Citation: Zuzana Chladná. Optimal time to intervene: The case of measles child immunization[J]. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2018, 15(1): 323-335. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2018014
[1] | Deborah Lacitignola . Saturated treatments and measles resurgence episodes in South Africa: A possible linkage. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2013, 10(4): 1135-1157. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2013.10.1135 |
[2] | Muhammad Fakhruddin, Dani Suandi, Sumiati, Hilda Fahlena, Nuning Nuraini, Edy Soewono . Investigation of a measles transmission with vaccination: a case study in Jakarta, Indonesia. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(4): 2998-3018. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020170 |
[3] | Yuta Okada, Hiroshi Nishiura . Vaccine-induced reduction of COVID-19 clusters in school settings in Japan during the epidemic wave caused by B.1.1.529 (Omicron) BA.2, 2022. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2024, 21(9): 7087-7101. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2024312 |
[4] | Maddalena Donà, Pieter Trapman . Possible counter-intuitive impact of local vaccine mandates for vaccine-preventable infectious diseases. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2024, 21(7): 6521-6538. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2024284 |
[5] | Beatriz Machado, Liliana Antunes, Constantino Caetano, João F. Pereira, Baltazar Nunes, Paula Patrício, M. Luísa Morgado . The impact of vaccination on the evolution of COVID-19 in Portugal. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(1): 936-952. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022043 |
[6] | Majid Jaberi-Douraki, Seyed M. Moghadas . Optimal control of vaccination dynamics during an influenza epidemic. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2014, 11(5): 1045-1063. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2014.11.1045 |
[7] | Hamed Karami, Pejman Sanaei, Alexandra Smirnova . Balancing mitigation strategies for viral outbreaks. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2024, 21(12): 7650-7687. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2024337 |
[8] | Xiaojing Wang, Yu Liang, Jiahui Li, Maoxing Liu . Modeling COVID-19 transmission dynamics incorporating media coverage and vaccination. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(6): 10392-10403. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023456 |
[9] | Eunha Shim, Beth Kochin, Alison Galvani . Insights from epidemiological game theory into gender-specific vaccination against rubella. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2009, 6(4): 839-854. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2009.6.839 |
[10] | Xinyu Liu, Zimeng Lv, Yuting Ding . Mathematical modeling and stability analysis of the time-delayed SAIM model for COVID-19 vaccination and media coverage. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(6): 6296-6316. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022294 |
The World Health Organization (WHO) Measles and Rubella Strategic Plan aims to eliminate measles and rubella in at least five WHO regions by the end of 2020 ([18]). However, despite the existence of an inexpensive measles vaccine there are obstacles to achieving this goal. In developing countries the vaccine is not always available. Whether the poorest countries with poor infrastructure for routine health services can achieve sufficiently high coverage is unknown ([18]).
In Europe, the elimination of measles is endangered by non-vaccinated individuals; a growing number of parents refuse to vaccinate their children for various reasons, e.g. too many shots or concern about autism (see e.g. [16]).
Slovakia is one of the few European countries where vaccination is enacted by law. Vaccination against measles was introduced in 1969. Currently, to prevent measles, children should be vaccinated with the measles, mumps, and rubella (MMR) vaccine. Two doses of this vaccine are needed for complete protection. Children should be given the first dose of MMR vaccine at 15 to 18 months of age. The second dose should be given at the 11th year of life. As Figure 1a indicates, because of the mandatory vaccination, incidence of measles cases in Slovakia is quite low compared to other surrounding countries: in the period
Since becoming independent in
One can identify several factors responsible for this situation. Firstly, a decline in immunization rates of newborns is most likely related to the increasing activity of the anti-vaccination lobby: their massive campaign has started in the beginning of the year
In the light of the above, the question we need to resolve is whether we should worry about the decline in the vaccination rates and coverage. For how long can the past high immunization rates of newborns save us from the future measles outbreaks? Naturally, it all mainly depends on the future dynamics of the immunization rate of newborns. In order to illustrate the problem, we have proposed three potential situations, which are depicted on Figure 2.
The three curves represent temporal dynamics of the average vaccination coverage under three different scenarios, the horizontal grey line depicts the critical vaccination coverage needed to achieve herd immunity. In Figure 2a the initial immunization rate of newborns is assumed to be
The only possible way to get the vaccination coverage back above the critical level appears to be an intervention at the government level. Examples of intervention applied in different countries are summarized e.g. in the study by [15]. The most frequent types are advertisement, education, or law restrictions requiring a proof of vaccination for the school entry.
For the purposes of this study, we have defined intervention in terms of financial or real options terminology as a right but not the obligation to intervene at any time until the end of the planning period. The real options approach can be viewed as an extension of the financial options theory into the investment making process. The standard valuation techniques, such as, for instance, the net present value method (see e.g. [3]), consider a single decision pathway with fixed outcomes only: all decisions are thus prespecified by the expected future revenues path. Moreover, it is assumed that the decision maker follows the original plan irrespectively of changing circumstances. On the other hand, the real options models allow to incorporate flexibility into the model and thus modify business plans taking into account new information. This is particularly important when modeling highly uncertain future outcomes.
In our proposed model setup we assume that the intervention induces costs and results in predetermined increase in immunization rate of newborns in the next period. Our aim is to analyze the cost-effectiveness of intervention and to estimate the moment when it is optimal to intervene. We introduce a real options model, which is a kind of stochastic dynamic problem. It is constructed from the perspective of a policy maker, who faces three types of uncertainties: the stochastic evolution of the future immunization rate of newborns, the random occurrence of an imported measles case and the uncertain outbreak size. Using real options techniques (see e.g. [7], [6]) we determine the level of vaccination coverage at which it is optimal to intervene. A sensitivity analysis shows the importance of early intervention in the population with high initial average vaccination coverage. Furthermore, our numerical results demonstrate that the less certain we are about the future development of the immunization rate of newborns, the more valuable is the option to intervene. To our knowledge, this is the first study analyzing the economic effect of intervention using real options techniques.
During the last two decades many authors attempted to explain human decision-making with respect to vaccination (see e.g.[13]). As the first study within this concept can be probably considered the work [2]. Under the game theory setup authors propose vaccination game and show that it is not possible to eradicate a disease under voluntary vaccination scheme. A number of studies has followed to extend this result. The work [8], resp. [4] seems to be the most relevant to our study. The authors introduce various models of the vaccination behavior dynamics and discuss the impact of information dependence function on the resulting vaccination coverage. In this paper we adopt a different approach: we try to extend the existing studies by establishing a model under the presence of uncertainty in the vaccination behavior. Our assumption reflects the possibility that behavior of a part of parents does not present any rational pattern and therefore cannot be explained by any deterministic model. Furthermore, stochastic setup enables us to study the role of uncertainty in the planning vaccination interventions.
The paper is organized as follows. We first introduce the newly developed real options model, which constitutes a flexible evidence-based dynamic decision making tool. We then present the results of simulations. As a benchmark case, we analyze the model without intervention. In the next step we compare the expected costs with and without the intervention, and thus calculate the value of the option to intervene. We conclude with the most relevant observations following from this modelling exercise.
The aim of the policy maker is to minimize the expected costs associated with a measles outbreak during the fixed time period of length
V(t,xt,Xt)=minut{utP+11+rE(˜V(t+1,xt+1,Xt+1|t,xt,Xt))}, | (1) |
for
The minimization procedure chooses either to intervene (
E(˜V(t+1,xt+1,Xt+1|t,xt,Xt))=pepi(c0E(It|Xt)+E(V(t+1,xmax,Xmax|t,xt,Xt)))+(1−pepi)E(V(t+1,xt+1,Xt+1|t,xt,Xt)) | (2) |
In Equation 2 the weight
The outbreak costs are the product of costs per case
dStdt=(1−xt)μN−(βItN+μ)StdItdt=βItNSt−(γ+μ)ItdRtdt=xtμN+γIt−μRt | (3) |
with the initial conditions
E(It|Xt)={a0−a1Xt,if Xt<1−1/R00if Xt≥1−1/R0 | (4) |
As Equation 4 states, if the average vaccination coverage is below the critical level
In order to complete our model specification, we need to describe the dynamics of the state variables. First, we propose that without intervention, the immunization rate of newborns follows Geometric Brownian motion (GBM) process, i.e. the rate
dxt=αxtdt+σxtdWt, | (5) |
where
Equation 5 states that the percentage change in the immunization rate of newborns equals the drift term
For the modeling purposes, we have used the discretized version of the process 6. We denote the size of the time step by
xt+1={xt+αxtΔt+σxtεt√Δt if ut=0xt+g(xt) if ut=1 | (6) |
Several properties are required for a function
1.
2.
3.
The above mentioned properties must hold for any
The dynamics of the average vaccination coverage is described as follows:
Xt+1=Xt+1n(xt−xDt) | (7) |
where
1We should remark here that the oldest cohorts have not been vaccinated but they are immune thanks to recovery from the natural infection.
In terms of the numerical analysis, we perform a case study motivated by the current epidemiological situation in Slovakia as described in Section 1. We chose the Bratislava region as the study area because its decline in the immunization rate of newborns is the most significant in recent years. The region has approximately
Time horizon | |
Population size | |
Reproduction number | |
Recovery rate | |
Birth/death rate | |
Expected cases | |
Costs per measles case | |
Intervention costs | |
Probability of potential outbreak | |
Drift term of immunization rate of newborns | |
Volatility of immunization rate of newborns | |
Discount rate | |
Solving the problem formulated in Section 2 requires implementation of a dynamic programming algorithm moving backwards with respect to decision time points. The crucial point is the computation of the conditional expected value. Several techniques can be applied; we have adopted the basic and the most popular one, known as the binomial lattice (see e.g. [11]). The basic idea of this approach is a discrete time approximation of the underlying stochastic process
In order to determine the cost efficiency of intervention, we have performed several numerical experiments. As a basic case, we have analyzed the model without intervention. We have simulated stochastic development of the immunization rate of newborns until the first occurrence of an imported measles case, which happens with exogenously given probability
EAC=NPVEAC factor | (8) |
Symbol NPV in Formula 8 represents the net present value of the total costs during the period of the length
EAC factor=1−(11+r)Kr, | (9) |
where
Figure 3a summarizes results for the case without intervention and the initial immunization rate of newborns
Naturally, as the initial average vaccination coverage increases, expected costs decline. However, it is important to realize that this curve declines quite sharply: a decrease of
The results of the sensitivity analysis on the initial immunization rate of newborns are presented in Figure 3b. The dashed curve represents the situation when the initial average vaccination coverage is
In this section we explore the model incorporating intervention options. In the first step of calculation, the so called decision tool is created. It means that for each combination of state variables we determine whether it is optimal to intervene or not. Figure 4 shows the typical shape of decision diagrams under the stochastic immunization rate of newborns.
On all subfigures, the
As a further step we have run 100000 simulations and compared the expected costs with and without the intervention, thus producing an estimate for the value of the option to intervene. Figure 5 shows the sensitivity of the option value to the two model parameters: the level of the intervention costs
The first observation is rather expected: higher intervention costs decrease costs-effectiveness of an intervention. However, the value of intervention option tends to decrease rather slowly. E.g., the option becomes cost-less for the intervention costs of approx.
Further, the simulations show that under our model setup, an increase in the volatility of the immunization rate of newborns implies an increase in the intervention option value. For the considered range of the intervention costs, the highest considered volatility (
Table 2a summarizes the estimated percentage of annual savings induced by the intervention. For the initial average vaccination coverage
intervention costs(in thousands of €) | savings in exp. costs | inital average vacc coverage | savings in expected costs | |
0 | 8.8% | 92% | 2.3% | |
2 | 6.7% | 93% | 2.9% | |
4 | 4.0% | 94% | 4.4% | |
8 | 3.5% | 95% | 55.9% | |
10 | 2.3% | 96% | 72.5% | |
20 | 2.0% | 97% | 78.6% | |
30 | 1.8% | 98% | 79.9% | |
(A) Initial immunization rate of newborns |
(B) Initial immunization rate of newborns |
However, these results are highly sensitive to the level of the initial average vaccination coverage. As Table 2b shows, if the initial average vaccination coverage is below the critical level needed to achieve herd immunity, the savings in expected costs induced by intervention reach only around
In Table 3 we present the expected time of the first intervention together with the expected number of interventions during the
Initial immunization rate of newborns | Time of first intervention | Number of interventionss | ||
expected | s.e. | expected | s.e. | |
6.87 | 3.79 | 3.48 | 3.05 | |
6.89 | 3.86 | 3.20 | 2.79 | |
7.92 | 4.26 | 3.36 | 2.81 | |
7.92 | 4.34 | 3.10 | 2.68 | |
7.96 | 4.44 | 2.89 | 2.51 | |
9.19 | 4.13 | 3.19 | 2.71 |
This study provides a detailed valuation analysis of cost effectiveness of an intervention aimed to improve the immunization rates of newborns. The impetus comes from the policy makers in Slovakia who are facing decline of the parents' willingness to vaccinate against measles in all regions. However, since a corresponding decline can be observed worldwide the conclusions are of general interest.
We have introduced a decision model assuming that a policy maker faces uncertainty in the future development of the immunization rate of newborns and a random occurrence of imported measles cases. To our knowledge, the presented study is the first attempt to evaluate the option to intervene using real options techniques. This modern valuation approach enables one not just to estimate the value of intervention option but in addition it provides a way to estimate the optimal time to carry out the intervention.
Numerical results indicate the impact of several factors involved in the decision to intervene. We have demonstrated that the value of the option to intervene decreases for high intervention costs. This result is consistent with our expectations since, under the assumptions of the proposed model, the resulting increase in the immunization rate of newborns is independent of the amount invested in intervention. Furthermore, simulations show the importance of early intervention in the population with a long history of high immunization rate of newborns, e.g. with high initial average vaccination coverage. Intervention directed to improve immunization rate of newborns is more cost effective if the average vaccination coverage remains close to the critical boundary needed to achieve herd immunity. Once the average vaccination coverage falls far below the critical boundary, interventions of this type might not be sufficiently efficient due to a long time period needed for generation-based shift. Another significant role in determination of cost-effectiveness of intervention is played by the level of volatility of the underlying stochastic process. Our results illustrate that the less certain we are about the future development of the immunization rate of newborns the more valuable is the option to intervene. Of course, this is the consequence of the proposed model setup: due to the Markov property of GBM intervention helps not just increase but also stabilize immunization rate of newborns to certain extent.
The presented real options model can be extended in several directions. First of all, the specification of the stochastic model for immunization rate of newborns can be modified: In our study the willingness to vaccinate was modeled via a random variable. According to the real options techniques, we have selected GBM as the first natural candidate. However, one can perform a detailed statistical analysis based on the large data set on historical immunization rates in different countries provided by WHO and thus propose a more sophisticated model. The sensitivity of the option value with respect to the model chosen is another interesting aspect. Another subject to modification is the model of the number of expected cases. In our work, this estimation has been based on the assumption of homogeneous population. However, in reality this is rarely the case: typically, the unvaccinated individuals are members of a single local community (the role of the heterogeneous setup is highlighted e.g in [1]). Examples include religious groups, kindergartens or schools which do not require children to be vaccinated in order to be accepted. In the case of a heterogeneous population, micro-level aspects should also be taken into account. The model, presented in this paper, can be modified for this case. For instance, in the case of a kindergarten, age categories can be modeled as state variables. Another natural extension is to analyze the option value under the assumption of an uncertain effect of intervention. This would cover the case of interventions relying on advertisement and education rather than law or other penalty establishment. Finally, the recent large scale European immigration may increase the likelihood of the occurrence of measles cases in particular countries and change the epidemiological dynamics in general. This fact makes the development of a flexible evidence-based dynamic decision making tools even more urgent.
This study was partly supported by Slovak Grant Agency APVV-0096-12.
[1] | [ J. Arino,C. Bauch,F. Brauer,S. M. Driedger,A. L. Greer,S. M. Moghadas,N. J. Pizzi,B. Sander,A. Tuite,P. Van Den Driessche, Pandemic influenza: Modelling and public health perspectives, Math Biosci Eng, 8 (2011): 1-20. |
[2] | [ C. T. Bauch,D. J. Earn, Vaccination and the theory of games, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 101 (2004): 13391-13394. |
[3] | [ R. A. Brealey,S. C. Myers,F. Allen, null, Corporate Finance, Auflage, New York, 2006. |
[4] | [ B. Buonomo,A. d'Onofrio,D. Lacitignola, Modeling of pseudo-rational exemption to vaccination for seir diseases, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 404 (2013): 385-398. |
[5] | [ Z. Chladná,E. Moltchanova, Incentive to vaccinate: A synthesis of two approaches, Acta Mathematica Universitatis Comenianae, 84 (2015): 283-296. |
[6] | [ T. E. Copeland, V. Antikarov and T. E. Copeland, Real Options: A Practitioner's Guide, Texere New York, 2001. |
[7] | [ A. K. Dixit,R. S. Pindyck, null, Investment Under Uncertainty, Princeton university press, 1994. |
[8] | [ A. d'Onofrio, P. Manfredi and P. Poletti, The interplay of public intervention and private choices in determining the outcome of vaccination programmes, PLoS ONE, 7 (2012), e45653. |
[9] | [ Analýza epidemiologickej situácie a činnosti odborov epidemiológie v Slovenskej republike. (In Slovak), 2005-2014, URL http://www.epis.sk/InformacnaCast/Publikacie/VyrocneSpravy.aspx. |
[10] | [ H. Hudečková,S. Straka,M. Avdičová,S. Rusnáková, Health and economic benefits of mandatory regular vaccination in Slovakia. IV. Measles, rubella and mumps (In Slovak), Epidemiologie, mikrobiologie, imunologie: Časopis Společnosti pro epidemiologii a mikrobiologii České lékařské společnosti JE Purkyně, 50 (2001): 31-35. |
[11] | [ J. C. Hull, Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, Pearson Education India, 2006. |
[12] | [ M. J. Keeling,P. Rohani, null, Modeling Infectious Diseases in Humans and Animals, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 2008. |
[13] | [ P. Manfredi and A. d'Onofrio, Modeling the Interplay Between Human Behavior and the Spread of Infectious Diseases, Springer Science & Business Media, 2013. |
[14] | [ Public Health Act, Slovakia 2007, Public Health Protection Act, Slovakia 2007 (In Slovak: Zákon č. 355/2007 Z. z. o ochrane, podpore a rozvoji verejného zdravia a o zmene a doplnení niektorých zákonov), URL http://www.zakonypreludi.sk/zz/2007-355. |
[15] | [ A. Shefer,P. Briss,L. Rodewald,R. Bernier,R. Strikas,H. Yusuf,S. Ndiaye,S. Wiliams,M. Pappaioanou,A. R. Hinman, Improving immunization coverage rates: An evidence-based review of the literature, Epidemiologic Reviews, 21 (1999): 96-142. |
[16] | [ P. J. Smith, S. G. Humiston, E. K. Marcuse, Z. Zhao, C. G. Dorell, C. Howes and B. Hibbs, Parental delay or refusal of vaccine doses, childhood vaccination coverage at 24 months of age, and the health belief model, Public Health Reports, 126 (2011), p135. |
[17] | [ E. Vynnycky,R. White, null, An Introduction to Infectious Disease Modelling, Oxford University Press, 2010. |
[18] | [ WHO 2012, Global measles and rubella strategic plan : 2012-2020. The World Health Organization, URL http://apps.who.int/iris/bitstream/10665/44855/1/9789241503396_eng.pdf. |
[19] | [ WHO 2015, Monitoring and surveillance. Data, statistics and graphics. The World Health Organization, URL http://www.who.int/immunization/monitoring_surveillance/data/en/. |
Time horizon | |
Population size | |
Reproduction number | |
Recovery rate | |
Birth/death rate | |
Expected cases | |
Costs per measles case | |
Intervention costs | |
Probability of potential outbreak | |
Drift term of immunization rate of newborns | |
Volatility of immunization rate of newborns | |
Discount rate | |
intervention costs(in thousands of €) | savings in exp. costs | inital average vacc coverage | savings in expected costs | |
0 | 8.8% | 92% | 2.3% | |
2 | 6.7% | 93% | 2.9% | |
4 | 4.0% | 94% | 4.4% | |
8 | 3.5% | 95% | 55.9% | |
10 | 2.3% | 96% | 72.5% | |
20 | 2.0% | 97% | 78.6% | |
30 | 1.8% | 98% | 79.9% | |
(A) Initial immunization rate of newborns |
(B) Initial immunization rate of newborns |
Initial immunization rate of newborns | Time of first intervention | Number of interventionss | ||
expected | s.e. | expected | s.e. | |
6.87 | 3.79 | 3.48 | 3.05 | |
6.89 | 3.86 | 3.20 | 2.79 | |
7.92 | 4.26 | 3.36 | 2.81 | |
7.92 | 4.34 | 3.10 | 2.68 | |
7.96 | 4.44 | 2.89 | 2.51 | |
9.19 | 4.13 | 3.19 | 2.71 |
Time horizon | |
Population size | |
Reproduction number | |
Recovery rate | |
Birth/death rate | |
Expected cases | |
Costs per measles case | |
Intervention costs | |
Probability of potential outbreak | |
Drift term of immunization rate of newborns | |
Volatility of immunization rate of newborns | |
Discount rate | |
intervention costs(in thousands of €) | savings in exp. costs | inital average vacc coverage | savings in expected costs | |
0 | 8.8% | 92% | 2.3% | |
2 | 6.7% | 93% | 2.9% | |
4 | 4.0% | 94% | 4.4% | |
8 | 3.5% | 95% | 55.9% | |
10 | 2.3% | 96% | 72.5% | |
20 | 2.0% | 97% | 78.6% | |
30 | 1.8% | 98% | 79.9% | |
(A) Initial immunization rate of newborns |
(B) Initial immunization rate of newborns |
Initial immunization rate of newborns | Time of first intervention | Number of interventionss | ||
expected | s.e. | expected | s.e. | |
6.87 | 3.79 | 3.48 | 3.05 | |
6.89 | 3.86 | 3.20 | 2.79 | |
7.92 | 4.26 | 3.36 | 2.81 | |
7.92 | 4.34 | 3.10 | 2.68 | |
7.96 | 4.44 | 2.89 | 2.51 | |
9.19 | 4.13 | 3.19 | 2.71 |