Research article

Bank regulation induced new credit channels and obscure obstruction of monetary transmission

  • In response to the financial crisis, some central banks have employed quantitative easing policies to stimulate economic recovery. Furthermore, stringent bank regulatory policies were introduced to ensure economic stability. The interplay between these measures has raised concerns about the effectiveness of monetary transmission. We aimed to examine the credit creation of banks with bank regulations and how these regulations reshape the transmission of monetary policy through bank lending. The results revealed that each bank regulatory requirement forms a maximum amount of credit, named as a credit capacity, which constrains credit creation of banks. Additionally, banks would reconstruct the balance sheets as a response to these regulations. Thus, bank regulations can reshape bank lending via the following two ways. Firstly, with the influence of bank regulations on bank lending, new monetary channels emerge, including new bank capital, new risk-taking, new bank lending, and new bank balance sheet channels. Specifically, the new bank capital channel refers to monetary shocks changing the amount of bank capital, which is subject to the CAR and LR regulations and affects bank lending via corresponding credit capacity. The new risk-taking channel is also related to the CAR regulation, which results in a variation in credit capacity due to changes in the bank's weighting parameters of risky assets. Both the new bank lending and new bank balance sheet channels are transmitted via the credit capacity formed by multiple bank regulations. Secondly, we proposed some plausible obstacles in the monetary transmission and analyzed the reasons for their formation. When banks' credit creation is subject to multiple bank regulations, the credit capacity is determined by the tightest bank regulation. As the tightest one shifts between various bank regulations, the bank credit base also undergoes constant changes. Only when a monetary shock effectively increases the credit base corresponding to the tightest regulations can the bank's credit capacity increase, ensuring the effectiveness of monetary policy; otherwise, obstacles may arise. The empirical results showed that after the financial crisis, capital regulation has become the tightest constraint to the expansion of bank credit. We believe that our theoretical findings can lay a new foundation for designing effective monetary policy.

    Citation: Hua Zhong, Xudong Zhang, Yougui Wang. Bank regulation induced new credit channels and obscure obstruction of monetary transmission[J]. National Accounting Review, 2025, 7(2): 249-270. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2025011

    Related Papers:

    [1] Ryan G. Howell, Steven L. Petersen . A comparison of change detection measurements using object-based and pixel-based classification methods on western juniper dominated woodlands in eastern Oregon. AIMS Environmental Science, 2017, 4(2): 348-357. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2017.2.348
    [2] Ammon Boswell, Steven Petersen, Bruce Roundy, Ryan Jensen, Danny Summers, April Hulet . Rangeland monitoring using remote sensing: comparison of cover estimates from field measurements and image analysis. AIMS Environmental Science, 2017, 4(1): 1-16. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2017.1.1
    [3] Tamara S. Wilson, Benjamin M. Sleeter, Jason Sherba, Dick Cameron . Land-use impacts on water resources and protected areas: applications of state-and-transition simulation modeling of future scenarios. AIMS Environmental Science, 2015, 2(2): 282-301. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2015.2.282
    [4] Mijeong Kim, Seungtaek Jeong, Jong-min Yeom, Hyun-ok Kim, Jonghan Ko . Determination of rice canopy growth based on high resolution satellite images: a case study using RapidEye imagery in Korea. AIMS Environmental Science, 2016, 3(4): 631-645. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2016.4.631
    [5] Hedi Indra Januar, Neviaty Putri Zamani, Dedi Soedarma, Ekowati Chasanah . Changes in soft coral Sarcophyton sp. abundance and cytotoxicity at volcanic CO2 seeps in Indonesia. AIMS Environmental Science, 2016, 3(2): 239-248. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2016.2.239
    [6] Lewis Trotter, Ashraf Dewan, Todd Robinson . Effects of rapid urbanisation on the urban thermal environment between 1990 and 2011 in Dhaka Megacity, Bangladesh. AIMS Environmental Science, 2017, 4(1): 145-167. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2017.1.145
    [7] Rachel R. Sleeter, William Acevedo, Christopher E. Soulard, Benjamin M. Sleeter . Methods used to parameterize the spatially-explicit components of a state-and-transition simulation model. AIMS Environmental Science, 2015, 2(3): 668-693. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2015.3.668
    [8] Hoa T. Trinh, Peter Adriaens, Christian M. Lastoskie . Fate factors and emission flux estimates for emerging contaminants in surface waters. AIMS Environmental Science, 2016, 3(1): 21-44. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2016.1.21
    [9] Frank Chambers, Alistair Crowle, John Daniell, Dmitri Mauquoy, Julia McCarroll, Nicole Sanderson, Tim Thom, Phil Toms, Julia Webb . Ascertaining the nature and timing of mire degradation: using palaeoecology to assist future conservation management in Northern England. AIMS Environmental Science, 2017, 4(1): 54-82. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2017.1.54
    [10] Pablo Andrés–Meza, Noé Aguilar–Rivera, Isaac Meneses–Márquez, José Luis Del Rosario–Arellano, Gloria Ivette Bolio–López, Otto Raúl Leyva–Ovalle . Cassava cultivation; current and potential use of agroindustrial co–products. AIMS Environmental Science, 2024, 11(2): 248-278. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2024012
  • In response to the financial crisis, some central banks have employed quantitative easing policies to stimulate economic recovery. Furthermore, stringent bank regulatory policies were introduced to ensure economic stability. The interplay between these measures has raised concerns about the effectiveness of monetary transmission. We aimed to examine the credit creation of banks with bank regulations and how these regulations reshape the transmission of monetary policy through bank lending. The results revealed that each bank regulatory requirement forms a maximum amount of credit, named as a credit capacity, which constrains credit creation of banks. Additionally, banks would reconstruct the balance sheets as a response to these regulations. Thus, bank regulations can reshape bank lending via the following two ways. Firstly, with the influence of bank regulations on bank lending, new monetary channels emerge, including new bank capital, new risk-taking, new bank lending, and new bank balance sheet channels. Specifically, the new bank capital channel refers to monetary shocks changing the amount of bank capital, which is subject to the CAR and LR regulations and affects bank lending via corresponding credit capacity. The new risk-taking channel is also related to the CAR regulation, which results in a variation in credit capacity due to changes in the bank's weighting parameters of risky assets. Both the new bank lending and new bank balance sheet channels are transmitted via the credit capacity formed by multiple bank regulations. Secondly, we proposed some plausible obstacles in the monetary transmission and analyzed the reasons for their formation. When banks' credit creation is subject to multiple bank regulations, the credit capacity is determined by the tightest bank regulation. As the tightest one shifts between various bank regulations, the bank credit base also undergoes constant changes. Only when a monetary shock effectively increases the credit base corresponding to the tightest regulations can the bank's credit capacity increase, ensuring the effectiveness of monetary policy; otherwise, obstacles may arise. The empirical results showed that after the financial crisis, capital regulation has become the tightest constraint to the expansion of bank credit. We believe that our theoretical findings can lay a new foundation for designing effective monetary policy.



    In 1870, an American astrophysicist by name Jonathan Homer Lane first published the Lane–Emden type equations [1] and were further explored by a Swiss theoretical physicist (astrophysicist and meterologist) Robert Emden in 1907 [2]. They used the equations to describe the internal structure of gaseous spheres.

    The standard form of Lane–Emden differential equation is given by [3]

    {y(t)+λty(t)+f(t,y(t))=g(t),0<t1,λ0, y(0)=A,y(0)=B. (1.1)

    This equation is a singular initial value problems relating to second order differential equations, used to describe the theory of singular boundary value problem. The Lane–Emden equation best depicts and describes a wide range of phenomena in mathematical physics, chemistry, and astrophysics, specifically in the areas of theory of stellar structure, thermal explosion, the thermal behaviour of a spherical cloud of gas, isothermal gas spheres and thermionic currents [4,5]. For recent stochastic model applications, the authors in [6] adopted a design of Morlet wavelet neutral network to find a solution of second order Lane–Emden equation. Other stochastic models for singular Lane–Emden equations include [7,8,9,10].

    Next, we review some other numerical and analytical methods of solutions to both the standard and fractional Lane–Emden type equations in literature. In 2013, the authors [11] constructed a second kind Chebyshev operational matrix algorithm to give numerical solutions of a class of linear and nonlinear Lane–Emden type singular initial value problems; in 2014, the same authors in [12] used shifted ultraspherical operational matrices of derivatives to give solutions of singular Lane–Emden equations arising in astrophysics; and in 2018, another set of authors in [13] developed an algorithm based on operational matrix of integration for Jacobi polynomials and collocation method to obtain an approximate solution of nonlinear Lane–Emden type equations arising in astrophysics. In a recent development, the authors in [14] were able to successfully propose a computationally effective approximation technique based on Bessel matrix representation and collocation points to find numerical solution of a nonlinear, singular second-order Lane–Emden pantograph delay differential equation. Other recent numerical methods of solving Lane–Emden type equation include the use of ultraspherical wavelets methods [15], the use of spectral Legendre's derivative algorithms [16], etc.

    Now, one could ask, why the fractional Lane–Emden differential equation? It is known that fractional derivatives are needed in order to best describe the dynamics of materials in fractal medium, to capture the long-term memory effect and long-range interactions of systems, the apparent importance of fractional derivatives in modeling mechanical and electrical properties of real materials, and in the description of properties of gases, liquids and rocks, see [17,18,19,20] and their references. Consequently, the authors [3] in 2012, generalized Eq (1.1) to a nonlinear-singular fractional Lane–Emden system

    {Dαy(t)+λtαβDβy(t)+f(t,y(t))=g(t),0<t1, y(0)=c0,y(1)=d0,

    where λ0,0<α2,0<β1,f:[0,1]×RR,g:[0,1]R are continuous, A,B constants and Dα,Dβ are Riemann–Liouville fractional derivatives. The fractional Lane–Emden equation is of a significant importance in the accurate modeling of real-life phenomena. For example, the nonlinear singular fractional Lane–Emden systems have been applied in a novel design of fractional Meyer wavelet neutral networks [21].

    Many researchers have employed different approaches and methods in formulating the analytical solution to the fractional Lane–Emden equations. Recently in 2022, the author in [22] studied analytical solution to a class of fractional Lane–Emden equation using a power series method. Another analytical solution involves the method of Laplace transform [5]. The author in [3] imployed a numerical method of collocation to give approximate solution of the fractional Lane–Emden equation. Some other numerical methods have also been developed to give approximate solutions of fractional order Lane–Emden-type differential equations. These methods include matrix method in terms of generalized Bessel functions and based on suitable collocation points [23], the homotopy perturbation using Adomian decomposition method [24] and Polynomial Least Square Method (PLSM) which gives an analytical approximate polynomial solution of fractional Lane–Emden differential equations [25].

    In this paper, as a motivation, we seek to find a simplified and an alternative formulation of analytical solution to a fractional Lane–Emden type equation and consider the following

    {LCDαa+φ(t)+λtαβLCDβa+ϖ(t,φ(t))=0,0<a<tT,φ(a)=ν, (1.2)

    where 0<β<α<1,LCDαa+ and LCDβa+ are Liouville–Caputo fractional derivatives, and ϖ:[a,T]×RR is Lipschitz continuous. In contrast to the known fractional Lane–Emden equations, Eq (1.2) is a singular initial value nonlinear fractional Lane–Emden type equation relating to first order differential equations.

    Remark 1.1. (1) The novelty of the paper is that it is the first to apply this analytical method in solving nonlinear singular fractional Lane–Emden type equation. The advantage of using the fractional product rule and fractional integration by parts formula is that it is simple, straightforward and less complicated; the only downside is that the method was unable to capture all the usual order 0<α2, because of the positive requirement of 1α in Γ(1α) in our formulation.

    (2) Our results are performed at approximation of the singular point since we have some terms in our solution kernel that are not defined at 0.

    The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 contains the preliminaries and formulation of the solution; and in Section 3, we give the main results of the paper. Section 4 contains some examples to illusrate our main results and Section 5 provides a short summary of the paper.

    Here, we present definitions of some basic concepts. See [26] for more concepts on fractional calculus.

    Definition 2.1 ([27]). Let a<b be positive real numbers and f:[a,b]R be an integrable function. The left sided Katugampola fractional integral of order α and parameter ρ is given by

    Iα,ρa+f(t)=ρ1αΓ(α)tasρ1(tρsρ)α1f(s)ds.

    Remark 2.2. For ρ=1, one gets the Riemann–Liouville fractional integral of order α>0 of a function f:[a,b]R given by

    Iαa+f(t)=1Γ(α)ta(ts)α1f(s)ds, (2.1)

    provided that the integral exists and finite.

    Definition 2.3. ([28]). The Riemann–Liouville fractional derivative of order 0<α<1 of a function f:[a,b]R is given by

    Dαa+f(t)=1Γ(1α)ddtta(ts)αf(s)ds,

    provided that the integral exists and finite.

    Definition 2.4 ([27]). Let a<b be positive real numbers, ρ>0,αR+ and nN such that n1<α<n, and f:[a,b]R is a class of Cn function. The left-sided Caputo–Katugampola fractional derivative of order α and parameter ρ is defined by

    CDα,ρa+f(t)=Iα,ρa+(t1ρddt)nf(t)=ρ1n+αΓ(nα)tasρ1(tρsρ)α1(t1ρdds)nf(s)ds.

    Remark 2.5. For n=1 and ρ=1, then the Liouville–Caputo fractional derivative of order 0<α<1 of a function f:[a,b]R is given by

    LCDαa+f(t)=1Γ(1α)ta(ts)αf(s)ds,

    provided that the integral exists and finite.

    Lemma 2.6 ([28]). The relationship between the Liouville–Caputo and Riemann–Liouville derivatives is

    LCDαa+f(t)=Dαa+f(t)n1k=0(ta)kαΓ(kα+1)f(k)(a).

    When n=1, it implies that k=0 and

    LCDαa+f(t)=Dαa+f(t)(ta)αΓ(1α)f(a).

    For an example, if a function f:[a,b]R is given by f(t)=tν. Then

    Dαa+f(t)=Γ(ν+1)Γ(να+1)tνα.

    Theorem 2.7 ([27]). Let yCn[a,b], then we have

    Iα,ρa+CDα,ρa+y(t)=y(t)n1k=0ρkk!(tρaρ)ky(k)(a).

    For a function yC[a,b] and ρ=1, we have

    Iαa+LCDαa+y(t)=y(t)y(a). (2.2)

    The following is a generalized fractional integration by parts formula:

    Theorem 2.8 ([27]). Let fC[a,b] and gCn[a,b] be two functions. Then

    baf(t)CDα,ρa+g(t)dt=batρ1g(t)Dα,ρb(t1ρ)f(t)dt+[n1k=0(t1ρddt)kInα,ρb(t1αf(t))g(nk1)(t)]t=bt=a.

    In particular, for n=1 and ρ=1,

    baf(t)LCDαa+g(t)dt=bag(t)Dαbf(t)dt. (2.3)

    Definition 2.9 ([29,30]). For μ,υ>0, one defines the incomplete beta function by

    B(τ,μ,υ)=τ0tμ1(1t)υ1dt,τ[0,1].

    It also has a representation in terms of a hypergeometric function given by

    B(τ,μ,υ)=τμμ2F1(μ,1υ;μ+1;τ).

    Definition 2.10 ([31]). The regularized incomplete beta function is defined by

    I(τ,μ,υ)=B(τ,μ,υ)B(μ,υ)=1B(μ,υ)τ0τμ1(1τ)υ1dτ,

    satisfying the following properties:

    I(τ,μ,υ)=I(τ,μ+1,υ1)+τμ(1τ)υ1μB(μ,υ),

    I(τ,μ,υ)=I(τ,μ+1,υ+1)τμ(1τ)υ1υB(μ,υ),

    I(τ,μ,υ)=I(τ,μ+1,υ)+τμ(1τ)υμB(μ,υ),

    I(τ,μ,υ)=I(τ,μ,υ+1)τμ(1τ)υυB(μ,υ),

    I(τ,μ,υ)+I(1τ,υ,μ)=1,

    I(1,μ,υ)=1 and I(τ,μ,υ)[0,1].

    Here, we make sense of the solution to Eq (1.2).

    Lemma 2.11. The solution to fractional Lane–Emden type equation (1.2) is given by

    φ(t)=ν+λΓ(αβ)ta(ts)αβ1sβαϖ(s,φ(s))dsλΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)ta(ts)α1sαϖ(s,φ(s))ds.

    Proof. Apply the fractional integral operator Iαa+ on both sides of Eq (1.2) to obtain

    Iαa+[LCDαa+φ(t)]+Iαa+[λtαβLCDβa+ϖ(t,φ(t))]=0.

    From Eq (2.2) in Theorem 2.7 and Eq (2.1), we have

    φ(t)φ(a)+λΓ(α)ta(ts)α1sαβLCDβa+ϖ(s,φ(s))ds=0.

    By Eq (2.3) in Theorem 2.8, we obtain

    φ(t)φ(a)+λΓ(α)taϖ(s,φ(s))Dβa+((ts)α1sβα)ds=0. (2.4)

    Apply the product rule on Dβa+((ts)α1sβα) as follows

    Dβa+((ts)α1sβα)=(ts)α1Dβa+sβα+sβαDβa+(ts)α1=(ts)α1Γ(βα+1)Γ(βαβ+1)sβαβsβαΓ(α1+1)Γ(α1β+1)(ts)αβ1=Γ(βα+1)Γ(1α)(ts)α1sαΓ(α)Γ(αβ)(ts)αβ1sβα.

    Therefore, from Eq (2.4), one gets

    φ(t)φ(a)+Γ(βα+1)Γ(1α)λΓ(α)taϖ(s,φ(s))(ts)α1sαdsΓ(α)Γ(αβ)λΓ(α)taϖ(s,φ(s))(ts)αβ1sβαds=0.

    Using the cosecant identity Γ(α)Γ(1α)=πcsc(πα)=πsin(πα), we obatin

    φ(t)φ(a)+Γ(βα+1)λsin(πα)πtaϖ(s,φ(s))(ts)α1sαdsλΓ(αβ)taϖ(s,φ(s))(ts)αβ1sβαds=0.

    Alternatively, by the property of Beta functions B(1α,α)=Γ(1α)Γ(α)Γ(1α+α)=Γ(1α)Γ(α), one writes the solution as

    φ(t)φ(a)+Γ(βα+1)λB(1α,α)taϖ(s,φ(s))(ts)α1sαdsλΓ(αβ)taϖ(s,φ(s))(ts)αβ1sβαds=0,

    and the desired result follows.

    Now, we define the norm of φ by

    φ:=supatT|φ(t)|.

    We start with the following global Lipschitz condition on ϖ(.,φ) as follows:

    Condition 3.1. Let 0<Lipϖ<, and for all x,yR, and t[a,T], we have

    |ϖ(t,x)ϖ(t,y)|Lipϖ|xy|. (3.1)

    We set ϖ(t,0)=0 for convenience only.

    The existence and uniqueness of solution to our Eq (1.2) will be proved by Banach's fixed point theorem.

    To begin, we define the operator

    Aφ(t)=ν+λΓ(αβ)ta(ts)αβ1sβαϖ(s,φ(s))dsλΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)ta(ts)α1sαϖ(s,φ(s))ds, (3.2)

    and show that the fixed point of the operator A gives the solution to Eq (1.2).

    Lemma 3.2. Let φ be a solution to Eq (1.2) and suppose that Condition 3.1 holds. Then for β+1>α and 0<β<α<1,

    Aφν+c1λLipϖφ, (3.3)

    with positive constant

    c1:=[1Γ(αβ)[πcsc(π(αβ))+B(1α+β,αβ)]+Γ(βα+1)B(1α,α)[πcsc(πα)+B(1α,α)]]<.

    Proof. We take absolute value of the Eq (3.2) to obtain

    |Aφ(t)|ν+λΓ(αβ)ta(ts)αβ1sβα|ϖ(s,φ(s))|ds+λΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)ta(ts)α1sα|ϖ(s,φ(s))|ds.

    Applying Eq (3.1) of Condition 3.1, we have

    |Aφ(t)|ν+λLipϖΓ(αβ)ta(ts)αβ1sβα|φ(s)|ds+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)ta(ts)α1sα|φ(s)|dsν+λLipϖΓ(αβ)φta(ts)αβ1sβαds+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)φta(ts)α1sαds=ν+λLipϖΓ(αβ)φ[πcsc(π(αβ))B(at,1α+β,αβ)]+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)φ[πcsc(πα)B(at,1α,α)]ν+λLipϖΓ(αβ)φ[πcsc(π(αβ))+B(at,1α+β,αβ)]+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)φ[πcsc(πα)+B(at,1α,α)],

    where B(.,.,.) is an incomplete Beta function. Now, applying the property of a regularized incomplete Beta function I(z,a,b)1 for all 0<z<1, we have B(z,a,b)=B(a,b)I(z,a,b)B(a,b). Thus, for all 0<a<t, we have

    |Aφ(t)|ν+λLipϖΓ(αβ)φ[πcsc(π(αβ))+B(1α+β,αβ)]+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)φ[πcsc(πα)+B(1α,α)].

    Taking supremum over t[a,T] on both sides, we get

    Aφν+λLipϖΓ(αβ)φ[πcsc(π(αβ))+B(1α+β,αβ)]+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)φ[πcsc(πα)+B(1α,α)],

    and the result follows.

    Lemma 3.3. Let ψ and φ be solutions to Eq (1.2) and suppose that Condition 3.1 holds. Then for β+1>α and 0<β<α<1,

    AψAφc1λLipϖψφ. (3.4)

    Proof. Since the proof follows same steps as the proof of Lemma 3.2, we omit the details to avoid repetition.

    Theorem 3.4. Let β+1>α and 0<β<α<1; and suppose Condition 3.1 holds. Then there exists a positive constant c1 such that for c1<1λLipϖ, Eq (1.2) has a unique solution.

    Proof. By fixed point theorem, one has φ(t)=Aφ(t). So, using Eq (3.3) of Lemma 3.2,

    φ=Aφν+c1λLipϖφ.

    This gives φ[1c1λLipϖ]ν and therefore, φ< if and only if c1<1λLipϖ.

    On the other hand, suppose ψφ are two solutions to Eq (1.2). Then, from Eq (3.4) of Lemma 3.3, one obtains

    ψφ=AψAφc1λLipϖψφ.

    Thus, ψφ[1c1λLipϖ]0. But 1c1λLipϖ>0, it follows that ψφ<0, which is a contradiction and therefore, ψφ=0. Hence, the existence and uniqueness result follows from contraction principle.

    In 2005, Agarwal et al. in [32], presented the following retarded Gronwall-type inequality:

    u(t)a(t)+ni=1bi(t)bi(t0)gi(t,s)wi(u(s))ds,t0t<t1. (3.5)

    Theorem 3.5 (Theorem 2.1 of [32]). Suppose that the hypotheses of (Theorem 2.1 of [32]) hold and u(t) is a continuous and nonnegative function on [t0,t1) satisfying (3.5). Then

    u(t)W1n[Wn(rn(t))+bn(t)bn(t0)maxt0τtgn(τ,s)ds],t0tT1,

    where rn(t) is determined recursively by

    r1(t):=a(t0)+tt0|a(s)|ds,
    ri+1:=W1i[Wi(ri(t))+bi(t)bi(t0)maxt0τtgi(τ,s)ds],i=1,...,n1,

    and Wi(x,xi):=xxidzwi(z).

    Remark 3.6. Now, consider the case where n=2. If

    u(t)a(t)+b1(t)b1(t0)g1(t,s)w1(u(s))ds+b2(t)b2(t0)g2(t,s)w2(u(s))ds,

    then

    u(t)W12[W2(r2(t))+b2(t)b2(t0)maxt0τtg2(τ,s)ds],

    with r2(t)=W11[W1(r1(t))+b1(t)b1(t0)maxt0τtg1(τ,s)ds].

    Here, take w1(u(s))=w2(u(s))=u(s),b1(t0)=b2(t0)=t0=a and b1(t)=b2(t)=t.

    Thus, we estimate the upper growth bound on the solution.

    Theorem 3.7. Given that Condition 3.1 holds. Then for all t[a,T],a>0 and c2,c3>0, we have

    |φ(t)|νexp(c2(at)αβ+c3(at)α),

    with c2=λLipϖΓ(1+αβ)1aαβ,c3=λLipϖΓ(βα+1)αB(1α,α)1aα, for 0<β<α<1 and β+1>α.

    Proof. From the proof of Lemma 3.2, it was obtained that

    |φ(t)|ν+λLipϖΓ(αβ)ta(ts)αβ1sβα|φ(s)|ds+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)ta(ts)α1sα|φ(s)|dsν+λLipϖΓ(αβ)supastsβαta(ts)αβ1|φ(s)|ds+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)supastsαta(ts)α1|φ(s)|ds.

    Since sβα and sα are both decreasing for 0<β<α, we have

    |φ(t)|ν+λLipϖΓ(αβ)aβαta(ts)αβ1|φ(s)|ds+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)aαta(ts)α1|φ(s)|ds.

    Let h(t):=|φ(t)|, for t[0,T] to get

    h(t)ν+λLipϖΓ(αβ)1aαβt0(ts)αβ1h(s)ds+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)1aαt0(ts)α1h(s)ds. (3.6)

    Now, we apply Theorem 3.5 to (3.6). For W2, we have that

    W2(x,x2)=xx2dzz=lnxlnx2.

    For convenience, we take x2=1 and W2(x)=lnx with the inverse W12(x)=ex. Similarly, W1(x)=lnx with its inverse W11(x)=ex.

    Also, a(t)=ν and a(t)=0, so r1(t)=ν. Next, define non-negative functions g1,g2:[a,T]×[a,T]R+ as follows:

    g1(τ,s):=λLipϖΓ(αβ)1aαβ(τs)αβ1,

    and

    g2(τ,s):=λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)1aα(τs)α1.

    For as<τ and given that αβ1<0, then g1 is continuous and decreasing, hence,

    maxaτtg1(τ,s)=λLipϖΓ(αβ)1aαβ(as)αβ1,

    and we have

    r2(t)=exp[ln(ν)+λLipϖΓ(αβ)1aαβta(as)αβ1ds]=exp[ln(ν)λLipϖΓ(αβ)1aαβ(at)αβαβ].

    Also, for as<τ, and for all α<1, g2 is continuously decreasing, and

    maxaτtg2(τ,s)=λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)1aα(as)α1.

    Thus,

    h(t)exp[ln(r2(t))+λLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)1aαta(as)α1ds]=exp[ln(ν)λLipϖΓ(1+αβ)1aαβ(at)αβλLipϖΓ(βα+1)B(1α,α)1aα(at)αα]=νexp[λLipϖΓ(1+αβ)(at)αβaαβλLipϖΓ(βα+1)αB(1α,α)(at)αaα],

    and this completes the proof.

    Here, we give examples to illustrate Theorem 3.4.

    (1) Let α=35 and β=25 and define the nonlinear Lipschitz continuous function ϖ:[a,T]×RR by ϖ(t,φ(t))=sin(φ(t)) with Lipschitz constant Lipϖ=1. Then the fractional Lane–Emden type equation

    {LCD35a+φ(t)+λ5tLCD25a+sin(φ(t))=0,0<a<tT,φ(a)=ν,

    has a unique solution whenever

    c1:=1Γ(15)[πcsc(π5)+B(45,15)]+Γ(45)B(25,35)[πcsc(3π5)+B(25,35)]=4.65692<1λ,

    or for all λ such that 0<λ<0.214734.

    (2) Suppose α=23 and β=13 and define ϖ:[a,T]×R[0,) by ϖ(t,φ(t))=|φ(t)| with Lipϖ=1. Then the fractional Lane–Emden type equation

    {LCD23a+φ(t)+λ3tLCD13a+|φ(t)|=0,0a<tT,φ(a)=ν,

    has a unique solution for

    c1:=1Γ(13)[πcsc(π3)+B(23,13)]+Γ(23)B(13,23)[πcsc(2π3)+B(13,23)]=5.41648<1λ,

    or for all λ in 0<λ<0.184622.

    A new analytical technique of solution to a nonlinear singular fractional Lane–Emden type differential equation which involves the use of fractional product rule and fractional integration by parts formula applying the fractional integral operator was considered. Our proposed analytical method is easier and straightforward to apply when compared to other analytical methods of solutions. Furthermore, we study the estimation of the upper growth bound (exponential growth in time) of the solution using retarded Gronwall-type inequality, and the existence and uniqueness of solution to the nonlinear fractional Lane–Emden type differential equation using Banach's fixed point theorem. For further studies, one can investigate the asymptotic behaviour of the solution, estimate the lower growth bound of the solution, the continuous dependence on the initial condition and the stability of the solution. Moreso, one can seek to extend this method for the singular IVPs relating to second order differential equation, that is, for 0<α2.

    The author gratefully acknowledges technical and financial support from the Agency for Research and Innovation, Ministry of Education and University of Hafr Al Batin, Saudi Arabia. The author also acknowledges the reviewers for their comments and suggestions.

    This research is funded by the University of Hafr Al Batin, Institutional Financial Program under project number IFP-A-2022-2-1-09.

    The author declares no conflicts of interest.



    [1] Acharya VV, Richardson M (2009) Causes of the financial crisis. Crit Rev 21: 195–210. https://doi.org/10.1080/08913810902952903 doi: 10.1080/08913810902952903
    [2] Adrian T, Shin HS (2010) Liquidity and leverage. J Financ Intermed 19: 418–437 2010. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2008.12.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jfi.2008.12.002
    [3] Agénor PR, da Silva LAP (2014) Macroprudential regulation and the monetary transmission mechanism. J Financ Stab 13: 44–63. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2014.02.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jfs.2014.02.002
    [4] Berger, AN, Bouwman CHS (2017) Bank liquidity creation, monetary policy, and financial crises. J Financ Stab 30: 139–155. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2017.05.001 doi: 10.1016/j.jfs.2017.05.001
    [5] Berger AN, Boubakri N, Guedhami O, et al. (2019) Liquidity creation performance and financial stability consequences of islamic banking: Evidence from a multinational study. J Financ Stab 44: 100692. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2019.100692 doi: 10.1016/j.jfs.2019.100692
    [6] Haldane AG (2018) Multi-polar regulation. Int J Cent Bank 11: 385–401.
    [7] Angeloni I, Faia E (2013) Capital regulation and monetary policy with fragile banks. J Monetary Econ 60: 311–324. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2013.01.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2013.01.003
    [8] Anginer D, Bertay AC, Cull R, et al. (2024) Bank capital regulation and risk after the Global Financial Crisis. J Financ Stab 74: 100891. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2021.100891 doi: 10.1016/j.jfs.2021.100891
    [9] Moore B (1988) Horizontalists and verticalists: the macroeconomics of credit money. J Econ Issues 23: 1181–1189.
    [10] BCBS Basel Ⅲ (2010) A global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs189.pdf.
    [11] BCBS Basel Ⅲ (2013) The liquidity coverage ratio and liquidity risk monitoring tools. Bank for International Settlements. Available from: https://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs238.pdf.
    [12] Bernanke BS, Gertler M (1995) Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission. J Econ Perspect 9: 27–48. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.9.4.27 doi: 10.1257/jep.9.4.27
    [13] Bernanke BS, Lown CS, Friedman BM (1991) The credit crunch. Brook Pap Econ Act 1991: 205–247. https://doi.org/10.2307/2534592 doi: 10.2307/2534592
    [14] Holmstrom B, Tirole J (1997) Financial intermediation, loanable funds, and the real sector. Q J Econ 112: 663–691. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555316 doi: 10.1162/003355397555316
    [15] Li BY, Xiong WT, Chen LJ, et al. (2017) The impact of the liquidity coverage ratio on money creation: A stock-flow based dynamic approach. Econ Model 67: 193–202. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2016.12.016 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2016.12.016
    [16] Cetorelli N, Goldberg LS (2010) Global Banks and International Shock Transmission: Evidence from the Crisis. IMF Econ Rev 59: 41–76.
    [17] Borio C, Zhu H (2012) Capital regulation, risk-taking and monetary policy: a missing link in the transmission mechanism? J Financ Stab 8: 236–251. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2011.12.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jfs.2011.12.003
    [18] Duffie D, Krishnamurthy A (2016) Passthrough efficiency in the fed's new monetary policy setting. In: Designing Resilient Monetary Policy Frameworks for the Future. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole Symposium, 1815–1847.
    [19] Martinez-Miera D, Suarez J (2012) A macroeconomic model of endogenous systemic risk taking. Available from: https://ssrn.com/abstract = 2153575.
    [20] VanHoose D (2007) Theories of bank behavior under capital regulation. J Bank Financ 31: 3680–3697. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2007.01.015 doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2007.01.015
    [21] Dombret A (2013) Total impact-how regulation and crisis management will change the world's financial landscape. Available from: https://www.bis.org/review/r130320c.pdf.
    [22] Diamond DW, Rajan RG (2000) A theory of bank capital. J Financ 55: 2431–2465. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00296 doi: 10.1111/0022-1082.00296
    [23] Angelopoulou E, Gibson HD (2009) The balance sheet channel of monetary policy transmission: Evidence from the united kingdom. Economica 76: 675–703. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.2008.00710.x doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0335.2008.00710.x
    [24] Dia E, VanHoose D (2017) Banking in macroeconomic theory and policy. J Macroecon 54: 149–160. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2017.07.009 doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2017.07.009
    [25] De Graeve F, Kick T, Koetter M (2008) Monetary policy and financial (in) stability: An integrated micro–macro approach. J Financ Stab 4: 205–231. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2007.09.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jfs.2007.09.003
    [26] Smets F (2014) Financial stability and monetary policy: How closely interlinked? Int J Cent Bank 10: 263–300.
    [27] Gambacorta L, Shin HS (2018) Why bank capital matters for monetary policy. J Financ Intermed 35: 17–29. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2016.09.005 doi: 10.1016/j.jfi.2016.09.005
    [28] Sellon GH (2003) Monetary policy and the zero bound: policy options when short-term rates reach zero. Econ Rev 88: 5–43.
    [29] Cozzi G, Darracq-Paries M, Karadi P, et al. (2020) Macroprudential policy measures: macroeconomic impact and interaction with monetary policy. ECB Working Paper NO.2376. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3541732
    [30] Hernando I, Martínez-Pagés J (2001) Is There a Bank Lending Channel of Monetary Policy in Spain? Available from: https://hdl.handle.net/10419/152533.
    [31] Imbierowicz B, Löffler A, Vogel U (2021) The transmission of bank capital requirements and monetary policy to bank lending in Germany. Rev Int Econ 29: 144–164. https://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12500 doi: 10.1111/roie.12500
    [32] Pyka I, Nocoń A, Muszyński M (2021) The role of capital adequacy standards in creating financial safety of the bank: the evaluation and analysis of the survey results. Ekon Prawo 20: 641–657. https://doi.org/10.12775/EiP.2021.038 doi: 10.12775/EiP.2021.038
    [33] Drechsler I, Savov A, Schnabl P (2017) The deposits channel of monetary policy. Q J Econ 132: 1819–1876. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjx019 doi: 10.1093/qje/qjx019
    [34] Tobin J (1963) Commercial banks as creators of 'money'. Available from: https://elischolar.library.yale.edu/cowles-discussion-paper-series/388.
    [35] Eisenschmidt J, Ma Y, Zhang AL (2024) Monetary policy transmission in segmented markets. J Financ Econ 151. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2023.103738 doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2023.103738
    [36] Jiménez G, Ongena S, Peydró JL, et al. (2012) Credit Supply and Monetary Policy: Identifying the Bank Balance-Sheet Channel with Loan Applications. Am Econ Rev 102: 2301–2326. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.5.2301 doi: 10.1257/aer.102.5.2301
    [37] Kapan T, Minoiu C (2018) Balance sheet strength and bank lending: Evidence from the global financial crisis. J Bank Financ 92: 35–50. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2018.04.011 doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2018.04.011
    [38] Kim D, Sohn W (2017) The effect of bank capital on lending: Does liquidity matter?. J Bank Financ 77: 95–107. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2017.01.011 doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2017.01.011
    [39] Kopecky KJ, VanHoose D (2004) Bank capital requirements and the monetary transmission mechanism. J Macroecon 26: 443–464. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2003.03.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2003.03.002
    [40] Lane PR (2013) Financial Globalisation and the Crisis. Open Econ Rev 24: 555–580. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-012-9266-0 doi: 10.1007/s11079-012-9266-0
    [41] Summers LH (2015) Demand side secular stagnation. Am Econ Rev 105: 60–65. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20151103 doi: 10.1257/aer.p20151103
    [42] Gambacorta L, Mistrulli PE (2004) Does bank capital affect lending behavior? J Financ Intermed 13: 436–457. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2004.06.001 doi: 10.1016/j.jfi.2004.06.001
    [43] Ehrmann M, Gambacorta L, Martínez-Pagés J, et al. (2003) Financial systems and the role of banks in monetary policy transmission in the euro area, In: Angeloni, I., Kashyap, A.K., Mojon, B., Monetary Policy Transmission in the Euro Area: A Study by the Eurosystem Monetary Transmission Network, Cambridge University Press, 235–269. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511492372.018
    [44] Gertler M, Karadi P (2011) A model of unconventional monetary policy. J Monetary Econ 58: 17–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.10.004 doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.10.004
    [45] Ciccarelli M, Maddaloni A, Peydró JL (2015) Trusting the bankers: A new look at the credit channel of monetary policy. Rev Econ Dyn 18: 979–1002. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.red.2014.11.002 doi: 10.1016/j.red.2014.11.002
    [46] Meh CA, Moran K (2010) The role of bank capital in the propagation of shocks. J Econ Dyn Control 34: 555–576. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2009.10.009 doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2009.10.009
    [47] McLeay M, Radia A, Thomas R (2014) Money in the modern economy: an introduction. Available from: https://ssrn.com/abstract = 2416229.
    [48] Muduli S, Behera H (2020) Bank capital and monetary policy transmission in India. Macroecon Financ Emerg Mark Econ 16: 32–56. https://doi.org/10.1080/17520843.2021.1918461 doi: 10.1080/17520843.2021.1918461
    [49] Martynova N (2015) Effect of bank capital requirements on economic growth: a survey. De Nederlandsche Bank Working Paper, No. 467. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2577701
    [50] Cetorelli N, Goldberg LS (2016) Organizational complexity and balance sheet management in global banks. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w22169
    [51] Orzechowski PE (2019) The bank capital channel and bank profits. Rev Financ Econ 37: 372–388. https://doi.org/10.1002/rfe.1054 doi: 10.1002/rfe.1054
    [52] Abbassi P, Linzert T (2012) The effectiveness of monetary policy in steering money market rates during the financial crisis. J Macroecon 34: 945–954. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2012.06.004 doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2012.06.004
    [53] Rajan RG (2006) Has finance made the world riskier?. Eur Financ Manag 12: 499–533. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-036X.2006.00330.x doi: 10.1111/j.1468-036X.2006.00330.x
    [54] Chami R, Cosimano TF (2010) Monetary policy with a touch of basel. J Econ Bus 62: 161–175. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconbus.2009.12.001 doi: 10.1016/j.jeconbus.2009.12.001
    [55] Werner RA (2014) Can banks individually create money out of nothing?—the theories and the empirical evidence. Int Rev Financ Anal 36: 1–19. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2014.07.015 doi: 10.1016/j.irfa.2014.07.015
    [56] Rasche RH, Johannes JM (1987) Controlling the growth of monetary aggregates. Springer Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-009-3275-3
    [57] Townsend RM (1979) Optimal contracts and competitive markets with costly state verification. J Econ Theory 21: 265–293. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(79)90031-0 doi: 10.1016/0022-0531(79)90031-0
    [58] Schmidt S (2013) Optimal monetary and fiscal policy with a zero bound on nominal interest rates. J Money Credit Bank 45: 1335–1350. https://doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12054 doi: 10.1111/jmcb.12054
    [59] Carpenter S, Demiralp S (2012) Money, reserves, and the transmission of monetary policy: Does the money multiplier exist?. J Macroecon 34: 59–75. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2011.09.009 doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2011.09.009
    [60] Misa T (2002) How do bank capital and capital adequacy regulation affect the monetary transmission mechanism?. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.348461
    [61] Misa T (2003) The macroeconomic implications of the new basel accord. CESifo Econ Stud 49: 217–232. https://doi.org/10.1093/cesifo/49.2.217 doi: 10.1093/cesifo/49.2.217
    [62] Juurikkala T, Karas A, Solanko L (2011) The role of banks in monetary policy transmission: Empirical evidence from russia. Rev Int Econ 19: 109–121. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9396.2010.00935.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9396.2010.00935.x
    [63] Dang VD, Huynh J (2021) How do bank characteristics affect the bank liquidity creation channel of monetary policy?. Financ Res Lett 43: 101984. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2021.101984 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2021.101984
    [64] Dang VD (2022) Bank funding, market power, and the bank liquidity creation channel of monetary policy. Res Int Bus Financ 59: 101531. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ribaf.2021.101531 doi: 10.1016/j.ribaf.2021.101531
    [65] VanHoose DD (2008) Bank capital regulation, economic stability, and monetary policy: what does the academic literature tell us?. Atl Econ J 36: 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-007-9100-z doi: 10.1007/s11293-007-9100-z
    [66] Xiong W, Wang Y (2022) A reformulation of the bank lending channel under multiple prudential regulations. Econ Model 114. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2022.105916 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2022.105916
    [67] Xiong W, Li B, Wang Y, et al. (2020) The versatility of money multiplier under basel iii regulations. Financ Res Lett 32: 101167. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2019.04.024 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2019.04.024
    [68] Xing X, Wang M, Yougui Wang, et al. (2020) Credit creation under multiple banking regulations: The impact of balance sheet diversity on money supply. Econ Model 91: 720–735. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2019.09.030 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2019.09.030
    [69] Honda Y (2004) Bank capital regulations and the transmission mechanism. J Policy Model 26: 675–688. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2004.01.006 doi: 10.1016/j.jpolmod.2004.01.006
    [70] Zhong H, Feng Z, Wang Z, et al. (2024) Revisiting the monetary transmission mechanism via banking from the perspective of credit creation. Natl Account Rev 6: 116–147. https://doi.org/10.3934/NAR.2024006 doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024006
    [71] Jakab Z, Kumhof M (2015a) Banks are not intermediaries of loanable funds – and why this matters. Bank of England Working Paper, No.529. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2612050
    [72] Zoltan Jakab, Michael Kumhof (2015b) Banks are not intermediaries of loanable funds—facts, theory and evidence. Bank of England Working Paper, No.761. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3274706
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Nicole Durfee, Carlos Ochoa, Ricardo Mata-Gonzalez, The Use of Low-Altitude UAV Imagery to Assess Western Juniper Density and Canopy Cover in Treated and Untreated Stands, 2019, 10, 1999-4907, 296, 10.3390/f10040296
    2. Barry Middleton, Laura Norman, Remote Sensing Analysis to Quantify Change in Woodland Canopy Cover on the San Carlos Apache Reservation, Arizona, USA (1935 vs. 2017), 2021, 10, 2073-445X, 393, 10.3390/land10040393
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2025 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(486) PDF downloads(36) Cited by(0)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog