
This paper focuses on the Italian economy and investigates the causal nexus between economic growth, tourism development and labor market dynamics. We performed a two-step analysis. In the first step, we evaluate whether tourism stimulates Italian economic growth or if it is the economic growth that promotes tourism expansion. To get the goal, we use panel data from 1997 to 2019 concerning the GDP and overnight stays in each Italian region. We performed the Granger causality test on the whole panel and analyzed a panelvar model. In the second step, after having established the relationship between the two variables of interest, we extended our analysis to investigate—throughout the estimate of the employment intensity of growth and the impact of GDP growth on employment, at both aggregate and disaggregate level. The main findings of our analysis are as follows: a) the existence of a unidirectional causality going from economic growth to tourism development (i.e., validation of economic-driven tourism growth hypothesis), and b) a significant estimated magnitude of the (average) employment intensity of growth.
Citation: Giorgio Colacchio, Anna Serena Vergori. GDP growth rate, tourism expansion and labor market dynamics: Applied research focused on the Italian economy[J]. National Accounting Review, 2022, 4(3): 310-328. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022018
[1] | Akira Nishimura, Tadaki Inoue, Yoshito Sakakibara, Masafumi Hirota, Akira Koshio, Fumio Kokai, Eric Hu . Optimum molar ratio of H2 and H2O to reduce CO2 using Pd/TiO2. AIMS Materials Science, 2019, 6(4): 464-483. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2019.4.464 |
[2] | Liang Wu . Cu-based mutlinary sulfide nanomaterials for photocatalytic applications. AIMS Materials Science, 2023, 10(5): 909-933. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2023049 |
[3] | Nhung Thi-Tuyet Hoang, Anh Thi-Kim Tran, Nguyen Van Suc, The-Vinh Nguyen . Antibacterial activities of gel-derived Ag-TiO2-SiO2 nanomaterials under different light irradiation. AIMS Materials Science, 2016, 3(2): 339-348. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2016.2.339 |
[4] | Evangelos Karagiannis, Dimitra Papadaki, Margarita N. Assimakopoulos . Circular self-cleaning building materials and fabrics using dual doped TiO2 nanomaterials. AIMS Materials Science, 2022, 9(4): 534-553. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2022032 |
[5] | Ya-Ting Tsu, Yu-Wen Chen . Preparation of gold-containing binary metal clusters by co-deposition-precipitation method and for hydrogenation of chloronitrobenzene. AIMS Materials Science, 2017, 4(3): 738-754. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2017.3.738 |
[6] | Ahmed Z. Abdullah, Adawiya J. Haider, Allaa A. Jabbar . Pure TiO2/PSi and TiO2@Ag/PSi structures as controllable sensor for toxic gases. AIMS Materials Science, 2022, 9(4): 522-533. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2022031 |
[7] | Nahlah Challob Younus, Hussein M. Hussein . A competitive candidate for the Cu2ZnSnS4 compound in solar photocatalytic degradation of organic pollutants. AIMS Materials Science, 2025, 12(2): 380-394. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2025020 |
[8] | Alfa Akustia Widati, Nuryono Nuryono, Indriana Kartini . Water-repellent glass coated with SiO2–TiO2–methyltrimethoxysilane through sol–gel coating. AIMS Materials Science, 2019, 6(1): 10-24. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2019.1.10 |
[9] | Zoubir Chaieb, Ould Mohamed Ouarda, Azzeddine Abderrahmane Raho, Mouhyddine Kadi-Hanifi . Effect of Fe and Si impurities on the precipitation kinetics of the GPB zones in the Al-3wt%Cu-1wt%Mg alloy. AIMS Materials Science, 2016, 3(4): 1443-1455. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2016.4.1443 |
[10] | Ririn Cahyanti, Sumari Sumari, Fauziatul Fajaroh, Muhammad Roy Asrori, Yana Fajar Prakasa . Fe-TiO2/zeolite H-A photocatalyst for degradation of waste dye (methylene blue) under UV irradiation. AIMS Materials Science, 2023, 10(1): 40-54. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2023003 |
This paper focuses on the Italian economy and investigates the causal nexus between economic growth, tourism development and labor market dynamics. We performed a two-step analysis. In the first step, we evaluate whether tourism stimulates Italian economic growth or if it is the economic growth that promotes tourism expansion. To get the goal, we use panel data from 1997 to 2019 concerning the GDP and overnight stays in each Italian region. We performed the Granger causality test on the whole panel and analyzed a panelvar model. In the second step, after having established the relationship between the two variables of interest, we extended our analysis to investigate—throughout the estimate of the employment intensity of growth and the impact of GDP growth on employment, at both aggregate and disaggregate level. The main findings of our analysis are as follows: a) the existence of a unidirectional causality going from economic growth to tourism development (i.e., validation of economic-driven tourism growth hypothesis), and b) a significant estimated magnitude of the (average) employment intensity of growth.
There are different patterns of rumor spreading depending on the presence or absence of online media [7], for example, the emergence of influential spreaders [2]. Before the development of online media, rumors were transmitted from person to person. With the development of online media such as social network service (SNS), personal broadcasting, blog, and group chatting, rumors can now spread in a variety of ways. In the past, offline media was the starting point and an important means of information delivery. Recently, it has become a social problem that offline media reproduces and delivers rumors from online media. This is a sign that information in online is rapidly being accepted by various social classes. In this paper, we study how the combination of classical interpersonal rumor spreading and online media influences rumor outbreak.
In order to consider the influence of online media, we denote by
dIdt=b−λsIS−λwIW−δiI,dSdt=λsIS+λwIW−σsSS−σrSR−μS−δsS,dWdt=ξS−δwW,dRdt=σsSS+σrSR+μS−δrR. | (1) |
Remark 1. (1) This rumor spreading process is a relatively short time process. Thus, we do not consider vertical transmission. See [8].
(2) If we take
Since the Daley-Kendall model [3], various studies on rumor spreading have been conducted. We briefly state the history of rumor spreading models associated with online media. See [12] for a general rumor spread, and [14] for threshold phenomena for general epidemic models. Since information transmission via online media developed in the late 1990s, intensive researches on rumors and online media began mainly in the early 2000s. In [1], the authors focused on the spread of computer-based rumors and analyzed the spread of rumors via computer-based communication in terms of information transmission. The authors in [7] noted the difference between online-based media and offline media. The study in [17] considered the spread of rumors through online networks by using the SIR model. The fast speed and unprofessional communication of online media is considered in [13]. See also [9]. In [11], a statistical rumor diffusion model is considered for online networks and it contained positive and negative bipolar reinforcement factors. [4,6,18] studied a rumor propagation model similar to the European fox rabies SIR model for the situation of changing online community number. In [10], the authors studied the rumor propagation phenomena for a model with two layers: online and offline. See also [19] for the SEIR type online rumor model.
This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present the nonnegativity property of the solution to (1) and the stability of the rumor-free equilibrium. The basic reproduction number
In this section, we consider the conservation of nonnegativity of the densities
Lemma 2.1. Let
S(0)2+W(0)2>0, |
then the solution is nonnegative for all
Proof. We take any positive
|I(t)|,|S(t)|,|W(t)|,|R(t)|<C(T). |
By the first equation in (1) and the boundedness, if
I(t)=I(0)e−∫t0(λsS(s)+λwW(s)+δi)ds+b∫t0e−∫tu(λsS(s)+λwW(s)+δi)dsdu>0. |
We first prove that
S(t−s)<0. |
Let
S(t)=S(0)e∫t0(λsI(s)−σsS(s)−σrR(s)−μ−δs)ds+∫t0λwI(u)W(u)e∫tu(λsI(s)−σsS(s)−σrR(s)−μ−δs)dsdu. | (2) |
This and the positivity of
W(t)=W(0)e−δwt+∫t0ξS(u)e−δw(t−u)du. | (3) |
Thus,
However, on
(I(t),S(t),W(t),R(t))=(I(t0)e−δi(t−t0)+b(1−e−δi(t−t0))δi,0,0,R(t0)e−δr(t−t0)) |
is a solution to (1). By uniqueness of the solution, there is no
Similarly, we can also easily obtain that there is no
Moreover, if
In this part, we calculate the basic reproduction number using a next-generation matrix. To consider the asymptotic behavior of the dynamics in (1), we determine the equilibrium point such that
˙I=˙S=˙W=˙R=0. | (4) |
If we assume that there is no rumor
E0=(Irf,Srf,Wrf,Rrf)=(bδi,0,0,0). |
The basic reproduction number
For the infected compartments, the next generation matrices at the rumor-free state
F=1δi(bλsbλw00)andV=(μ+δs0−ξδw), |
and hence
V−1=1(μ+δs)δw(δw0ξμ+δs). |
Here,
FV−1=(bλs(μ+δs)δi+bλwξ(μ+δs)δiδwbλwδiδw00). |
Therefore, we obtain the following formula for the basic reproduction number:
R0=ρ(FV−1)=bδi(λsμ+δs+λwξ(μ+δs)δw). |
Here,
For the linear stability, we consider the Jacobian matrix as follows.
J=(−λsS−λwW−δi−λsI−λwI0λsS+λwWλsI−2σsS−σrR−μ−δsλwI−σrS0ξ−δw002σsS+σrR+μ0σrS−δr). |
Since the rumor-free equilibrium is
E0=(bδi,0,0,0), |
the Jacobian matrix at the rumor-free equilibrium is given by
JE0=(−δi−λsbδi−λwbδi00λsbδi−μ−δsλwbδi00ξ−δw00μ0−δr). |
Therefore, the corresponding characteristic equation is
p(x)=(x+δr)(x+δi)×(x2−(bλsδi−μ−δs−δw)x−bδwλsδi+μδw+δsδw−bλwξδi). |
Assume that
bδiλsμ+δs<bδi(λsμ+δs+λwξ(μ+δs)δw)<1. |
Thus,
c1:=−(bλsδi−μ−δs−δw)>δw>0. |
Note that
c2:=−bδwλsδi+(μ+δs)δw−bλwξδi=δw(μ+δs)(−bλsδi(μ+δs)−bλwξδiδw(μ+δs)+1)=δw(μ+δs)(1−R0)>0. |
Clearly,
p0(x)=x2−(bλsδi−μ−δs−δw)x−bδwλsδi+(μ+δs)δw−bλwξδi=x2+c1x+c2. |
Since
Clearly, if
Theorem 2.2. The rumor-free equilibrium
The rumor-free equilibrium
Theorem 2.3. If
{(I,S,R,W):S>0orW>0}∩{(I,S,W,R):I,S,W,R≥0}. |
Proof. Let
V0(I,S,W)=[I−Irf−IrflogIIrf]+S+IrfλsδwW, |
where
I−Irf−IrflogIIrf>0,forI≠Irf, |
and
I−Irf−IrflogIIrf=0,forI=Irf, |
we note that
dV0dt=(b−λsIS−λwIW−δiI)−bδi(bI−λsS−λsW−δi)+λsIS+λwIW−σsSS−σrSR−(μ+δs)S+bλsδiδw(ξS−δwW)=b−δiI−σsSS−σrSR−(μ+δs)S+bλsδiδw(ξS−δwW)−bδi(bI−λsS−λsW−δi)=−b(bδiI+δiIb−2)−σsSS−σrSR−(μ+δs)S+bλsδiδw(ξS−δwW)+bδi(λsS+λsW)=−b(bδiI+δiIb−2)−σsSS−σrSR−(μ+δs)S(1−bλs(μ+δs)δi−bλsξ(μ+δs)δiδw). |
Therefore, we have
dV0dt=−b(bδiI+δiIb−2)−σsSS−σrSR−(μ+δs)S(1−R0). | (5) |
Note that by Lemma 2.1 in Section 2,
dV0dt<0. |
Therefore,
Therefore, the rumor-free equilibrium
In this section, we present the existence and stability of endemic steady states for the rumor spreading model with an online reservoir. Endemic state refers to a nonzero steady state of
To obtain the endemic equilibrium
E∗=(I∗,S∗,W∗,R∗), |
we consider the following steady state equation:
dIdt=dSdt=dWdt=dRdt=0. |
Then the endemic equilibrium
0=b−λsI∗S∗−λwI∗W∗−δiI∗,0=λsI∗S∗+λwI∗W∗−σsS∗S∗−σrS∗R∗−μS∗−δsS∗,0=ξS∗−δwW∗,0=σsS∗S∗+σrS∗R∗+μS∗−δrR∗. |
We set
U∗=δwξW∗,˜I∗=δiI∗,˜S∗=δsS∗,˜R∗=δrR∗, |
and
˜μ=μδs,˜λs=λsδw+λwξδiδsδw,˜σs=σsδ2s,˜σr=σrδsδr. |
Then
0=b−˜λs˜I∗˜S∗−˜I∗,0=˜λs˜I∗˜S∗−˜σs˜S∗˜S∗−˜σr˜S∗˜R∗−˜μ˜S∗−˜S∗,0=˜σs˜S∗˜S∗+˜σr˜S∗˜R∗+˜μ˜S∗−˜R∗. | (6) |
Note that the basic reproduction number satisfies
R0=b˜λs˜μ+1. |
To find endemic equilibrium
˜S∗>0. |
The sum of all equations in (6) implies that
˜R∗=(b−˜I∗−˜S∗). | (7) |
From the second equation in (6),
(˜λs˜S∗+˜σr˜S∗)˜I∗=˜σs˜S∗˜S∗−˜σr˜S∗˜S∗+(˜μ+1)˜S∗+˜σrb˜S∗. | (8) |
By (7)-(8),
˜I∗=˜σs−˜σr˜λs+˜σr˜S∗+˜μ+1+˜σrb˜λs+˜σr:=β˜S∗+γ. |
Substituting
b−˜λs(β˜S∗+γ)˜S∗−(β˜S∗+γ)=0. |
Therefore, we have
β˜λs˜S2∗+(˜λsγ+β)˜S∗+γ−b=0. | (9) |
If we obtain positive
˜I∗=b˜λs˜S∗+1 |
and
˜R∗=˜σs˜S∗˜S∗+˜μ˜S∗1−˜σr˜S∗. |
Thus, if all components are nonnegative,
S∗<1˜σr. | (10) |
Theorem 3.1. If
Proof. Assume that
● Case 1
˜S∗=b−γ˜λsγ=bb˜σr+˜μ+1R0−1R0<1˜σr. |
Condition (10) holds, which implies that a positive endemic state
● Case 2
˜S2∗+(b˜σr+˜μ+1˜σs−˜σr+1˜λs)˜S∗+b˜σs−˜σr1−R0R0=0. |
Since
b˜σs−˜σr1−R0R0<0. |
Therefore, there is a unique positive real root of the equation. To check the condition in (10), let
f(x)=x2+(b˜σr+˜μ+1˜σs−˜σr+1˜λs)x+b˜σs−˜σr1−R0R0. | (11) |
By elementary calculation,
f(1/˜σr)=(˜λs+˜σr)(˜μ˜σr+˜σs)˜λs˜σ2r(˜σs−˜σr). | (12) |
Thus,
● Case 3
D=(b˜σr+˜μ+1˜σs−˜σr+1˜λs)2−4b˜σs−˜σr1−R0R0. |
Since we assume that
Let
g(x)=(x−˜σr+˜λs(1+˜μ+b˜σr))2−4˜λs(−1−˜μ+b˜λs)(˜σr−x). |
Then the discriminant is represented as for
D=g(˜σs)(˜λs+˜σr)2. |
Note that
x=−b˜σr˜λs+˜σr−2b˜λ2s+˜μ˜λs+˜λs. |
Since we assume that
−b˜σr˜λs+˜σr−2b˜λ2s+˜μ˜λs+˜λs<−(˜μ+1)˜σr+˜σr−2b˜λ2s+˜μ˜λs+˜λs=−˜μ˜σr+˜λs(−2b˜λs+˜μ+1)<0. |
Therefore, the minimum value of
g(˜σs)≥g(0)=(˜λs(b˜σr+˜μ+1)−˜σr)2+4˜σr˜λs(−b˜λs+˜μ+1)=:h(˜σr). |
We consider
h(˜σr)≥4b˜μ˜λ3s(b˜λs−˜μ−1)(b˜λs−1)2>0. |
Therefore,
b˜σs−˜σr1−R0R0>0. |
Thus,
By (12) and
f(1/˜σr)=(˜λs+˜σr)(˜μ˜σr+˜σs)˜λs˜σ2r(˜σs−˜σr)<0. |
Therefore,
For any case, we conclude that if
For the remaining part, we assume that
● Case 1
˜S∗=b−γ˜λsγ=bb˜σr+˜μ+1R0−1R0≤0. |
Thus there is no positive endemic state
● Case 2
D=g(˜σs)(˜λs+˜σr)2 |
and
Since we assume that
b˜σs−˜σr1−R0R0≥0, |
this implies that if
Note that
x=−bσrλs+μλs+λs+(σs−σr)2λs(σs−σr)<0. |
Thus,
● Case 3
˜S2∗+(b˜σr+˜μ+1˜σs−˜σr+1˜λs)˜S∗+b˜σs−˜σr1−R0R0=0. |
Since
b˜σs−˜σr1−R0R0≥0. |
Therefore, there is at most one positive real root of the equation. However,
f(1/˜σr)=(˜λs+˜σr)(˜μ˜σr+˜σs)˜λs˜σ2r(˜σs−˜σr)<0. |
Thus, (10) does not hold. This implies that there is no positive endemic equilibrium
Therefore, we conclude that if
In this part, we consider asymptotic stability for the endemic state
Theorem 3.2. If
{(I,S,R,W):S>0orW>0}∩{(I,S,W,R):I,S,W,R≥0}. |
Proof. Let
V∗(I,S,W,R)=[I−I∗−I∗logII∗]+[S−S∗−S∗logSS∗]+λwδwI∗[W−W∗−W∗logWW∗]+R∗σrμ+R∗σr[R−R∗−R∗logRR∗]=:J1+J2+J3+J4. |
In the same manner as Theorem 2.3, note that
We claim that if
dV∗dt<0. |
Since
(b−λsI∗S∗−λwI∗W∗−δiI∗)=0. |
Therefore,
dJ1dt=(b−λsIS−λwIW−δiI)(1−I∗I)+(b−λsI∗S∗−λwI∗W∗−δiI∗)(1−II∗)=b(2−I∗I−II∗)−λs(I∗−I)(S∗−S)−λw(I∗−I)(W∗−W). |
Similarly,
(λsI∗S∗+λwI∗W∗−σsS∗S∗−σrS∗R∗−μS∗)=0. |
This implies that
dJ2dt=(λsIS+λwIW−σsSS−σrSR−(μ+δs)S)(1−S∗S)+(λsI∗S∗+λwI∗W∗−σsS∗S∗−σrS∗R∗−(μ+δs)S∗)(1−SS∗)=λs(I∗−I)(S∗−S)−σs(S∗−S)(S∗−S)−σr(R∗−R)(S∗−S)+λwIW(1−S∗S)+λwI∗W∗(1−SS∗). |
Note that
dJ3dt=λwδwI∗(ξS−δwW)(1−W∗W). |
We add the derivatives of
d(J1+J2+J3)dt−b(2−I∗I−II∗)+σs(S∗−S)(S∗−S)+σr(R∗−R)(S∗−S)=−λw(I∗−I)(W∗−W)+λwIW(1−S∗S)+λwI∗W∗(1−SS∗)+λwδwI∗(ξS−δwW)(1−W∗W)=λwI∗W+λwIW∗−λwIS∗SW−λwI∗SS∗W∗+λwδwI∗(ξS−δwW)(1−W∗W). |
Using
d(J1+J2+J3)dt−b(2−I∗I−II∗)+σs(S∗−S)(S∗−S)+σr(R∗−R)(S∗−S)=λw(IW∗−IS∗SW−ξδwI∗W∗WS+I∗W∗). | (13) |
Using
IW∗−IS∗SW−ξδwI∗W∗WS+I∗W∗=(IW∗+I∗I∗IW∗−2I∗W∗)−(ξδwI∗SW∗W+IS∗SW+I∗I∗IW∗−3I∗W∗)=I∗W∗(II∗+I∗I−2)−ξδwI∗W∗(SW+δ2wξ2IWI∗S+δwξI∗I−3δwξ). | (14) |
Combining (13) and (14) with
d(J1+J2+J3)dt=(λwξδwI∗S∗−b)(II∗+I∗I−2)−λwξ2δ2wI∗S∗(SW+δ2wξ2IWI∗S+δwξI∗I−3δwξ)−σs(SS+S∗S∗−2SS∗)−σr(SR+S∗R∗−S∗R−R∗S). |
Since
σsS∗S∗+σrS∗R∗+μS∗−δrR∗=0, |
we have
μ+R∗σrR∗σrdJ4dt=dRdt(1−R∗R)=(σsSS+σrSR+μS−δrR)(1−R∗R)+(σsS∗S∗+σrS∗R∗+μS∗−δrR∗)(1−RR∗)=σs(SS+S∗S∗−R∗RSS−RR∗S∗S∗)+σr(SR+S∗R∗−R∗RRS−RR∗R∗S∗)+μ(S+S∗−R∗RS−RR∗S∗). |
Then we have
dV∗dt=(λwξδwI∗S∗−b)(II∗+I∗I−2)−λwξ2δ2wI∗S∗(SW+δ2wξ2IWI∗S+δwξI∗I−3δwξ)−σs(SS+S∗S∗−2SS∗)−σr(SR+S∗R∗−S∗R−R∗S)+R∗σrμ+R∗σrσs(SS+S∗S∗−R∗RSS−RR∗S∗S∗)+R∗σrμ+R∗σrσr(SR+S∗R∗−R∗RRS−RR∗R∗S∗) |
+R∗σrμ+R∗σrμ(S+S∗−R∗RS−RR∗S∗). |
Note that
−σs(SS+S∗S∗−2SS∗)+R∗σrμ+R∗σrσs(SS+S∗S∗−R∗RSS−RR∗S∗S∗)=−μμ+R∗σrσs(SS+S∗S∗−2SS∗)−R∗σrμ+R∗σrσsS∗S(R∗RSS∗+RR∗S∗S−2) |
and
−σr(SR+S∗R∗−S∗R−R∗S)+R∗σrμ+R∗σrσr(SR+S∗R∗−R∗RRS−RR∗R∗S∗)+R∗σrμ+R∗σrμ(S+S∗−R∗RS−RR∗S∗)=−R∗σrμ+R∗σrμS(RR∗+R∗R−2). |
In conclusion, we have
dV∗dt=(λwξδwI∗S∗−b)(II∗+I∗I−2)−λwξ2δ2wI∗S∗(SW+δ2wξ2IWI∗S+δwξI∗I−3δwξ)−μμ+R∗σrσs(SS+S∗S∗−2SS∗)−R∗σrμ+R∗σrσsS∗S(R∗RSS∗+RR∗S∗S−2)−R∗σrμ+R∗σrμS(RR∗+R∗R−2). |
From the first equation in (1), it follows that
b=λsI∗S∗+λwI∗W∗+δiI∗=λsI∗S∗+λwξδwI∗S∗+δiI∗. |
This implies that
λwξδwI∗S∗−b=−λsI∗S∗−δiI∗<0. |
By the relationship between arithmetic and geometric means, if
(I(t),S(t),W(t),R(t))≠(I∗,S∗,W∗,R∗)andS(t)>0, |
then
dV∗dt<0. |
If we assume that
{(I,S,R,W):S>0orW>0}∩{(I,S,W,R):I,S,W,R≥0}. |
In this section, we carry out some numerical simulations to verify the theoretical results. We use the fourth-order Runge-Kutta method with time step size
As shown before, the basic reproduction number is
R0=ρ(FV−1)=bδi(λsμ+δs+λwξ(μ+δs)δw). |
We assume that the influx
Now, we investigate the influence of an online reservoir. We change
Even though the contact rates
We next compare the SIR and SIWR models. Without online an reservoir, the basic reproduction number of the SIR model is given by
RSIR0=bλs(μ+δs)δi. |
If we fix the parameters such as
In this paper, we consider a rumor spreading model with an online reservoir. By using a next-generation matrix, we calculated the basic reproduction number
S.-H. Choi and H. Seo are partially supported by National Research Foundation (NRF) of Korea (no. 2017R1E1A1A03070692). H. Seo is partially supported by NRF of Korea (no. 2020R1I1A1A01069585).
[1] | Abonazel MR (2016) Bias correction methods for dynamic panel data models with fixed effects. Available from: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/70628/ |
[2] | Abrigo MRM, Love I (2016) Estimation of Panel Vector Autoregression in Stata. 16: 778–804. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X1601600314 |
[3] |
Antonakakis N, Dragouni M, Eeckels B (2019) The tourism and economic growth enigma: examining an ambiguous relationship through multiple prisms. J Travel Res 58: 3–24. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047287517744671 doi: 10.1177/0047287517744671
![]() |
[4] |
Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58: 277–297. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297968 doi: 10.2307/2297968
![]() |
[5] | Arthur BW (1994) Increasing returns and Path Dependence in the Economy. University of Michigan Press. https://doi.org/10.3998/mpub.10029 |
[6] |
Aslan A (2013) Tourism development and economic growth in the Mediterranean countries: evidence from panel Granger causality tests. Curr Issues Tour 17: 363–372. https://doi.org/10.1080/13683500.2013.768607 doi: 10.1080/13683500.2013.768607
![]() |
[7] |
Balaguer J, Cantavella-Jordà M (2002) Tourism as a long-run economic growth factor: the Spanish case. Appl Econ 34: 877–884. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036840110058923 doi: 10.1080/00036840110058923
![]() |
[8] |
Baum CF, Schaffer ME, Stillman S (2003) Instrumental variables and GMM: Estimation and testing. Stata J 3: 1–31. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X0300300101 doi: 10.1177/1536867X0300300101
![]() |
[9] | Boltho A, Glyn A (1995) Can Macroeconomic Policies Raise Employment? Int Labour Rev 134: 451–470. |
[10] |
Breitung J, Das S (2005) Panel unit root tests under cross-sectional dependence. Stat Neerl 59: 414–433. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9574.2005.00299.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9574.2005.00299.x
![]() |
[11] |
Brida J, Cortes-Jimenez I, Pulina M (2016) Has the tourism-led growth hypothesis been validated? A literature review. Curr Issues Tour 19: 394–430. https://doi.org/10.1080/13683500.2013.868414 doi: 10.1080/13683500.2013.868414
![]() |
[12] | Busetti F, Cova P (2013) L'impatto macroeconomico della crisi del debito sovrano: un'analisi controfattuale per l'economia italiana. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2405442 |
[13] |
Cardenas-Garcia PJ, Sanchez-Rivero M, Pulido-Fernandez JI (2015) Does Tourism Growth Influence Economic Development? J Travel Res 54: 206–221. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047287513514297 doi: 10.1177/0047287513514297
![]() |
[14] |
Centinaio A, Comerio N, Pacicco F (2022) Arrivederci! An Analysis of Tourism Impact in the Italian Provinces. Int J Hosp Tour Adm. https://doi.org/10.1080/15256480.2021.2025187 doi: 10.1080/15256480.2021.2025187
![]() |
[15] |
Chen CF, Chiou-Wei SZ (2009) Tourism Expansion, Tourism Uncertainty and Economic Growth: New Evidence from Taiwan and Korea. Tourism Manage 30: 812–818. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2008.12.013 doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2008.12.013
![]() |
[16] |
Chirilă V, Butnaru GI, Chirilă C (2020) Spillover Index Approach in Investigating the Linkage between International Tourism and Economic Growth in Central and Eastern European Countries. Sustainability 12: 1–36. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12187604 doi: 10.3390/su12187604
![]() |
[17] |
Chiu YB, Yeh LT (2017) The threshold effects of the tourism-led growth hypothesis: evidence from a cross-sectional model. J Travel Res 56: 625–637. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047287516650938 doi: 10.1177/0047287516650938
![]() |
[18] |
Choi I (2001) Unit root tests for panel data. J Int Money Financ 20: 249–272. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0261-5606(00)00048-6 doi: 10.1016/S0261-5606(00)00048-6
![]() |
[19] |
Cortés-Jiménez J (2008) Which type of tourism matters to the regional economic growth? The cases of Spain and Italy. Int J Tour Res 10: 127–139. https://doi.org/10.1002/jtr.646 doi: 10.1002/jtr.646
![]() |
[20] |
Cortes-Jimenez J, Pulin M (2010) Inbound tourism and long-run economic growth. Curr Issues Tour 13: 61–74. https://doi.org/10.1080/13683500802684411 doi: 10.1080/13683500802684411
![]() |
[21] | Crivelli E, Furceri D, Toujas-Bernaté J (2012) Can policies affect employment intensity of growth? A cross-country analysis. Available from: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12218.pdf. |
[22] |
Ditzen J (2018) Estimating dynamic common correlated effects in Stata. Stata J 18: 585–617. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X1801800306 doi: 10.1177/1536867X1801800306
![]() |
[23] |
Dogru T, Bulut U (2018) Is tourism an engine for economic recovery? Theory and empirical evidence. Tour Manag 67: 425–434. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2017.06.014 doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2017.06.014
![]() |
[24] |
Dumitrescu EI, Hurlin C (2012) Testing for Granger non-causality in heterogeneous panels. Econ Model 29: 1450–1460. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2012.02.014 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2012.02.014
![]() |
[25] | ECB (2016) The employment-GDP relationship since the crisis. Available from: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/eb201606_article01.en.pdf. |
[26] | Eugenio-Martin JL, Morales NM, Scarpa R (2004) Tourism and Economic Growth in Latin American Countries: A Panel Data Approach. Available from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=504482. |
[27] |
Fonseca N, Sanchez-Rivero M (2019) Publication bias and genuine effects: the case of Granger causality between tourism and income. Curr Issues Tour 23: 1084–1108 https://doi.org/10.1080/13683500.2019.1585419 doi: 10.1080/13683500.2019.1585419
![]() |
[28] |
Hadri K (2000) Testing for stationarity in heterogeneous panel data. Economet J 3: 148–161. https://doi.org/10.1111/1368-423X.00043 doi: 10.1111/1368-423X.00043
![]() |
[29] |
Hoechle D (2007) Robust standard errors for panel regressions with cross-sectional dependence. Stata J 7: 281–312. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X0700700301 doi: 10.1177/1536867X0700700301
![]() |
[30] |
Hwang J, Sun Y (2018) Should we go one-step further? An accurate comparison of one-step and two-step procedures in a generalized method of moments framework. J Econom 207: 381–405. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2018.07.006 doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2018.07.006
![]() |
[31] | Italian Government (2021) Recovery and resilience Plan. Available from: https://www.governo.it/sites/governo.it/files/PNRR.pdf. |
[32] |
Ivanov SH, Webster C (2013) Tourism's contribution to economic growth: a global analysis for the first decade of the millennium. Tourism Econ 19: 477–508. doi: 10.5367/te.2013.0211
![]() |
[33] |
Labra R, Torrecillas C (2018) Estimating dynamic Panel data. A practicalapproach to perform long panels. Revista Colombiana de Estadística 41: 31–52. https://doi.org/10.15446/rce.v41n1.61885 doi: 10.15446/rce.v41n1.61885
![]() |
[34] |
Levin A, Lin CF, Chu CSJ (2002) Unit root test in panel data: asymptotic and finite sample properties. J Econom 108: 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(01)00098-7 doi: 10.1016/S0304-4076(01)00098-7
![]() |
[35] |
Massidda C, Mattana P (2012) A SVECM Analysis of the relationship between international tourism arrivals, GDP and trade in Italy. J Travel Res 52: 93–105. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047287512457262 doi: 10.1177/0047287512457262
![]() |
[36] | Mehrhoff J (2009) A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2785360 |
[37] |
Pablo-Romero M, Molina J (2013) Tourism and economic growth: A review of empirical literature. Tour Manag Perspect 8: 28–41. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tmp.2013.05.006 doi: 10.1016/j.tmp.2013.05.006
![]() |
[38] | Padalino S, Vivarelli M (1997) The Employment Intensity of Economic Growth in the G-7 Countries. Int Labour Rev 136: 191–213. |
[39] |
Pesaran H (2003) A Simple Panel Unit Root Test in the Presence of Cross Section Dependence. J Appl Economet 22: 265–312. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.951 doi: 10.1002/jae.951
![]() |
[40] |
Proença S, Soukiazis E (2008) Tourism as an economic growth factor: a case study for Southern European countries. Tourism Econ 14: 791–806. https://doi.org/10.5367/000000008786440175 doi: 10.5367/000000008786440175
![]() |
[41] |
Roodman D (2009) How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM. Stata J 9: 86–136. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867X0900900106 doi: 10.1177/1536867X0900900106
![]() |
[42] |
Sharpley R (2022) Tourism and (sustainable) development: Revisiting the theoretical divide. Tourism in Development: reflective essays, 13–24. https://doi.org/10.1079/9781789242812.000 doi: 10.1079/9781789242812.000
![]() |
[43] |
Sigmund M, Ferstl R (2019) Panel vector Autoregression in R with the packagepanelvar. Q Rev Econ Financ 80: 693–720. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.qref.2019.01.001 doi: 10.1016/j.qref.2019.01.001
![]() |
[44] |
Shahbaz M, Ferrer R, Shahzad SJH, et al. (2017) Is the tourism–economic growth nexus time-varying? Bootstrap rolling-window causality analysis for the top 10 tourist destinations. Appl Econ. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2017.1406655 doi: 10.1080/00036846.2017.1406655
![]() |
[45] |
Shahzad SJH, Shahbaz M, Ferrer R, et al. (2017) Tourism-led growth hypothesis in the top ten tourist destinations: new evidence using the quantile-on-quantile approach. Tourism Manage 60: 223–232. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2016.12.006 doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2016.12.006
![]() |
[46] | SVIMEZ (2019) Rapporto SVIMEZ 2019, Rome. |
[47] |
Tugcu CT (2014) Tourism and economic growth nexus revisited: A panel causality analysis for the case of the Mediterranean region. Tourism Manage 42: 207–212. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2013.12.007 doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2013.12.007
![]() |
[48] |
Vergori AS (2017) Patterns of seasonality and tourism demand forecasting. Tourism Econ 23: 1011–1027. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2020.104263 doi: 10.1177/1354816616656418
![]() |
[49] |
Zellner A (1962) An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for aggregation bias. J Am Stat Assoc 57: 348–368. doi: 10.1080/01621459.1962.10480664
![]() |
1. | Akira Nishimura, 2021, Chapter 4, 978-1-83968-223-0, 10.5772/intechopen.93105 | |
2. | B. Toubal, K. Elkourd, R. Bouab, O. Abdelaziz, The impact of copper–cerium (Cu–Ce) addition on anatase-TiO2 nanostructured films for its inactivation of Escherichia coli and Staphylococcus aureus, 2022, 103, 0928-0707, 549, 10.1007/s10971-022-05763-7 | |
3. | Akira Nishimura, Ryouga Shimada, Yoshito Sakakibara, Akira Koshio, Eric Hu, Comparison of CO2 Reduction Performance with NH3 and H2O between Cu/TiO2 and Pd/TiO2, 2021, 26, 1420-3049, 2904, 10.3390/molecules26102904 | |
4. | Akira Nishimura, Impact of molar ratio of NH3 and H2O on CO2 reduction performance over Cu/TiO2 photocatalyst, 2019, 3, 25764543, 176, 10.15406/paij.2019.03.00179 |