Research article Special Issues

Risk-seeking insider trading with partial observation in continuous time

  • In this paper, a continuous-time insider trading model is investigated in which an insider is risk-seeking and market makers may receive partial information on the value of a risky asset. With the help of filtering theory and dynamic programming principle, the uniqueness and existence of linear equilibrium is established. It shows that (ⅰ) as time goes by, the residual information decreases, but both the trading intensity and the market liquidity increases, and (ⅱ) with the partial observation accuracy decreasing, both the market liquidity and the residual information will increase while the trading intensity decreases. On the whole, the risk-seeking insider is eager to trade all the trading period, and for market development, it is necessary to increase the insider's risk-preference behavior appropriately.

    Citation: Kai Xiao. Risk-seeking insider trading with partial observation in continuous time[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(11): 28143-28152. doi: 10.3934/math.20231440

    Related Papers:

    [1] Kai Xiao . Dynamic asset risk-seeking insider trading under signal observation. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(5): 11036-11051. doi: 10.3934/math.2025500
    [2] Kai Xiao, Yonghui Zhou . Linear Bayesian equilibrium in insider trading with a random time under partial observations. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(12): 13347-13357. doi: 10.3934/math.2021772
    [3] Jixiu Qiu, Yonghui Zhou . Insider trading with dynamic asset under market makers' partial observations. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(10): 25017-25036. doi: 10.3934/math.20231277
    [4] Xian Wen, Haifeng Huo, Jinhua Cui . The optimal probability of the risk for finite horizon partially observable Markov decision processes. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(12): 28435-28449. doi: 10.3934/math.20231455
    [5] Huayu Sun, Fanqi Zou, Bin Mo . Does FinTech drive asymmetric risk spillover in the traditional finance?. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(12): 20850-20872. doi: 10.3934/math.20221143
    [6] Xiuxian Chen, Zhongyang Sun, Dan Zhu . Mean-variance investment and risk control strategies for a dynamic contagion process with diffusion. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(11): 33062-33086. doi: 10.3934/math.20241580
    [7] Chunwei Wang, Jiaen Xu, Naidan Deng, Shujing Wang . Two-sided jumps risk model with proportional investment and random observation periods. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(9): 22301-22318. doi: 10.3934/math.20231137
    [8] Chunwei Wang, Shaohua Li, Jiaen Xu, Shujing Wang . Dividend problem of an investment risk model under random observation. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(9): 24039-24057. doi: 10.3934/math.20241169
    [9] Ebenezer Fiifi Emire Atta Mills . The worst-case scenario: robust portfolio optimization with discrete distributions and transaction costs. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(8): 20919-20938. doi: 10.3934/math.20241018
    [10] Liushuang Meng, Bin Wang . Risk spillovers and extreme risk between e-commerce and logistics markets in China. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(10): 29076-29106. doi: 10.3934/math.20241411
  • In this paper, a continuous-time insider trading model is investigated in which an insider is risk-seeking and market makers may receive partial information on the value of a risky asset. With the help of filtering theory and dynamic programming principle, the uniqueness and existence of linear equilibrium is established. It shows that (ⅰ) as time goes by, the residual information decreases, but both the trading intensity and the market liquidity increases, and (ⅱ) with the partial observation accuracy decreasing, both the market liquidity and the residual information will increase while the trading intensity decreases. On the whole, the risk-seeking insider is eager to trade all the trading period, and for market development, it is necessary to increase the insider's risk-preference behavior appropriately.



    In Kyle's insightful pioneering paper [4], he gave a dynamic model of insider trading where a risk-neutral insider received a liquidation value of a fundamental asset, and found that at the market equilibrium, the insider slowly released her/his private information to obtain profit and incorporated all of the private information into market price at the end of trading. In fact, different agents have different risky preferences, which is an important factor in affecting the market equilibrium. In most cases, investors are assumed to be risk-averse by many researchers. Baruch [1] used an exponential utility to study risk-averse insider trading. Immediately afterward, Cho [2] selected the same utility function in a risk-averse insider trading market. Actually, there is much literature on risk-averse models [6,8,12].

    However, the risk-seeking insider does exist in the actual trading process, due to the temptation of very high profits. For example, Tang et al. [5] gave an empirical research on CEO aggressive insider trading behavior and social media presence, and found that the aggressive insiders are risk-seeking. Moreover, Gong and Zhou [3] considered a multi-stage model of risk-seeking insider trading where they first maximized the risky profit, and then maximized the guaranteed profit.

    Recently, Zhou [13] investigated a linear strategy equilibrium of continuous-time insider trading where market makers were allowed to know partial information on the risky asset, and pointed out that there was no equilibrium in a Cournot competition when two insiders adopted a linear strategy. Subsequently, Xiao and Zhou [9,10] expanded Zhou's model [13] and continued to study insider trading at a random deadline with partial observation.

    In this paper, inspired by the literature above, we will continue to study a continuous-time insider trading model, in which an insider is risk-seeking and market makers are allowed to have partial information on the value of a risky asset, and establish the uniqueness and existence of linear Bayesian equilibrium. It shows that at the equilibrium, the market liquidity in our model is a monotonically increasing function of time, which contrasts to those in insider trading with a risk-averse insider [2,6].

    The rest of the paper is as follows. In section two, a risk-seeking insider trading model with partial observation is introduced. Section three gives some necessary conditions of the linear Bayesian equilibrium. The main conclusions in this paper are contained in section four, including the existence and uniqueness of the linear Bayesian equilibrium. In section five, we get some numerical simulations for the equilibrium, and conclusions are drawn in section six.

    We assume that all of random variables in this paper come from a common filtered probability space (Ω,F,{Ft}t0,P) satisfying the usual conditions.

    In a market, there is a risky asset traded in a finite time interval [0, 1], whose liquidation value v is normally distributed with a mean of zero and variance σ2v. There are three representative agents in the market:

    (i) an insider, who gets the perfect knowledge of the liquidation value v and submits her/his order xt, as in the form:

    dxt=βt(vpt)dt,x0=0, (2.1)

    where β is a deterministic measurable function, called trading intensity [4];

    (ii) liquidity traders, who have no information on the value v of the risky asset and submit total order zt evolving as the dynamics [2]:

    zt=σzBzt, (2.2)

    where the constant σz>0 and Bz is a standard Brownian motion independent of v;

    (iii) market makers, who collect the total orders

    yt=xt+zt (2.3)

    and observe a signal of the value v as

    u=v+ϵ (2.4)

    with the random variable ϵ normally distributed as N(0,σ2ϵ) and independent of v and Bzt, and according to the trading volume yt and the signal u, set the market a local linear price p satisfying

    dpt=λtdyt,  p0=0,

    where λ is a deterministic measurable function, called price pressure [1].

    Roughly speaking, the insider's profit from time t to one is given by

    πt=1tβs(vps)2ds. (2.5)

    As a risk-seeking insider, she/he has an exponential utility function from time t to one in the form

    U(πt)=expπt. (2.6)

    To ensure the well-posedness, the following three technical conditions must be guaranteed, 10β2tdt<, 10λ2tdt< and E(exp1tβs(vps)2ds)<. Next, we will give the concept of an equilibrium in our model.

    Definition 2.1. A risk-seeking linear Bayesian equilibrium is a pair of (β,λ) such that

    (i) maximization of utility: for the given λ, the function β maximizes

    E[U(πt)|FIt]=E[exp1tβs(vps)2ds|FIt], (2.7)

    where the insider's information field FIt=σ{v}σ{ps,0st} for t[0,1), and

    (ii) market efficiency: for the given β, the function λ satisfies

    t0λsdys=E[v|FMt], (2.8)

    where FMt=σ{ys,0st}σ{u} for t[0,1).

    Unquestionably, the signal-observation system for market makers is given by

    Signal  v: dv=0,Obervation y: dξt=(A0+A1v)dt+A2dBt, (3.1)

    where ξt=(ytu), ξ0=(0v+ϵ), A0=(ptβt0), A1=(βt0), A2=(σz000), Bt=(Bzt0).

    By Theorem 12.1 in [7] and Lemma 3.1 in [9], we obtain

    dpt=dE[v|FMt]=λtdyt, (3.2)

    where λt=Σtβtσ2z, and

    dΣtdt=Σ2tβ2tσ2z, (3.3)

    where Σt=E[(vpt)2] with Σ0=σ2ϵσ2vσ2v+σ2ϵ, which is called residual information [4].

    We now turn to investigate the risk-seeking linear Bayesian equilibrium.

    Let (β,λ) be a linear Bayesian equilibrium. From Definition 2.1, the insider's value function is given by for t[0,1]

    V(t,vpt)=max˜βU(t,β)E[exp1t˜βs(vps)2ds|FIt]=E[exp1tβs(vps)2ds|FIt], (4.1)

    where U(t,β) is the collection of all these functions ˜β such that ˜βs=βs for 0st, and the two conditions for (4.1) are needed

    limt1V(t,(vpt))=0,  Σ0=10λ2tσ2zdt. (4.2)

    Of course, the first is obvious, and the second can be inferred by (3.2), (3.3) and the equality limt1Σt=0.

    The following conclusion is the stochastic version on Bellman's principle of optimality for above insider trading problem.

    Proposition 4.1. Given t[0,1), for ˆt[t,1]

    V(t,vpt)=max˜βU(t,β)E[exp1t˜βs(vps)2ds(1expˆtt˜βs(vps)2ds)+V(ˆt,vpˆt)|FIt]. (4.3)

    Proof. From (4.1), we have

    V(t,vpt)=max˜βU(t,β)E[exp1t˜βs(vps)2ds|Ft]=max˜βU(t,β)E[exp1t˜βs(vps)2ds(1expˆtt˜βs(vps)2ds)+exp1ˆt˜βs(vps)2ds|Ft]=max˜βU(t,β)E[exp1t˜βs(vps)2ds(1expˆtt˜βs(vps)2ds)+V(ˆt,vpˆt)|Ft]. (4.4)

    By the dynamic programming principle, the insider's optimal condition is portrayed as follows.

    Proposition 4.2. If the value function of insider is determined by Proposition 4.1, then the Hamiton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB for short) equation will be given by

    Vt+12λ2tσ2z2Vp2+maxβR[β(λt(vpt)Vp+(vpt)2V)]=0. (4.5)

    Proof. Applying Itˆos formula to the difference V(ˆt,vpˆt)V(t,vpt), and as ˆtto, the limit of

    1expˆttβs(vps)2dsˆtt

    is equal to βt(vpt)2. Then, using the HJB equation [11], the conclusion holds.

    Proposition 4.3. If the value function satisfies (4.5), then it will be given by

    V(t,mt)=c2c1σ2zt+c1expσ2zσ2vt2expp2t2λtvptλt,

    where

    λt=1c1σ2zt, (4.6)

    the two constants c1 and c2 satisfy the following two equations, respectively

    c1=σ4z+4σ2zΣ0+σ2z2

    and

    c2=c1(1+σ2v(c1σ2z))c1σ2zexpσ2zσ2v2.

    Proof. We know that (4.5) is equivalent to the following two equations:

    Vt+12λ2tσ2z2Vp2=0,λtVp+(vpt)V=0. (4.7)

    The second equation of (4.7) can be viewed as an ordinary differential equation with respect to pt, which has a solution of the form

    V(t,pt)=g(t)expp2t2λtvptλt, (4.8)

    where g(t) is a deterministic function on [0, 1].

    Substituting (4.8) into the first equation of (4.7), we can obtain the equation

    g(t)g(t)(vptp2t2)(1λt)+g(t)2σ2z(vpt)2+12λtg(t)σ2z=0,

    which is equivalent to

    g(t)+g(t)2σ2z(v2+λt)g(t)p2t2(σ2z+(1λt))+g(t)vpt((1λt)+σ2z)=0.

    Taking expectation for the above equation, the following two equations hold:

    (1λt)=σ2z,g(t)+g(t)σ2z2(σ2v+λt)=0. (4.9)

    Then, by the first equation of (4.9),

    λt=1c1σ2zt, (4.10)

    where 1λ0=c1 is some constant real number. We now bring (4.10) into the second equation of (4.9)

    g(t)=c2c1σ2zt+c1expσ2zσ2vt2, (4.11)

    where g0=c2 is some constant real number. According to the boundary conditions in (4.2), the constant c1 can be solved by the following system:

    c2c1(1+σ2v(c1σ2z))c1σ2zexpσ2zσ2v2=1;c21Σ0c1Σ0σ2zσ2z=0. (4.12)

    Namely,

    c1=σ2z±σ4z+4σ2zΣ02

    by (4.10), we assert

    c1=σ2z+σ4z+4σ2zΣ02

    and

    c2=c1(1+σ2v(c1σ2z))c1σ2zexpσ2zσ2v2.

    Theorem 4.1. There is a unique linear equilibrium (β,λ) satisfying

    βt=c1σ2z1t,λt=1c1σ2zt.

    At the equilibrium, the residual information Σt at time t is

    Σt=1c1σ2z1c1σ2zt

    and the insider's total ex ante utility

    E[V(0,v)]=c1(1+2c1σ2v)(c1σ2z)expσ2zσ2v2,

    where

    c1=σ2z+σ4z+4σ2zΣ02

    and

    c2=c1(1+σ2v(c1σ2z))c1σ2zexpσ2zσ2v2.

    Proof. By the optimal filtering theorem [7], we have

    Σt=1tλ2sσ2zds, (4.13)
    λt=βtΣtσ2z. (4.14)

    Taking (4.10) into (4.14), we have

    Σt=1c1σ2z1c1σ2zt.

    Again, together with (4.14), we obtain

    βt=c1σ2z1t.

    By the properties of expectation and the expression of c2

    E[V(0,v)]=c1(1+2c1σ2v)(c1σ2z)expσ2zσ2v2,

    where

    c1=σ2z+σ4z+4σ2zΣ02.

    The proof is complete.

    Corollary 4.1. At the equilibrium (β,λ) in Theorem 4.1, the following results hold:

    (i) As the time goes by, both the optimal trading intensity and the market liquidity increase, while the residual information decreases.

    (ii) Given a fixed time, the less partial observation accuracy, then the weaker the optimal trading intensity is, while the stronger both the market liquidity and the residual information are.

    Proof. Omitted.

    In Corollary 4.1, we gave some theoretical characteristics of the equilibrium. Next, we will give numerical simulations on the equilibrium. First of all, we assume σ2v=4.

    In Figure 1, as time t goes by, insider's private information slowly releases even time close to zero. Beside that, we find that the private information is released slowly at the beginning and rapidly at the end, which explains why the trading intensity will be strong at last. Different from risk-aversion, the market liquidity increases with time going by when the insider is risk-seeking. According to the views of economics, as the market liquidity becomes strong, the market activity will increase, and the market price will remain relatively stable. Moreover, it is beneficial for market makers to obtain more sample information and contribute to market auction; that is, the risk-seeking insider can make the market more active.

    Figure 1.  λ, β and Σ varying with t, σ2z=σ2ϵ=2.

    Next, we will give numerical simulations on partial observation accuracy as given below.

    In Figure 2, as the accuracy of partial observations decreases, the residual information of market increases. Therefore, the more residual information for the insider, then the weaker the trading intensity, such that the insider can obtain higher profits, corresponding to case (ⅱ) in Corollary 4.1.

    Figure 2.  λ, β and Σ varying with σ2ϵ.

    In this paper, we established the uniqueness and existence of the linear Bayesian equilibrium for a continuous-time insider trading model, in which an insider is required to be risk-seeking and the market makers can observe partial signals on the risky asset.

    It shows that at the equilibrium, (ⅰ) as time goes by, both the market liquidity and the trading intensity increased quickly in the later trading and the residual information decreased slowly at the beginning. In fact, the characteristic of market liquidity indicated that the insider was willing to trade, and that they had a stronger desire to trade when there was less residual information, and (ⅱ) the residual information and the partial observation accuracy have a relative relationship. In other words, the worse the partial information on the risky asset received by market makers, the more residual information relatively the insider owns. Further, the market liquidity decreased if market makers observed more accurate information on the risky asset.

    We remarked that our model extended Kyle's version (1985) [4] from the risk-seeking perspective. In Kyle's model, the market liquidity was always a constant, while the market liquidity was a decreasing function of time in the models of risk-aversion [1,2,6]. In contrast to those in the above models [1,2,4,6], the market liquidity in our model was an increasing function of time. This indicates that the insider was eager to trade in the latter. Generally speaking, it is beneficial for market development when the insider increases appropriately for her/his risk appetite behavior, and the insider should try their best to avoid private information exposure. In the future, we will try to study a risk-seeking insider trading model with memory, which will be a challenging research.

    The author declares that they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    Supported by Guizhou QKZYD[2022]4055, the innovative exploration and new academic seedling project of Guizhou University of Finance and Economics (No. 2022XSXMB25).

    Thanks to Professor Yonghui Zhou, who carefully revised our manuscript, and provided many suggestions and assistance on the review comments.

    The author declares no conflict of interest in this paper.



    [1] S. Baruch, Insider trading and risk aversion, J. Financ. Mark., 5 (2002), 451–464. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1386-4181(01)00031-3 doi: 10.1016/S1386-4181(01)00031-3
    [2] K. Cho, Continuous auctions and insider trading: uniqueness and risk aversion, Finance Stochast., 7 (2003), 47–71. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s007800200078 doi: 10.1007/s007800200078
    [3] F. Gong, D. Zhou, Insider trading in the market with rational expected price, arXiv: 1012.2160.
    [4] A. Kyle, Continuous auctions and insider trading, Econometrica, 53 (1985), 1315–1335. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1913210 doi: 10.2307/1913210
    [5] Z. Li, C. Liang, Z. Tang, CEO social media presence and insider trading behavior, SSRN, in press. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3532495
    [6] B. Lim, A risk-averse insider and asset pricing in continuous time, Management Science and Financial Engineering, 19 (2013), 11–16. http://dx.doi.org/10.7737/MSFE.2013.19.1.011 doi: 10.7737/MSFE.2013.19.1.011
    [7] R. Lipeser, A. Shiryaev, Statistic of Random process II: applications, Berlin: Springer, 2001. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-10028-8
    [8] G. Nunno, J. Corcuera, B. Øksendal, G. Farkas, Kyle-Back's model with Levy noise, Preprint series.
    [9] K. Xiao, Y. Zhou, Insider trading with a Random deadline under partial observations: maximal principle method, Acta Math. Appl. Sin. Engl. Ser., 38 (2022), 753–762. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10255-022-1112-6 doi: 10.1007/s10255-022-1112-6
    [10] K. Xiao, Y. Zhou, Linear Bayesian equilibrium in insider trading with a random time under partial observations, AIMS Mathematics, 6 (2021), 13347–13357. http://dx.doi.org/10.3934/math.2021772 doi: 10.3934/math.2021772
    [11] J. Yong, X. Zhou, Stochastic controls, New York: Springer, 2012. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4612-1466-3
    [12] D. Zhou, F. Zhen, Risk aversion, informative noise trading, and long-lived information, Econ. Model., 97 (2021), 247–254. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2021.02.001 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2021.02.001
    [13] Y. Zhou, Existence of linear strategy equilibrium in insider trading with partial observations, J. Syst. Sci. Complex., 29 (2016), 1281–1292. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11424-015-4186-x doi: 10.1007/s11424-015-4186-x
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1253) PDF downloads(43) Cited by(0)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog