Research article

Climate-mediated activity of the Javan Slow Loris, Nycticebus javanicus

  • Joint impacts of anthropogenic disturbance and climate change are of pressing concern for modern conservationists. Climate change patterns have various diminishing effects on the biodiversity of an ecosystem, requiring an understanding of a species’ ability to adapt. Agricultural practices are expanding at an altitudinal gradient on the Indonesian island of Java, forcing endemic species to range at increased elevation with lower temperatures, and in human-populated areas. One example is the Critically Endangered Javan slow loris (Nycticebus javanicus), which finds itself increasingly restricted to montane regions with extreme climate patterns and habitat disturbance. We observed wild N. javanicus in a highly fragmented, montane agroforest area to determine if climate variables and forest connectivity influence activity budget and behavior. Lorises ranged at different altitudes (1275 m above sea level (asl)—1570 m asl) and were observed for six months in Cipaganti, West Java. Using multinomial regression analyses, we found loris individuals were most likely to engage in increased foraging, feeding and travelling behavior than resting when relative humidity increases and in habitats with greater forest connectivity. Regression analyses found effects of relative humidity and forest connectivity to be the most significant predictors of N. javanicus foraging behavior (P = 0.001, P = 0.030). We suggest that future-climate shifts and increased anthropogenic disturbance will detrimentally influence wild populations of N. javanicus, requiring immediate plans for mitigation in conserving these already scarce wild populations. We also suggest the altering of reintroduction protocols in relation to climate and geographic region.

    Citation: Kathleen D Reinhardt, Wirdateti, K.AI. Nekaris. Climate-mediated activity of the Javan Slow Loris, Nycticebus javanicus[J]. AIMS Environmental Science, 2016, 3(2): 249-260. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2016.2.249

    Related Papers:

    [1] Ryo Kinoshita, Sung-mok Jung, Tetsuro Kobayashi, Andrei R. Akhmetzhanov, Hiroshi Nishiura . Epidemiology of coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) in Japan during the first and second waves. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(6): 6088-6101. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022284
    [2] Pannathon Kreabkhontho, Watchara Teparos, Thitiya Theparod . Potential for eliminating COVID-19 in Thailand through third-dose vaccination: A modeling approach. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2024, 21(8): 6807-6828. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2024298
    [3] Weike Zhou, Aili Wang, Fan Xia, Yanni Xiao, Sanyi Tang . Effects of media reporting on mitigating spread of COVID-19 in the early phase of the outbreak. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(3): 2693-2707. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020147
    [4] Sarafa A. Iyaniwura, Musa Rabiu, Jummy F. David, Jude D. Kong . Assessing the impact of adherence to Non-pharmaceutical interventions and indirect transmission on the dynamics of COVID-19: a mathematical modelling study. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(6): 8905-8932. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021439
    [5] Jiangbo Hao, Lirong Huang, Maoxing Liu, Yangjun Ma . Analysis of the COVID-19 model with self-protection and isolation measures affected by the environment. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2024, 21(4): 4835-4852. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2024213
    [6] Hao Wang, Di Zhu, Shiqi Li, Robert A. Cheke, Sanyi Tang, Weike Zhou . Home quarantine or centralized quarantine? A mathematical modelling study on the COVID-19 epidemic in Guangzhou in 2021. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(9): 9060-9078. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022421
    [7] Hamdy M. Youssef, Najat A. Alghamdi, Magdy A. Ezzat, Alaa A. El-Bary, Ahmed M. Shawky . A new dynamical modeling SEIR with global analysis applied to the real data of spreading COVID-19 in Saudi Arabia. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(6): 7018-7044. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020362
    [8] Liping Wang, Jing Wang, Hongyong Zhao, Yangyang Shi, Kai Wang, Peng Wu, Lei Shi . Modelling and assessing the effects of medical resources on transmission of novel coronavirus (COVID-19) in Wuhan, China. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(4): 2936-2949. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020165
    [9] Yong Zhou, Minrui Guo . Isolation in the control of epidemic. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(11): 10846-10863. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022507
    [10] Abdallah Alsammani, Calistus N. Ngonghala, Maia Martcheva . Impact of vaccination behavior on COVID-19 dynamics and economic outcomes. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2025, 22(9): 2300-2338. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2025084
  • Joint impacts of anthropogenic disturbance and climate change are of pressing concern for modern conservationists. Climate change patterns have various diminishing effects on the biodiversity of an ecosystem, requiring an understanding of a species’ ability to adapt. Agricultural practices are expanding at an altitudinal gradient on the Indonesian island of Java, forcing endemic species to range at increased elevation with lower temperatures, and in human-populated areas. One example is the Critically Endangered Javan slow loris (Nycticebus javanicus), which finds itself increasingly restricted to montane regions with extreme climate patterns and habitat disturbance. We observed wild N. javanicus in a highly fragmented, montane agroforest area to determine if climate variables and forest connectivity influence activity budget and behavior. Lorises ranged at different altitudes (1275 m above sea level (asl)—1570 m asl) and were observed for six months in Cipaganti, West Java. Using multinomial regression analyses, we found loris individuals were most likely to engage in increased foraging, feeding and travelling behavior than resting when relative humidity increases and in habitats with greater forest connectivity. Regression analyses found effects of relative humidity and forest connectivity to be the most significant predictors of N. javanicus foraging behavior (P = 0.001, P = 0.030). We suggest that future-climate shifts and increased anthropogenic disturbance will detrimentally influence wild populations of N. javanicus, requiring immediate plans for mitigation in conserving these already scarce wild populations. We also suggest the altering of reintroduction protocols in relation to climate and geographic region.


    In the evolutionary history of natural communities, ecological competition has justifiably been a significant force, which consists of exploitation and interference [1,2,3]. In consequence, there has been increasing studies for consumer-resource competitive models by dynamical systems theory [4,5,6,7]. Mathematically, Gopalsamy [8] developed the following resource-based competition model.

    $ {dxdt=x(t)[bax(t)a1z1(t)a2z2(t)],dz1dt=z1(t)[b1x(t)β1z1(t)μ1z2(t)],dz2dt=z2(t)[b2x(t)β2z2(t)μ2z1(t)],
    $
    (1.1)

    where $ x(t) $ represents the density of a logistically self-renewing resource at time $ t $, $ z_{1}(t) $ and $ z_{2}(t) $ represent the densities at time $ t $ of two species which feed on this resource alone.

    For a population individual, its whole life history generally includes two or more stages, particularly, mammals show two different stages of immaturity and maturity [9,10,11]. Moreover, it takes some time from birth to adulthood which is considered as the maturity time delay. Thus, the competition models and stage structure population models with constant maturity delays have been studied. For example, the two-species competition model and stage-structured single population model established in [12,13] respectively have a constant maturity delay.

    Later, people noticed the biological fact about the maturity time of Antarctic whales and seals around the Second World War. Subsequent to the introduction of factory ships and with it a depletion of the large whale population, there has been a substantial increase in krill for seals and whales. It was then noted that seals took 3 to 4 years to mature and small whales only took 5 years [14]. Hence, their maturation time varies with the number of krill available, which implies that the maturity time delay is state-dependent, not a constant.

    Due to this, Aiello and Freedman [15] formulated the following stage-structured state-dependent delay model, in which the delay $ \tau(z(t)) $ is a bounded increasing function of the total population $ z(t) = x(t)+y(t) $.

    $ {dx(t)dt=αy(t)γx(t)αy(tτ(z(t)))eγτ(z(t)),dy(t)dt=αy(tτ(z(t)))eγτ(z(t))βy2(t).
    $

    Subsequently, the stage-structured and competitive models with state-dependent delays were developed [16,17,18,19,20,21,22,23,24,25,26]. In 2017, Lv and Yuan [27] proposed the competitive model with state-dependent delays:

    $ {dz1dt=b1z1(tτ(z1))eγ1τ(z1)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dz2dt=b2z2(tτ(z2))eγ2τ(z2)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t),
    $

    where the delays $ \tau(z_{i}(t)) $ are bounded increasing functions of the populations $ z_{i}(t) $, $ i = 1, 2 $, respectively.

    It is obvious that the above-mentioned models with state-dependent delays straight change the constant delays into the state-dependent delays, which is not appropriate to population modeling. Therefore, Wang, Liu and Wei [28] proposed the following new single population model with a state-dependent delay and a correction factor.

    $ {dx(t)dt=αy(t)γx(t)α[1τ(z(t))˙z(t)]y(tτ(z(t)))eγτ(z(t)),dy(t)dt=α[1τ(z(t))˙z(t)]y(tτ(z(t)))eγτ(z(t))βy2(t),
    $

    where the delay $ \tau(z(t)) $ is a function of the total population $ z(t) = x(t)+y(t) $.

    However, the aforementioned state-dependent delays are functions of populations, not resources. A worthwhile thought is how to reflect the direct relationship between the resources and maturity time? In view of the biological background above, the time varies with the resources available, that is, the species must spend enough time in the immature stage to accumulate a certain amount of food to reach maturity. To address the question raised above, we consider a stage-structured consumer-resource competition model with a state-dependent maturity time delay, in which the delay involves a correction term, $ 1-\tau'(x)x'(t) $, related to resource changes.

    The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we formulate a resource-based competition model with a state-dependent maturity delay. In section 3, we study the well-posedness properties for the model and prove the existence and uniqueness of all equilibria. In section 4, we analyze the local stabilities of equilibria. In section 5, we discuss the global behaviors of the coexistence equilibrium. Finally, section 6 gives the conclusions of the paper.

    Based on model (1.1), we will formulate the competition model with a state-dependent maturity delay. For each $ i = 1, 2 $, let $ y_{i}(t) $ and $ z_{i}(t) $ be the densities at time $ t $ of the immature and mature consumer species, respectively. Let $ x(t) $ be the density at time $ t $ of a logistically self-renewing resource which is necessary for two consumer species. Motivated by [28,29,30,31], we introduce a threshold age $ \tau (x(t)) $ to distinguish the immature and mature individuals, which depends on the density of the same resource. Suppose that $ \rho_{i}(t, a) $ is the population density of age $ a $ at time $ t $, then the densities of $ y_{i}(t) $ and $ z_{i}(t) $, respectively, are given by

    $ yi(t)=τ(x(t))0ρi(t,a)daandzi(t)=τ(x(t))ρi(t,a)da.
    $

    By virtue of [32,33], we have the following age structure partial differential equations to represent the development of the consumer species.

    $ ρ1(t,a)t+ρ1(t,a)a=γ1ρ1(t,a),ifaτ(x(t)),ρ1(t,a)t+ρ1(t,a)a=(β1z1(t)+μ1z2(t))ρ1(t,a),ifa>τ(x(t)),ρ2(t,a)t+ρ2(t,a)a=γ2ρ2(t,a),ifaτ(x(t)),ρ2(t,a)t+ρ2(t,a)a=(β2z2(t)+μ2z1(t))ρ2(t,a),ifa>τ(x(t)).
    $
    (2.1)

    We suppose that $ y_{1}(t) $ and $ y_{2}(t) $ die at the constant rate $ \gamma_{i} $ ($ i = 1, 2 $). The parameters $ \beta_{i} $ ($ i = 1, 2 $) represent the mature natural death and overcrowding rate for $ z_{i}(t) $, respectively. The parameters $ \mu_{i} $ ($ i = 1, 2 $) represent interspecific competition for $ z_{i}(t) $, respectively.

    Taking the derivatives of $ y_{i}(t) $ and $ z_{i}(t) $, respectively, and combining system (2.1), it then follows that

    $ dy1(t)dt=ρ1(t,0)γ1y1(t)[1τ(x)x(t)]ρ1(t,τ(x(t))),dz1(t)dt=[1τ(x)x(t)]ρ1(t,τ(x(t)))ρ1(t,)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dy2(t)dt=ρ2(t,0)γ2y2(t)[1τ(x)x(t)]ρ2(t,τ(x(t))),dz2(t)dt=[1τ(x)x(t)]ρ2(t,τ(x(t)))ρ2(t,)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t).
    $

    Note that the two primes refer to differentiation with respect to $ x $ and time $ t $, respectively, namely, $ \dot{\tau}(x(t)) = d\tau(x(t))/dt = \tau'(x)x'(t) $.

    Because of the finitude of individual life span, $ \rho_{i}(t, \infty) $ is considered as zero. Assume that the immature consumers' functional response is Holling type I, that is, $ b_{i}x(t) $, then the term $ \rho_{i}(t, 0) = b_{i} x(t)z_{i}(t) $ represents the number of immature individuals born at time $ t $. Therefore, for $ t\geq \tilde{\tau} = \max\{\tau(x(t))\} $, we have

    $ ρi(t,τ(x(t)))=ρi(tτ(x(t)),0)=bix(tτ(x(t)))zi(tτ(x(t)))eγiτ(x(t)),i=1,2.
    $

    Consequently, we obtain the following stage-structured consumer-resource competition model with a state-dependent delay.

    $ {dxdt=rx(t)(1x(t)K)a1x(t)z1(t)a2x(t)z2(t),dy1dt=b1x(t)z1(t)b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)γ1y1(t),dz1dt=b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dy2dt=b2x(t)z2(t)b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)γ2y2(t),dz2dt=b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t),
    $
    (2.2)

    where $ r $ and $ K $ represent the growth rate of the resource and its carrying capacity, respectively. The parameters $ a_{1} $ and $ a_{2} $ represent the capture rate of $ z_{1} $ and $ z_{2} $, respectively. By [28], the inequality, $ 1-\tau'(x)x'(t) > 0 $, holds true, which implies that $ t-\tau(x(t))) $ is a strictly increasing function in $ t $. This shows that mature individuals become immature only by birth.

    For system (2.2), there are the following basic hypotheses:

    ($ \mathcal{A}_{1} $) The constant parameters $ r $, $ K $, $ a_{1} $, $ a_{2} $, $ b_{1} $, $ b_{2} $, $ \gamma_{1} $, $ \gamma_{2} $, $ \beta_{1} $, $ \beta_{2} $, $ \mu_{1} $, $ \mu_{2} $ are all positive;

    ($ \mathcal{A}_{2} $) The state-dependent time delay $ \tau(x) $ is a decreasing differentiable bounded function of the resource $ x $, where $ \tau'(x)\leq0 $, and $ 0\leq\tau_{m} \leq\tau(x)\leq\tau_{M} $ with $ \tau(+\infty) = \tau_{m} $, $ \tau(0) = \tau_{M} $.

    To simplify system (2.2), we can readily scale off $ r $ and $ K $ by proper rescaling of $ t $ and $ x $. Accordingly, system (2.2) becomes

    $ {dxdt=x(t)(1x(t)a1z1(t)a2z2(t)),dy1dt=b1x(t)z1(t)b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)γ1y1(t),dz1dt=b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dy2dt=b2x(t)z2(t)b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)γ2y2(t),dz2dt=b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t).
    $
    (2.3)

    In this paper, we will study the dynamics of system (2.3). The initial data for system (2.3) are

    $ x(s)=Υ(s)0,z1(s)=Φ1(s)0,y1(s)=Ψ1(s)0for all s[τM,0],z2(s)=Φ2(s)0,y2(s)=Ψ2(s)0for all s[τM,0],
    $

    with

    $ Ψ1(0)=0τ(x(0))b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1sdsandΨ2(0)=0τ(x(0))b2x(s)z2(s)eγ2sds,
    $

    which represent the number of immature consumers who survived to time $ t = 0 $.

    In this section, we first study the well-posedness properties of the solution for system (2.3) and then prove the existence and uniqueness of all equilibria.

    Theorem 3.1. Let $ \Upsilon(t) \geq0 $, $ \Phi_{1}(t)\geq0 $ and $ \Phi_{2}(t)\geq0 $ for $ -\tau_{M}\leq t\leq0 $, then the solution $ (x(t), y_{1}(t), z_{1}(t), y_{2}(t), z_{2}(t)) $ of system (2.3) is nonnegative and uniformly ultimate bounded for all $ t\geq 0 $.

    Proof. Consider the first equation in system (2.3).

    $ dxdt=x(t)(1x(t)a1z1(t)a2z2(t)),
    $

    with $ x(0) = \Upsilon(0)\geq0 $. Then

    $ x(t)=x(0)expt0[1x(s)a1z1(s)a2z2(s)]ds0,t0.
    $

    Suppose that there exists $ t > 0 $ such that $ z_{1}(t) = 0 $. Let $ t^{*} = \inf\{t: t > 0, z_{1}(t) = 0\} $, then

    $ z1(t)=b1[1τ(x(t))x(t)]x(tτ(x(t)))z1(tτ(x(t)))eγ1τ(x(t)).
    $

    Since $ \tau(x) > 0, $ $ 1-\tau'(x(t^{*}))x'(t^{*}) > 0 $, $ t^{*}-\tau(x(t^{*})) < t^{*} $, it follows from the definition of $ t^{*} $ that $ z_{1}(t^{*}-\tau(x(t^{*}))) > 0 $, which implies that $ z_{1}'(t^{*}) > 0 $ and is a contradiction. Therefore, there does not exist $ t^{*} $ and $ z_{1}(t) > 0 $ for all $ t > 0 $.

    Integrating the second equation of system (2.3), we have the following integral expression for $ y_{1}(t) $.

    $ y1(t)=eγ1t(Φ1(0)+t0b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1sdstτ(x(t))τ(x(0))b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1sds)=ttτ(x(t))b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1(ts)ds.
    $

    It is easy to see that $ y_{1}(t)\geq0 $ by the nonnegativity $ x(t) $, $ z_{1}(t) $ and $ \tau(x) $. In a similar way, we can prove the nonnegativity of $ z_{2}(t) $ and $ y_{2}(t) $. Hence, the solution $ (x(t), y_{1}(t), z_{1}(t), y_{2}(t), z_{2}(t)) $ of system (2.3) is nonnegative. Especially, when $ \Upsilon(0) > 0, \Psi_{1}(0) > 0, \Phi_{1}(0) > 0 $, the solution of system (2.3) is positive.

    Now we prove uniform ultimate boundedness of the solution. Define the following Lyapunov functional.

    $ V=(b1a1+b2a2)x(t)+z1(t)+z2(t)+ttτ(x(t))b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1(ts)ds+ttτ(x(t))b2x(s)z2(s)eγ2(ts)ds.
    $

    Calculating the time derivative of $ V(t) $ along the solutions of system (2.3), we have

    $ V(t)=(b1a1+b2a2)x(t)[1x(t)a1z1(t)a2z2(t)]+b1x(t)z1(t)+b2x(t)z2(t)γ1ttτ(x(t))b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1(ts)dsβ1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t)γ2ttτ(x(t))b2x(s)z2(s)eγ2(ts)dsβ2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t)<γV+(b1a1+b2a2)[(1+γ)x(t)x2(t)]+γz1(t)β1z21(t)+γz2(t)β2z22(t)γV+M1+M2+M3,
    $

    where $ \gamma = \min\{\gamma_{1}, \gamma_{2}\} $, $ M_{1} $, $ M_{2} $ and $ M_{3} $ are the maximum values of quadratic function $ (b_{1}/a_{1}+b_{2}/a_{2})[(1+\gamma)x(t)-x^{2}(t)] $, $ \gamma z_{1}(t)-\beta_{1} z_{1}^{2}(t) $ and $ \gamma z_{2}(t)-\beta_{2} z_{2}^{2}(t) $, respectively. Obviously, $ M_{1} $, $ M_{2} $ and $ M_{3} $ are positive. Thus, $ \limsup_{t\rightarrow\infty}V(t)\leq (M_{1}+M_{2}+M_{3})/\gamma $ and the solution of system (3.1) is uniformly ultimate bounded. It then follows that the solution of system (2.3) is uniformly ultimate bounded.

    Since variables $ y_{1}(t) $ and $ y_{2}(t) $ of system (2.3) are decoupled from the other equations, we study the following reduced system:

    $ {dxdt=x(t)(1x(t))a1x(t)z1(t)a2x(t)z2(t),dz1dt=b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dz2dt=b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t).
    $
    (3.1)

    In the rest of this section, we will discuss the existence and patterns of equilibria $ (x, z_{1}, z_{2}) $ of system (3.1). The equilibria satisfy the following equations:

    $ {x(1xa1z1a2z2)=0,b1xz1eγ1τ(x)β1z21μ1z1z2=0,b2xz2eγ2τ(x)β2z22μ2z1z2=0.
    $
    (3.2)

    It is easy to see that system (3.1) has one trivial equilibrium $ E_{0} = (0, 0, 0) $ and one semitrivial equilibrium $ E_{1} = (1, 0, 0) $. And we obtain the following result for nontrivial equilibria.

    Theorem 3.2. System (3.1) has exactly two semitrivial equilibria $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $ and $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $. Assume that

    $ min{β1μ2,μ1β2}<b1eγ1τMb2eγ2τm<b1eγ1τmb2eγ2τM<max{β1μ2,μ1β2};min{β1μ1,μ2β2}<a1a2<max{β1μ1,μ2β2}.
    $
    (3.3)

    Then there exists unique coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $.

    Proof. There are three cases to prove the existence of nontrivial equilibria.

    Case 1 If $ z_{2} = 0 $, then Eq (3.2) reduces to

    $ {x(1xa1z1)=0,b1xz1eγ1τ(x)β1z21=0.
    $

    The inequality, $ z_{1} < b_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1}) $, is valid to make sure $ x = 1-a_{1}z_{1} > 0 $, $ y_{1} = \gamma_{1}^{-1}z_{1}(b_{1}-a_{1}b_{1}z_{1}-\beta_{1} z_{1}) > \; 0 $. Thus, we will investigate the existence and uniqueness of nontrivial equilibrium in $ \Lambda = \{z_{1}\in R\mid 0 < z_{1} < b_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1})\}\subset R $. Define $ f:\overline{\Lambda}\rightarrow R $ be a continuous mapping by

    $ f(z1)=b1(1a1z1)eγ1τ(1a1z1)β1z1.
    $

    Clearly, $ f(0) = b_{1} x e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1)} > 0 $, $ f(b_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1})) = b_{1}\beta_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1})[e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\beta_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1}))}-1] < 0 $, which implies that $ f(z_{1}) $ has at least one positive zero point $ \hat{z_{1}} $.

    Note that $ f'(\hat{z_{1}}) = -a_{1}b_{1} e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1-a_{1}\hat{z_{1}})}+a_{1}b_{1}\gamma_{1}(1-a_{1}\hat{z_{1}})e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1-a_{1}\hat{z_{1}})}\tau' (1-a_{1}\hat{z_{1}})-\beta_{1} < 0 $, it then follows that $ f(z_{1}) $ has a unique positive root in the interval $ (0, b_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1})) $. Hence, system (3.1) has a unique boundary equilibrium $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $.

    Case 2 If $ z_{1} = 0 $, then system (3.1) has a unique boundary equilibrium $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $ by similar arguments in the case 1.

    Case 3 If $ z_{1}\neq 0 $ and $ z_{2}\neq 0 $, then the coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $ satisfies the following equations:

    $ {1xa1z1a2z2=0,b1xeγ1τ(x)β1z1μ1z2=0,b2xeγ2τ(x)β2z2μ2z1=0.
    $
    (3.4)

    Solving Eq (3.4), we obtain that

    $ {x=11+a1Γ1+a2Γ2;z1=xΓ1,Γ1=β2b1eγ1τ(x)μ1b2eγ2τ(x)β1β2μ1μ2;z2=xΓ2,Γ2=β1b2eγ2τ(x)μ2b1eγ1τ(x)β1β2μ1μ2.
    $
    (3.5)

    In order to make sure the positivity of $ x^{*} $, $ z_{1}^{*} $ and $ z_{2}^{*} $, we get

    $ min{β1μ2,μ1β2}<b1eγ1τMb2eγ2τm<b1eγ1τ(x)b2eγ2τ(x)<b1eγ1τmb2eγ2τM<max{β1μ2,μ1β2}.
    $

    Now we prove the uniqueness of $ E^{*} $. Suppose that $ f(x) = 1-x-a_{1}z_{1}-a_{2}z_{2} $, combining Eq (3.5), we have

    $ f(x)=1xa1z1a2z2=1xxb1eγ1τ(x)a1β2a2μ2β1β2μ1μ2xb2eγ2τ(x)a2β1a1μ1β1β2μ1μ2=1xxf1(x)xf2(x),
    $

    where $ f_{1}(x) = b_{1}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(x)}(a_{1}\beta_{2}-a_{2}\mu_{2})/(\beta_{1}\beta_{2}-\mu_{1}\mu_{2}) $, $ f_{2}(x) = b_{2}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(x)}(a_{2}\beta_{1}-a_{1}\mu_{1})/(\beta_{1}\beta_{2}-\mu_{1}\mu_{2}) $.

    Obviously, $ f(0) = 1 > 0 $ and

    $ f(1) = \frac{-a_{1}\big(\beta_{2} b_{1}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1)}-\mu_{1}b_{2}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(1)}\big)-a_{2}\big(\beta_{1} b_{2}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(1)}-\mu_{2}b_{1}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1)}\big)}{\beta_{1}\beta_{2}-\mu_{1}\mu_{2}} \lt 0, $

    which implies that $ f(x) $ has at least one positive zero point $ x^{*} $.

    It follows from $ f_{1}(x^{*})+f_{2}(x^{*}) = 1/x^{*}-1 $ that

    $ f(x)=1[f1(x)+f2(x)]x[f1(x)+f2(x)]=1xx[f1(x)+f2(x)].
    $

    If $ \min\left\{\beta_{1}/\mu_{1}, \mu_{2}/\beta_{2}\right\} < a_{1}/a_{2} < \max\left\{\beta_{1}/\mu_{1}, \mu_{2}/\beta_{2}\right\} $, then $ f'(x^{*}) < 0 $. Thus, $ f(x) $ has a unique positive root $ x^{*} $ in the interval $ (0, 1) $, and system (3.1) has a unique coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $. This completes the proof.

    In this section, the linearized stability of equilibria will be studied. We utilize the method proposed by Cooke [34] to linearize system (3.1).

    Let $ \tilde{E} = (\tilde{x}, \tilde{z_{1}}, \tilde{z_{2}}) $ be an arbitrary equilibrium. Then the linearization of system (3.1) is

    $ {x(t)=Ax(t)a1˜xz1(t)a2˜xz2(t),z1(t)=A1x+b1eγ1τ(˜x)~z1x(tτ(˜x))+b1eγ1τ(˜x)˜xz1(tτ(˜x))+B1z1+C1z2,z2(t)=A2x+b2eγ2τ(˜x)~z2x(tτ(˜x))+b2eγ2τ(˜x)˜xz2(tτ(˜x))+B2z1+C2z2,
    $
    (4.1)

    where

    $ A=12˜xa1~z1a2~z2,A1=b1˜x~z1τ(˜x)eγ1τ(˜x)(γ1A),A2=b2˜x~z2τ(˜x)eγ2τ(˜x)(γ2A),B1=a1b1(˜x)2~z1τ(˜x)eγ1τ(˜x)2β1~z1μ1~z2,B2=a1b2(˜x)2~z2τ(˜x)eγ2τ(˜x)μ2~z2,C1=a2b1(˜x)2~z2τ(˜x)eγ1τ(˜x)μ1~z1,C2=a2b2(˜x)2~z2τ(˜x)eγ2τ(˜x)2β2~z2μ2~z1.
    $

    The corresponding characteristic equation of system (4.1) is as follows:

    $ \left| λAa1˜xa2˜xA1b1~z1e(γ1+λ)τ(˜x)λB1b1˜xe(γ1+λ)τ(˜x)C1A2b2~z2e(γ2+λ)τ(˜x)B2λC2b2˜xe(γ2+λ)τ(˜x)
    \right| = 0. $

    For the extinction equilibrium $ E_{0} = (0, 0, 0) $, it follows that $ A = 1, $ $ A_{1} = 0, $ $ B_{1} = 0, $ $ C_{1} = 0, $ $ A_{2} = 0, $ $ B_{2} = 0, $ $ C_{2} = 0 $, then $ (\lambda-1)\lambda^{2} = 0 $, and $ \lambda = 1 > 0 $ is one of these eigenvalues. Thus, we have the following result.

    Theorem 4.1. The extinction equilibrium $ E_{0} = (0, 0, 0) $ is unstable.

    For the trivial equilibrium $ E_{1} = (1, 0, 0) $, the characteristic equation is as follows.

    $ (λ+1)(λb1e(γ1+λ)τ(1))(λb2e(γ2+λ)τ(1))=0.
    $

    Obviously, $ \lambda = -1 < 0 $ is one of these eigenvalues. All the other eigenvalues $ \lambda $ satisfy the equations $ \lambda e^{\tau(1)(\gamma_{1}+\lambda)} = b_{1} > 0 $ and $ \lambda e^{\tau(1)(\gamma_{2}+\lambda)} = b_{2} > 0 $, which always have real, positive solutions. Hence, the conclusion about the linearized stability of $ E_{1} $ is as follows.

    Theorem 4.2. The trivial equilibrium $ E_{1} = (1, 0, 0) $ is a saddle point and unstable.

    In order to obtain the linearized stability of $ E_{2} $ and $ E_{3} $, we first give the results on the real positive roots of a quartic equation. Suppose that

    $ v4+K1v3+K2v2+K3v+K4=0.
    $
    (4.2)

    Let

    $ M=12K2316K21,N=132K3118K1K2+K3,Δ=(N2)3+(M2)3,σ=1+3i2,y1=3N2+Δ+3N2Δ,y2=σ3N2+Δ+σ23N2Δ,y3=σ23N2+Δ+σ3N2Δ,zi=yi3K14,i=1,2,3.
    $

    By virtue of [35], we have the following lemma.

    Lemma 4.3. The following statements hold true for Eq (4.2):

    (i) If $ K_{4} < 0 $, then Eq (4.2) has at least one positive root;

    (ii) If $ K_{4}\geq0 $ and $ \Delta\geq0 $, then Eq (4.2) has positive roots if and only if $ z_{1} > 0 $ and $ h(z_{1}) < 0 $;

    (iii) If $ K_{4}\geq0 $ and $ \Delta < 0 $, then Eq (4.2) has positive roots if and only if there exists at least one $ z^{*}\in\{z_{1}, z_{2}, z_{3}\} $ such that $ z^{*} > 0 $ and $ Q(z^{*})\leq0 $, where $ Q(z) = z^{4}+K_{1}z^{3}+K_{2}z^{2}+K_{3}z+K_{4} $.

    We are now in a position to prove the linearized stability of $ E_{2} $.

    Theorem 4.4. If $ \hat{z_{1}} < 3/(4a_{1}) $ and $ b_{1}\mu_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\hat{x})} > b_{2}\beta_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $, then the boundary equilibrium $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $ is locally asymptotically stable.

    Proof. The characteristic equation for the boundary equilibrium $ E_{2} $ is as follows:

    $ (λC2b2ˆxe(γ2+λ)τ(ˆx))[(λA)(λB1b1ˆxe(γ1+λ)τ(ˆx))+a1ˆx(A1+b1^z1e(γ1+λ)τ(ˆx))]=0.
    $
    (4.3)

    It is easy to see that some of the eigenvalues satisfy the following equation:

    $ λ+μ2^z1b2ˆxe(γ2+λ)τ(ˆx)=0.
    $
    (4.4)

    Claim. If $ b_{1}\mu_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\hat{x})} > b_{2}\beta_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $, that is, $ \hat{z_{1}} > \mu_{2}^{-1}b_{2}\hat{x}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $, then all eigenvalues of Eq (4.4) have negative real parts.

    Obviously, if $ \tau(\hat{x}) = 0 $, then Eq (4.4) has a unique negative real root $ \lambda = b_{2}\hat{x}-\mu_{2}\hat{z_{1}} < 0 $. In order to study whether any roots cross the imaginary axis, let $ \lambda = i\omega $ with $ \omega > 0 $ and substitute it into Eq (4.4), it follows from $ \hat{z_{1}} > \mu_{2}^{-1}b_{2}\hat{x}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $ that

    $ ω2=(b2ˆxeγ2τ(ˆx))2(μ2^z1)2<0.
    $

    Therefore, Eq (4.4) has no purely imaginary roots and each root has a negative real part.

    Other roots are given by equation:

    $ G(λ)=(λA)(λB1b1ˆxe(γ1+λ)τ(ˆx))+a1ˆx(A1+b1^z1e(γ1+λ)τ(ˆx))=λ2+H1λ+H2+(N1λ+N2)eλτ(ˆx)=0,
    $
    (4.5)

    where $ H_{1} = -A-B_{1}, $ $ H_{2} = AB_{1}+a_{1}A_{1} \hat{x}, $ $ N_{1} = -\beta_{1} \hat{z_{1}}, $ $ N_{2} = A\beta_{1} \hat{z_{1}}+a_{1}\beta_{1}\hat{z_{1}}^{2}. $

    Since $ \tau'(x)\leq0 $, we have $ G(0) = \beta_{1}\hat{x}\hat{z_{1}}-a_{1}\beta_{1}\gamma_{1} \hat{x}(\hat{z_{1}})^{2}\tau'(\hat{x})+a_{1}\beta_{1}(\hat{z_{1}})^{2} > 0 $, and thus Eq (4.5) has no zero roots.

    Next, we prove that Eq (4.5) has no purely imaginary roots.

    Assume, by contradiction, that Eq (4.5) has a purely imaginary root $ \lambda = iv $, where $ v > 0 $. Substituting it into Eq (4.5) and separating the real and imaginary parts, we have

    $ {v2H2=N1vsin(τ(ˆx)v)+N2cos(τ(ˆx)v),H1v=N1vcos(τ(ˆx)v)N2sin(τ(ˆx)v).
    $

    Considering $ \sin(\tau(\hat{x})v)^{2}+\cos(\tau(\hat{x})v)^{2} = 1 $, it follows that

    $ v4+D1v2+D2=0,
    $
    (4.6)

    where $ D_{1} = H_{1}^{2}-2H_{2}-N_{1}^{2} $, $ D_{2} = H_{2}^{2}-N_{2}^{2}. $

    In view of $ \tau'(\hat{x})\leq0 $, there are the following two cases.

    Case (1). If $ \tau'(\hat{x}) = 0 $, then $ \tau(\hat{x})\geq0 $, since $ \hat{x} > 0 $, it follows from the hypothesis ($ \mathcal{A}_{2} $) that $ \tau(\hat{x})\neq0 $ and $ \tau(\hat{x}) > 0 $. Therefore, $ D_{1} = A^{2}+3\beta_{1}^{2} \hat{z_{1}}^{2} > 0 $, $ D_{2} = \beta_{1}^{2}\hat{z_{1}}^{2}(4\hat{x}-1) = \beta_{1}^{2}\hat{z_{1}}^{2}(3-4a_{1}\hat{z_{1}}) > 0 $, which implies that Eq (4.5) has no purely imaginary roots and each root of characteristic equation has a negative real part.

    Case (2). If $ \tau'(\hat{x}) < 0 $, according to Lemma 4.3, we have $ K_{1} = 0, K_{2} = D_{1}, K_{3} = 0, K_{4} = D_{2} = \beta_{1}^{2}\hat{z_{1}}^{2}(3-4a_{1}\hat{z_{1}})-4 a_{1}\beta_{1}^{2}\gamma_{1} \hat{x}^{2}\hat{z_{1}}^{3}\tau'(\hat{x})+(a_{1}\beta_{1} \gamma_{1} \hat{x}\hat{z_{1}}^{2} \tau'(\hat{x}))^{2} > 0 $ providing $ \hat{z_{1}} < 3/(4a_{1}) $. Hence, Eq (4.6) has positive roots if the equation satisfies the case (ⅰ) or (ⅱ) in Lemma 4.3. However, $ Z_{i} = Y_{i}-3K_{1}/4 = Y_{i} = 0, $ $ i = 1, 2, 3 $. Then neither case (ⅰ) nor case (ⅱ) in Lemma 4.3 holds true, Eq (4.6) has no positive roots, that is, Eq (4.5) has no purely imaginary roots. Therefore, all eigenvalues of Eq (4.3) have negative real parts, and $ E_{2} $ is locally asymptotically stable. This completes the proof.

    Similarly, we have the following observation about the boundary equilibrium $ E_{3} $.

    Theorem 4.5. If $ \tilde{z_{2}} < 3/(4a_{2}) $ and $ b_{2}\mu_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\tilde{x})} > b_{1}\beta_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\tilde{x})} $, then the boundary equilibrium $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $ is locally asymptotically stable.

    In this section, we investigate the global attractivity of the coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} $ by a method of asymptotic estimates.

    Theorem 5.1. Let condition (3.3) hold, and assume that:

    $ 1>a1b1β1eγ1τ(1)+a2b2β2eγ2τ(1);
    $
    (5.1)
    $ b1(1a1b1β1eγ1τ(1)a2b2β2eγ2τ(1))eγ1τ(0)>μ1b2β2eγ2τ(1);
    $
    (5.2)
    $ b2(1a1b1β1eγ1τ(1)a2b2β2eγ2τ(1))eγ2τ(0)>μ2b1β1eγ1τ(1);
    $
    (5.3)
    $ (a1b1β2+a2b1μ2)eγ1τ(0)+(a1b2μ1+a2b2β1)eγ2τ(0)>β1β2μ1μ2.
    $
    (5.4)

    Then the coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} $ is globally attractive.

    Proof. Since $ e^{-\gamma\tau(x)} $ is increase with respect to $ x $, then $ e^{-\gamma\tau(1)} > e^{-\gamma\tau(0)} $. It follows from inequality (5.2) that

    $ b1eγ1τ(1)>b1eγ1τ(0)>b1(1a1b1β1eγ1τ(1)a2b2β2eγ2τ(1))eγ1τ(0)>μ1b2β2eγ2τ(1).
    $

    Similarly, we have

    $ b2eγ2τ(1)>b2eγ2τ(0)>b2(1a1b1β1eγ1τ(1)a2b2β2eγ2τ(1))eγ2τ(0)>μ2b1β1eγ1τ(1).
    $

    Namely,

    $ μ1β2<b1eγ1τMb2eγ2τm<b1eγ1τ(1)b2eγ2τ(1)<b1eγ1τmb2eγ2τM<β1μ2,
    $

    which implies that both the boundary equilibria $ E_{2} $ and $ E_{3} $ are unstable.

    For the system

    $ {dm1dt=m1(t)(1m1(t)),dm(1)1dt=b1[1τ(m1)m1(t)]m1(tτ(m1))m(1)1(tτ(m1))eγ1τ(m1)β1(m(1)1(t))2,dm(2)1dt=b2[1τ(m1)m1(t)]m1(tτ(m1))m(2)1(tτ(m1))eγ2τ(m1)β2(m(2)1(t))2,
    $

    we have the unique positive equilibrium $ m^{*} = (1, b_{1}/\beta_{1}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1)}, b_{2}/\beta_{2}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(1)}). $

    Clearly, for system (3.1), we obtain that

    $ {dxdt<x(t)(1x(t)),dz1dt<b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x(t)))z1(tτ(x(t)))eγ1τ(x(t))β1z21(t),dz2dt<b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x(t)))z2(tτ(x(t)))eγ2τ(x(t))β2z22(t).
    $
    (5.5)

    By Theorem 3.1, for any $ \epsilon_{1} > 0 $, we can prove that there exists a $ t_{1} > 0 $ such that the following inequalities hold true for all $ t\geq t_{1} $.

    $ {x(t)<M1=1+ϵ1,z1(t)<M(1)1=b1β1eγ1τ(M1)+ϵ12,z2(t)<M(2)1=b2β2eγ2τ(M1)+ϵ12.
    $
    (5.6)

    We first select $ \epsilon_{1} > 0 $ and the corresponding $ t_{1} > 0 $ such that

    $ {1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1>0,b1(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ1τ(M1)>μ1M(2)1,b2(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ2τ(M1)>μ2M(1)1.
    $
    (5.7)

    Conditions (5.1)-(5.3) can guarantee the existence of $ \epsilon_{1} $ to satisfy conditions (5.6) and (5.7). Based on $ \epsilon_{1} > 0, \; t_{1} > 0 $, we choose sufficiently small $ \epsilon_{2} > 0 $ to make that $ \epsilon_{2} < \min\{1/2, \epsilon_{1}\}, $ and

    $ {1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1ϵ2>0,[b1(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ1τ(M1)μ1M(2)1]1β1ϵ22>0,[b2(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ2τ(M1)μ2M(1)1]1β1ϵ22>0.
    $
    (5.8)

    In view of inequality (5.7), it is possible to choose positive number $ \epsilon_{2} $ satisfying inequality (5.8). Combining with inequalities (5.6) and (5.8), we obtain that

    $ {dxdt>x(t)[(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)x(t)],dz1dt>b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x(t)))z1(tτ(x(t)))eγ1τ(x(t))β1z21(t)μ1M(2)1z1(t),dz2dt>b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x(t)))z2(tτ(x(t)))eγ2τ(x(t))β2z22(t)μ2M(1)1z2(t).
    $

    It follows that there exists a $ t_{2} > t_{1} $ to make that

    $ {x(t)>N1=1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1ϵ2,z1(t)>N(1)1=(b1N1eγ1τ(N1)μ1M(2)1)1β1ϵ22,z2(t)>N(2)1=(b2N1eγ2τ(N1)μ2M(1)1)1β2ϵ22.
    $
    (5.9)

    By system (3.1) and inequality (5.9), we have for $ t > t_{2} $,

    $ {dxdt<x(t)[(1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1)x(t)],dz1dt<b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1N(2)1z1(t),dz2dt<b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2N(1)1z2(t).
    $
    (5.10)

    With the first inequality of (5.7), we see that

    $ 1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1=1a1[(b1N1eγ1τ(N1)μ1M(2)1)1β1ϵ22]a2[(b2N1eγ2τ(N1)μ2M(1)1)1β2ϵ22]>1a1b1β1N1eγ1τ(N1)a2b2β2N1eγ2τ(N1)>1a1b1β1M1eγ1τ(M1)a2b2β2M1eγ2τ(M1)>0.
    $
    (5.11)

    Then from inequalities (5.10) and (5.11), there exists a $ t_{3} > t_{2} $ and $ 0 < \epsilon_{3} < \min\{1/3, \epsilon_{2}\} $ such that, for $ t > t_{3} $,

    $ {x(t)<M2=1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1+ϵ3,z1(t)<M(1)2=(b1M2eγ1τ(M2)μ1N(2)1)1β1+ϵ32,z2(t)<M(2)2=(b2M2eγ2τ(M2)μ2N(1)1)1β2+ϵ32.
    $
    (5.12)

    We next prove that the estimates $ M_{2}^{(1)} $ and $ M_{2}^{(2)} $ are positive.

    $ b1M2eγ1τ(M2)μ1N(2)1=b1(1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1+ϵ3)eγ1τ(M2)μ1[(b2N1eγ2τ(N1)μ2M(1)1)1β2ϵ22]>b1(1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1)eγ1τ(M2)μ1b2β2N1eγ2τ(N1)>b1(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ1τ(0)μ1b2β2M1eγ2τ(M1)>0,
    $
    (5.13)

    and

    $ b2M2eγ2τ(M2)μ2N(1)1=b2(1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1+ϵ3)eγ2τ(M2)μ2[(b1N1eγ1τ(N1)μ1M(2)1)1β1ϵ22]>b2(1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1)eγ2τ(M2)μ2b1β1N1eγ1τ(N1)>b2(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ2τ(0)μ2b1β1M1eγ1τ(M1)>0.
    $
    (5.14)

    In view of the upper estimates in equality (5.12), we will get a lower set of estimates. Since $ \epsilon_{3} < \epsilon_{1} $, inequalities (5.13) and (5.14), the following result is valid.

    $ 1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2=1a1[(b1M2eγ1τ(M2)μ1N(2)1)1β1+ϵ32]a2[(b2M2eγ2τ(M2)μ2N(1)1)1β2+ϵ32]>1a1(b1β1M2eγ1τ(M2)+ϵ32)a2(b2β2M2eγ2τ(M2)+ϵ32)>1a1(b1β1M1eγ1τ(M1)+ϵ32)a2(b2β2M1eγ2τ(M1)+ϵ32)>0.
    $
    (5.15)

    Denote $ n_{2}, $ $ n_{2}^{(1)} $, $ n_{2}^{(2)} $ as follows:

    $ {n2=1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2,n(1)2=b1n2eγ1τ(n2)μ1M(2)2,n(2)2=b2n2eγ2τ(n2)μ2M(1)2.
    $
    (5.16)

    By inequalities (5.2) and (5.15) and the second inequality of (5.7), we get that

    $ n(1)2=b1(1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2)eγ1τ(n2)μ1M(2)2>b1(1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2)eγ1τ(0)μ1M(2)1>0.
    $
    (5.17)

    It follows from inequalities (5.3) and (5.15) and the third inequality of (5.7) that

    $ n(2)2=b2(1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2)eγ2τ(n2)μ2M(1)2>b2(1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2)eγ2τ(0)μ2M(1)1>0.
    $
    (5.18)

    Combining with inequalities (5.15)–(5.18), there exists a $ 0 < \epsilon_{4} < \min\{1/4, \epsilon_{3}\} $ satisfying

    $ {n2ϵ4>0,(b1n2eγ1τ(n2)μ1M(2)2)1β1ϵ42>0,(b2n2eγ2τ(n2)μ2M(1)2)1β2ϵ42>0.
    $
    (5.19)

    With the upper estimates in inequality (5.12), we obtain the following comparative system for all $ t > t_{3} $.

    $ {dxdt>x(t)[(1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2)x(t)],dz1dt>b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1M(2)2z1(t),dz2dt>b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2M(1)2z2(t).
    $

    Using inequality (5.19), there exists a $ t_{4} > t_{3} $ such that

    $ {x(t)>N2=1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2ϵ4,z1(t)>N(1)2=(b1N2eγ1τ(N2)μ1M(2)2)1β1ϵ42,z2(t)>N(2)2=(b2N2eγ2τ(N2)μ2M(1)2)1β2ϵ42.
    $

    The estimates $ N_{2} $, $ N_{2}^{(1)} $ and $ N_{2}^{(2)} $ are all positive by inequality (5.19). Therefore, we obtain that, for $ t > t_{2} $,

    $ N1<x(t)<M1,N(1)1<z1(t)<M(1)1,N(2)1<z2(t)<M(2)1,
    $

    and for $ t > t_{4} $,

    $ N2<x(t)<M2,N(1)2<z1(t)<M(1)2,N(2)2<z2(t)<M(2)2.
    $

    Now we compare the obtained estimates, respectively:

    $ M2M1=1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1+ϵ3(1ϵ1)<ϵ3ϵ1<0,M(1)2M(1)1=(b1M2eγ1τ(M2)μ1N(2)1)1β1+ϵ32b1β1eγ1τ(M1)ϵ12<b1β1M2eγ1τ(M2)b1β1M1eγ1τ(M1)+12(ϵ3ϵ1)<b1β1eγ1τ(M1)(M2M1)+12(ϵ3ϵ1)<0.
    $

    Similarly, $ M_{2}^{(2)}-M_{1}^{(2)} < 0. $

    Moreover,

    $ N2N1=1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2ϵ4(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)+ϵ2=a1(M(1)2M(1)1)a2(M(2)2M(2)1)+(ϵ2ϵ4)>0,
    $

    and

    $ N(1)2N(1)1=(b1N2eγ1τ(N2)μ1M(2)2)1β1ϵ42(b1N1eγ1τ(N1)μ1M(2)1)1β1+ϵ22>b1β1eγ1τ(N1)(N2N1)μ1β1(M(2)2M(2)1)+12(ϵ2ϵ4)>0.
    $

    Similarly, $ N_{2}^{(2)}-N_{1}^{(2)} > 0. $

    Hence, from the above arguments, we have for $ t > t_{4} $

    $ N1<N2<x(t)<M2<M1,N(1)1<N(1)2<z1(t)<M(1)2<M(1)1,N(2)1<N(2)2<z2(t)<M(2)2<M(2)1.
    $

    By extending the above step, it then follows that

    $ N1<N2<N3<<Nn<x(t)<Mn<<M3<M2<M1,N(1)1<N(1)2<N(1)3<<N(1)n<z1(t)<M(1)n<<M(1)3<M(1)2<M(1)1,N(2)1<N(2)2<N(2)3<<N(2)n<z2(t)<M(2)n<<M(2)3<M(2)2<M(2)1,
    $

    where

    $ Mn=1a1N(1)n1a2N(2)n1+ϵ2n1,M(1)n=(b1Mneγ1τ(Mn)μ1N(2)n1)1β1+ϵ2n12,M(2)n=(b2Mneγ2τ(Mn)μ2N(2)n1)1β2+ϵ2n12,
    $
    (5.20)

    with $ n = 2, 3, 4, \cdots $, and

    $ Nn=1a1M(1)na2M(2)nϵ2n,N(1)n=(b1Nneγ1τ(Nn)μ1M(2)n)1β1ϵ2n2,N(2)n=(b2Nneγ2τ(Nn)μ2M(2)n)1β2ϵ2n12,
    $
    (5.21)

    with $ n = 1, 2, 3, \cdots $.

    Since $ \epsilon_{n} < 1/n $, we have $ \epsilon_{n}\rightarrow 0 $ as $ n\rightarrow\infty $. And the monotone sequences $ N_{n} $, $ N_{n}^{(1)} $, $ N_{n}^{(2)} $, $ M_{n} $, $ M_{n}^{(1)} $, and $ M_{n}^{(2)} $ converge to positive limits as $ n\rightarrow\infty $. Let

    $ M=limnMnandN=limnNn,M(1)=limnM(1)nandN(1)=limnN(1)n,M(2)=limnM(2)nandN(2)=limnN(2)n.
    $
    (5.22)

    By virtue of Eqs (5.20)–(5.22) and $ \lim_{n\rightarrow\infty}\epsilon_{n} = 0 $, it follows that

    $ M=1a1N(1)a2N(2),N=1a1M(1)a2M(2),
    $
    (5.23)

    and

    $ β1M(1)=b1Meγ1τ(M)μ1N(2),β1N(1)=b1Neγ1τ(N)μ1M(2),β2M(2)=b2Meγ2τ(M)μ2N(1),β2N(2)=b2Neγ2τ(N)μ2M(1).
    $
    (5.24)

    From Eq (5.24), we have

    $ M(1)N(1)=b1β2B1+b2μ1B2β1β2μ1μ2,M(2)N(2)=b1μ2B1+b2β1B2β1β2μ1μ2,
    $
    (5.25)

    where $ B_{1} = \Big(M_{*}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(M_{*})}-N_{*}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(N_{*})}\Big) $, $ B_{2} = \Big(M_{*}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(M_{*})}-N_{*}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(N_{*})}\Big). $

    Combining Eqs (5.23) and (5.25), we see that

    $ MN=a1(M(1)N(1))a2(M(2)N(2))=(a1b1β2+a2b1μ2)B1+(a1b2μ1+a2b2β1)B2β1β2μ1μ2.
    $

    Let $ Q_{1} = (a_{1}b_{1}\beta_{2}+a_{2}b_{1}\mu_{2})/(\beta_{1}\beta_{2}-\mu_{1}\mu_{2}) $, $ Q_{2} = (a_{1}b_{2}\mu_{1}+a_{2}b_{2}\beta_{1})/(\beta_{1}\beta_{2}-\mu_{1}\mu_{2}) $, then

    $ M(1Q1eγ1τ(M)Q2eγ2τ(M))=N(1Q1eγ1τ(N)Q2eγ2τ(N)).
    $
    (5.26)

    Denote $ h(x) = x\big(1-Q_{1}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(x)}-Q_{2}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(x)}\big) $, for all $ x\geq0 $. From (5.4) and $ \tau'(x)\leq0 $, we have

    $ h(x)=1Q1eγ1τ(x)Q2eγ2τ(x)+x[Q1γ1τ(x)eγ1τ(x)+Q2γ2τ(x)eγ2τ(x)]<1Q1eγ1τ(x)Q2eγ2τ(x)<1Q1eγ1τ(0)Q2eγ2τ(0)<0,
    $

    and thus, $ h(x) $ is a monotone decrease function with respect to $ x $. It then follows from Eq (5.26) that $ M_{*} = N_{*} $. Therefore, $ M_{*}^{(1)} = N_{*}^{(1)} $ and $ M_{*}^{(2)} = N_{*}^{(2)} $. Further, the relations in Eqs (5.23) and (5.24) are also true for $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $. Then by the uniqueness of the coexistence equilibrium of system (3.1), we know that $ \Big(M_{*}, M_{*}^{(1)}, M_{*}^{(2)}\Big) $ and $ \Big(N_{*}, N_{*}^{(1)}, N_{*}^{(2)}\Big) $ are the coexistence equilibrium of system (3.1), and hence $ M_{*} = N_{*} = x^{*} $, $ M_{*}^{(1)} = M_{*}^{(1)} = z_{1}^{*} $, $ M_{*}^{(2)} = M_{*}^{(2)} = z_{2}^{*} $. Accordingly, $ x^{*} = \lim_{t\rightarrow\infty}x(t) $, $ z_{1}^{*} = \lim_{t\rightarrow\infty}z_{1}(t) $ and $ z_{2}^{*} = \lim_{t\rightarrow\infty}z_{2}(t) $. The proof is complete.

    Next we deduce the global attractivity for the other variables $ y_{1} $ and $ y_{2} $ in system (2.3). By using the integral form for $ y_{1} $ and $ y_{2} $, we obtain that

    $ yi=limtyi(t)=ttτ(x)bixzieγi(ts)ds,i=1,2.
    $

    Therefore, we have the following result.

    Theorem 5.2. Let condition (3.3) hold. Assume that conditions (5.1)-(5.4) hold true, then the coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, y_{1}^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, y_{2}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $ is globally attractive for system (2.3).

    At the end of this section, we give the dynamical results of two boundary equilibria and coexistence equilibrium for the original system (2.2). The reduced system of model (2.2) is as follows.

    $ {dxdt=rx(t)(1x(t)K)a1x(t)z1(t)a2x(t)z2(t),dz1dt=b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dz2dt=b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t).
    $
    (5.27)

    Obviously, system (5.27) has exactly one trivial equilibrium $ E_{0} = (0, 0, 0) $, one semitrivial equilibrium $ E_{1} = (K, 0, 0) $, two boundary equilibria $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $ and $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $. And condition (3.3) holds true, then there exists a unique coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $.

    Theorem 5.3. If $ \hat{z_{1}} < 3r/(4a_{1}) $ and $ b_{1}\mu_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\hat{x})} > b_{2}\beta_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $, then the boundary equilibrium $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $ of system (5.27) is locally asymptotically stable.

    Theorem 5.4. If $ \tilde{z_{2}} < 3r/(4a_{2}) $ and $ b_{2}\mu_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\tilde{x})} > b_{1}\beta_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\tilde{x})} $, then the boundary equilibrium $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $ of system (5.27) is locally asymptotically stable.

    Theorem 5.5. Let condition (3.3) hold, and assume that:

    $ r>a1b1β1Keγ1τ(K)+a2b2β2Keγ2τ(K);
    $
    (5.28)
    $ b1(ra1Kb1β1eγ1τ(K)a2Kb2β2eγ2τ(K))eγ1τ(0)1r>μ1b2β2eγ2τ(K);
    $
    (5.29)
    $ b2(ra1Kb1β1eγ1τ(K)a2Kb2β2eγ2τ(K))eγ2τ(0)1r>μ2b1β1eγ1τ(K);
    $
    (5.30)
    $ Kr[(a1b1β2+a2b1μ2)eγ1τ(0)+(a1b2μ1+a2b2β1)eγ2τ(0)]>β1β2μ1μ2.
    $
    (5.31)

    Then the coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} $ of system (5.27) is globally attractive.

    In this paper, given that the maturity time of Antarctic whales and seals varies with the number of krill available around the Second World War, we formulated a consumer-resource competition model that, for the first time, incorporates a state-dependent maturity time delay associated with resource changes and structured consumer species. The main difference from the state-dependent delay equations previously studied is that model (2.3) directly manifests the relationship between resources and maturity time of consumers through the correction term, $ 1-\tau'(x(t))x'(t) $.

    Besides, the state-dependent delay $ \tau(x(t)) $ reflects exploitation and interference competition effects of two consumer species. On one hand, the exploitative ability of the mature individual is stronger, the juvenile will get more resources, which leads to a shorter maturation time. On the other hand, because of the limited resource, the consumer species spend more time and energy to obtain resource for keeping themselves alive. Unfortunately, what often happens is that there is not enough food for their children and so they take longer time to mature. Further, it is clear that the greater the ability of an adult to intervene is, the shorter the maturity time is.

    From mathematical point of view, firstly, we study the well-posedness of the solution for model (2.3) and the existence and uniqueness of all equilibria. We then show the linear stability of equilibria. The trivial equilibria $ E_{0} = (0, 0, 0) $ and $ E_{1} = (1, 0, 0) $ are always unstable, which can be explained by the fact that since the resource is self-renewing with a logistic growth and two competitive species depend entirely on it, the resource are not used up or maximized. For the linear stability of boundary equilibrium $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $, according to Theorem 4.4, the first sufficient condition $ \hat{z_{1}} < 3/(4a_{1}) $ is equivalent to $ \hat{x} > 1/4 $, which means the resource must be the specific level to make sure that one of the consumer species survives. For the original system (2.2), in Theorem 5.3, the condition is changed to $ \hat{z_{1}} < 3r/(4a_{1}) $, which is equivalent to $ \hat{x} > K-3K/(4r) $ and implies that the resource must be above a certain value of the interaction between the growth rate of resource and its carrying capacity. And another sufficient condition $ b_{1}\mu_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\hat{x})} > b_{2}\beta_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $ implies $ (b_{1}\hat{x}e^{-\gamma_{1}\hat{x}})/\beta_{1} > (b_{2}\hat{x}e^{-\gamma_{2}\hat{x}})/\mu_{2} $, on the basis of the threshold resource $ \hat{x} $, when the maximum growth of the first species is large than the interspecific competitive effect on the second species, the second species has a negative growth effect, which illustrates the first species will win the competition. There is a similar biological explanation for the linear stability of $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $. Finally, we discuss the global properties of $ E^{*} $. Theorem 5.1 shows the sufficient conditions for $ E^{*} $ to be globally attractive. The condition (5.1) implies that the number of the two consumers are at their potential maximum, and the maximum self-updating value of the resource is large than the exploitation effects; conditions (5.2) and (5.3) imply that when the resource is at its minimum, the number of the consumers who were born at time $ t-\tau(x(t)) $ and still alive now are enough to make up for the possible interspecific competition effects; condition (5.4) is a technical assumption and has no practical biological significance. For the global properties of $ E^{*} $ in original system (2.2), the condition (5.28) implies that when the maximum carrying capacity $ K $ of the resource is reached, the two consumers are at their potential maximum, and the growth rate $ r $ of the resource is larger than the exploitation effect. Conditions (5.29) and (5.30) have biological explanations similar to conditions (5.2) and (5.3).

    This paper only considers the case of one resource. And since the fitting of state-dependent delay $ \tau(x(t)) $ is very challenging, we are unable to validate theoretical results by numerical simulations. We would like to leave this problem and propose a competition model with state-dependent delay between two species for two resources in the further research.

    This work is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant Nos. 11671327, 11901326). We are grateful to the editor and reviewers for their valuable comments and suggestions that greatly improved the presentation of this paper.

    The authors declared that they have no conflicts of interest to this work.

    [1] Paull SH, Johnson PTJ (2013) Can we predict climate-driven changes to disease dynamics? Applications for theory and management in the face of uncertainty. In: Brodie JF, Post E and Doak DF (eds.) Wildlife conservation in a changing climate. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
    [2] Dunbar RIM (2002) Impact of global warming on the distribution of survival of the gelada baboon: a modeling approach. Global Change Biol 4: 293-304.
    [3] Bettridge C, Lehmann J, Dunbar RIM (2010) Trade-offs between time, predation risk and life history, and their implications for biogeography: a system modeling approach with a primate case study. Ecol Model 221: 777-790. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolmodel.2009.11.017
    [4] Gabriel DN (2013) Habitat use and activity patterns as an indication of fragment quality in a strepsirrhine primate. Int J Primatol 34: 388-406.
    [5] Graham TL, Matthews HD, Turner SE (2016) A global-scale evaluation of primate exposure and vulnerability to climate change. Int J Primatol, 1-17.
    [6] Adams-Hosking C, Grantham HS, Rhodes JR, et al. (2011) Modelling climate-change-induced shifts in the distribution of the koala. Wildlife Res 38: 122-130. doi: 10.1071/WR10156
    [7] Lovegrove BG, Canale C, Levesque D, et al. (2014) Are tropical small mammals physiologically vulnerable to Arrhenius effects and climate change? Physiol Biochem Zool 87: 30-45.
    [8] Hockings KJ, Anderson JR, Matsuzawa T (2012) Socioecological adaptations by chimpanzees, Pan troglodytes verus, inhabiting an anthropogenically impacted habitat. Anim Behav 83: 801-810.
    [9] Whitten T, Soeriaatmadja RE, Afiff SA (1996) The Ecology of Java & Bali: The Ecology of Indonesia Series, Volume II. Periplus Editions (HK) Ltd, Singapore.
    [10] Nijman V (2013) One hundred years of solitude: effects of long-term forest fragmentation on the primate community of Java, Indonesia. Developments in Primatology: Progress and Prospects, Primates in Fragments, Springer, 33-45.
    [11] Rice RA, Greenberg R (2000) Cacao cultivation and the conservation of biological diversity. Ambio 29: 167-173. doi: 10.1579/0044-7447-29.3.167
    [12] Rode-Margono EJ, Nijman V, Wirdateti, et al. (2014) Ethology of the Critically Endangered Javan slow loris Nycticebus javanicus E. Geoffroy Saint-Hilaire in West Java. Asian Primates Journal 4: 27-41.
    [13] Nekaris KAI (2014) Extreme primates: Ecology and evolution of Asian lorises. Evolutionary Anthropology23: 177-187.
    [14] Streicher U (2005) Seasonal body weight changes in pygmy lorises Nycticebus pygmaeus. Verhandlungsber. Zootierkrk 42: 144-145.
    [15] Xiao CH, Wang ZK, Zhu WL, et al. (2010) Energy metabolism and thermoregulation in pygmy lorises (Nycticebus pygmaeus) from Yunnan Daweishan Nature Reserve. Acta Ecologica Sinica30: 129-134.
    [16] Ruf T, Streicher U, Stalder GL, et al. (2015) Hibernation in the pygmy slow loris (Nycticebus pygmaeus): multiday torpor in primates is not restricted to Madagascar. Sci rep 5: 17392. doi: 10.1038/srep17392
    [17] Starr C, Nekaris KAI, Leung L (2012) Hiding from the moonlight: luminosity and temperature affect activity of Asian nocturnal primates in a highly seasonal forest. PloS one 7: e36396. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0036396
    [18] Rode-Margono EJ, Nekaris KAI (2014) Impact of climate and moonlight on a venomous mammal, the Javan slow loris (Nycticebus javanicus Geoffroy, 1812). Contrib Zool 83: 217-225.
    [19] Braak C (1929) The Climate of the Netherland Indies; Volumes I and II. Verhandelingen No. 8, Koninklijk Magnetisch en Meteorologisch Observatorium te Batavia.
    [20] Schmidt FH, Ferguson HA (1951) Rainfall types based on wet and dry period ratios for Indonesia and Western New Guinea. Verh. Djawatan Met. Geofisik, Jakarta 42.
    [21] RePPProT (1990) The land resources of Indonesia: a national overview. Jakarta: Directorate General of Settlement Preparation, Ministry of Transmigration and London: Natural Resources Institute, Overseas Development Administration.
    [22] Hill RA, Dunbar RIM (2002) Climatic determinants of diet and foraging behaviour in baboons. Evol Ecol 16: 579-593.
    [23] Grueter CC, Li D, Ren B, et al. (2013) Overwintering strategy of Yunnan snub-nosed monkeys: adjustments in activity scheduling and foraging patterns. Primates 54: 125-135. doi: 10.1007/s10329-012-0333-3
    [24] Young BE, Hall KR, Byers E, et al. (2013) Rapid assessment of plant and animal vulnerability to climate change. In: Brodie JF, Post E and Doak DF (eds.) Wildlife conservation in a changing climate. Chicago: Chicago University Press, USA.
    [25] Fadamiro HY, Wyatt TD (1995) Flight initiation by Prostephanus truncates in relation to time of day, temperature, relative humidity and starvation. Entomol Exp Appl 75: 273-277.
    [26] Rode-Margono EJ, Rademaker M, Wirdateti W, et al. (2015) Noxious arthropods as potential prey of the venomous Javan slow loris (Nycticebus javanicus) in a West Javan volcanic agricultural system. J Nat Hist 49: 1949-1959. doi: 10.1080/00222933.2015.1006282
    [27] Sharmoun-Baranes J, Van Loon E, van Gasteren H, et al. (2006) A comparative analysis of the influence of weather on the flight altitudes of birds. B Am Meteorol Soc 87: 47-61. doi: 10.1175/BAMS-87-1-47
    [28] Chaves OM, Stoner KE, Arroyo-Rodriguez V (2011) Seasonal differences in activity patterns of Geoffroyi’s spider monkeys (Ateles geoffroyi) living in continuous and fragmented forests in southern Mexico. Int J Primatol 32: 960-973. doi: 10.1007/s10764-011-9515-x
    [29] Langvatn R, Albon SD, Burkey T, et al. (1996) Climate, plant phenology and variation in age of first reproduction in a temperate herbivore. J Anim Ecol 65: 653-670. doi: 10.2307/5744
    [30] Starr C, Nekaris KAI (2013) Obligate exudativory characterizes the diet of the pygmy slow loris Nycticebus pygmaeus. Am j primatol 75: 1054-1061. doi: 10.1002/ajp.22171
    [31] Moore RS, Wihermanto W, Nekaris KAI (2014) Compassionate conservation, rehabilitation and translocation of Indonesian slow lorises. Endangered Species Research 26: 93-102. doi: 10.3354/esr00620
    [32] Reinhardt KD, Wirdateti, Nekaris KAI (2015) “Relationships between altitude, habitat structure and behaviour of Nycticebus javanicus in a submontane agroforest. Folia Primatologica 86(4): 345-346.
    [33] Davies-Colley RJ, Payne GW, van Elswijk (2000) Microclimate gradients across a forest edge. New Zeal J Ecol 24: 111-121.
    [34] Cleugh HA (1998) Effects of windbreaks on airflow, microclimates and crop yields. Agroforest Syst 41: 55-84. doi: 10.1023/A:1006019805109
    [35] Nowack J, Nomakwezi M, Dausmann KH (2013) Torpor as an emergency solution in Galago moholi: heterothermy is triggered by different constraints. J Comp Physiol B 183: 547-556. doi: 10.1007/s00360-012-0725-0
    [36] Adolph SC (1990) Influence of behavioral thermoregulation on microhabitat use by two Sceloporus lizards. Ecology 7: 315-327.
    [37] Donati G, Ricci E, Baldi N, et al. (2011) Behavioral thermoregulation in a gregarious lemur, Eulemur collaris: effects of climatic and dietary-related factors. Am J Phys Anthropol 144: 355-364. doi: 10.1002/ajpa.21415
    [38] Majolo B, McFarland R, Young C, et al. (2013) The effects of climatic factors on the activity budgets of Barbary macaques (Macaca sylvanus). Int J Primatol 34: 500-514.
    [39] Korstjens AH, Lehmann J, Dunbar RIM (2010) Resting time as an ecological constraint on primate biogeography. Anim Behav 79: 361-374.
    [40] Kobbe S, Nowack J, Dausmann KH (2014) Torpor is not the only option: seasonal variations of the thermoneutral zone in a small primate. J Comp Physiol B 184: 789-797. doi: 10.1007/s00360-014-0834-z
    [41] Reinhardt KD, Spaan D, Wirdateti, et al. (2014) Torpor in a Critically Endangered primate: climate effects on Javan slow loris (Nycticebus javanicus) behavior. Proceedings of the 37th Annual Meeting. American Society of Primatology. Decatur, Georgia. Abstract no. 55.
    [42] Nekaris KAI, Starr CR (2015) Conservation and ecology of the neglected slow loris: priorities and prospects.Endangered Species Research 28: 87-95. doi: 10.3354/esr00674
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Biao Tang, Kexin Ma, Yan Liu, Xia Wang, Sanyi Tang, Yanni Xiao, Robert A. Cheke, Kimberly M. Pepin, Managing spatio-temporal heterogeneity of susceptibles by embedding it into an homogeneous model: A mechanistic and deep learning study, 2024, 20, 1553-7358, e1012497, 10.1371/journal.pcbi.1012497
    2. Laura J. Faherty, Pedro Nascimento de Lima, Jing Zhi Lim, Derek Roberts, Sarah Karr, Emily Lawson, Henry H. Willis, Effects of non-pharmaceutical interventions on COVID-19 transmission: rapid review of evidence from Italy, the United States, the United Kingdom, and China, 2024, 12, 2296-2565, 10.3389/fpubh.2024.1426992
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2016 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(7783) PDF downloads(1681) Cited by(16)

Figures and Tables

Figures(3)  /  Tables(1)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog