://doi.org/10.33736/ijbs.480.2017 |
[23] |
F. Caputo, M. D. Giudice, F. Evangelista, G. Russo, Corporate disclosure and intellectual capital: the light side of information asymmetry, Int. J. Manag. Financ. Account., 8 (2016), 75-97. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJMFA.2016.076668 doi: 10.1504/IJMFA.2016.076668
![]() |
[24] |
J. Chouaibi, A. Kouaib, Impact of shareholder' identity on intellectual capital performance: evidence from Tunisian manufacturing companies, Int. J. Manag. Financ. Account., 7 (2016), 246-267. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJMFA.2015.074903 doi: 10.1504/IJMFA.2015.074903
![]() |
[25] |
A. Limijaya, Y. Hutagaol-Martowidjojo, E. Hartanto, Intellectual capital and firm performance in Indonesia: the moderating role of corporate governance, Int. J. Manag. Financ. Account., 13 (2021), 159-182. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJMFA.2021.117772 doi: 10.1504/IJMFA.2021.117772
![]() |
1. | Sadek Gala, Maria Alessandra Ragusa, A Regularity Criterion of Weak Solutions to the 3D Boussinesq Equations, 2020, 51, 1678-7544, 513, 10.1007/s00574-019-00162-z | |
2. | Zhouyu Li, Wenjuan Liu, Qi Zhou, Conditional Regularity for the 3D Damped Boussinesq Equations with Zero Thermal Diffusion, 2024, 55, 1678-7544, 10.1007/s00574-024-00411-w |