Research article

GDP growth rate, tourism expansion and labor market dynamics: Applied research focused on the Italian economy

  • Received: 09 July 2022 Revised: 07 September 2022 Accepted: 09 September 2022 Published: 19 September 2022
  • JEL Codes: C51, J69, L830, O47

  • This paper focuses on the Italian economy and investigates the causal nexus between economic growth, tourism development and labor market dynamics. We performed a two-step analysis. In the first step, we evaluate whether tourism stimulates Italian economic growth or if it is the economic growth that promotes tourism expansion. To get the goal, we use panel data from 1997 to 2019 concerning the GDP and overnight stays in each Italian region. We performed the Granger causality test on the whole panel and analyzed a panelvar model. In the second step, after having established the relationship between the two variables of interest, we extended our analysis to investigate—throughout the estimate of the employment intensity of growth and the impact of GDP growth on employment, at both aggregate and disaggregate level. The main findings of our analysis are as follows: a) the existence of a unidirectional causality going from economic growth to tourism development (i.e., validation of economic-driven tourism growth hypothesis), and b) a significant estimated magnitude of the (average) employment intensity of growth.

    Citation: Giorgio Colacchio, Anna Serena Vergori. GDP growth rate, tourism expansion and labor market dynamics: Applied research focused on the Italian economy[J]. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(3): 310-328. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022018

    Related Papers:

    [1] Guido Ferrari, Yanyun Zhao, José Mondéjar Jiménez, Luca Secondi . The economy of Tuscany in the post Covid-19 era: struggling with energy crisis and inflation. What to do to resume the journey?1. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(1): 1-26. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024001
    [2] Tran Van Hoa, Jo Vu, Pham Quang Thao . Vietnam's sustainable tourism and growth: a new approach to strategic policy modelling. National Accounting Review, 2020, 2(4): 324-336. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2020019
    [3] Daniel Francois Meyer . Economic sectoral diversification: A case study of the Gauteng provincial region, South Africa. National Accounting Review, 2023, 5(4): 356-372. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2023021
    [4] Yuyi Huang, Qian Guo, Manxiang Xiao . The unbalanced development and trends of China's regional tourism. National Accounting Review, 2021, 3(1): 69-85. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2021003
    [5] Guido Ferrari, José Mondéjar Jiménez, Yanyun Zhao . The statistical information for tourism economics. The National Accounts perspective. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(2): 204-217. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022012
    [6] Mei Liu, Qing-Ping Ma . The impact of saving rate on economic growth in Asian countries. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(4): 412-427. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022023
    [7] Asensi Descals-Tormo, María-José Murgui-García, José-Ramón Ruiz-Tamarit . A new strategy for measuring tourism demand features. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(4): 480-497. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024022
    [8] Guillermo Peña . The inequality-credit linkage. National Accounting Review, 2025, 7(2): 143-176. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2025007
    [9] Liming Chen, Zhi Zhang, Fangyuan Chen, Na Zhou . A study on the relationship between economic growth and energy consumption under the new normal. National Accounting Review, 2019, 1(1): 28-41. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2019.1.28
    [10] Jorge V. Pérez-Rodríguez, Heiko Rachinger, Maria Santana-Gallego . Revisiting the export-led growth hypothesis for OECD countries. A fractionally integrated heterogeneous panel data framework. National Accounting Review, 2025, 7(2): 221-248. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2025010
  • This paper focuses on the Italian economy and investigates the causal nexus between economic growth, tourism development and labor market dynamics. We performed a two-step analysis. In the first step, we evaluate whether tourism stimulates Italian economic growth or if it is the economic growth that promotes tourism expansion. To get the goal, we use panel data from 1997 to 2019 concerning the GDP and overnight stays in each Italian region. We performed the Granger causality test on the whole panel and analyzed a panelvar model. In the second step, after having established the relationship between the two variables of interest, we extended our analysis to investigate—throughout the estimate of the employment intensity of growth and the impact of GDP growth on employment, at both aggregate and disaggregate level. The main findings of our analysis are as follows: a) the existence of a unidirectional causality going from economic growth to tourism development (i.e., validation of economic-driven tourism growth hypothesis), and b) a significant estimated magnitude of the (average) employment intensity of growth.



    Tourism is not identifiable in a single unitary industry; its economic effects impact many sectors, such as transportation, accommodation, food services and recreational services, to cite a few. Such widespread economic benefits, jointly with the growing relevance of the phenomenon worldwide, have stimulated scholars' interest in measuring the contribution of tourism to economic growth.

    Most studies focus on the role of inbound tourism, contributing to gross domestic product (GDP) just as exports, and sometimes neglecting the impact of domestic tourism. Although foreign tourism entrances have been growing worldwide in the last few decades, domestic tourism also plays a crucial role in economic growth. This is because the expenditures of domestic tourists jointly with those done by tourism employees are accounted for in the final consumption of the households; hence, as part of aggregate demand, they contribute to the national income.

    Since the seminal study by Balaguer and Cantavella-Jorda in 2002, many scholars have analyzed the causal relationship between tourism and economic growth. Does tourism development stimulate economic growth or, on the contrary, does economic growth lead to tourism development? No univocal answer to the question was found. While finding different causal relationships for different countries is reasonable, heterogeneous results have also been found for the same country due to the variables used, the time series length and the methodologies.

    Tourism has been proved to be a powerful vehicle for the development of many countries, contributing to global employment and income (Sharpley, 2022). However, the effects on employment could have two drawbacks. First, tourism is a labor-intensive industry with low productivity; accordingly, tourism development could provoke a switch in resources from high productive sectors to the tourism sector (Chiu and Yeh, 2017), generating a kind of Dutch disease. Second, due to seasonality in tourism (Vergori, 2017), most of the available jobs could be temporary, which could create uncertainty.

    This paper focuses on the Italian economy and investigates the causal nexus between economic growth, tourism development and labor market dynamics. We performed a two-step analysis. In the first step, we evaluated whether tourism stimulates Italian economic growth, or if it is the economic growth that promotes tourism expansion. To achieve the goal, we used panel data from 1997 to 2019 concerning the GDP and overnight stays in each Italian region. Regional data should allow us to obtain more accurate results than aggregate national data. We performed a Granger causality test on the whole panel and analyzed a panelvar (PVAR) model. In the second step, after having established the relationship between the two variables of interest, we extended our analysis, using the estimate of the employment intensity of growth to investigate the impact of GDP growth on employment, taking into account both the aggregate and disaggregate labor markets by sector.

    This kind of analysis is of particular interest in this historic period due to the considerable funds that Italy and other European countries have received from the European Union, via the Next Generation EU program, to recover their economy from the effects of the pandemic. The Italian government envisages allocating more than six billion Euros (out of 205 billion) to culture and tourism, which are considered among the key sectors to recover the Italian economy from the crisis generated by the pandemic.

    The relationship between tourism development and economic growth has been widely analyzed in the last two decades. Since the seminal contribution of Balaguer and Cantavella-Jorda (2002), various literature reviews on the topic have been published (Ivanov and Webster, 2013; Pablo-Romero and Molina, 2013; Brida et al., 2016; Fonseca and Sanchez-Rivero, 2019). The linkages between the two variables are not stable over time due to structural changes in the time series (e.g., Antonakakis et al. 2019; Shahbaz et al. 2017). Accordingly, different results (in terms of direction and magnitude of the relationship) have also been obtained by scholars for the same country. Furthermore, countries with different levels of tourism specialization tend to exhibit different tourism-growth nexuses (Chiu and Yeh, 2017).

    While the real GDP is generally used to measure economic growth, three variables are used as proxies for tourism development, i.e., international tourist arrivals or overnight stays, international tourism receipts and tourism expenditures. The latter are used singularly, separately or in weighted indexes.

    Generally, using the Granger causality test to investigate the causality nexus between tourism and economic growth leads to the validation of one of the four hypotheses identified in the literature. The tourism-led economic growth (TLEG) hypothesis implies a unidirectional causality from tourism to economic growth. In this case, tourism development is one of the main determinants of economic growth. Studying international tourism, many scholars validated this hypothesis. Indeed, for related factors such as goods and services export, inbound tourism behaves as an exogenous component of the aggregate demand, having a multiplicative effect on the tourist destination's GDP. Various studies have proved the validity of this hypothesis. Proença and Soukiazis (2008) confirmed the tourism-led growth hypothesis for Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain for the period of 1990–2014 by using the Barro and Sala-i-Martin conditional convergence approach. Brida et al. (2016) validated the tourism-led growth hypothesis for Italy (years 1954–2000) and Spain (from 1964 to 2000). The TLEG hypothesis has also been confirmed for Italy and Spain for the years from 1998 to 2011 by Tugcu (2014), who used both tourism receipts and tourism expenditures as proxies for tourism growth. Some studies have highlighted that tourism development can boost economic growth in developing or the least developed countries, but not in developed countries (see Eugenio-Martin et al., 2004; Cardenas-Garcia et al., 2015). Chen and Chiou-Wei (2009) also found evidence of the TLEG hypothesis in Taiwan.

    The second hypothesis tested in the literature for the causality nexus between tourism growth and economic growth is the economic-driven tourism growth (EDTG) one. According to this hypothesis, there is a unidirectional causality going from economic growth to tourism development. Aslan (2013) applied the Granger causality approach to a panel of Mediterranean countries for the period going from 1995 to 2010. He validated the EDTG hypothesis for six out of the 12 countries analyzed, among which were Italy, Greece and Spain. Massidda and Mattana (2012) applied a structural vector error correction model to the quarterly Italian data from 1987 to 2009. In the short-run, the EDTG hypothesis emerged, while, in the long run, the authors found a bidirectional relationship. Bidirectional causality is another hypothesis often found in the literature; it is known as the feedback hypothesis. Dogru and Bulut (2008) also validated the feedback hypothesis for seven European countries from 1996 to 2014. Using data from the first quarter of 1990 to the fourth quarter 2015, Shahbaz et al. (2017) applied a bootstrap rolling window Granger causality approach to prove the existence of a bidirectional Granger causality for Italy, Mexico, the UK and the USA.

    The fourth hypothesis found in the literature is the neutrality one. In this case, no relationship between tourism development and economic growth emerges. Some examples are China, France, Germany and Turkey, according to Shahbaz et al. (2017), and some African countries, according to the results by Tugcu (2014).

    Most of the studies that involved Granger causality analysis focused on national data; however, it is worth stressing the importance of studying the role played by tourism in economic development at sub-national levels (see, for example, Cortés-Jiménez, 2008; Centinaio et al., 2022). This kind of analysis, although desirable, is not always possible due to data availability. Even if our research is performed at the national level, however, the panel data are at the NUTS 2 level. This aspect is not marginal because it allows us to have more accurate information than the studies using aggregate national data.

    We use data collected by the Italian Institute of Statistics. Panel data concerning the real total GDP, the tourist overnight stays (TOS) and the employment level for the 20 Italian regions over the period of 1997–2019. We gathered data at the regional level to have a more extended time series.

    Although we use the real GDP as a measure of economic growth, following the main literature (e.g., Antonakakis et al., 2019; Tugcu, 2014; Brida et al., 2016), we have also made alternative estimations using per capita GDP growth rate (PGDP). The use of the PGDP allows us to investigate the effect of tourism development on the Italian standard of living. However, the outcomes of this alternative analysis are almost identical to those obtained by using the GDP growth rate (see Footnote 3 below). The explanation of this result must be traced back to the very low Italian population growth rate over the period considered, which makes the two growth rates almost similar. Actually, over the period of 1997–2019, the average population growth rate has been equal to 6.5%, while the yearly growth rate over the same period has always been below 0.7%, becoming negative over the periods of 1995–1999 and 2018–2019.

    As hinted in the previous section, the different variables were used as proxies for tourism development in previous studies. When the analysis focuses on inbound tourism, scholars tend to use data on international expenditures because they are generally available and allow them to catch the monetary aspect of tourism flows. Since foreign and domestic tourism are both equally important in Italy, we are interested in analyzing the whole phenomenon. Unfortunately, this choice does not allow us to use data on tourism expenditures because of their unavailability; thus, we chose to represent tourism development through TOS data. As mentioned, overnight stays give us information about the number of tourists and the duration of their stay, unlike tourism arrivals, which only represent the number of tourists visiting a destination. Since tourism spending increases when the number of days of vacation increases, we believe that TOS data are a good proxy for the aim of our study.

    Furthermore, data about employment were also analyzed to estimate the employment-GDP relationship. In particular, we split all of the data based on the number of employees in each region (EMPL), as shown in Table 1, as follows:

    Table 1.  Descriptive statistics.
    Regions Variables Mean Stand. Dev. Min Max
    North-West Liguria GDP (thousands) 50, 176, 783 2, 179, 560 46, 652, 960 53, 903, 768
    PGDP 31, 838 1, 440 29, 723 34, 278
    TOS 14, 588, 187 827, 175 13, 149, 699 15, 893, 637
    EMPL 616, 290 10, 797 599, 150 635, 690
    Lombardy GDP (thousands) 359, 866, 679 17, 379, 083 322, 231, 870 386, 906, 618
    PGDP 38, 004 1, 160 36, 165 39, 796
    TOS 30, 212, 698 5, 816, 343 22, 839, 872 40, 482, 939
    EMPL 4, 180, 800 159, 070 3, 858, 400 4, 483, 100
    Piedmont GDP (thousands) 131, 934, 361 4, 915, 177 125, 164, 231 140, 630, 528
    PGDP 30, 606 1, 392 28, 461 32, 816
    TOS 11, 211, 201 2, 482, 823 7, 323, 814 15, 100, 768
    EMPL 1, 798, 300 40, 753 1, 687, 300 1, 860, 900
    Valle d'Aosta GDP (thousands) 4, 945, 679 191, 213 4, 588, 479 5, 192, 843
    PGDP 39, 987 2, 186 36, 036 43, 103
    TOS 3, 265, 181 189, 031 2, 981, 002 3, 625, 616
    EMPL 55, 697 965.56 54, 423 58, 013
    North-East Emilia Romagna GDP (thousands) 146, 705, 551 7, 590, 858 128, 944, 968 157, 372, 139
    PGDP 34, 885 1, 245 33, 012 37, 206
    TOS 37, 126, 257 1, 973, 726 32, 352, 975 40, 647, 799
    EMPL 1, 900, 000 68, 193 1, 744, 900 2, 032, 600
    Friuli V. G. GDP (thousands) 36, 765, 202 1, 420, 600 34, 025, 237 39, 556, 732
    PGDP 30, 528.7 1242.473 28, 887.4 32, 811.0
    TOS 8, 568, 500 546574 7, 585, 468 9, 570, 747
    EMPL 502, 830 9, 818 481, 140 519, 020
    Trentino A.A. GDP (thousands) 39, 692, 517 2, 771, 699 34, 170, 492 45, 184, 797
    PGDP 39, 865 937 37, 481 42, 070
    TOS 42, 607, 174 4, 725, 492 35, 978, 061 52, 074, 506
    EMPL 453, 780 28, 560 405, 380 499, 390
    Veneto GDP (thousands) 151, 759, 939 6, 307, 798 138, 018, 301 160, 977, 195
    PGDP 32, 142 1, 126 30, 353 34, 041
    TOS 58, 845, 262 7, 759, 813 41, 918, 281 71, 236, 630
    EMPL 2, 054, 500 73, 433 1, 880, 000 2, 166, 900
    Center Lazio GDP (thousands) 190, 987, 205 8, 605, 541 170, 993, 096 203, 843, 973
    PGDP 35, 290 2, 080 32, 283 38, 624
    TOS 29, 814, 210 4, 489, 686 21, 061, 286 39, 029, 255
    EMPL 2, 141, 200 178, 360 1, 834, 900 2, 385, 900
    Marche GDP (thousands) 40, 886, 074 1, 893, 522 36, 861, 242 44, 622, 187
    PGDP 27, 174 1, 297 25, 352 29, 655
    TOS 11, 813, 640 1, 077, 258 9, 656, 538 13, 584, 582
    EMPL 624, 870 20, 240 572, 840 652, 510
    Tuscany GDP (thousands) 110, 762, 671 3, 882, 122 100, 692, 937 116, 920, 077
    PGDP 30, 673 1, 047 28, 813 32, 355
    TOS 40, 541, 696 4, 456, 336 31, 448, 543 48, 077, 301
    EMPL 1, 524, 100 48, 058 1, 412, 700 1, 602, 200
    Umbria GDP (thousands) 23, 102, 075 1, 228, 213 21, 085, 851 24, 994, 562
    PGDP 26, 949 2, 075 23, 514 29, 485
    TOS 5, 606, 037 672, 163 3, 682, 822 6, 252, 102
    EMPL 347, 640 12, 889 315, 280 367, 210
    South and Islands Abruzzo GDP (thousands) 32, 184, 291 823, 203 30, 435, 023 33, 472, 276
    PGDP 24, 918 793 23, 840 26, 396
    TOS 6, 677, 066 573, 866 5, 605, 314 7, 560, 476
    EMPL 487, 860 11, 518 462, 090 510, 700
    Apulia GDP (thousands) 73, 714, 536 2, 620, 842 69, 511, 582 77, 693, 357
    PGDP 18, 233 712 17, 148 19, 298
    TOS 11, 688, 106 2, 549, 083 7, 091, 509 15, 441, 469
    EMPL 1, 221, 900 35, 822 1, 143, 700 1, 278, 400
    Basilicata GDP (thousands) 12, 101, 682 592, 486 11, 143, 545 12, 951, 176
    PGDP 20, 660.3 1132.296 18, 699.8 22, 836.8
    TOS 1, 896, 824 41, 946 1, 132, 630 2, 733, 969
    EMPL 189, 830 5, 202.5 178, 620 197, 060
    Calabria GDP (thousands) 34, 172, 855 1, 805, 883 31, 629, 770 36, 430, 219
    PGDP 17, 202.3 843.5722 15, 992.0 18, 514.8
    TOS 7, 718, 185 1, 233, 646 4, 914, 227 9, 509, 423
    EMPL 569, 410 32, 287 515, 210 619, 190
    Campania GDP (thousands) 110, 030, 993 5, 363, 081 101, 171, 868 118, 366, 938
    PGDP 19, 109 1, 047 17, 534 20, 629
    TOS 19, 501, 211 1, 142, 677 17, 722, 308 22, 013, 245
    EMPL 1, 663, 800 69, 335 1, 561, 000 1, 777, 400
    Molise GDP (thousands) 6, 865, 584 546, 871 5, 987, 374 7, 581, 996
    PGDP 21, 646 1, 495 19, 024 23, 902
    TOS 587, 468 118, 904 419, 597 769, 334
    EMPL 107, 110 3, 533.8 98, 568 112, 920
    Sardinia GDP (thousands) 34, 105, 439 1, 090, 425 32, 260, 827 35, 906, 865
    PGDP 20, 779 747 19, 563 21, 898
    TOS 11, 308, 895 1, 894, 934 8, 117, 266 15, 145, 885
    EMPL 581, 980 17, 073 546, 330 605, 910
    Sicily GDP (thousands) 92, 117, 466 4, 388, 621 85, 887, 181 99, 251, 477
    PGDP 18, 426 977 16, 986 19, 974
    TOS 13, 701, 788 1, 203, 423 10, 292, 337 15, 135, 259
    EMPL 1, 411, 400 51, 873 1, 321, 700 1, 493, 600
    ITALY GDP (thousands) 1, 684, 821, 471 58, 517, 597 1, 545, 758, 634 1, 778, 792, 031
    PGDP 28, 741 1, 059 27, 178 30, 551
    TOS 367, 279, 587 37, 401, 631 292, 276, 323 436, 739, 271
    EMPL 21, 048, 120 129, 87 21, 047, 910 21, 048, 330
    Source: Own elaboration of ISTAT data.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    •    EMPL_COMM: the number of employees in commerce, accommodation and service sectors (ATECO 2007 code, letters G and I);

    •    EMPL_SERV: the number of employees in the service sector net of the above defined EMPL_COMM sector (ATECO 2007 code, letters H and L–U);

    •    EMPL_IND: employment levels in the sectors covering the remaining economic activities (ATECO 2007 code, letters A–F).

    Table 1 shows some descriptive statistics about the variables for GDP (values in thousands), TOS and EMPL. Furthermore, for the sake of completeness, in the same table, we have added the PGDP values, which represent one of the main indicators of the standard of living in each of the various Italian regions.

    The table shows the Italian regions grouped according to the macro-area of belonging. Looking at the PGDP values, we noticed that they tend to decrease moving from the north to the south of the peninsula. Regarding TOS, six regions account for 65% of the tourism flows in Italy; four of these regions belong to the north of Italy (Veneto, Trentino Alto Adige, Lombardy and Emilia Romagna), while two of the most touristic regions are in the center (Tuscany and Lazio). Finally, with reference to the employed in the Italian economy, about 54% of the total employed were found to be concentrated in five regions, four of which are in the north (Lombardy, Veneto, Emilia Romagna and Piedmont), and one (Lazio) in the center of Italy.

    All of the variables show a gap between the north and south of the country. It is important to point out that a peculiar aspect of the divide is represented by the migration flows from southern regions toward central and northern regions (as well as toward foreign countries). This is nothing but the well-known adjustment mechanism based on the production factors mobility in the presence of areas characterized by different levels of economic growth. According to SVIMEZ (2019), in the period of 2000–2018 approximately 2 million residents left southern Italy, half of them young people up to age 34, and almost a fifth of them graduated. The main consequences of these flows are evident and can be summed up in the deterioration of human capital with the related decrease in potential GDP.

    Since we analyzed the relationship between tourism and economic growth, we will focus on the growth rates of the real total GDP (GDPgr) and TOS (TOSgr).

    Before testing for the stationarity of both time series, we selected the optimal lag length according to the Akaike (AIC(n)), Schwarz (SC(n)), Hannan-Quinn (HQ(n)) and Final Prediction Error (FPE(n)) criteria. In accordance with the AIC, HQ, and PFE criteria, the optimal lag length was set as 2, while the SC criterion suggests that the optimal length is 1. We chose the optimal length to equal to 1 because it is the usual choice for annual data, and because the number of time periods of our panel is relatively small; however, for a robustness check, we also performed a PVAR regression with two lags (see Footnote 3 below). The Levin-Lin-Chu unit root test states that both series are stationary (with p-values > 0), and this result is also corroborated by other Fisher-type tests, like the Hadri and Choi unit root tests (see Choi, 2001; Hadri, 2000; Levin et al., 2002).

    About the Granger causality analysis, we have performed the test proposed by Dumitrescu-Hurlin (2012), computing also the intermediate Wbar statistics (average of individual Granger chi-square statistics). We found that the GDPgr ("Granger causes") to TOSgr was at a significance level near 0%, while there was no causality from TOSgr to GDPgr. However, if we run the Granger causality test assuming the panel data as a stacked set of data, and if we had relevant time dummies, there would be strong evidence of causality running both from GDPgr to TOSgr (p-value = 0.003) and from TOSgr to GDPgr (p-value = 0.046). We point out that this is a relevant finding since the Chow test for poolability of the data do not reject the null hypothesis of slope coefficient homogeneity across cross sections1.

    1The Dumitrescu-Hurlin panel causality test is suited for heterogeneous panels, since it is based on the assumption that all coefficients may be different across different cross sections. Furthermore, as has been stated, "the panel Granger causality analysis recently developed by Dumitrescu and Hurlin (2012), […] is superior to former panel Granger causality tests in terms of giving efficient results even in panels with small sample sizes, being applicable in unbalanced and/or cross-sectionally dependent panels without requiring any particular estimation, and allowing different lag orders for each cross-section unit" (Tugcu, 2014). For these reasons, the results of this test are usually reported in terms of econometric analyses dealing with dynamic panel models; in what follows, we will report the results of both tests.

    Considering that our data cover various regions of the same country over two decades, we have performed a PVAR analysis, which stands as a combination of a dynamic panel model and a vector autoregressive model. The autoregressive structure of the model allows us to capture the lagged effects of each variable on itself and/or on the other variable. Since the presence of lagged dependent variables causes the ordinary least squares OLS estimator to be biased (the bias is of order 1/T), in what follows, we use the generalized method of moments estimator (also known as the system GMM estimator) developed by Arellano and Bond (1991). The proliferation of instruments, which may cause bias estimation due to overidentification, is a matter of concern for the system GMM estimator (see Baum et al., 2003); in order to avoid this problem, we referred to Roodman's (2009) seminal paper, where the author shows how the number of instruments may be limited by "collapsing" them and reducing, at the same time, the number of lagged dependent variable instruments.

    We used the R package "panelvar" by Sigmund and Ferstl (2019) to obtain the results reported in Table 2. The model estimated is the following:

    TOSgrt=α11TOSgrt1+α12GDPgrt1+INVGDPt+PARTRATEt+α15d2009+α16d2012+ε1,t (1)
    GDPgrt=α21TOSgrt1+α22GDPgrt1+INVGDPt+PARTRATEt+α25d2009+α26d2012+ε2,t (2)
    Table 2.  PVAR results.
    TOSgrt GDPgrt
    FEOLS GMM (one-step) GMM (two-step)+ FEOLS GMM (one-step) GMM (two-step)+
    TOSgrt-1 0.0426
    (0.0513)
    0.112**
    (0.046)
    0.118*
    (0.067)
    0.029*
    (0.016)
    0.035*
    (0.018)
    0.037
    (0.023)
    GDPgrt-1 0.405****
    (0.128)
    0.426****
    (0.115)
    0.419****
    (0.109)
    0.152****
    (0.041)
    0.184****
    (0.036)
    0.197****
    (0.047)
    Y2009 −3.013**
    (1.317)
    −2.807***
    (0.885)
    −2.087
    (1.315)
    −5.79****
    (0.430)
    −5.694****
    (0.477)
    −5.155****
    (0.623)
    Y2012 −5.237****
    (1.289)
    −5.296****
    (1.012)
    −5.153****
    (0.920)
    −3.567****
    (0.421)
    −3.582****
    (0.362)
    −3.101****
    (0.537)
    INV/GDP 0.028
    (0.121)
    0.024
    (0.086)
    −0.015
    (0.104)
    0.022
    (0.038)
    0.020
    (0.031)
    0.046
    (0.030)
    PART_RATE 0.036
    (0.166)
    −0.027
    (0.110)
    0.014
    (0.139)
    −0.008
    (0.052)
    −0.051
    (0.045)
    −0.0003
    (0.056)
    Note: **** p < 0.001; *** p < 0.01; ** p < 0.05; * < 0.1, +Hansen test of overidentification restrictions: chi2(8) = 12.83 Prob > chi2 = 0.118.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    where INV/GDP and PART_RATE are two exogenous control variables that stand respectively for gross fixed capital formation as a percentage of GDP and labor force participation rate. In addition, d2009 and d2012 are two dummy variables for the years 2009 and 2012, respectively, and the corresponding economic recession engendered by the sovereign debt crisis. Although this latter crisis exploded in Italy in 2011, in terms of a decrease in aggregate demand and, particularly, in consumption, it had its most severe effects the following year (see Busetti and Cova, 2013).

    In what follows, for robustness checking, we will report the results of both one-step and two-step GMM estimation2 and, for comparative purposes, also the results of a standard fixed-effects OLS estimator. For the sake of brevity, we do not report the estimates of the control variable parameters. Standard errors are in brackets.

    2For deeper insight into the GMM estimator and the related matter of overidentification restrictions, the reader is also referred to Abonazel (2016), Abrigo and Love (2016), Hwang and Sun (2018), Labra and Torrecillas (2018), Mehrhoff (2009) and Sigmund and Ferstl (2019).

    In line with the Granger causality analysis performed before, the above regression results confirm a significant dependence of TOSgrt on GDPgrt-1; actually, the GDPgrt-1 coefficient is quite relevant and highly statistically significant. On the contrary, the increment in TOS at time t-1 seems to have a weak, almost negligible (if compared to α12 estimate), effect on the growth of GDP at time t. Furthermore, the above results show an autoregressive structure of both GDPgr and TOSgr, while the coefficients of the time dummy variables have the expected signs and are statistically significant3.

    3As we have said, we have also performed a PVAR regression using two lags. We point out to the reader that the results we have obtained are strongly consistent with those of Table 2. The only slight difference we have found is related to the greater magnitude of the estimated value of α12; actually, with two lags, the two-step GMM estimate is α12 = 0.57, once again with a p-value < 1%. Furthermore, as we have anticipated, we have also performed a PVAR regression replacing the GDP growth rate with the PGDP growth rate. The results we have obtained are almost identical to those reported in Table 2, and the explanation for these outcomes, as we have already said, lies in the very small value of the population growth rate over the period under examination. For instance, the GMM two-step parameter estimations of α11, α12, α21, α22, using the PGDP growth rate, are respectively given by 0.112*, 0.426 ****, 0.037, 0.197****, where the asterisks have the same meaning as in Table 2.

    After having checked the stability of the model (i.e., after verifying that all eigenvalues lie inside the unit circle, which means that the PVAR is stable), we analyzed the generalized impulse response functions.

    From Figure 1 (see the upper-right box) we can see the response function for TOSgr responding to a one-time (one standard deviation) positive shock on GDPgr. After an initial significant increase in TOSgr value, the response function curves shifts downward and the shock was "reabsorbed" very slowly in about 4 years. On the contrary, a one-time shock on TOSgr (see the lower-left box) caused a very small, almost negligible, initial increase in GDPgr and was reabsorbed in about 3 years. The remaining two boxes confirm the autoregressive structure of both GDGgr and TOSgr. These findings are in line with the PVAR analysis of the previous section and confirm the relevance of the impact of GDP changes on TOS.

    Figure 1.  Impulse response functions with 95% bootstrapped confidence bands; the vertical axis shows the magnitude of the response (in percentage) to a one-time positive shock.

    As we have shown in the previous section, the PVAR analysis for the entire panel confirms that tourism growth in Italy depends on the past value of the economic growth rate (EDTG hypothesis), even if we have also found a weak dependence of economic growth on tourism development. It may be interesting to further extend our analysis, taking explicitly into account the implications of these findings on the labor market, with particular regard to the employment levels.

    In this section, we will show how to use the estimation of the elasticity of employment to GDP, also known as the employment intensity of growth, EMPLGDPGDPEMPL%, to investigate the effect of GDP on employment level EMPL for the whole economy. Furthermore, we will extend our analysis at the sectoral level, taking explicitly into account the relation between the employment growth rates in EMPL_COMM, EMPL_IND and EMPL_SERV sectors (which we have defined above in Section 3).

    We proceed with a preliminary analysis of the order of integration of the log of the variables of interest, i.e., ln(GDP), ln(EMPL), ln(EMPL_COMM), ln(EMPL_IND), and ln(EMPL_SERV).

    Given the presence of cross-sectional dependence (CSD), which is common with this kind of model, in order to check the integration order of our series, we have relied on the so called "second generations tests", which are robust against CSD, the Breitung test and the Pesaran cross-sectionally augmented Dickey-Fuller ADF statistics (CADF)4 (see Breitung and Das, 2005 and Pesaran, 2003). In Table 3, for the sake of brevity, we report only the main results of the former test; however, we point out to the reader that the CADF test gives identical outcomes.

    4 We have employed the Stata packages xtunitroot and pescadf.

    Table 3.  Breitung unit root test-H0; the panels contain unit roots.
    Variable Lambda p-value Integration order
    Ln (GDP) −0.0530 0.4789 I(1)
    ΔLn (GDP) −3.0686 0.0011 I(0)
    Ln (EMPL) 1.1644 0.8779 I(1)
    ΔLn (EMPL) −5.1870 0.0000 I(0)
    Ln (EMPL_COMM) 0.3745 0.6460 I(1)
    ΔLn (EMPL_COMM) −7.4979 0.0000 I(0)
    Ln (EMPL_IND) 0.5689 0.7153 I(1)
    ΔLn (EMPL_IND) −7.9897 0.0000 I(0)
    Ln (EMPL_SERV) 2.3464 0.9905 I(1)
    ΔLn (EMPL_SERV) −6.7832 0.0000 I(0)

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    As is evident from Table 3, all of our variables are integrated on an order of 1 (the log differences being stationary). At this point, instead of getting the short-run estimates by simply regressing Δln(EMPL) on Δln(GDP), it may be interesting to verify the presence of a long-run relationship between ln(EMPL) and ln(GDPt) by performing a cointegration test between the two series. In light of the already mentioned strong CSD detected, we relied on the second-generation Westerlund cointegration test, which is robust against CSD5. Table 4 sums up the main findings of our analysis.

    5 For the robustness check, we also performed the alternative Pedroni cointegration test, and the results are strongly consistent with those presented in Table 4.

    Table 4.  Westerlund cointegration test.
    Variables: Ln (EMPL), Ln (GDP) – H0: no cointegation
    Statistic Value Z-value P-value
    Gt −1.601 −2.687 0.004
    Ga −6.006 −2.167 0.015
    Pt −5.664 −2.897 0.002
    Pa −3.359 −3.063 0.000

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Since, as is evident from Table 4, ln(EMPL) and ln(GDPt) are cointegrated at an order of 1, we can simply estimate the following equation (see, for instance, Crivelli et al., 2012):

    ln(EMPLt)=α+βLn(GDPt)+εt (2)

    Given the above-mentioned presence of CSD, we estimated Equation (2) by employing the estimated generalized least squares (EGLS) technique with fixed effects and a cross-sectional seemingly unrelated regression SUR (see Zellner, 1962) even if, for the robustness check, we have also performed an alternative estimate using the xtscc Stata package, which produces regression estimates with Driscoll-Kraay standard errors (see Hoechle, 2007); both estimators are well suited for panels characterized by CSD, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation6.

    6We point out to the reader that the results obtained with the two estimators are almost identical. In particular, the estimated β value using the xtscc package was equal to 0.581, with a p-value > 0.

    We can get more information about the stability of the long-run relationship between ln(EMPL) and ln(GDP) by performing a dynamic analysis of an autoregressive distributed lag model (ARDL), reparameterized into error correction model (ECM) representation. In our case, a general ARDL(p, q) model can be written as follows:

    ln(EMPLt)=μ+pj=1ajln(EMPLtj)+qj=0bjln(GDPtj)+εt (3)

    with the corresponding ECM representation given by the following reparameterization:

    Δln(EMPLit)=μ+p1j=1αjΔln(EMPLtj)+q1i=0βjΔln(GDPiti)+π[ln(EMPLt1)+γLn(GDPit1)]+εit (4)

    where π=(1pj=1aj), and γ=(qj=0βj)/π.

    As to the choice of the optimal lag length, the comparison of the AIC, SC and HQ criteria suggest to choose an ARDL(4, 1) model.

    Our ECM is then described by the following equation:

    ln(EMPLt)=μ+4j=1ajln(EMPLtj)+b0ln(GDPt)+b1ln(GDPt1)+εit (5)

    which admits the following ECM representation:

    Δln(EMPLit)=3J=1αjΔln(EMPLtj)+β0Δln(GDPt)+π[ln(EMPLt1)+γLn(GDPit1)]+εit (6)

    where π is the adjustment (feedback) parameter speed and γ represents the long-run estimate of the elasticity of the employment to GDP.

    In order to estimate Equation (5) (or Equation (6)) we have relied on the cross-sectional augmented ARDL estimator (CS-ARDL) which, once again, is robust againsts the presence of CSD7. The following table sums up the main findings of our analysis.

    7We used the Stata package xtdcce2: see Dizten (2018).

    As is evident from Table 5 and Table 6, the estimated value of the long-run employment intensity of growth was about 0.55%, implying that an increase of 1.8% of real GDP leads to an increase of about 1% in employment level. It should be noted that this result is consistent with the one found by ECB (2016), for the period ranging 1999–2016, and it is not very far from the estimated values found for other countries (see, for instance, Padalino and Vivarelli, 1997, for the USA economy, and Boltho and Glyin, 1995, for a set of OECD—Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development member countries). As to the error correction coefficient π, it has the expected (negative) sign and a value between -1 and 0, implying a stable adjustment mechanism, even if its small magnitude indicates a slow adjustment speed to the long-run equilibrium.

    Table 5.  EGLS (cross-sectional SUR).
    Ln (EMPL) Coef. Std. Err t P > |t| 95% CI
    Low High
    Ln (GDP) 0.579771 0.003260 177.8535 0.000 0.573 0.586
    const −0.352269 0.034924 −10.0867 0.000 −0.420 −0.283
    Weighted Statistics
    R-squared 0.999 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000
    Adj R-squared 0.999 Durbin-Watson 2.047
    S.E. of regression 1.024 Pesaran CD test 0.991
    F-statistic 1080919

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Table 6.  (Dynamic) Common correlated effects estimator-(CS-ARDL).
    ΔLn(EMPL) Coefficient Std. Errors z P > |z|
    Ln (EMPLt-1) 0.8977 0.0889 10.10 0.000
    Ln (EMPLt-2) −0.2893 0.1159 −2.49 0.013
    Ln (EMPLt-3) 0.1911 0.0866 2.20 0.027
    Ln (EMPLt-4) −0.026 0.0600 −0.43 0.664
    Ln (GDP) 0.3071 0.0810 3.79 0.000
    Ln (GDPt-1) 0.1154 0.0444 2.60 0.019
    π −0.2264 0.0633 −3.58 0.000
    γ 0.5478 0.0048 112.67 0.000
    F (200, 140) 2.18e+06 R-squared (MG) 0.89
    Prob > F 0.000 Pesaran CD test 0.8708

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    As we have said, we have further extended the analysis in order to capture the effects of GDP variations on the employment level in those sectors more related to tourism activities. Accordingly, the model that we have estimated is the following one:

    Δln(EMPLCOMMt)=α+β1Δln(GDPt)+β2Δln(EMPLSERVt)+β3Δln(EMPLINDt)+εt (7)

    The two relevant results of this last regression (see Table 7) are represented by a) the value of β1, which is not so far from the estimated value of the elasticity of total employment to GDP, and b) the negative signs of β2 and β3, which are respectively the parameters that capture the relationship between employment in service (EMPL_SERV) and non-service sectors (EMPL_IND) with that in the commerce, accommodation and food services sector (EMPL_COMM). The first finding may be simply explained by considering that the ratio of commerce, accommodation, and food services employment to total employment in the period under consideration has been characterized by small oscillations around 0.18%, after which point it has been almost stable. The second result, i.e., that a variation of 1 point in the growth rate of EMPL_IND or in the growth rate of EMPL_SERV would cause, respectively, a variation in the opposite direction of 0.15 and of 0.44 points in the growth rate of EMPL_COMM, is very interesting since it highlights at least two important related aspects of the Italian labor market First, the progressive tertiarization of the Italian economy; secondly, a possible phenomenon of re-employment of workers—forced out of the primary and secondary sectors and in the tertiary sector (with particular regard to those economic activities more related to tourism services).

    Table 7.  EGLS (cross-section SUR).
    ΔLn (EMPL_COMM) Coef. Std. Err t P > |t| 95% CI
    Low High
    ΔLn (GDP) 0.6418 0.0152 41.99 0.000 0.6022 0.6813
    ΔLn(EMPL_SER) −0.4472 0.009 −48.498 0.000 −0.4711 −0.4233
    ΔLn(EMPL_IND) −0.1526 0.0104 −14.590 0.000 −0.1797 −0.338
    const 0.0044 0.0003 13.224 0.000 0.003 0.1255
    Weighted Statistics
    R-squared 0.9033 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000
    Adj R-squared 0.8980 Durbin-Watson 2.16
    S.E. of regression 1.026 Pesaran CD test 0.999
    F-statistic 168.6806

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The analysis we have performed so far suggests that economic growth is the key element to fostering the Italian tourism industry, while tourism does not have a relevant impact on the Italian economic growth.

    These results are in line with a part of the literature that focus on Italian data. For example, Massidda and Mattana (2012) for the long run, Shahbaz et al. (2017) and Dogru and Bulut (2018) confirmed a weak feedback hypothesis for inbound tourism in Italy. Of course, every comparison one tries to do with previous works focused on Italian data should consider that most of them analyzed international tourism. Furthermore, the causality linkages between economic growth and tourism development are not stable over time, mainly due to structural changes in the time series (e.g., Antonakakis et al., 2015; Shahbaz et al., 2017). If we consider the relevant effect of PGDP growth on TOS growth jointly with the small opposite effect, we should be more likely to confirm an EDTG hypothesis, which was also found for Italy (once again for inbound tourism) by Aslan (2013), and, for the short run, also by Massidda and Mattana (2012). Furthermore, the results obtained at the sub-national level do not provide information about the relationship between economic growth and tourism that is easy to compare to our results. For example, Centinaio et al. (2022) neither confirmed the TLEG nor EDTG hypothesis for many of the largest and richest Italian provinces, justifying this result with the decreasing marginal contribution of tourism to economic growth over a certain threshold of development. In addition, they confirmed the existence of a univocal or bi-univocal relationship between tourism and economic growth only in 35 out of 107 Italian provinces. Therefore, it is quite evident that sub-national data may provide a more detailed framework, but there is a need for more extended time series. Nevertheless, their analysis has the value of being a starting point for future research.

    About the interpretation of our results, the first partial explanation of the impact of GDP on TOS may be based on a dynamical version of the Keynesian theory of consumption demand. Since we considered both domestic and foreign demand for tourism services, the positive relationship we have found between GDPgrt-1 and TOSgrt could simply indicate that an increase in the past value of GDP causes an increase in current domestic consumption, and also in current domestic demand for tourism services. Furthermore, as far as the inbound tourism is concerned, the positive effect of GDP growth on the growth of foreign tourists may be explained, as has been pointed out, by the fact that "the development of a country is due to good economic policies and governmental investments in both fixed and human capitals. They create a trustworthy climate and culture which encourage the foreign tourist arrivals" (Chirilă et al., 2020).

    However, the point of interest is that, as we have seen, the increase in both domestic and foreign tourist demand is not sufficient to cause an opposite effective multiplicative effect, i.e., from TOSgrt-1 to GDPgrt, in light of the small estimated value of α21, which, moreover, according to the two-step GMM estimator, would not be significant even at the 10% significance level (see Table 2 above).

    The analysis of the employment-GDP relationship has confirmed the impact of economic growth on tourism development previously highlighted by the Granger causality and PVAR analysis. Our results show that economic growth stimulates an increase in the commerce, accommodation and food services sector's employment rate that is in line with the employment intensity of growth for the whole economy. Furthermore, the negative relationship between the employed in the primary and secondary sectors and those in the sector most representative of tourism (commerce, accommodation and food services) confirms the tendency of the tourism sector to attract a workforce that the primary and secondary sectors are not able to absorb. This latter result makes sense in consideration of the economy's tertiarization process and the tourism sector's development related to economic growth.

    What our analysis seems to suggest is that the tourism sector in Italy is not strong enough to have an effective impact on economic growth. Indirectly, we can also find corroboration of our results by looking at the tourism sector's share of GDP. According to the United Nations World Tourism Organization (UNWTO) data, Italy is the third most visited European tourist destination after France and Spain; however, the tourism sector's contribution to the Italian GDP was around 6% in 2018, while it was around 7% and 12%, respectively, for France and Spain.

    We maintain that these findings are strongly consistent with the dynamic evolution of the Italian economy. In a country that, in the last 20 years, has experienced a long recessionary phase, jumping from one economic crisis to another, one cannot think to boost economic growth by simply relying on tourism sector expansion or by simply counting on the fact that the employment in tourism sector may replace the job losses in the primary and secondary economic sectors. In the presence of path dependence (Arthur, 1994), the effects of such a long recession, i.e., in terms of the deterioration of human capital, a decrease in labor productivity and the related loss of competitiveness, an increase in the unemployment rate (about 10% in 2019), etc., require stronger policies that may reverse the economic course of the country.

    Here, we come to the opportunity offered by the Next-Generation EU program, which is a recovery plan agreed upon by the European Council to support European countries hit by the COVID-19 pandemic, which allocated about 205 billion euros to Italy to be spent over the period of 2021–2026 (see Italian Government, 2021).

    If the Italian federal economic policies were to hit the target of increasing GDP—for instance, by increasing labor productivity through the promotion of enterprise innovations and human capital accumulation, one would expect to find the following in the coming years: from one side, an increase in the employment rate in both primary, secondary and tertiary sectors (i.e., reversing the negative sign of ΔEMPLCOMMΔEMPLINDEMPLINDEMPLCOMM%)), and, on the other side, a bidirectional causality between GDP and TOS, meaning that tourism has become a leading sector in Italy. After all, the significant estimated magnitude of the (average) employment intensity of growth, which we have found in the previous section above, indicates that there is room for a stronger increase in the employment rate.

    All authors declare no conflict of interest regarding this study.



    [1] Abonazel MR (2016) Bias correction methods for dynamic panel data models with fixed effects. Available from: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/70628/
    [2] Abrigo MRM, Love I (2016) Estimation of Panel Vector Autoregression in Stata. 16: 778–804. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X1601600314
    [3] Antonakakis N, Dragouni M, Eeckels B (2019) The tourism and economic growth enigma: examining an ambiguous relationship through multiple prisms. J Travel Res 58: 3–24. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047287517744671 doi: 10.1177/0047287517744671
    [4] Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58: 277–297. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297968 doi: 10.2307/2297968
    [5] Arthur BW (1994) Increasing returns and Path Dependence in the Economy. University of Michigan Press. https://doi.org/10.3998/mpub.10029
    [6] Aslan A (2013) Tourism development and economic growth in the Mediterranean countries: evidence from panel Granger causality tests. Curr Issues Tour 17: 363–372. https://doi.org/10.1080/13683500.2013.768607 doi: 10.1080/13683500.2013.768607
    [7] Balaguer J, Cantavella-Jordà M (2002) Tourism as a long-run economic growth factor: the Spanish case. Appl Econ 34: 877–884. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036840110058923 doi: 10.1080/00036840110058923
    [8] Baum CF, Schaffer ME, Stillman S (2003) Instrumental variables and GMM: Estimation and testing. Stata J 3: 1–31. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X0300300101 doi: 10.1177/1536867X0300300101
    [9] Boltho A, Glyn A (1995) Can Macroeconomic Policies Raise Employment? Int Labour Rev 134: 451–470.
    [10] Breitung J, Das S (2005) Panel unit root tests under cross-sectional dependence. Stat Neerl 59: 414–433. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9574.2005.00299.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9574.2005.00299.x
    [11] Brida J, Cortes-Jimenez I, Pulina M (2016) Has the tourism-led growth hypothesis been validated? A literature review. Curr Issues Tour 19: 394–430. https://doi.org/10.1080/13683500.2013.868414 doi: 10.1080/13683500.2013.868414
    [12] Busetti F, Cova P (2013) L'impatto macroeconomico della crisi del debito sovrano: un'analisi controfattuale per l'economia italiana. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2405442
    [13] Cardenas-Garcia PJ, Sanchez-Rivero M, Pulido-Fernandez JI (2015) Does Tourism Growth Influence Economic Development? J Travel Res 54: 206–221. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047287513514297 doi: 10.1177/0047287513514297
    [14] Centinaio A, Comerio N, Pacicco F (2022) Arrivederci! An Analysis of Tourism Impact in the Italian Provinces. Int J Hosp Tour Adm. https://doi.org/10.1080/15256480.2021.2025187 doi: 10.1080/15256480.2021.2025187
    [15] Chen CF, Chiou-Wei SZ (2009) Tourism Expansion, Tourism Uncertainty and Economic Growth: New Evidence from Taiwan and Korea. Tourism Manage 30: 812–818. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2008.12.013 doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2008.12.013
    [16] Chirilă V, Butnaru GI, Chirilă C (2020) Spillover Index Approach in Investigating the Linkage between International Tourism and Economic Growth in Central and Eastern European Countries. Sustainability 12: 1–36. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12187604 doi: 10.3390/su12187604
    [17] Chiu YB, Yeh LT (2017) The threshold effects of the tourism-led growth hypothesis: evidence from a cross-sectional model. J Travel Res 56: 625–637. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047287516650938 doi: 10.1177/0047287516650938
    [18] Choi I (2001) Unit root tests for panel data. J Int Money Financ 20: 249–272. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0261-5606(00)00048-6 doi: 10.1016/S0261-5606(00)00048-6
    [19] Cortés-Jiménez J (2008) Which type of tourism matters to the regional economic growth? The cases of Spain and Italy. Int J Tour Res 10: 127–139. https://doi.org/10.1002/jtr.646 doi: 10.1002/jtr.646
    [20] Cortes-Jimenez J, Pulin M (2010) Inbound tourism and long-run economic growth. Curr Issues Tour 13: 61–74. https://doi.org/10.1080/13683500802684411 doi: 10.1080/13683500802684411
    [21] Crivelli E, Furceri D, Toujas-Bernaté J (2012) Can policies affect employment intensity of growth? A cross-country analysis. Available from: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12218.pdf.
    [22] Ditzen J (2018) Estimating dynamic common correlated effects in Stata. Stata J 18: 585–617. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X1801800306 doi: 10.1177/1536867X1801800306
    [23] Dogru T, Bulut U (2018) Is tourism an engine for economic recovery? Theory and empirical evidence. Tour Manag 67: 425–434. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2017.06.014 doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2017.06.014
    [24] Dumitrescu EI, Hurlin C (2012) Testing for Granger non-causality in heterogeneous panels. Econ Model 29: 1450–1460. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2012.02.014 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2012.02.014
    [25] ECB (2016) The employment-GDP relationship since the crisis. Available from: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/eb201606_article01.en.pdf.
    [26] Eugenio-Martin JL, Morales NM, Scarpa R (2004) Tourism and Economic Growth in Latin American Countries: A Panel Data Approach. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=504482.
    [27] Fonseca N, Sanchez-Rivero M (2019) Publication bias and genuine effects: the case of Granger causality between tourism and income. Curr Issues Tour 23: 1084–1108 https://doi.org/10.1080/13683500.2019.1585419 doi: 10.1080/13683500.2019.1585419
    [28] Hadri K (2000) Testing for stationarity in heterogeneous panel data. Economet J 3: 148–161. https://doi.org/10.1111/1368-423X.00043 doi: 10.1111/1368-423X.00043
    [29] Hoechle D (2007) Robust standard errors for panel regressions with cross-sectional dependence. Stata J 7: 281–312. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X0700700301 doi: 10.1177/1536867X0700700301
    [30] Hwang J, Sun Y (2018) Should we go one-step further? An accurate comparison of one-step and two-step procedures in a generalized method of moments framework. J Econom 207: 381–405. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2018.07.006 doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2018.07.006
    [31] Italian Government (2021) Recovery and resilience Plan. Available from: https://www.governo.it/sites/governo.it/files/PNRR.pdf.
    [32] Ivanov SH, Webster C (2013) Tourism's contribution to economic growth: a global analysis for the first decade of the millennium. Tourism Econ 19: 477–508. doi: 10.5367/te.2013.0211
    [33] Labra R, Torrecillas C (2018) Estimating dynamic Panel data. A practicalapproach to perform long panels. Revista Colombiana de Estadística 41: 31–52. https://doi.org/10.15446/rce.v41n1.61885 doi: 10.15446/rce.v41n1.61885
    [34] Levin A, Lin CF, Chu CSJ (2002) Unit root test in panel data: asymptotic and finite sample properties. J Econom 108: 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(01)00098-7 doi: 10.1016/S0304-4076(01)00098-7
    [35] Massidda C, Mattana P (2012) A SVECM Analysis of the relationship between international tourism arrivals, GDP and trade in Italy. J Travel Res 52: 93–105. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047287512457262 doi: 10.1177/0047287512457262
    [36] Mehrhoff J (2009) A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2785360
    [37] Pablo-Romero M, Molina J (2013) Tourism and economic growth: A review of empirical literature. Tour Manag Perspect 8: 28–41. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tmp.2013.05.006 doi: 10.1016/j.tmp.2013.05.006
    [38] Padalino S, Vivarelli M (1997) The Employment Intensity of Economic Growth in the G-7 Countries. Int Labour Rev 136: 191–213.
    [39] Pesaran H (2003) A Simple Panel Unit Root Test in the Presence of Cross Section Dependence. J Appl Economet 22: 265–312. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.951 doi: 10.1002/jae.951
    [40] Proença S, Soukiazis E (2008) Tourism as an economic growth factor: a case study for Southern European countries. Tourism Econ 14: 791–806. https://doi.org/10.5367/000000008786440175 doi: 10.5367/000000008786440175
    [41] Roodman D (2009) How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM. Stata J 9: 86–136. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X0900900106 doi: 10.1177/1536867X0900900106
    [42] Sharpley R (2022) Tourism and (sustainable) development: Revisiting the theoretical divide. Tourism in Development: reflective essays, 13–24. https://doi.org/10.1079/9781789242812.000 doi: 10.1079/9781789242812.000
    [43] Sigmund M, Ferstl R (2019) Panel vector Autoregression in R with the packagepanelvar. Q Rev Econ Financ 80: 693–720. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2019.01.001 doi: 10.1016/j.qref.2019.01.001
    [44] Shahbaz M, Ferrer R, Shahzad SJH, et al. (2017) Is the tourism–economic growth nexus time-varying? Bootstrap rolling-window causality analysis for the top 10 tourist destinations. Appl Econ. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2017.1406655 doi: 10.1080/00036846.2017.1406655
    [45] Shahzad SJH, Shahbaz M, Ferrer R, et al. (2017) Tourism-led growth hypothesis in the top ten tourist destinations: new evidence using the quantile-on-quantile approach. Tourism Manage 60: 223–232. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2016.12.006 doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2016.12.006
    [46] SVIMEZ (2019) Rapporto SVIMEZ 2019, Rome.
    [47] Tugcu CT (2014) Tourism and economic growth nexus revisited: A panel causality analysis for the case of the Mediterranean region. Tourism Manage 42: 207–212. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2013.12.007 doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2013.12.007
    [48] Vergori AS (2017) Patterns of seasonality and tourism demand forecasting. Tourism Econ 23: 1011–1027. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2020.104263 doi: 10.1177/1354816616656418
    [49] Zellner A (1962) An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for aggregation bias. J Am Stat Assoc 57: 348–368. doi: 10.1080/01621459.1962.10480664
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Giorgio Colacchio, Anna Serena Vergori, Tourism Development and Italian Economic Growth: The Weight of the Regional Economies, 2023, 16, 1911-8074, 245, 10.3390/jrfm16040245
    2. Bianca Biagi, Hasan Engìn Duran, Manuela Pulina, Is tourism specialisation a trap for economic growth? The case of the Italian regions, 2024, 1368-3500, 1, 10.1080/13683500.2024.2411706
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2022 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1779) PDF downloads(120) Cited by(2)

Figures and Tables

Figures(1)  /  Tables(7)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog