Loading [MathJax]/jax/output/SVG/jax.js
Research article

A survey comparative analysis of cartesian and complexity science frameworks adoption in financial risk management of Zimbabwean banks

  • Received: 06 May 2022 Revised: 11 June 2022 Accepted: 17 June 2022 Published: 21 June 2022
  • JEL Codes: G15, G23, F36

  • Traditionally, financial risk management is examined with cartesian and interpretivist frameworks. However, the emergence of complexity science provides a different perspective. Using a structured questionnaire completed by 120 Risk Managers, this paper pioneers a comparative analysis of cartesian and complexity science theoretical frameworks adoption in sixteen Zimbabwean banks, in unique settings of a developing country. Data are analysed with descriptive statistics. The paper finds that overally banks in Zimbabwe are adopting cartesian and complexity science theories regardless of bank size, in the same direction and trajectory. However, adoption of cartesian modeling is more comprehensive and deeper than complexity science. Furthermore, due to information asymmetries, there is diverging modeling priorities between the regulator and supervisor. The regulator places strategic thrust on Knightian risks modeling whereas banks prioritise ontological, ambiguous and Knightian uncertainty measurement. Finally, it is found that complexity science and cartesianism intersect on market discipline. From these findings, it is concluded that complexity science provides an additional dimension to quantitative risk management, hence an integration of these two perspectives is beneficial. This paper makes three contributions to knowledge. First, it adds valuable insights to theoretical perspectives on Quantitative Risk Management. Second, it provides empirical evidence on adoption of two theories from developing country perspective. Third, it offers recommendations to improve Quantitative Risk Management policy formulation and practice.

    Citation: Gilbert Tepetepe, Easton Simenti-Phiri, Danny Morton. A survey comparative analysis of cartesian and complexity science frameworks adoption in financial risk management of Zimbabwean banks[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(2): 359-384. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022016

    Related Papers:

    [1] Eiman, Kamal Shah, Muhammad Sarwar, Thabet Abdeljawad . On rotavirus infectious disease model using piecewise modified ABC fractional order derivative. Networks and Heterogeneous Media, 2024, 19(1): 214-234. doi: 10.3934/nhm.2024010
    [2] Sun-Ho Choi, Hyowon Seo . Rumor spreading dynamics with an online reservoir and its asymptotic stability. Networks and Heterogeneous Media, 2021, 16(4): 535-552. doi: 10.3934/nhm.2021016
    [3] Carlo Brugna, Giuseppe Toscani . Boltzmann-type models for price formation in the presence of behavioral aspects. Networks and Heterogeneous Media, 2015, 10(3): 543-557. doi: 10.3934/nhm.2015.10.543
    [4] Michele Gianfelice, Enza Orlandi . Dynamics and kinetic limit for a system of noiseless d-dimensional Vicsek-type particles. Networks and Heterogeneous Media, 2014, 9(2): 269-297. doi: 10.3934/nhm.2014.9.269
    [5] Michael Herty, Lorenzo Pareschi, Sonja Steffensen . Mean--field control and Riccati equations. Networks and Heterogeneous Media, 2015, 10(3): 699-715. doi: 10.3934/nhm.2015.10.699
    [6] Xia Li, Chuntian Wang, Hao Li, Andrea L. Bertozzi . A martingale formulation for stochastic compartmental susceptible-infected-recovered (SIR) models to analyze finite size effects in COVID-19 case studies. Networks and Heterogeneous Media, 2022, 17(3): 311-331. doi: 10.3934/nhm.2022009
    [7] Vincent Renault, Michèle Thieullen, Emmanuel Trélat . Optimal control of infinite-dimensional piecewise deterministic Markov processes and application to the control of neuronal dynamics via Optogenetics. Networks and Heterogeneous Media, 2017, 12(3): 417-459. doi: 10.3934/nhm.2017019
    [8] Xiaoqian Gong, Benedetto Piccoli . A measure model for the spread of viral infections with mutations. Networks and Heterogeneous Media, 2022, 17(3): 427-442. doi: 10.3934/nhm.2022015
    [9] Mirela Domijan, Markus Kirkilionis . Graph theory and qualitative analysis of reaction networks. Networks and Heterogeneous Media, 2008, 3(2): 295-322. doi: 10.3934/nhm.2008.3.295
    [10] Paulo Amorim, Alessandro Margheri, Carlota Rebelo . Modeling disease awareness and variable susceptibility with a structured epidemic model. Networks and Heterogeneous Media, 2024, 19(1): 262-290. doi: 10.3934/nhm.2024012
  • Traditionally, financial risk management is examined with cartesian and interpretivist frameworks. However, the emergence of complexity science provides a different perspective. Using a structured questionnaire completed by 120 Risk Managers, this paper pioneers a comparative analysis of cartesian and complexity science theoretical frameworks adoption in sixteen Zimbabwean banks, in unique settings of a developing country. Data are analysed with descriptive statistics. The paper finds that overally banks in Zimbabwe are adopting cartesian and complexity science theories regardless of bank size, in the same direction and trajectory. However, adoption of cartesian modeling is more comprehensive and deeper than complexity science. Furthermore, due to information asymmetries, there is diverging modeling priorities between the regulator and supervisor. The regulator places strategic thrust on Knightian risks modeling whereas banks prioritise ontological, ambiguous and Knightian uncertainty measurement. Finally, it is found that complexity science and cartesianism intersect on market discipline. From these findings, it is concluded that complexity science provides an additional dimension to quantitative risk management, hence an integration of these two perspectives is beneficial. This paper makes three contributions to knowledge. First, it adds valuable insights to theoretical perspectives on Quantitative Risk Management. Second, it provides empirical evidence on adoption of two theories from developing country perspective. Third, it offers recommendations to improve Quantitative Risk Management policy formulation and practice.



    Tourism is a major source of economic wealth. It is an important industry in both developed and developing countries, providing jobs and revenues above and beyond other industries. Today, tourism activity contributes well over 10% to GDP and employment in many countries. Moreover, in the last three decades, world tourism has demonstrated significant resilience against external shocks such as geopolitical uncertainty, natural disasters, terrorist attacks, financial and economic crises, and, more recently, the COVID-19 pandemic. Tourism being such an important industry, we cannot rely solely on the successful results of the past; entrepreneurs and policy makers must design medium and long-term viability and sustainability plans. As Aguiló-Pérez et al. (2005) and Rosselló-Nadal et al. (2005) pointed out, it is necessary to know the determinants of demand with precision, a pre-requisite for estimating income and price elasticities that will help to fulfill the goals of the sector. Prices and tourists' income are the most commonly used variables to explain tourism demand, although other factors, ranging from the cultural, natural, and sociopolitical features of the chosen destination to the competitiveness of alternative destinations and tourism advertising campaigns, could also be relevant.

    Understanding tourist behavior, demand elasticities, and the purchasing power of regular tourists visiting a destination is of great interest to the tourism industry for business strategy and to governments for tourism public policy. Entrepreneurs and policymakers need accurate forecasts of tourism demand to assist them in their decision-making. Price elasticities of demand and the socioeconomic status of tourists are signals of how tourists may switch destinations and how a destination can change from mass tourism to alternative tourism. The economic agents involved in tourism activity may wish to influence the determinants of demand in order to increase or change it. They realize that the amount of tourist spending in a given destination can be modified by attracting more tourists or by stimulating the arrival of wealthier tourists.

    On the one hand, high values of the own-price elasticity of the demand for tourist goods and services imply that there exist close substitute destinations, and the margin for raising prices without losing tourists is very small. There is an inverse relationship between price elasticity and market power that plays in favor of alternative destinations. Second, high values of the cross-price elasticity of the demand for tourist goods and services with respect to the price of accommodation imply that small changes in the price of overnight stays will cause large shifts in the demand for tourism products. This would mean that any intervention on the side of tourist accommodation is of greatest importance for the results in the market for tourist goods and services. Finally, higher values of the marginal utility of income associated with tourists visiting a destination are representative of lower socioeconomic status (lower purchasing power), so one would expect lower tourism expenditure.

    The modeling and forecasting of tourism demand have received a great deal of attention in the literature.1 However, exhaustive statistical information, which is the main support for the economic analysis of tourism, is only available for a period of just over two decades. Even so, it is not unusual to find omitted data holes and records that are not entirely homogeneous in international comparisons or among the different organizations that provide them. These shortcomings weaken the effectiveness of the quantitative study of tourism. In fact, there are no official sources of forecasts for the tourism sector. Moreover, the essential tasks of measurement, estimation, and evaluation are very demanding for researchers due to the nature of the sector. Since the usual definitions of tourism are too generic, it is not easy to identify what parts of the firms' activity go to satisfy the demands of tourists and non-tourists, respectively. It is almost impossible to isolate the quantity of goods and services produced for tourism (Ferrari et al., 2022).

    1 The reader is referred to Divisekera (2013), Dwyer et al. (2011), Lim(1997, 2006), Rosselló-Nadal and Santana-Gallego (2022), Song and Li (2008), Song and Turner (2006) and Witt and Witt (1995) for a comprehensive review of the literature on tourism demand modeling and forecasting.

    These are the challenging conditions under which empirical research in tourism economics must be carried out. In any case, it is absolutely necessary to know the elasticities of tourism demands for any decision or intervention in this sector to be reasonable and reliable. At the firm level, there are several ways of estimating the elasticity of demand: by surveying the attitude of its customers to price changes, by a cross-sectional analysis of the price-demand relationship, by experimenting in the market with a price change over a fixed period of time, and also by making conjectures based on its past pricing experience. However, given the aforementioned shortcomings, perhaps a better strategy is to focus on the tourists themselves and try to estimate the value of tourist spending through surveys or by recording the expenditure as tourism when paying the bill.

    In empirical studies, income is a recurrent determinant of tourism demand, with an estimated elasticity usually greater than 1. This would mean that tourism is a luxury product. Prices are the other major determinant of tourism demand, but there are different alternatives currently in use.2 Overall, the estimated direct-price elasticities are around −1, which means that tourism demand is moderately elastic or even inelastic (Forsyth et al., 2014; Song et al., 2010). The concern about the magnitude of elasticities is usually addressed by the estimated parameter values in a log-linear specification of tourism demand. However, given the nature of the tourism product, which is a broad set of heterogeneous goods and services, it is difficult to find standard forecasts based on a general consensus. The specialized literature has used regression analysis to estimate the relationship between tourism demand and its determinants considering different measures of demand: the number of visitor arrivals, the number of overnight stays, and per capita expenditure, each one associated with a different empirical model (Divisekera, 2003; Pyo et al., 1991; Schiff and Becken, 2011; Song et al., 2010). These options are substitutes for each other and, consequently, researchers must make a choice.

    2 These are prices at destination in absolute terms, or relative to prices at origin, or relative to prices in competing destinations, adjusted to account for exchange rate changes or by putting the effect of exchange rates separately (Crouch, 1996).

    For years, econometric studies have estimated tourism demand elasticities, but little effort has been made to integrate these results into a general theory capable of generating principles that reveal underlying invariant patterns in the form of causal relationships (Assaf and Scuderi, 2023; Crouch, 1996). In this field, the shortage of theoretical papers is well known. Much of the published work consists of empirical papers that are not directly attached to a specific theoretical model. They mainly hypothesize ad hoc equations estimated with different econometric techniques. These empirical studies have considered a wide range of independent variables but, in essence, they all suggest similar determinants drawn from a common panel of explanatory variables.

    In any case, what emerges from the empirical debate in tourism economics is the unquestionable fact that, in order to predict the effect of a policy change or to launch a business course of action, entrepreneurs and policymakers need to know both the elasticities of demand for tourist goods and services and some particular features of their visitors. In the following pages, we provide an approach that defies traditional procedures and represents an interesting methodological advance. With the explicit support of theory plus a minimum data requirement and without the need for complex estimation methods, we obtain the target elasticities and, in addition, we extract the values of the preference parameters that allow us to classify the tourists.

    As mentioned above, in this paper, we propose a new method to empirically estimate the own-price and cross-price elasticities of demand for tourist goods and services. The approach is based on theoretical results derived from a new model of the tourist's choice developed by Descals-Tormo and Ruiz-Tamarit (2024). A tourist journey includes transportation and lodging, but the main purpose of a trip is to consume the tourist services provided at the destinations, i.e., gastronomy, a variety of attractions and guide services, entertainment, shopping, and so on. We abstract from the choice of transportation and the round-trip travel itself because, according to Crouch (1996), the cost of transportation does not influence the estimated elasticity of demand, and no bias appears when it is omitted. It is assumed that there are two relevant markets in the tourism sector: one for tourist goods and services and the other for accommodation. These sub-markets are considered separate but interrelated due to the feedback that exists between tourist services and lodging through a strong vertical relationship of complementarity (Divisekera, 2009a, 2009b).

    Once the optimal solution to the tourist choice problem has been obtained, along with the primary demand for tourist goods and services and the derived demand for overnight stays as the main outcomes, we focus on the problem of forecasting these demands and obtaining a consistent estimate of elasticities. The determinants of tourism demands are basically a combination of the various expenditures made by tourists and the prices they pay at the destination. Tourism demands can also be characterized by their dependencies on the structural parameters concerning tourists' preferences and standard of living. The higher the relative attractiveness of a destination as perceived by tourists, the higher the demand for both tourist services and overnight stays. The lower the income level and socioeconomic status of the regular tourists arriving at a destination, the lower the demand for both tourism products and overnight stays.

    The paper is organized as follows: In Section 2, we provide a brief outline of the tourism decision theory and characterize the demand functions. In Section 3, we study tourism demands from an empirical point of view. We find new specifications for the demand equations corresponding to tourist goods and services and overnight stays. The equation to be estimated econometrically comes directly from the model discussed in the previous section. In this section, we also identify the relationship between the estimated parameters of the empirical equation and the structural parameters of the theoretical model. In Section 4, we focus on the two main price elasticities of tourism demand for goods and services. In Section 5, we analyze the parameter representing the marginal utility of total expenditure or income and the relationship with the socioeconomic status of tourists. In Section 6, we show the outcome of the quantitative exercise conducted with the databases for Australia, Canada, Spain, and the United States, and discuss some economic implications of these numerical results. In the final Section 7, we present our conclusions.

    In a recent paper, Descals-Tormo and Ruiz-Tamarit (2024) have developed a groundbreaking theoretical model of the tourist's choice, which allows for new specifications of the tourism demand equations. These equations reveal theoretical relationships between the endogenous variables and their determinants. The determinants are essentially a combination of the various expenditures made by tourists and the prices they pay at the destination, which are easily observable and significantly simplify the forecasting process. The following is a brief description of the main building blocks of the model and its most significant results.

    Consider a representative tourist consumer who has decided to travel to a specific destination and has to choose the demand for three goods: quantity of tourist goods and services, or vector x, 3 number of overnight stays, or vector q, 4 and income available to consume other non-tourist products, y. The particular utility function that represents the tourist preferences over these goods takes the standard form,

    W(x,y)=αγϕ+α(x+γ)ϕ+βy, (1)

    3 This variable represents a bundle of tourism products supplied at the destination, which includes tourism attractions and guide services, nature, adventure, culture, sport, business, leisure, local transportation, food and beverage gastronomy, entertainment, shopping, and so on.

    4 These can be carried out in different types of establishments such as hotels, apartments, campsites, cottages, guest houses, visitor flats, and non-market tourist accommodation.

    With the specificity that it does not depend on q.5 This function is additively separable, strictly concave in x, and linear in income y. Parameters α > 0 and β > 0 are transformation coefficients for each consumption in utility. Moreover, α and the parameter 0 < ϕ < 1 represent the scale and intensity of preferences over x, the parameter β stands for the constant marginal utility of income, and γ > 0 implies that reservation prices for the consumer-tourist are finite.6 Since tourists choose the type of destination based on their socioeconomic status, the class of tourists arriving at a given destination shares a certain income range. Therefore, for such a tourist destination and its tourists, it is realistic to assume that the marginal utility of income is constant. Changing this is not an easy task because attracting tourists from other wealth segments requires time and active tourism policy measures.

    5 This means that overnight stays, although necessary to enjoy the consumption of tourist goods and services, do not directly provide any utility or disutility. This assumption could be considered somewhat unrealistic to characterize the specific case of leisure tourism, since it is mainly associated with relaxation activities and sun and beach consumption, and the characteristics and quality of different types of lodging establishments are probably relevant for leisure tourists' decisions. However, in characterizing tourism as a whole, we consider that tourists demand tourism products for which accommodation is necessary, but not a major determinant. Therefore, in the most general context, the assumption that overnight stays do not appear explicitly in the utility function seems a reasonable simplifying assumption.

    6 The slope of indifference curves on the y-axis takes the value dy/dx=(ϕα/βγ1ϕ).

    The tourist's budget constraint is,

    m=pxx+pq+y, (2)

    where m represents the total money income net of the round-trip travel fare.7 The tourist expenditure on goods and services is the product pxx, being px a vector of unit prices corresponding to tourist goods and services. The expenditure allocated to overnight stays is pq, where p is the vector of unit prices of accommodations, and the expenditure in other goods is pyy, where y plays the role of numéraire and its price is normalized assuming py=1.

    7 The cost of round-trip transportation between origin and destination, Ϝ, although it may represent a significant part of the tourist's expenditure, is treated as a lump-sum deduction, m=MϜ, being M the total money income. This cost could play a role in the decision to travel or not, but only in the case of large differences will it affect the choice of destination. Of course, by decreasing the net money income, it may affect the quantity of overnight stays and tourist goods and services demanded.

    The demand for accommodation is a derived demand since the only way to enjoy tourist goods and services is by staying at the destination. Overnight stays are assumed to depend linearly on the demand for tourist goods and services according to a fixed proportion, 8 i.e.,

    q=xa1,ppqR,otherwise  q=0. (3)

    8 Although there is no empirical evidence, it is plausible to assume a monotonically increasing relationship. However, the choice between a strictly convex or concave relationship is not so obvious, since they represent that the number of goods and services consumed per day decreases or increases, respectively, with the demand for tourist goods and services. In this context, we have opted for the intermediate case of a linear relationship.

    The proportion is the reciprocal of a, the number of tourist goods and services that our representative tourist consumes per day, and pqR stands for its reservation price for accommodation. Moreover, no matter how strong the tourist's preference for x is, if the associated price exceeds the corresponding reservation price pxR, the tourist will choose another destination, cancelling out the demands of x and q.

    The static constrained optimization problem to be solved by the representative consumer is: max{x,y}(1)s.t. (2) and (3), which may be written under the following Lagrangian form,

    max{x,y,λ}L=αγϕ+α(x+γ)ϕ+βy+λ(m(px+pa)xy). (4)

    From the first-order conditions, we draw the following demand functions for the two main endogenous variables of the model,

    x(px,p,Ω)=γ+(ϕαβ)11ϕ1(px+pa)11ϕ, (5)
    q(px,p,Ω)=xa=γa+(ϕαβ)11ϕ1a(px+pa)11ϕ, (6)

    Bing Ω=(α,β,γ,ϕ,a) the vector of structural parameters of the model. The marginal utility of money is constant, which leads to a constant optimal value of the Lagrangian multiplier λ=β. Consequently, demands for tourist goods and services x and overnight stays q do not depend on the tourist's available total net money income m but only on prices and parameters. In this context, the only relationship between demands and income is indirect and related to the parameter β, which depends on the purchasing power of tourists visiting a destination.9

    9 The diagrammatic representation of the two tourism sub-markets, their interdependencies, and the comparative statics are shown in Figures A.1 and A.2 in the Appendix.

    The modeling and forecasting of tourism demand has received a great deal of attention in the literature, but the bulk of the work focuses on empirical models that do not depend directly on a specific theoretical model. These are mostly ad hoc models estimated with different econometric techniques, which basically propose similar determinants drawn from a common panel of explanatory variables, regardless of the fact that their format and units of measurement vary considerably across studies. The main concern shown in the literature when studying tourism demand is centered on the different elasticities yielded by the estimated values of the parameters in the log-linear specification. In this paper, Equations (5) and (6) represent our theoretical demands for tourist services and overnight stays. Before going on to study these functions from an empirical point of view, we will characterize some of their properties by making explicit the main price elasticities involved and the dependencies of the demands on the structural parameters. Accommodation and tourism products are complementary. The demand for overnight stays is derived from the demand for tourist goods and services. The slope of the tourism demand is negative, x/px<0, and complementarity implies that the cross-price effect is also negative, x/p<0. Therefore, the own-price elasticity of the demand for tourist goods and services is,

    |εxpx|=px(1ϕ)(px+pa)x+γx, (7)

    And the corresponding cross-price elasticity is,

    |εxp|=pa(1ϕ)(px+pa)x+γx. (8)

    These two elasticities are related to each other in the following way,

    |εxpx|=apxp|εxp|, (9)

    And,

    |εxpx|+|εxp|=11ϕx+γx. (10)

    Our tourism demands can also be characterized with respect to the model parameters. First, the higher the relative attractiveness of a destination as perceived by tourists and captured by the values of α and ϕ, which depend on factors like political stability, transport facilities, and qualitative aspects of the tourism supply, the higher the demand for both tourist services and overnight stays. Second, the lower the income level and socioeconomic status of the regular tourists arriving at a destination, which are expressed in higher values of the parameter β, the lower the demand for both tourist services and overnight stays. Third, the bigger the number of goods and services the tourist consumes per day, i.e., the greater the value of coefficient a, the higher the demand for tourist goods and services, but most likely the lower the demand for overnight stays. Finally, the lower the reservation prices, which correspond to higher values of parameter γ, the lower the demand for both tourist services and overnight stays.

    Taking a step further, in this section we study the tourism demand from an empirical point of view focusing on the statistical relationship between the dependent variables and their explanatory variables. The literature considers basically two indicators to quantify the dependent variable: the number of tourist arrivals and/or overnight stays, and the expenditures on tourist goods and services at the destination (Aguiló-Pérez et al., 2017; Rosselló-Nadal and He, 2020; Tran et al., 2018; Tran et al., 2020). Empirical studies treat these two measures of tourism demand as substitutes for each other, and researchers tend to choose one or the other according to their own criteria or depending on data availability. However, in the previous section, we have shown that it is better to look at overnight stays as complementary to tourist goods and services. We assume a linear function that connects the two through a fixed coefficient representing the number of tourist goods and services that the tourist can consume throughout the day. Based on this, we have deduced simultaneously and within the same theoretical model the demand functions for quantities of tourist goods and services and overnight stays.

    Regarding the explanatory variables, there is a wide range of factors affecting the dependent variable (Brida and Scuderi, 2013). However, most empirical studies assign a central role to income, prices (adjusted for the exchange rate), the level of economic activity, and population as the most salient determinants (Song and Turner, 2006). The usual study of tourism demand estimates an equation in which the variables are expressed in nominal or real terms, in levels or per capita, per visitor, or per day (Crouch, 1996; Lim, 1997; Witt and Witt, 1995). According to our approach, the determinant of both endogenous variables is a combination of the various expenditures made by tourists and the prices they pay at the destination, which are easily observable or proxied.

    Substituting Equation (3) into Equation (5), we can express the demand for tourist goods and services x as depending on the expenditure on tourist goods and services gx=pxx, and the expenditure on accommodation gq=pq. However, the tourism product is a collection of very diverse goods and services provided by multiple suppliers and industries. Actually, it is a multidimensional vector including a great variety of products. Because of this broad conceptualization, it is very difficult, if not impossible, to obtain direct data on the quantity corresponding to each component of the vector. Even so, there is an alternative to overcome this problem because it is easier to obtain data on total expenditure. From the data on total expenditure, it is possible to approximate the aggregate quantity of tourist goods and services purchased by dividing total expenditure by the level of the price index. That is, in the case of the tourism sector, we can measure market demand by deflating the sum of monetary expenditures. Then, Equation (5) can be rewritten as,

    gxpx=γ+(ϕαβ)11ϕp11ϕx(1+gqgx)11ϕ. (11)

    However, this expression shows that we will face important statistical problems if we decide to estimate directly the demand for tourist goods and services. It is evident that both variables gx and px appear on both sides of the equation, and this reveals a clear endogeneity problem. We therefore conclude that Equation (5) is worthless from the point of view of empirical analysis, and we need to find a global alternative to achieve our goals.

    Hopefully, we can estimate the demand for overnight stays q for which there are reliable records of data on quantities, 10 and then use the results to infer the parameters of the demand for tourist goods and services x. From Equation (6), under the simplifying assumption that γ is close to zero, which means that the reservation prices pqR and pxR for tourists are high enough, and taking logarithms, we get,

    lnq=ln(1a(ϕαβ)11ϕ)11ϕlnpx(1+gqgx). (12)

    10 Unlike information on different tourism expenditures, there is a large amount of statistical information on tourist arrivals, departures, and overnight stays that can be used for the analysis of structural aspects of the tourism sector.

    It is now possible to specify an empirical equation to be estimated econometrically,

    lnqit=CiρilnCPIit(1+1πit)+εit. (13)

    The dependent variable qit represents the number of overnight stays at the destination i in period t. The variable CPIit is the consumer price index at the destination i in period t.11, 12 The variable πit is defined as the ratio between the tourism expenditure on tourist goods and services, gxit, and the tourism expenditure on accommodation, gqit, both referred to destination i in period t, that is,

    πit=gxitgqit>0. (14)

    11 Although the price of some tourist goods and services is available, a single price cannot be taken as the tourism price because the tourist's consumption basket includes many items. Then, the problem is how to price the composite good. Since the tourist price index (TPI) is usually not available, the consumer price index (CPI) in the tourist destination is used as a proxy. Morley (1994) investigated the evidence for the use of the CPI as a proxy for the TPI and showed that tourism prices are highly correlated with general consumer prices. However, Divisekera (2003) proposed using price indexes that reflect the cost of a specific basket of goods and services consumed by tourists at the destination or, alternatively, the average observed expenditure per diem, because she considered that using the CPI rather than the TPI may result in biased price elasticities. Ultimately, the researchers find no clear advantage in using one or the other.

    12 In general, in tourism demand studies, the use of a specific TPI for a destination is usually accompanied by the exchange rate if the study refers to inbound international tourism. However, this requires that data on international tourists visiting a destination be broken down by country of origin, which imposes a strong fragmentation of the hypothesized international tourism demand when we analyze highly popular and consolidated destinations. In any case, the exchange rate is only relevant for international tourists from countries that do not belong to an economic space with a common currency and if, in addition, bilateral exchange rates between the countries of origin and destination are not fixed or are not sufficiently stable.

    With respect to the coefficients in Equation (13), the slope is exclusively related to the intensity of preferences over the tourist goods and services supplied at the destination i,

    ρi=11ϕi>1, (15)

    And the other coefficient Ci is a destination-specific constant reflecting a nonlinear combination of the preference parameters α, β and ϕ,

    Ci=11ϕiln(ϕiαiβi)lnai. (16)

    Finally, εit is an unknown variable representing the random disturbance. Under the proviso that this error term be independently and identically distributed (i.i.d.), we can perform an efficient estimation of coefficients.13

    13 Although the majority of studies have used ordinary least squares (OLS), other estimation techniques have also been used (Morley, 1996, 2009; Song and Li, 2008).

    Having reached this point, we can use the estimated values of coefficients ρi and Ci to approximate the values of the structural parameters of the tourism model,

    0<ˆϕi=ˆρi1ˆρi<1, (17)
    ^(αβ)i=exp{(1ˆϕi)(ˆCi+lnai)lnˆϕi}>0. (18)

    The coefficient a can be directly computed from the database according to Equation (3). Let us first consider, for any given destination, the time series,

    ait=gxitqitCPIit, (19)

    And then we associate to each destination the sample mean of the series,

    ai=1TTt=1ait. (20)

    Now, we can choose a reference destination ˉı for which we assume a constant marginal utility of total expenditure or income equal to unity, βˉı=1. For this particular destination, we just identify the value αˉı=^(α/β)ˉı. Here, for the sake of simplicity, we assume that tourists' preferences in all destinations share the same value αˉı.14 In this way, we arrive at the values of the constant marginal utility of income that characterize tourists in different destinations,

    ˆβi=αˉı^(α/β)i. (21)

    14 Recall that α is a scale parameter that determines the position of an ordinal utility function, while the parameter ϕ is concerned with the curvature of that function and the intensity of preferences for tourist goods and services. These two parameters go hand in hand with the demands for tourist services and overnight stays. In addition, the attractiveness of competing destinations as perceived by tourists, which depends on political considerations, transports facilities and characteristics, and qualitative aspects of the tourism supply, is represented by parameters α and ϕ. In consequence, we can account for the degree of substitutability between destinations by referring only to the parameter ϕ.

    These values, greater or smaller than 1, are an indicator of the position in terms of wealth status associated with the predominant tourist in each destination. Of course, this measure is relative to the wealth status of tourists coming to the destination taken as a reference.

    From Equations (9) and (10), given (3) and (14), and keeping in mind the assumption that γ is asymptotically equal to zero, we find the following relationships between demand elasticities, tourists' expenditures, and tourists' preferences:

    |εxpx|it|εxp|it=πit, (22)

    And,

    |εxpx|it+|εxp|it=11ϕi. (23)

    Then, the estimated ˆϕi values for each destination along with the values of πit at the destination i in period t allow us to derive the value of the direct-price elasticity and the value of the cross-price elasticity of demand for tourist goods and services, |εxpx|it and |εxp|it, respectively. These can be easily calculated as follows:

    ^|εxpx|it=11ˆϕiπit1+πit, (24)
    ^|εxp|it=11ˆϕi11+πit. (25)

    In these two expressions, the first term on the right-hand side is greater than 1 and the second term is lower than 1. In addition, as long as πit is greater than 1, we find that ^|εxpx|it>^|εxp|it. It is easy to check that, for each destination, the sum of the two elasticities is constant. Finally, it follows that,

    ^|εxpx|itˆϕi>0,^|εxpx|itπit>0, (26)
    ^|εxp|itˆϕi>0,^|εxp|itπit<0. (27)

    On the one hand, a low value of ˆϕi, which is associated with a low value of ˆρi, also implies low values for both the direct-price elasticity and the cross-price elasticity of demand for tourist goods and services. On the other hand, a high value of πit, which is representative of high spending on tourist goods and services relative to spending on accommodation, implies high values for the direct-price elasticity of demand for tourist goods and services, but low values for the corresponding cross-price elasticity.

    In this paper, we have assumed that people have constant marginal utility of income; as an individual's income changes by one additional euro, the extra utility for that individual remains unchanged. In the case of tourists, such a representation of preferences leads to demands for x and q that are independent of m, as in Equations (5) and (6). This simplifying assumption is indeed quite realistic because tourism destinations are matched with classes of tourists characterized by a common socioeconomic status. In other words, tourists who share similar levels of income and wealth mostly choose the same destination and thus contribute to featuring the destination with their marginal utility of money, that is, the value of parameter β. However, an extra euro given to a rich tourist increases his total utility less than it increases the total utility of the poor tourist if he is given the same euro. Therefore, we will consider a constant marginal utility of total expenditure within each group of tourists visiting a destination but allow for different levels associated with different destinations. Consistent with this, our model predicts the following dependencies of the demands for tourist services and overnight stays: (x/β)<0 and (q/β)<0. That is, the higher the purchasing power of the class of tourists, the greater the demands for both tourist services and overnight stays.15

    15 People's income influences their propensity to travel. This could increase tourism expenditure by increasing the demand for tourist goods and services, increasing overnight stays, upgrading their accommodation, increasing the frequency of travel, or traveling in higher classes. But it can also cause tourists to change their destination if they adapt their itinerary to the new economic conditions.

    Parameter β is not objectively observable, but from Equations (18) and (21) we arrive at the following expression that allows us to calculate and rank destinations according to their average tourist's marginal utility of income.

    ˆβi=αˉıexp{(1ˆϕi)(ˆCi+lnai)+lnˆϕi}>0. (28)

    In this equation, we also find,

    ˆβiˆϕi>0,ˆβiai<0. (29)

    Moreover, from Descals-Tormo and Ruiz-Tamarit (2024), we know that the values of the direct-price elasticity and cross-price elasticity of demand for tourist goods and services are related to the income level and the corresponding socioeconomic status of tourists as follows:

    ^|εxpx|itˆβi>0,^|εxp|itˆβi>0. (30)

    In accordance with the methodology detailed in the previous sections, we focus on the demand for overnight stays to gather information on the most relevant parameters of the theoretical model and thus obtain the value of the direct and cross-price elasticity of the demand for tourist goods and services through indirect channels. The first step of this new path leads us to estimate the empirical Equation (13). All our calculations and equation estimations have been carried out considering only inbound tourism data from four countries: Australia, Canada, Spain, and the United States. Inbound tourism includes the activities of non-resident international tourists visiting a destination country on a trip. The data series used here are drawn from the World Tourism Organization (UNWTO), the National Accounts of each country (in particular the Tourism Satellite Account, TSA, when available), and The World Bank database. A detailed description of these data sources is provided in the Appendix.

    More specifically, we use time series for the number of overnight stays qit, the consumer price index CPIit, the tourism expenditure on accommodation gqit, and the expenditure on tourist goods and services gxit.16 The sample period depends on data availability and is slightly different for each country. In any case, beyond differences in the starting period, the samples span from the mid-1990s to 2019, the year before the COVID-19 pandemic. The graph with the temporal profile of the dependent variable lnqit and the independent variable lnCPIit(1+1/πit), as well as the values of their main descriptive statistics calculated country by country, can be observed in Figures A.3-6, together with Table A.2 in the Appendix.

    16 The series of tourism expenditure on goods and services is obtained by the difference between the series of total tourism expenditure and that corresponding to transportation and accommodation.

    Table 1 shows the results of the parameter estimation by OLS. We include a linear trend in our regression analysis based on the observed profile of the data series corresponding to the variables in Equation (13).17 The goodness of fit, as measured by the adjusted R-squared shown in the last row of the table, is high enough, standing in all four cases between 80% and 90%. The results of the autocorrelation, heteroscedasticity, and normality tests for the residuals of each of the estimates are displayed in the middle boxes of the table. First, the serial autocorrelation tests show that the null hypothesis of no serial correlation cannot be rejected for any of the estimates; the Breusch-Godfrey test, which is more accurate for small samples, does not reject the null hypothesis at the 1% significance level. Second, the Breusch-Pagan test for heteroscedasticity and the White test both support the non-rejection of the null hypothesis, suggesting that the regression residuals are homoscedastic. Finally, we find the Jarque-Bera normality test and the Sktest (skewness and kurtosis tests for normality) adjusted for the sample size. The corresponding results show that in none of the cases can the null hypothesis be rejected, which means that it is very likely that the estimated residuals follow a normal distribution.

    17 In the estimation of this equation for Spain and the United States, a time dummy variable has also been included to capture the lagged average differential effect that certain exceptional events had on the dependent variable in 2009 in Spain and in 2003 in the United States.

    Table 1.  Demand for overnight stays: econometric estimation. Dependent variable: lnqit.
    Country Australia (1) Canada (2) Spain (3) U.S. (4)
    Ci 11.4768*** 11.3405*** 13.3720*** 12.8878***
    (0.1858) (0.3950) (0.2267) (0.3762)
    lnCPIit(1+1/πit) −1.7836*** −4.8660*** −2.1733*** −3.5822***
    (0.3689) (1.4528) (0.4242) (1.0603)
    Trend 0.0470*** 0.1256*** 0.0661*** 0.1229***
    (0.0078) (0.0294) (0.0095) (0.0254)
    Autocorrelation test
    Breusch-Godfrey LM(2) 1.805 0.594 2.251 3.594
    p-value 0.2141 0.5618 0.1420 0.0486
    Heteroskedasticity tests
    Breusch-Pagan
    p-value
    1.33
    0.2491
    3.05
    0.0805
    0.31
    0.5759
    1.14
    0.2847
    White's test
    p-value
    9.33
    0.0966
    6.35
    0.2734
    5.67
    0.4611
    10.17
    0.1177
    Normality tests
    Jarque-Bera
    p-value
    0.294
    0.8630
    0.168
    0.9193
    5.863
    0.0533
    1.005
    0.6049
    Skewness and kurtosis
    p-value
    0.07
    0.9668
    0.30
    0.8626
    7.28
    0.0262
    1.19
    0.5511
    Period (yearly data) 2005−2019 1995-2019 2000-2019 1996−2019
    Adj. R2 0.8392 0.8641 0.8859 0.7991
    Notes: OLS estimation. Standard errors are in parentheses. Coefficients are statistically significant at * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, and *** p < 0.01.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    In the upper block of Table 1, we can see that the estimated parameters in each country-specific regression have the expected sign and are statistically significant. The coefficient ρi, as detailed in Equation (15), is directly and univocally related to the average intensity of preferences for tourist goods and services offered in a particular destination. The country-specific constant Ci, according to Equation (16), is just a nonlinear combination of the parameters that shape the tourist's utility function. From these estimated coefficients of the accommodation demand equation, we can recover the values of the structural parameters of the tourism model ˆϕi and ˆβi, for each country, using Equations (17) and (28), respectively. In addition, we can also calculate the two price elasticities of the demand for tourist goods and services by means of Equations (24) and (25). The average values of these parameters and elasticities for the sample period, which is different for each of the countries, are reported in Table 2.

    Table 2.  Demand for tourist goods and services: values of parameters and elasticities.
    Country Australia (1) Canada (2) Spain (3) U.S. (4)
    ˆϕi=ˆρi1ˆρi 0.4394 0.7945 0.5399 0.7208
    ^|εxpx|i 1.4670 3.4232 1.5305 2.5911
    ^|εxp|i 0.3166 1.4429 0.6429 0.9908
    ˆβi 0.0063 7.1802 0.0361 1.0000
    Notes: These figures are the average values corresponding to the sample periods for each country. To compute the price elasticities, we use Equations (24) and (25); for ˆβi, we use Equation (28).

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    According to our model, the parameter ϕ represents the intensity of preferences for tourist goods and services being offered in the destination country. These preferences, and hence the market demand, may be affected by social, political, and economic factors. Then, according to the first row of Table 2, international tourists visiting Canada show the highest preference for tourist goods and services provided in that country. The preferences of international tourists visiting the United States are also strong, but 10% lower. On the low side, international tourists visiting Spain show 25% less intense preferences for Spanish tourist goods and services than the corresponding tourists visiting the United States. Finally, the lowest intensity of preferences is among international tourists visiting Australia, which only slightly exceeds 50% of the intensity shown by tourists visiting Canada.

    The demand for tourist goods and services in a particular destination depends on the price of those goods and services, as well as on the price of accommodation. We then compute the elasticity of demand with respect to these two determinants. The second row of Table 2 shows the estimated absolute values of the own-price elasticity for the tourism demand of international tourists in each of the countries. All these elasticities are above 1, but they are not too high. Empirical studies show that the demand for accommodation is quite inelastic to price, while supply is much more elastic. Also, the demand for tourist goods and services is moderately elastic in response to price, while supply is significantly inelastic (Forsyth et al., 2014; Johnson and Thomas, 1992; Morley, 1998; Peng et al., 2015; Song et al., 2010). According to our computations, the lowest elasticities stand at around 1.5 in Australia and Spain, while they are somewhat higher in the United States and, especially, in Canada. Based on the elasticity values, the Lerner index suggests that the tourism industries in Australia and Spain enjoy strong market power when it comes to tourism demand from international tourists visiting those countries. Conversely, the market power of the tourism industry in the two North American countries is significantly lower.

    In the third row of Table 2, we find the absolute values of the cross-price elasticity. All these elasticities, country by country, are lower than the corresponding price elasticities. This is consistent with Equation (22) because the ratio of tourism expenditure on goods and services to tourism expenditure on accommodation is greater than 1 in all countries (the sample means are 2.38 in Canada, 2.39 in Spain, 2.63 in the United States, and 4.65 in Australia). The low values recorded for the cross-price elasticity in Australia and Spain mean that any changes in the accommodation market that affect prices will have little effect on shifting demand for tourist goods and services.

    Finally, parameter β is the constant marginal utility of money, income, or total expenditure. The value of this parameter characterizes the socioeconomic status of international tourists visiting each country and thus allows us to make international comparisons. A higher value of β in a given destination means that the group of tourists visiting it shares, on average, a lower level of purchasing power. Moreover, as mentioned above, the higher the value of β, the lower the demand for both tourist goods and services and overnight stays. According to our estimates, international tourists visiting Australia are wealthier than international tourists visiting Spain. They are followed by tourists coming to the United States, the country we have taken as a reference and for which β equals 1. Closing the ranking we find tourists visiting Canada with the lowest purchasing power. Of course, this result should be independently verified, for example, using information from surveys that directly ask departing tourists about their socioeconomic profile, their attitudes toward the destination's tourism offer, and other questions related to their recent tourism experience.

    Overall, there is one remarkable feature that emerges from Table 2: the order of the countries according to the value of any of the parameters in the table does not change. This result is a direct consequence of the model predictions, as can be seen from the signs of the derivatives in Equations (26), (27), (29), and (30).

    This paper addresses the problem of the empirical modeling of the tourism demand function from a new perspective. Many empirical studies on tourism demand are grounded on ad hoc formulations with little connection to theoretical models. Moreover, it is widely recognized that there is a shortage of theoretical papers in tourism economics. Our paper, however, is a theoretical-empirical contribution that provides a detailed characterization of the linkages between the demand for tourist goods and services and the demand for accommodation using economic theory.

    In order to understand the mechanics of a sector as strategic as tourism and to make sound decisions and recommendations, the entrepreneurs and policymakers involved need an accurate theoretical representation that captures the interdependencies between the relevant variables and their relationship with the parameters. Our model of tourism choice is a model in which the representative tourist arriving at a destination decides the amount of goods and services they want to purchase and the number of overnight stays required to enjoy such tourism consumption. These two decisions are separate but interrelated because of the feedback between demands for lodging and tourism products through a vertical relationship of complementarity.

    Overall, this work extends existing theory and also makes a contribution to the empirics of tourism economics. The latter consists of an application to the tourism database of Australia, Canada, Spain, and the United States that quantifies demand elasticities and identifies the socioeconomic status of their respective tourists. Our approach focuses on estimating the demand for overnight stays from which we retrieve the value of the parameters that allow us to compute the elasticities corresponding to the demand for tourist goods and services. Simultaneously, we also derive the marginal utility of income that characterizes tourists in different destinations. In doing so, the paper opens new ways of thinking about and understanding complex phenomena and can be a reference for future empirical and theoretical studies on tourism economics.

    In conclusion, the model and application discussed in these pages represent an alternative way to have a complete characterization of demand functions and to obtain the estimation of their elasticities. Our results show that the own-price elasticity of the demand for tourist goods and services is not much higher than 1, particularly in Australia and Spain. In addition, the cross-price elasticity of the demand for tourist goods and services is substantially lower than the previous one, which means that price changes in the accommodation market will have little effect on the demand for tourist goods and services. On the other hand, based on empirical studies, we also assume that while the supply of accommodation is very elastic, the demand is pretty inelastic to price.

    The relevance of these results is due, among other reasons, to the controversial debate between lodging entrepreneurs and policymakers on the convenience of taxing tourism with a tax on overnight stays. Without entering into the discussion about the many compelling reasons that would recommend taxing tourism, even under the assumption of perfect competition and in the absence of market failures, the estimated values of the elasticities suggest that the tourist tax will not have a significant negative impact on the level of competitiveness, tourism activity, or the number of visitors. Consequently, the revenues of both accommodation providers and suppliers of tourist services will hardly be reduced by the application of a tourism tax that does not raise the price of lodging above the reservation price.

    The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    This study was supported by the Spanish Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovación [PID2019-107161GB-C32 and PID2022-138706NB-I00]; the Spanish Ministerio de Ciencia, Innovación y Universidades, Agencia Estatal de Investigación and FEDER [PID2021-127636-NB-I00]; the Belgian research programmes ARC on Sustainability 03/08-302; and the Generalitat Valenciana [PROMETEO/2020/083]. The authors are very grateful to the members of EconLab of Fundació NEXE and Càtedra de Tributació Autonòmica (Universitat de València and Generalitat Valenciana) for their valuable comments and suggestions. We also thank an academic editor and a reviewer for their thoughtful comments and insightful questions. The views expressed here, however, are our own.

    All authors declare no conflicts of interest in this paper.



    [1] Aikman D, Galesic M, Gigerenzer G, et al. (2014) Taking uncertainty seriously: simplicity versus complexity in financial regulation. Ind Corp Change 30: 317–345. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dtaa024 doi: 10.1093/icc/dtaa024
    [2] Allan N, Cantle N, Godfrey P (2013) A review of the use of complex systems applied to risk appetite and emerging risks in ERM practice: Recommendations for practical tools to help risk professionals tackle the problem of risk appetite and emerging risks. Brit Actuar J 18: 163–234. https://doi.org/10.1017/S135732171200030X doi: 10.1017/S135732171200030X
    [3] Allen F, Gale D (2000) Financial Contagion. J Polit Econ 108: 1–33. https://doi.org/10.1086/262109 doi: 10.1086/262109
    [4] Althaus CE (2005) A disciplinary perspective on the epistemological status of risk. Risk Anal 25: 567–588. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1539-6924.2005.00625.x doi: 10.1111/j.1539-6924.2005.00625.x
    [5] Anagnostou I, Sourabh S, Kandhai D (2018) Incorporating Contagion in Portfolio Credit Risk Models using Network Theory. Complexity 2018. https://doi.org/10.1155/2018/6076173 doi: 10.1155/2018/6076173
    [6] Anderson N, Noss J (2013) The Fractal Market Hypothesis and its implications for the stability of financial markets. Available from: https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/-/media/boe/files/financial-stability-paper/2013/the-fractal-market-hypothesis-and-its-implications-for-the-stability-of-financial-markets.pdf?la=en&hash=D096065EA97BE61902BDE5CC022D1E6EA38AAC49.
    [7] Anderson PW (1972) More is different. Science 177: 393–396. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.177.4047.393 doi: 10.1126/science.177.4047.393
    [8] Arthur WB (2021) Foundations of Complexity. Nat Rev Phys 3: 136–145. https://doi.org/10.1038/s42254-020-00273-3 doi: 10.1038/s42254-020-00273-3
    [9] Arthur WB (2013) Complexity Economics: A Different Framework for Economic Thought. Complexity Economics, Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.2469/dig.v43.n4.70
    [10] Arthur WB (1999) Complexity and the economy. Science 284: 107–09. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.284.5411.107 doi: 10.1126/science.284.5411.107
    [11] Aven T (2017) A Conceptual Foundation for Assessing and Managing Risk, Surprises and Black Swans. In: Motet, G., Bieder, C., The Illusion of Risk Control, Springer Briefs in Applied Sciences and Technology. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-32939-0_3
    [12] Aven T (2013) On how to deal with deep uncertainties in risk assessment and management context. Risk Anal 33: 2082–2091. https://doi.org/10.1111/risa.12067 doi: 10.1111/risa.12067
    [13] Aven T, Flage R (2015) Emerging risk – Conceptual definition and a relation to black swan type of events. Reliab Eng Syst Safe 144: 61–67. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ress.2015.07.008 doi: 10.1016/j.ress.2015.07.008
    [14] Aven T, Krohn BS (2014) A new perspective on how to understand, assess and manage risk and the unforeseen. Reliab Eng Syst Safe 121: 1–10. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ress.2013.07.005 doi: 10.1016/j.ress.2013.07.005
    [15] Babbie ER (2011) The Practice of Social Science Research. South African Ed. Cape Town. Oxford University Press.
    [16] Baranger M (2010) Chaos, Complexity, and Entropy. A Physics Talk for Non-Physicists. Report in New England Complex Systems Institute, Cambridge.
    [17] Barberis N (2017) Behavioural Finance: Asset Prices and Investor Behaviour. Available from: https://www.aeaweb.org/content/file?id=2978.
    [18] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2017) Basel Ⅲ: Finalising Post-Crisis Reforms. Available from: https://www.bis.org/bcbs/publ/d424.htm.
    [19] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2013) Fundamental Review of the Trading Book: A Revised Market Risk Framework. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs265.pdf.
    [20] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2006) Basel Ⅱ International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards: A Revised Framework-Comprehensive Version. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs128.pdf.
    [21] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (1996) Amendment to the Capital Accord to Incorporate Market Risks. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs24.pdf.
    [22] Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) (1988) International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs107.pdf.
    [23] Battiston S, Caldarelli G, May R, et al. (2016a) The Price of Complexity in Financial Networks. P Natl A Sci 113: 10031–10036. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1521573113. doi: 10.1073/pnas.1521573113
    [24] Battiston S, Farmer JD, Flache A, et al. (2016b) Complexity theory and financial regulation: Economic policy needs interdisciplinary network analysis and behavioural modelling. Science 351: 818–819. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aad0299 doi: 10.1126/science.aad0299
    [25] Bayes T, Price R (1763) An Essay towards Solving a Problem in the Doctrine of Chances. Philos T R Soc London 53: 370–418. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstl.1763.0053 doi: 10.1098/rstl.1763.0053
    [26] Beck U (1992) Risk society: towards a new modernity. Sage London.
    [27] Beissner P, Riedel F (2016) Knight-Walras Equilibria. Centre for Mathematical Economics Working Paper 558.
    [28] Bharathy GK, McShane MK (2014) Applying a Systems Model to Enterprise Risk Management. Eng Manag J 26: 38–46. https://doi.org/10.1080/10429247.2014.11432027 doi: 10.1080/10429247.2014.11432027
    [29] Black F, Scholes M (1973) The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. J Polit Econ 29: 449–470.
    [30] Blume L, Durlauf (2006) The Economy as an Evolving Complex System Ⅲ: current perspectives and future directios. https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195162592.001.0001
    [31] Bolton P, Despres M, Pereira da Silva L, et al. (2020) The green swan: central banking and financial stability in the age of climate change. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/othp31.pdf.
    [32] Bonabeau E (2002) Agent-Based Modeling: Methods and Techniques for Simulating Human Systems. Natl Acad Sci 99: 7280–7287. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.082080899 doi: 10.1073/pnas.082080899
    [33] Brace I (2008) Questionnaire Design: How to Plan, Structure, and Write Survey Material for Effective Market Research, 2 Eds., London: Kogan Page. https://doi.org/10.5860/choice.42-3520
    [34] Bronk R (2011) Uncertainty, modeling monocultures and the financial crisis. Bus Econ 42: 5–18.
    [35] Bruno B, Faggini M, Parziale A (2016) Complexity Modeling in Economics: the state of the Art. Econ Thought 5: 29–43.
    [36] Burzoni M, Riedel F, Soner MH (2021) Viability and arbitrage under Knightian uncertainty. Econometrica 89: 1207–1234. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA16535 doi: 10.3982/ECTA16535
    [37] Chan-Lau JA (2017) An Agent Based Model of the Banking System. IMF Working Paper. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781484300688.001
    [38] Chaudhuri A, Ghosh SK (2016) Quantitative Modeling of Operational Risk in Finance and Banking Using Possibility Theory, Springer International Publishing Switzerland. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-26039-6
    [39] Collis J, Hussey R (2009) Business Research: a practical guide for undergraduate and postgraduate students, 3rd ed., New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
    [40] Corrigan J, Luraschi P, Cantle N (2013) Operational Risk Modeling Framework. Milliman Research Report. Available from: https://web.actuaries.ie/sites/default/files/erm-resources/operational_risk_modelling_framework.pdf.
    [41] De Bondt W, Thaler R (1985) Does the stock market overact? J Financ 40: 793–808. https://doi.org/10.2307/2327804 doi: 10.2307/2327804
    [42] Diebold FX, Doherty NA, Herring RJ (2010) The Known, Unknown, and the Unknowable. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
    [43] Dorigo M (2007) Editorial. Swarm Intell 1: 1–2. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11721-007-0003-z doi: 10.1007/s11721-007-0003-z
    [44] Dorigo M, Maniezzo V, Colorni A (1996) Ant system: optimisation by a colony cooperating agents. IEEE T Syst Man Cy B 26: 29–41. https://doi.org/10.1109/3477.484436 doi: 10.1109/3477.484436
    [45] Dowd K (1996) The case for financial Laissez-faire. Econ J 106: 679–687. https://doi.org/10.2307/2235576 doi: 10.2307/2235576
    [46] Dowd K, Hutchinson M (2014) How should financial markets be regulated? Cato J 34: 353–388.
    [47] Dowd K, Hutchinson M, Ashby S, et al. (2011) Capital Inadequacies the Dismal Failure of the Basel Regime of Bank Capital Regulation. Banking & Insurance Journal.
    [48] Easterby-Smith M, Thorpe R, Jackson PR (2015) Management and Business Research, 5 Eds., London: Sage.
    [49] Ellinas C, Allan N, Combe C (2018) Evaluating the role of risk networks on risk identification, classification, and emergence. J Network Theory Financ 3: 1–24. https://doi.org/10.21314/JNTF.2017.032 doi: 10.21314/JNTF.2017.032
    [50] Ellsberg D (1961) Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axioms. Q J Econ 75: 643–669. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884324 doi: 10.2307/1884324
    [51] Evans JR, Allan N, Cantle N (2017) A New Insight into the World Economic Forum Global Risks. Econ Pap 36. https://doi.org/10.1111/1759-3441.12172 doi: 10.1111/1759-3441.12172
    [52] Fadina T, Schmidt T (2019) Default Ambiguity. Risks 7: 64. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks7020064 doi: 10.3390/risks7020064
    [53] Fama EF (1970) Efficient Capital Markets: A review of Theory and Empirical Work. J Financ 25: 383–417. https://doi.org/10.2307/2325486 doi: 10.2307/2325486
    [54] Farmer JD (2012) Economics needs to treat the economy as a complex system. Institute for New Economic Thinking at Oxford Martin School. Working Paper.
    [55] Farmer D (2002) Market force, ecology, and evolution. Ind Corp Change 11: 895–953. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/11.5.895 doi: 10.1093/icc/11.5.895
    [56] Farmer D, Lo A (1999) Fronties of finance: Evolution and efficient markets. Pro Nat Acad Sci 96: 9991–9992. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.96.18.99 doi: 10.1073/pnas.96.18.99
    [57] Farmer JD, Gallegati C, Hommes C, et al. (2012) A complex systems approach to constructing better models for financial markets and the economy. Eur Phys J-Spec Top 214: 295–324. https://link.springer.com/article/10.1140/epjst/e2012-01696-9
    [58] Farmer JD, Foley D (2009) The economy needs agent-based modeling. Nature 460: 685–686. https://www.nature.com/articles/460685a
    [59] Fellegi IP (2010) Survey Methods and Practices, Available from: https://unstats.un.org/wiki/download/attachments/101354131/12-587-x2003001-eng.pdf?api=v2.
    [60] Field A (2009) Discovering Statistics Using SPSS, 3 eds., London: Sage.
    [61] Fink A (2009) How to Conduct Surveys, 4 eds., Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
    [62] Fink A (1995) How to Measure Survey Reliability and Validity, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
    [63] Forrester JW (1969) Urban Dynamics. Cambridge Mass M.I.T Press.
    [64] Ganegoda A, Evans J (2014) A framework to manage the measurable, immeasurable and the unidentifiable financial risk. Aust J Manage 39: 5–34. https://doi.org/10.1177/0312896212461033 doi: 10.1177/0312896212461033
    [65] Gao Q, Fan H, Shen J (2018) The Stability of Banking System Based on Network Structure: An Overview. J Math Financ 8: 517–526. 10.4236/jmf.2018.83032 doi: 10.4236/jmf.2018.83032
    [66] Gebizlioglu OL, Dhaene J (2009) Risk Measures and Solvency-Special Issue. J Comput Appl Math 233: 1–2. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cam.2009.07.030 doi: 10.1016/j.cam.2009.07.030
    [67] Gigerenzer G (2007) Gut feelings: The Intelligence of the unconscious. New York: Viking Press.
    [68] Gigerenzer G, Hertwig R, Pachur T (Eds) (2011) Heuristics: The foundations of adaptive behaviour, New York: Oxford University Press.
    [69] Glasserman P, Young HP (2015) How likely is contagion in financial networks? J Bank Financ 50: 383–399. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.02.006 doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.02.006
    [70] Gros S (2011) Complex systems and risk management. IEEE Eng Manag Rev 39: 61–72.
    [71] Hair J, Black W, Babin B, et al (2014) Multivariate Data Analysis, 7 eds., Pearson Prentice Hall, Auflage.
    [72] Haldane AG (2017) Rethinking Financial Stability. Available from: https://www.bis.org/review/r171013f.pdf.
    [73] Haldane AG (2016) The dappled world. Available from: https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/-/media/boe/files/speech/2016/the-dappled-world.pdf.
    [74] Haldane AG (2012) The Dog and the Frisbee. Available from: https://www.bis.org/review/r120905a.pdf.
    [75] Haldane AG (2009) Rethinking the financial network. Available from: https://www.bis.org/review/r090505e.pdf.
    [76] Haldane AG, May RM (2011) Systemic risk in banking ecosystems. Available from: https://www.nature.com/articles/nature09659.
    [77] Hayek FA (1964) The theory of complex phenomena. The critical approach to science and philosophy, 332–349. https://doi.org/10.4324/9781351313087-22
    [78] Helbing D (2013) Globally network risks and how to respond. Nature 497: 51–59. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature12047 doi: 10.1038/nature12047
    [79] Holland JH (2002) Complex adaptive systems and spontaneous emergence. In Curzio, A.Q., Fortis, M., Complexity and Industrial Clusters: Dynamics and Models in Theory and Practice, New York: Physica-Verlag, 25–34. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-50007-7_3
    [80] Hommes C (2011) The heterogeneous expectations hypothesis: Some evidence from the lab. J Econ Dyn Control 35: 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2010.10.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2010.10.003
    [81] Hommes C (2001) Financial markets as nonlinear adaptive evolutionary systems. Quant Financ 1: 149–167. https://doi.org/10.1080/713665542 doi: 10.1080/713665542
    [82] Hull J (2018) Risk Management and Financial Institutions, 5 eds., John Wiley.
    [83] Ingram D, Thompson M (2011) Changing seasons of risk attitudes. Actuary 8: 20–24.
    [84] Joshi D (2014) Fractals, liquidity, and a trading model. European Investment Strategy, BCA Research.
    [85] Karp A, van Vuuren G (2019) Investment's implications of the Fractal Market Hypothesis. Ann Financ Econ 14: 1–27. https://doi.org/10.1142/S2010495219500015 doi: 10.1142/S2010495219500015
    [86] Katsikopoulos KV (2011) Psychological Heuristics for Making Inferences: Definition, Performance, and the Emerging Theory and Practice. Decis Anal 8: 10–29. https://doi.org/10.1287/deca.1100.0191 doi: 10.1287/deca.1100.0191
    [87] Keynes JM (1921) A Treatise on Probability, London: Macmillan.
    [88] Kimberlin CL, Winterstein AG (2008) Validity and Reliability of Measurement Instruments in Research. Am J Health Syst Pharma 65: 2276–2284. https://doi.org/10.2146/ajhp070364. doi: 10.2146/ajhp070364
    [89] Kirman A (2006) Heterogeneity in economics. J Econ Interact Co-ordination 1: 89–117. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-006-0005-8 doi: 10.1007/s11403-006-0005-8
    [90] Kirman A (2017) The Economy as a Complex System. In: Aruka, Y., Kirman, A., Economic Foundations for Social Complexity Science. Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-5705-2_1
    [91] Klioutchnikova I, Sigovaa M, Beizerova N (2017) Chaos Theory in Finance. Procedia Comput Sci 119: 368–375. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.procs.2017.11.196 doi: 10.1016/j.procs.2017.11.196
    [92] Knight FH (1921) Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, Boston and New York: Houghton Mifflin Company.
    [93] Krejcie RV, Morgan DW (1970) Determining the sample size for research activities. Educ Psychol Meas 30: 607–610.
    [94] Kremer E (2012) Modeling and Simulation of Electrical Energy Systems though a Complex Systems Approach using Agent Based Models, Kit Scientific Publishing.
    [95] Kurtz CF, Snowden DJ (2003) The new dynamics of strategy: Sense-making in a complex and complicated world. IBM Syst J 42: 462–483. https://doi.org/10.1147/sj.423.0462 doi: 10.1147/sj.423.0462
    [96] Li Y (2017) A non-linear analysis of operational risk and operational risk management in banking industry, PhD Thesis, School of Accounting, Economics and Finance, University of Wollongong. Australia.
    [97] Li Y, Allan N, Evans J (2018) An analysis of the feasibility of an extreme operational risk pool for banks. Ann Actuar Sci 13: 295–307. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1748499518000222 doi: 10.1017/S1748499518000222
    [98] Li Y, Allan N, Evans J (2017) An analysis of operational risk events in US and European banks 2008–2014. Ann Actuar Sci 11: 315–342. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1748499517000021 doi: 10.1017/S1748499517000021
    [99] Li Y, Allan N, Evans J (2017) A nonlinear analysis of operational risk events in Australian banks. J Oper Risk 12: 1–22. https://doi.org/10.21314/JOP.2017.185 doi: 10.21314/JOP.2017.185
    [100] Li Y, Evans J (2019) Analysis of financial events under an assumption of complexity. Ann Actuar Sci 13: 360–377. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1748499518000337 doi: 10.1017/S1748499518000337
    [101] Li Y, Shi L, Allan N, et al. (2019) An Analysis of power law distributions and tipping points during the global financial crisis. Ann Actuar Sci 13: 80–91. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1748499518000088 doi: 10.1017/S1748499518000088
    [102] Liu G, Song G (2012) EMH and FMH: Origin, evolution, and tendency. 2012 Fifth International Workshop on Chaos-fractals Theories and Applications. https://doi.org/10.1109/IWCFTA.2012.71
    [103] Lo A (2004) The adaptive markets hypothesis: Market efficiency from an evolutionary perspective. J Portfolio Manage 30: 15–29. https://doi.org/10.3905/jpm.2004.442611 doi: 10.3905/jpm.2004.442611
    [104] Lo A (2012) Adaptive markets and the new world order. Financ Anal J 68: 18–29. https://doi.org/10.2469/faj.v68.n2.6 doi: 10.2469/faj.v68.n2.6
    [105] Macal CM, North MJ, Samuelson MJ (2013) Agent-Based Simulation. In: Gass, S.I., Fu M.C., Encyclopaedia of Operations Research and Management Science, Springer, Boston MA.
    [106] Mandelbrot B (1963) The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices. J Bus 36: 394–419. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2350970
    [107] Mandelbrot B, Hudson RL (2004) The (Mis) behaviour of Markets: A Fractal View of Risk, Ruin, and Reward, Basic Books: Cambridge.
    [108] Mandelbrot B, Taleb N (2007) Mild vs. wild randomness: Focusing on risks that matter. In: Diebold, F.X., Doherty, N.A., Herring, R.J., The Known, the Unknown, and the Unknowable in Financial Risk Management: Measurement and Theory Advancing Practice, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 47–58.
    [109] Markowitz HM (1952) Portfolio Selection. J Financ 7: 77–91. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1952.tb01525.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1952.tb01525.x
    [110] Martens D, Van Gestel T, De Backer M, et al. (2010) Credit rating prediction using Ant Colony Optimisation. J Oper Res Soc 61: 561–573.
    [111] Mazri C (2017) (Re)Defining Emerging Risk. Risk Anal 37: 2053–2065. https://doi.org/10.1111/risa.12759 doi: 10.1111/risa.12759
    [112] McNeil AJ, Frey R, Embrechts P (2015) Quantitative Risk Management (2nd ed): Concepts, Techniques and Tools, Princeton University Press. Princeton.
    [113] Merton RC (1974) On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rate. J Financ 29: 637–654. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1974.tb03058.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1974.tb03058.x
    [114] Mikes A (2005) Enterprise Risk Management in Action. Available from: https://etheses.lse.ac.uk/2924/.
    [115] Mitchell M (2006) Complex systems: Network thinking. Artif Intell 170: 1194–1212. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.artint.2006.10.002 doi: 10.1016/j.artint.2006.10.002
    [116] Mitchell M (2009) Complexity: A Guided Tour. Oxford University Press.
    [117] Mitleton-Kelly E (2003) Complex systems and evolutionary perspectives on organisations: the application of complexity theory to organisations. Oxford: Pergamon.
    [118] Mohajan H (2017) Two Criteria for Good Measurements in Research: Validity and Reliability. Annals of Spiru Haret University 17: 58–82.
    [119] Mohajan HK (2018) Qualitative Research Methodology in Social Sciences and Related Subjects. J Econ Dev Environ Peopl 7: 23–48.
    [120] Morin E (2014) Complex Thinking for a Complex World-About Reductionism, Disjunction and Systemism. Systema 2: 14–22.
    [121] Morin E (1992) From the concept of system to the paradigm of complexity. J Soc Evol Sys 15: 371–385. https://doi.org/10.1016/1061-7361(92)90024-8 doi: 10.1016/1061-7361(92)90024-8
    [122] Motet G, Bieder C (2017) The Illusion of Risk Control, Springer Briefs in Applied Sciences and Technology. Springer, Cham.
    [123] Mousavi S, Gigerenzer G (2014) Risk, Uncertainty and Heuristics. J Bus Res 67: 1671–1678. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2014.02.013 doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2014.02.013
    [124] Muth JF (1961) Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements. Econometrica 29: 315–35.
    [125] Newman MJ (2011) Complex systems: A survey. Am J Phy 79: 800–810. https://doi.org/10.1119/1.3590372 doi: 10.1119/1.3590372
    [126] Pagel M, Atkinson Q, Meade A (2007) Frequency of word-use predicts rates of lexical evolution throughout Indo-European history. Nature 449: 717–720.
    [127] Pallant J (2010) SPSS Survival Manual: A Step-by-Step Guide to Data Analysis using SPSS for Windows, Maidenhead: Open University Press.
    [128] Peters E (1991) Fractal Market Analysis: Applying Chaos Theory to Investment and Economics. London: Wiley Finance. John Wiley Science.
    [129] Peters E (1994) Fractal Market Analysis: Applying Chaos Theory to Investment and Economics. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
    [130] Pichler A (2017) A quantitative comparison of risk measures. Ann Oper Res 254: 1–2. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-017-2397-3 doi: 10.1007/s10479-017-2397-3
    [131] Plosser M, Santos J (2018) The Cost of Bank Regulatory Capital. Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Staff Report Number 853.
    [132] Ponto J 2015) Understanding and Evaluatin Survey Research. J Adv Pract Oncol 6: 66–171. https://doi.org/10.6004/jadpro.2015.6.2.9 doi: 10.6004/jadpro.2015.6.2.9
    [133] Quinlan C (2011) Business Research Methods. South Westen Cengage Learning.
    [134] Ramsey FP (1926) Truth and Probability. In Ramsey 1931, The Foundations of Mathematics and Other Logical Essays, Chapter Ⅶ, 156–198, edited by R.B. Braithwaite, London: Kegan, Paul, Trench, Trubner and Co., New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company.
    [135] Righi BM, Muller FM, da Silveira VG, et al. (2019) The effect of organisational studies on financial risk measures estimation. Rev Bus Manage 21: 103–117. https://doi.org/10.7819/rbgn.v0i0.3953 doi: 10.7819/rbgn.v0i0.3953
    [136] Ross SA (1976) The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. J Econ Theory 13: 341–360. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(76)90046-6 doi: 10.1016/0022-0531(76)90046-6
    [137] Saunders M, Lewis P, Thornhill A (2019) Research Methods for Business Students, New York Pearson Publishers.
    [138] Saunders M, Lewis P, Thornhill A (2012) Research Methods, Pearson Publishers.
    [139] Savage LJ (1954) The Foundations of Statistics. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
    [140] Sekaran U (2003) Research Methods for Business (4th ed.), Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley &Sons. Shane, S. and Cable.
    [141] Senge P (1990) The Fifth Discipline- The Art and Practice of the Learning Organisation. New York, Currency Doubleday.
    [142] Shackle GLS (1949) Expectations in Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    [143] Shackle GLS (1949) Probability and uncertainty. Metroeconomica 1: 161–173. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-999X.1949.tb00040.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-999X.1949.tb00040.x
    [144] Sharpe WF (1964) Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk. J Financ 19: 425–442. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1964.tb02865.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1964.tb02865.x
    [145] Shefrin H (2010) Behaviouralising Finance. Found Trends Financ 4: 1–184. http://dx.doi.org/10.1561/0500000030 doi: 10.1561/0500000030
    [146] Shefrin H, Statman M (1985) The disposition to sell winners to early and ride loses too long: Theory and evidence. J Financ 40: 777–790. https://doi.org/10.2307/2327802 doi: 10.2307/2327802
    [147] Snowden D, Boone M (2007) A leader's framework for decision making. Harvard Bus Rev 85: 68–76.
    [148] Soramaki K, Cook S (2018) Network Theory and Financial Risk, Riskbooks.
    [149] Sornette D (2003) Why Stock Markets Crash: Critical Events in Complex Financial Systems, Princeton University Press.
    [150] Sornette D, Ouillon G (2012) Dragon-kings: mechanisms, statistical methods, and empirical evidence. Eur Phys J Spec Topics 205: 1–26. https://doi.org/10.1140/epjst/e2012-01559-5 doi: 10.1140/epjst/e2012-01559-5
    [151] Sweeting P (2011) Financial Enterprise Risk Management. Cambridge University Press.
    [152] Tepetepe G, Simenti-Phiri E, Morton D (2021) Survey on Complexity Science Adoption in Emerging Risks Management of Zimbabwean Banks. J Global Bus Technol 17: 41–60
    [153] Thaler RH (2015) Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioural Economics. New York: W. W. Norton and Company.
    [154] Thompson M (2018) How banks and other financial institutions. Brit Actuar J 23: 1–16.
    [155] Tukey JW (1977) Exploratory Data Analysis, MA: Addison-Wesley.
    [156] Turner RJ, Baker MR (2019) Complexity Theory: An Overview with Potential Applications for the Social Sciences. Sys Rev 7: 1–22. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems7010004 doi: 10.3390/systems7010004
    [157] Virigineni M, Rao MB (2017) Contemporary Developments in Behavioural Finance. Int J Econ Financ Issues 7: 448–459.
    [158] Yamane T (1967) Statistics: An Introductory Analysis (2nd ed), New York: Harper and Row.
    [159] Zadeh LA (1965) Fuzzy sets. Inf Control 8: 335–338. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0019-9958(65)90241-X doi: 10.1016/S0019-9958(65)90241-X
    [160] Zadeh LA (1978) Fuzzy sets as basis for a theory of possibility. Fuzzy Set Syst 1: 3–28. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-0114(78)90029-5 doi: 10.1016/0165-0114(78)90029-5
    [161] Zikmund W (2003) Business Research Methods, 7th Ed, Mason, OH. and Great Britain, Thomson/South-Western.
    [162] Zimbabwe (2011) Technical Guidance on the Implementation of the Revised Adequacy Framework in Zimbabwe. Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe.
    [163] Zimmerman B (1999) Complexity science: A route through hard times and uncertainty. Health Forum J 42: 42–46.
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Rossella Della Marca, Nadia Loy, Marco Menale, Intransigent vs. volatile opinions in a kinetic epidemic model with imitation game dynamics, 2022, 1477-8599, 10.1093/imammb/dqac018
    2. Giacomo Albi, Giulia Bertaglia, Walter Boscheri, Giacomo Dimarco, Lorenzo Pareschi, Giuseppe Toscani, Mattia Zanella, 2022, Chapter 3, 978-3-030-96561-7, 43, 10.1007/978-3-030-96562-4_3
    3. Mattia Zanella, Kinetic Models for Epidemic Dynamics in the Presence of Opinion Polarization, 2023, 85, 0092-8240, 10.1007/s11538-023-01147-2
    4. Rossella Della Marca, Nadia Loy, Andrea Tosin, An SIR model with viral load-dependent transmission, 2023, 86, 0303-6812, 10.1007/s00285-023-01901-z
    5. Giulia Bertaglia, Andrea Bondesan, Diletta Burini, Raluca Eftimie, Lorenzo Pareschi, Giuseppe Toscani, New trends on the systems approach to modeling SARS-CoV-2 pandemics in a globally connected planet, 2024, 34, 0218-2025, 1995, 10.1142/S0218202524500301
    6. Marzia Bisi, Silvia Lorenzani, Mathematical Models for the Large Spread of a Contact-Based Infection: A Statistical Mechanics Approach, 2024, 34, 0938-8974, 10.1007/s00332-024-10062-2
    7. Giulia Bertaglia, Lorenzo Pareschi, Giuseppe Toscani, Modelling contagious viral dynamics: a kinetic approach based on mutual utility, 2024, 21, 1551-0018, 4241, 10.3934/mbe.2024187
    8. Bruno Felice Filippo Flora, Armando Ciancio, Alberto d’Onofrio, On Systems of Active Particles Perturbed by Symmetric Bounded Noises: A Multiscale Kinetic Approach, 2021, 13, 2073-8994, 1604, 10.3390/sym13091604
    9. Rossella Della Marca, Marco Menale, Modelling the impact of opinion flexibility on the vaccination choices during epidemics, 2024, 0035-5038, 10.1007/s11587-023-00827-4
    10. Jonathan Franceschi, Andrea Medaglia, Mattia Zanella, On the optimal control of kinetic epidemic models with uncertain social features, 2024, 45, 0143-2087, 494, 10.1002/oca.3029
    11. Andrea Medaglia, Mattia Zanella, 2023, Chapter 15, 978-981-19-6461-9, 191, 10.1007/978-981-19-6462-6_15
    12. Marzia Bisi, Nadia Loy, Kinetic models for systems of interacting agents with multiple microscopic states, 2024, 457, 01672789, 133967, 10.1016/j.physd.2023.133967
    13. Giulia Bertaglia, 2023, Chapter 2, 978-3-031-29874-5, 23, 10.1007/978-3-031-29875-2_2
    14. Anton Chizhov, Laurent Pujo-Menjouet, Tilo Schwalger, Mattia Sensi, A refractory density approach to a multi-scale SEIRS epidemic model, 2025, 24680427, 10.1016/j.idm.2025.03.004
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2022 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(3319) PDF downloads(114) Cited by(1)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog