Loading [MathJax]/jax/element/mml/optable/GeneralPunctuation.js
Research article

COVID-19 and liquidity risk, exploring the relationship dynamics between liquidity cost and stock market returns

  • The impact on economic aspects of the COVID-19 is continuing under discussion. This study unveils effects of the pandemic on relationship dynamics between liquidity cost and stock market returns. Using the time series and machine learning techniques, the analysis is based on the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJI) index. If the entire dataset was examined, the liquidity cost was found to be positive and significantly related to the DJI index returns. From the VAR estimation, the market returns were significantly explained by past values of the liquidity cost. The statistical Granger-causality was also observed between variables. If the relationship was analyzed during peak restrictions, the results were changed. The liquidity cost was observed to be negative and insignificantly related to the DJI index returns. The market returns were not associated with lags of the liquidity cost. In addition, the Granger-causality was not found between variables. If effects associated with easing restrictions were examined, the liquidity cost was found to be positive and significantly associated with returns on the DJI index. Meanwhile, the returns were more sensitive to the liquidity cost. However, the market returns were not explained by lags of the liquidity cost. The liquidity cost did not Granger-cause returns. The findings suggest that the liquidity cost must be priced in returns due to the pandemic-related uncertainty.

    Citation: Jawad Saleemi. COVID-19 and liquidity risk, exploring the relationship dynamics between liquidity cost and stock market returns[J]. National Accounting Review, 2021, 3(2): 218-236. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2021011

    Related Papers:

    [1] Xiaotian Hao, Lingzhong Zeng . Eigenvalues of the bi-Xin-Laplacian on complete Riemannian manifolds. Communications in Analysis and Mechanics, 2023, 15(2): 162-176. doi: 10.3934/cam.2023009
    [2] Velimir Jurdjevic . Time optimal problems on Lie groups and applications to quantum control. Communications in Analysis and Mechanics, 2024, 16(2): 345-387. doi: 10.3934/cam.2024017
    [3] Vladimir Rovenski . Generalized Ricci solitons and Einstein metrics on weak K-contact manifolds. Communications in Analysis and Mechanics, 2023, 15(2): 177-188. doi: 10.3934/cam.2023010
    [4] Floyd L. Williams . From a magnetoacoustic system to a J-T black hole: A little trip down memory lane. Communications in Analysis and Mechanics, 2023, 15(3): 342-361. doi: 10.3934/cam.2023017
    [5] Jinguo Zhang, Shuhai Zhu . On criticality coupled sub-Laplacian systems with Hardy type potentials on Stratified Lie groups. Communications in Analysis and Mechanics, 2023, 15(2): 70-90. doi: 10.3934/cam.2023005
    [6] Jonas Schnitzer . No-go theorems for r-matrices in symplectic geometry. Communications in Analysis and Mechanics, 2024, 16(3): 448-456. doi: 10.3934/cam.2024021
    [7] Ying Chu, Bo Wen, Libo Cheng . Existence and blow up for viscoelastic hyperbolic equations with variable exponents. Communications in Analysis and Mechanics, 2024, 16(4): 717-737. doi: 10.3934/cam.2024032
    [8] Richard Cushman . Normalization and reduction of the Stark Hamiltonian. Communications in Analysis and Mechanics, 2023, 15(3): 457-469. doi: 10.3934/cam.2023022
    [9] Zhiyong Wang, Kai Zhao, Pengtao Li, Yu Liu . Boundedness of square functions related with fractional Schrödinger semigroups on stratified Lie groups. Communications in Analysis and Mechanics, 2023, 15(3): 410-435. doi: 10.3934/cam.2023020
    [10] Jinli Yang, Jiajing Miao . Algebraic Schouten solitons of Lorentzian Lie groups with Yano connections. Communications in Analysis and Mechanics, 2023, 15(4): 763-791. doi: 10.3934/cam.2023037
  • The impact on economic aspects of the COVID-19 is continuing under discussion. This study unveils effects of the pandemic on relationship dynamics between liquidity cost and stock market returns. Using the time series and machine learning techniques, the analysis is based on the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJI) index. If the entire dataset was examined, the liquidity cost was found to be positive and significantly related to the DJI index returns. From the VAR estimation, the market returns were significantly explained by past values of the liquidity cost. The statistical Granger-causality was also observed between variables. If the relationship was analyzed during peak restrictions, the results were changed. The liquidity cost was observed to be negative and insignificantly related to the DJI index returns. The market returns were not associated with lags of the liquidity cost. In addition, the Granger-causality was not found between variables. If effects associated with easing restrictions were examined, the liquidity cost was found to be positive and significantly associated with returns on the DJI index. Meanwhile, the returns were more sensitive to the liquidity cost. However, the market returns were not explained by lags of the liquidity cost. The liquidity cost did not Granger-cause returns. The findings suggest that the liquidity cost must be priced in returns due to the pandemic-related uncertainty.



    A harmonic map between Riemannian manifolds (M,g), dim (M)=m, and (N,h), dim (N)=n, are smooth maps giving the minimum to the energy functional

    E(f)=Me(f)dμ,e(f)(x)=nj=1mi=1h(wj,df(vi))2,f:MN, (1.1)

    where dμ is the Riemannian volume density on M, {vi}mi=1 is an orthonormal basis in TxM, and {wj}nj=1 is an orthonormal basis in Tf(x)N. Particular examples are maps f:[a,b]N, describing the Riemannian geodesics in N and harmonic functions f:MR. Other examples are minimal surfaces. For instance, a minimal surface in R3 can be seen as a harmonic map f:[a,b]×[a,b]R3; see, e.g., [1,2,3] or more recent survey for minimal submanifolds [4]. The Euler-Lagrange equations of (1.1) correspond to the solution of τ(f)=0, where τ(f)=trg×df(×) denotes the tension field of f, defined by using an induced connection on TMfTN from the Levi-Civita connections on respectively M and N. The celebrated result of [5] states that any smooth map fC(M,N) from a compact Riemannian manifold M to a manifold N of non-positive scalar curvature can be deformed to a harmonic map.

    A generalization of this terminology has been suggested for sub-Riemannian manifolds. A sub-Riemannian manifold is a triplet (M,D,g) consisting of a smooth, connected manifold M, a subbundle D of the tangent bundle TM, and a sub-Riemannian metric g defined only on vectors in D. We assume that D is bracket-generating, meaning that sections of D and a sufficient number of their Lie brackets span TxM at each point xM. Studies of harmonic maps f:MN from a sub-Riemannian (M,D,g) into a Riemannian manifold (N,h) of non-positive curvature was made, for instance, in [6,7,8,9]. Here, the energy functional (1.1) is modified by letting v1,,vm be an orthonormal basis of Dx, and the corresponding equation τ(f)=0 turns to be of a hypoelliptic type. The existence and regularity of the solution to τ(f)=0 was established in [7] under some convexity condition on N, and uniqueness has been shown in [10].

    In the present paper we consider harmonic maps allowing the target space to be a sub-Riemannian manifold. Already the study of curves in sub-Riemannian manifolds shows that it is not sufficient to deal exclusively with the Euler-Lagrange equation when it comes to minimizers of (1.1). More precisely, there are examples of curves that are energy minimizers, and hence the length minimizers, which are not solutions to the Euler-Lagrange equation. Such curves are necessarily singular points in the space of curves of finite sub-Riemannian length, also called horizontal curves, fixing two given points. Minimizers that are solutions of the Euler-Lagrange equation are called normal, and they are smooth [11,12]. There are several open questions related to the regularity of minimizers which are singular curves [13]; see also [14]. To simplify the exposition we choose the target sub-Riemannian manifold (N,E,h) to be a Lie group with a left-invariant sub-Riemannian structure (E,h); see also [15], where the target space is a Carnot group. The restriction of the target space to a Lie group allows one to avoid some of the complications of L2 and Sobolev maps between general manifolds; see, e.g., [16, Section 4]. Furthermore, applying the Maurer-Cartan form on a Lie group simplifies calculations and prevents the need of to choose an explicit connection for the target manifold as well. The map f:MN is required to be horizontal, that is df(D)E. We consider the harmonic maps to be analogous of "normal" and singular geodesics, based on the study of the maps that are regular or singular points of an analogue of the end-point-map. We finally produce equations for both types of horizontal maps: the singular (or abnormal) maps and the normal, latter being solutions of the Euler-Lagrange equation. We will not address conditions for existence or non-existence of such harmonic maps, rather leaving such questions for future research.

    We emphasize that we consider a sub-Riemannian analogue of (1.1) which is only defined for horizontal maps and a map f is harmonic if it is a critical value under horizontal variations. See (4.1) for the definition of the sub-Riemannian energy functional. Such an approach can be considered as the limiting case when the length of vectors outside of E in TN approach infinity. This is in contrast to work in [17, Proposition 5.1] on CR manifolds, which uses an orthogonal projection to define an energy functional for all maps, and where maps are considered harmonic if it is a critical value relative to all variations. The latter can be considered as a limiting case where the length of vectors orthogonal to E in TN approach zero. However, we note that if a map f is horizontal and harmonic in the sense of the definition in [17], then f will also be harmonic according to our definition, as being critical under all variations implies that f is also critical with respect to horizontal variations.

    The structure of the paper is as follows. In Section 2 we introduce sub-Riemannian manifolds, sub-Riemannian measure spaces, and connections compatible with such structures. In Section 3, we define horizontal maps from a compact sub-Riemannian measure space into a Lie group with a left-invariant sub-Riemannian structure, and we show the Hilbert manifold structure of the space of these maps. For the rest of the paper, we use the the convention that M is compact, which ensures that the functional in (1.1) is finite. Similar to what is done for Riemannian harmonic maps (see, e.g., [18, Section 2]) the case of M non-compact can be considered by calling f harmonic if it is a critical value of the energy functional when restricted to any (relatively) compact subdomain. For simplicity, we will also assume that M is simply connected. See Remark 3 where we suggest modifications for a non-simply connected manifold. We introduce the idea of regular and singular maps, as well as some conditions for these maps. Finally, in Section 4, we find equations for both the normal and abnormal harmonic maps. We show that these equations are a natural generalization of above-mentioned cases of maps into Riemannian manifolds, as well as abnormal and normal sub-Riemannian geodesics. We also give an explicit differential equation for harmonic maps into the Heisenberg group.

    A sub-Riemannian manifold is a triple (M,D,g) where M is a connected manifold, D is a subbundle of TM and g=,g is a metric tensor defined on sections of D. Throughout the paper, unless otherwise stated, the subbundle D is assumed to be bracket-generating, meaning that the sections of D and their iterated brackets span the tangent space at each point of M. This condition is sufficient to ensure that any pair of points x0 and x1 in M can be connected by a horizontal curve γ, i.e., an absolutely continuous curve such that ˙γ(t)Dγ(t) for almost every t; see [19,20]. Thus, the distance

    dg(x0,x1)=inf{10|˙γ(t)|gdt:γ is horizontalγ(0)=x0,γ(1)=x1} (2.1)

    is well defined. Furthermore, the metric topology with respect to dg coincides with the manifold topology on M. We do not exclude the possibility D=TM.

    Associated with the sub-Riemannian metric g, there is a vector bundle morphism

    g:TMD, (2.2)

    defined by

    α(v)=gα,vg

    for any xM, αTxM, and vDx. Define a cometric g=,g on TM by

    α,βg=α(gβ)=gα,gβg,α,βΓ(TM).

    This cometric is exactly degenerated along the subbundle Ann(D)TM of covectors vanishing on D. Conversely, given a cometric g on TM that is degenerated along a subbundle of TM, we can define the subbundle D of TM as the image of the map g:αα,g in (2.2), and a metric g on D by the relation

    gα,gβg=α,βg.

    Hence, a sub-Riemannian manifold can equivalently be defined as a connected manifold with a symmetric positive semi-definite tensor g on Γ(TM2) degenerating on a subbundle of TM. In what follows, we will speak about a sub-Riemannian structure interchangeably as (D,g) or g, assuming that the subbundle D is bracket-generating. For more on sub-Riemannian manifolds, see, e.g., [14,21].

    Definition 2.1. A sub-Riemannian measure space (M,D,g,dμ) is a sub-Riemannian manifold (M,D,g) with a choice of smooth volume density dμ on M. If D=TM, then dμ is the volume density of the Riemannian metric g.

    On a sub-Riemannian measure space (M,D,g,dμ) there is a unique choice of second order operator

    Δg,dμϕ=dvdμgdϕ,ϕC(M). (2.3)

    We call the operator in (2.3) the sub-Laplacian of the sub-Riemannian measure space. Since D is bracket-generating, the classical result of Hörmander [22] states that Δg,dμ is a hypoelliptic operator. If the measure dμ is clear from the context, we simply write Δg. We also denote the sub-Riemannian measure space as (M,g,dμ).

    We say that a Riemannian metric ˉg=,ˉg is a taming metric of (M,D,g,dμ) if g is the restriction ˉg|D of ˉg to D and the volume density of ˉg equals dμ.

    Lemma 2.2. Any sub-Riemannian measure space has a taming Riemannian metric.

    Proof. Let (M,D,g,dμ) be any sub-Riemannian measure space with dim M=m and rank D=k. If k=m, then by convention ˉg=g is a taming Riemannian metric. For k<m, we take an arbitrary Riemannian metric ˉg0 on M and let D denote the orthogonal complement of D with respect to ˉg0. The rank of D equals mk. Define a Riemannian metric ˉg1 such that D and D are still orthogonal with respect to ˉg1, and ˉg1|D=g, ˉg1|D=ˉg0|D. Let dˉμ be the Riemannian volume density with respect to ˉg1, and write dˉμ=ρdμ.

    Finally, we define the metric ˉg to be such that D and D are orthogonal with respect to ˉg and

    ˉg|D=g,ˉg|D=ρ1/(mk)ˉg1|D,

    which gives us the desired Riemannian metric.

    Remark 2.3 (Hausdorff and Popp's measure). A manifold M carries a measure dx which is the pushforward of the Lebesgue measure by the chart map. The distance dg in (2.1) generated by the sub-Riemannian metric tensor g produces the Hausdorff measure dH. Relative to any coordinate system defined sufficiently close to a regular point, dH=q(x)dx is absolutely continuous with respect to dx. It is not clear whether q is a smooth function. Another construction of a measure near regular point has been provided by O. Popp (see [21, Chapter 10]) which gives a measure dμ with a smooth Radon-Nikodym derivative with respect to dx. The latter allows one to define the sub-Laplacian by making use of the integration by parts with respect to the smooth measure dμ, which leads to the sub-Laplacian introduced in [23]. For the case of the Carnot groups, both the Hausdorff and the Haar measures are equal up to a constant, and are hence all smooth.

    Consider a sub-Riemannian structure g on M. For a two-tensor field ξΓ(TM2) we write

    trgξ(×,×)=ξ(g),i.e., trgξ(×,×)(x)=ki=1ξ(vi,vi)

    for an arbitrary orthonormal basis v1,,vk of Dx with k=rank D. We want to consider connections on sub-Riemannian manifolds and sub-Riemannian measure spaces. We begin with the following definition of a connection on tensor fields; see, for instance, [24, Chapter 4].

    Definition 2.4. Let be an affine connection on TM.

    (a) We say that is compatible with (D,g) (equiv. g) if it satisfies the following equivalent conditions:

    (i) g=0,

    (ii) g=g,

    (iii) For any X1,X2Γ(D), ZΓ(TM), we have that ZX1Γ(D) and

    ZX1,X2g=ZX1,X2g+X1,ZX2g.

    (b) We say that is compatible with (D,g,dμ) (equiv. (g,dμ)) if is compatible with (D,g) (equiv. g) and for any ϕC(M)

    trg×dϕ(×)=ki=1vidϕ(vi)=Δg,dμϕ

    for an orthonormal basis v1,,vk of Dx.

    The following is known on sub-Riemannian manifolds.

    Proposition 2.5. [25] Let g be a sub-Riemannian structure and dμ a volume density on M. Then (g,dμ) has a compatible connection.

    We also prove the following result.

    Lemma 2.6. (a) A connection is compatible with g if and only if for every point xM there exists a local orthonormal frame X1,,Xk of D around x such that Xj(x)=0.

    (b) A connection is compatible with (g,dμ) if and only if for every point xM there exists a local orthonormal frame X1,,Xk of D around x such that Xj(x)=0 and dvdμXi(x)=0.

    Proof. If preserves D, then |D is a connection on D preserving the inner product g. Hence there is a local orthonormal frame of D that is parallel with respect to at a given point x; see, e.g., [26, Theorem 2.1 and Remark 2.2] for details. Conversely, let α be an arbitrary one-form and xM an arbitrary point. Assume that there exists an orthonormal frame X1,,Xk of D around x such that it is -parallel at x. Completing calculations at x, we obtain

    X|α|2g(x)=ki=1X(α(Xi))2(x)=2ki=1α(Xi)(x)(Xα)(Xi)(x)=2α,Xαg(x).

    If we can find such a basis for every point in M, it follows that is compatible with g. This proves (a).

    The result in (b) follows from the identity

    Δg,dμf=ki=1X2if+ki=1(Xif)dvdμXi,

    that holds for any local orthonormal basis of M.

    Corollary 2.7. Let be a connection compatible with (g,μ) and let X be a horizontal vector field. Then

    dvdμX=trg×X,×g.

    Proof. For a given point xM, choose an orthonormal frame X1,,Xk of D around x with Xi(x)=0 and dvdμXi(x)=0. Write X=ki=1fiXi. Then

    dvdμX(x)=ki=1(Xifi(x)+fi(x)dvdμXi(x))=ki=1Xifi(x)=ki=1XiX,Xig(x).

    Since xM was arbitrary, the result follows.

    Let G be a Lie group with Lie algebra g. Let (E,h) be a sub-Riemannian structure on G. We say that the sub-Riemannian structure is left-invariant if E is a left-invariant distribution and if

    v,wh=av,awh,for any aG,  v,wE1=eg,

    where we denote by av the action on vg by the differential of the left translation by aG, and 1G is the identity element. Equivalently, let ω be the left Maurer-Cartan form, given by ω(v)=a1vg for any vTaG. Then vE if and only if ω(v)e=E1g. We then say that (E,h) is obtained by left translation of (e,,).

    Example 2.8 (The Heisenberg group). We consider the space Hn=R2n+1 with coordinates (a,b,c)=(a1,,an,b1,,bn,c). We give this space a global frame

    Aj=aj12bjc,Bj=bj+12ajc,C=c. (2.4)

    The corresponding coframe is given by daj, dbj and θ=dc+12nj=1(bjdajajdbj). Note the bracket relations

    [C,Ai]=[C,Bj]=[Ai,Aj]=[Bi,Bj]=0,[Ai,Bj]=δijC. (2.5)

    Hence, these vector fields form a Lie algebra which we will write as hn. We can give R2n+1 a group structure such that the vector fields in (2.4) become left-invariant. The group multiplication is given by

    (a,b,c)(˜a,˜b,˜c)=(a+˜a,b+˜b,c+˜c+12(a,˜bRn˜a,bRn)).

    We will define a sub-Riemannian structure (E,h) on Hn by letting A1,,An, B1,,Bn be an orthonormal basis.

    In what follows, we will let Ωp(M,g) be the space of g-valued differential p-forms on a manifold M. We recall the definition and properties of the Darboux derivative; referring to [27] for more details. Let G be a Lie group with Lie algebra g. Let ωΩ1(G,g) be the left Maurer-Cartan form as defined in Section 2.3. This form satisfies the left Maurer-Cartan equation

    dω+12[ω,ω]=0, (3.1)

    with [ω,ω] being the two-form (v,w)2[ω(v),ω(w)]. See Appendix A for more details. If M is a given manifold and f:MG is a smooth map, we say that αf:=fω is the left Darboux derivative of f. It follow from definition that αf satisfies (3.1). Conversely, if βΩ1(M,g) satisfies dβ+12[β,β]=0, then locally β is the Darboux derivative of some function. If the monodromy representation of β is trivial (see [27, Chapter 3, Theorem 7.14]) then the structural equation implies that β=αf for some map f:MG. Particularly, for a connected, simply connected manifold M the monodromy representation of any g-valued one-form is trivial, meaning that any form satisfying the left Maurer-Cartan equation can be represented as a Darboux derivative. Through the rest of the paper, we assume that M is connected and simply connected.

    Denote by AΩ1(M,g) the collection of forms α satisfying dα+12[α,α]=0, and define

    TαA={˙β(0):β:(ε,ε)Ω1(M,g) is smooth,β(0)=α,β(t)A for any t(ε,ε).}.

    Lemma 3.1. We have

    TαA={dF+[α,F]:FC(M,g)}.

    Proof. Let β(t) be a differentiable curve in Ω1(M,g) and assume that dβ(t)+12[β(t),β(t)]=0. If we differentiate this relation and assume that β(0)=α and ˙β(0)=η, then

    dη+[α,η]=0.

    If α=fω and we write η=Ad(f1)˜η, then

    Ad(f1)d˜η=0. (3.2)

    We remark that here we are abusing notation to write η|x=Ad(f(x)1)˜η|x, where f(x)1 is the inverse of f(x) with respect to the group operation in G. To see that (3.2) holds, recall first that for any curve A(t) in a Lie group G, we have that ddtAd(A(t)1)=ad(ω(˙A(t)))Ad(A(t)1), where ω is the Maurer-Cartan form for the group G. Considering the special case where A(t)=f(γ(t)) for an arbitrary smooth curve γ(t) in M with fω=α, we get the formula for the differential

    dAd(f1)=ad(fω)Ad(f1)=ad(α)Ad(f1).

    Using the definition of η=Ad(f1)˜η, this leads to

    0=dη+[α,η]=(dAd(f1))˜η+Ad(f1)d˜η+[α,Ad(f1)˜η]=Ad(f1)d˜η.

    In summary, the form ˜ηΩ1(M,g) is closed and we can find a function ˜F:Mg such that ˜η=d˜F due to the vanishing de Rham cohomology; see [28, Theorem 11.14]. Furthermore, if we define F=Ad(f1)˜F, then

    β=Ad(f1)d˜F=dF+[α,F].

    Conversely, for any FC(M,g), we can define a curve g(t)=fexp(tF) in the space of smooth maps MG and β(t)=g(t)ω. Here exp:gG is the group exponential. Let vTxM, xM, be arbitrary and define γ(s):(ϵ,ϵ)M, ϵ>0, as a curve with γ(0)=x and sγ(0)=v. If we set Γ(s,t)=g(t)(γ(s)), then we compute

    ˙β(0)(v)=tω(sΓ(s,t))|(s,t)=(0,0)=tΓω(s)|(s,t)=(0,0)=(sΓω(t)d(Γω)(s,t))|(s,t)=(0,0)=(s(ω(tΓ))d(Γω)(s,t))|(s,t)=(0,0)=sF(γ(s))|s=0+[ω(sΓ),ω(tΓ)]|(s,t)=(0,0)=dF(v)+[α(v),F(x)].

    Recall that α=fω. The result follows.

    We want to close our space of Darboux derivatives into a Hilbert space. Let (M,D,g,dμ) be a sub-Riemannian measure space and let ˉg be a taming Riemannian metric. Extend the inner product on e to a full inner product on g. These choices give us an induced inner product on kTMg, which allows us to define an L2-inner product β,β=Mβ(x),β(x)dμ(x) for any βΩk(M,g). With this definition, we consider L2Ω(M,g)=dim Mk=0L2Ωk(M,g) as the space of L2-forms with values in g. We remark that since M is compact and g is finite dimensional, any other choice of taming Riemannian metric ˉg and inner product of g will give us an equivalent L2-inner product, meaning in particular that L2-forms are independent of these choices. More about the theory of Lp forms can be found, for instance in [29].

    Corollary 3.2. Assume that M is simply connected and compact. Then the closure ¯A of A in L2Ω1(M,g) is a Hilbert submanifold of L2Ω1(M,g) with tangent space ¯TαAL2Ω1(M,g).

    Proof. Let αA be the Darboux derivative α=αf=fω of a map f. We consider an arbitrary curve βA that can be written as β=dF+[α,F] for some FC(M,g). From the proof of Lemma 3.1, we note that if F=Ad(f1)˜F, then Ad(f1)β=d˜F. We denote by ˜Fβ a unique solution to this equation satisfying M˜Fβdμ=0, and we define Fβ=Ad(f1)˜Fβ. Then,

    for some constant C > 0 . Note that the linear map \beta \mapsto \tilde F_\beta is bounded and invertible with respect to the L^2 metric, which, in particular, is smooth. Here we have used the Poincaré inequality for compact Riemannian manifolds found in, e.g., [30, Theorem 2.10]. It follows that this map can be extended by limits to be well defined as a map from \overline{T_\alpha \mathcal{A}} to \{ F \in L^2(M, \mathfrak{g}) \, : \, \int_M {\rm{Ad}}(f) F \, d\mu = 0 \} .

    Continuing, we introduce a map \Phi \colon T_\alpha \mathcal{A} \mapsto \mathcal{A} as

    \Phi(\beta) = (f \cdot e^{F_\beta})^* \omega, \quad \text{for}\quad\beta\in T_\alpha \mathcal{A}.

    We observe then that for any v \in T_xM , we can apply the formula for the differential of the Lie group exponential to obtain

    \begin{align*} \Phi(\beta)(v) & = e^{- F_{\beta} (x)} f(x)^{-1} df(v) e^{F_{\beta}(x)} + \frac{1- e^{-{\rm{ad}}(F_{\beta}(x))}}{{\rm{ad}}(F_{\beta}(x))} dF_{\beta}(v) \\ & = e^{- {\rm{ad}}(F_{\beta}(x))} \alpha + \frac{1- e^{-{\rm{ad}}(F_{\beta}(x))}}{{\rm{ad}}(F_{\beta}(x))} \big(\beta(v) + {\rm{ad}}(F_\beta(x)) \alpha(v)\big) \\ & = \alpha(v) + \frac{1- e^{-{\rm{ad}}(F_{\beta}(x))}}{{\rm{ad}}(F_{\beta}(x))} \beta(v), \end{align*}

    meaning that

    \begin{align*} \Phi(\beta) & = \alpha + \frac{1- e^{-{\rm{ad}}(F_{\beta})}}{{\rm{ad}}(F_{\beta})} \beta = \alpha + \sum\limits_{n = 0}^\infty \frac{(-1)^n {\rm{ad}}(F_\beta)^n}{(n+1)!} \beta. \end{align*}

    This map is well defined for any \beta \in \overline{T_\alpha \mathcal{A}} , giving a smooth map \Phi:\overline{T_\alpha \mathcal{A}} \to \overline{ \mathcal{A}} \subseteq L^2 \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}) . Furthermore, we see that its Fréchet differential at \beta = 0 is given by

    D\Phi|_0(\beta) = \beta.

    Thus, \Phi is locally injective, so it can be used as a chart close to 0 \in \overline{T_\alpha \mathcal{A}} . Since \mathcal{A} is dense in \overline{ \mathcal{A}} the result follows.

    For the rest of this section, (M, D, g, d\mu) will be a simply connected, compact sub-Riemannian measure space while G will be a Lie group with Lie algebra \mathfrak{g} and left Maurer-Cartan form \omega . The structure (E, h) on G will be defined by left translation of (\mathfrak{e}, \langle\cdot\, , \cdot\rangle) . We introduce the following concept.

    Definition 3.3. Let (M, D, g) and (N, E, h) be two sub-Riemannian manifolds. We say that a smooth map f\colon M \to N is horizontal if df(D) \subseteq E .

    To simplify the discussion in this paper, we only consider the case when N = G is a Lie group G with a left-invariant sub-Riemannian structure (E, g) that is the left translation of a vector space \mathfrak{e}\subset\mathfrak g and a scalar product \langle \cdot \, , \cdot \rangle on \mathfrak{e} . Then, f\colon M \to G is horizontal if and only if \alpha_f = f^* \omega sends D into \mathfrak{e} . We write \mathcal{A}_{D, E} for the collection of such forms \alpha_f .

    Consider \Omega^1(D, V) = \Gamma(D^* \otimes V) as partial one-forms only defined on D with values in a vector space V . Write L^2 \Omega^1(D, V) for its L^2 -closure. Consider \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} \subseteq \overline{ \mathcal{A}} . Define a linear map

    \begin{equation} P\colon L^2 \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}) \to L^2\Omega^1(D, \mathfrak{g}/\mathfrak{e})\quad \text{by}\quad P(\alpha) = \alpha|D \mod \mathfrak{e}. \end{equation} (3.3)

    Then \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} = \ker P \cap \overline{ \mathcal{A}} .

    Definition 3.4. We say that \alpha \in \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} is regular (respectively, singular) if \alpha is a regular (respectively, singular) point of P|_{ \mathcal{A}} ; that is the differential of the map P is surjective (not surjective) at \alpha\in\mathcal A . We say that a sub-Riemannian horizontal map f\colon M \to G is regular (respectively, singular) , if its Darboux derivative \alpha_f \in \mathcal{A}_D is regular (respectively, singular) .

    Since \overline{\mathcal{A}_{D, E}} = \ker P \cap \overline{ \mathcal{A}} , the implicit function theorem implies that \overline{\mathcal{A}_{D, E}} has the local structure of a manifold around any regular \alpha .

    We list the conditions for distributions on M and G , which guarantee the absence of singular morphisms.

    Definition 3.5. We say that \mathfrak{e}\subset\mathfrak g is a strongly q -bracket generating subspace of \mathfrak g if for any 1 \leq l \leq q and any set of linearly independent vectors A_1, \dots, A_l \in \mathfrak{e} and any Z_1, \dots, Z_l\in \mathfrak{g} , there exists an element B \in \mathfrak{e} such that

    Z_j - [A_j, B] \in \mathfrak{e}, \qquad j = 1, \dots, l.

    Example 3.6. Let \theta be a left-invariant one-form on a (2n+1) -dimensional Lie group G and define \ker \theta|_1 = \mathfrak{e} \subseteq \mathfrak{g} . Assume that d\theta|(\wedge^2 \mathfrak{e}) is non-degenerate, i.e., \theta is a contact form on G . We can find a basis A_1, \dots, A_n, B_1, \dots, B_{n} of \mathfrak{e} such that d\theta(A_i, A_j) = d\theta(B_i, B_j) = 0 and d\theta(B_i, A_j) = \delta_{ij} . Let Z \in \mathfrak{g} be the unique element satisfying \theta(Z) = 1 and d\theta(Z, \, \cdot \, ) = 0 . To find B\in\mathfrak e , we need to solve the equations

    [p_j A_i, B] = \tilde p_j Z, \qquad [q_j B_i, B] = \tilde q_j Z, \qquad p_j \neq 0, \quad q_j \neq 0.

    One can easily check that

    B = \sum\limits_{i = 1}^n \left( \frac{\tilde p_i}{p_i} B_i -\frac{\tilde q_i}{q_i} A_i\right).

    is a solution. This shows that such structures are strongly 2n -bracket generating. In particular, we note that the Heisenberg group H^n is has a strong 2n -bracket generating distribution.

    Proposition 3.7. Let (M, D, g) be a sub-Riemannian manifold, where M is simply connected and D has rank k \geq 2 . Let \mathfrak{g} be a Lie algebra with a generating subspace \mathfrak{e} \subseteq \mathfrak{g} of positive codimension. Let \alpha \in \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}) be a one-form satisfying \alpha(D) \subseteq \mathfrak{e} .

    \rm (a) Assume that there exists a non-intersecting horizontal loop \gamma:[0, 1] \to M such that \alpha(\dot \gamma(t)) = 0 for almost every t \in [0, 1] . Then \alpha is singular.

    \rm (b) Assume that \mathfrak{e} \subseteq \mathfrak{g} is strongly k -bracket generating. If \alpha|D is injective at every point, then \alpha is regular.

    Proof. Choose a complement \mathfrak{f} to \mathfrak{e} in \mathfrak{g} . Let F \in C^\infty(M, \mathfrak{g}) be a function and write F = F_{\mathfrak{e}} + F_{\mathfrak{f}} according to the decomposition \mathfrak{g} = \mathfrak{e} \oplus \mathfrak{f} . Recall that the regularity of \alpha is equivalent to the assumption that for any one-form \psi\in \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}) , one can choose F_{\mathfrak{e}} and F_{\mathfrak{f}} such that

    \begin{equation} dF_{\mathfrak{f}}|D + [\alpha |D, F_{\mathfrak{e}}] + [\alpha |D, F_{\mathfrak{f}}] = \psi|D \mod \mathfrak{e}. \end{equation} (3.4)

    \rm (a) If \gamma: [0, 1] \to M is a non-intersecting horizontal loop, then x_1 = \gamma(1/2) \neq x_0 = \gamma(0) = \gamma(1) by assumption. Define \gamma_1, \gamma_2: [0, 1] \to M by \gamma_1(t) = \gamma(t/2) and \gamma_2(t) = \gamma(1- t/2) , which are non-intersecting horizontal curves from x_0 to x_1 . Let U be an open set that does not intersect \gamma_2 , but intersects with a subset of \gamma_1 of positive length. Let \psi = \psi_0 \otimes Z , where Z \in \mathfrak{f} , Z\neq 0 , and \psi_0 denotes a real valued one-form with support in U such that C = \int_0^1 \psi_0(\dot \gamma(t)) \, dt > 0 . If we find a function F = F_{\mathfrak{e}}+ F_{\mathfrak{f}} solving (3.4) then

    F_{\mathfrak{f}}(x_1) - F_{\mathfrak{f}}(x_0) = \int_{\gamma_1} \psi \, = C Z\neq 0.

    However, in order for (3.4) to hold, we would also need to F_{\mathfrak{f}}(x_1) - F_{\mathfrak{f}}(x_0) tp equal \int_{\gamma_2} \psi which is clearly 0 by the definition of \psi , giving us a contradiction.

    \rm (b) If \alpha|D is injective, then we can choose F_{\mathfrak{f}} = 0 . To show the regularity of \alpha we need to solve the equation [\alpha|D, F_{\mathfrak{e}}] = \psi|D \mod \mathfrak{e} . The assumption of D being strongly k -bracket generating implies that the equation [\alpha|D, F_{\mathfrak{e}}] = \psi|D \mod \mathfrak{e} has a solution for any one-form \psi\in \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}) . To be more precise, let X_1 , \dots , X_k be a local basis of D and \psi\in \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}) . We respectively define A_j \in C^\infty(M, \mathfrak{e}) and Z_j \in C^\infty(M, \mathfrak{g}) by A_j = \alpha(X_j) and Z_j = \psi(X_j) , j = 1, \dots, k . Then we can then define F_{\mathfrak{e}} such that [A_j, F_{\mathfrak{e}}] = Z_j by the strongly k -bracket generating condition on D .

    Let (M, D, g, d\mu) be a given sub-Riemannian measure space and let (G, E, h) be a Lie group with a left-invariant sub-Riemannian structure. For a horizontal map f\colon M \to G with Darboux derivative \alpha_f , we define its energy as

    \begin{array}{*{20}{l}} {{\cal E}(f)}&{ = \frac{1}{2}\int_M | df|_{{g^*} \otimes {f^*}h}^2d\mu = \frac{1}{2}\int_M {{\rm{t}}{{\rm{r}}_g}} ({f^*}h)( \times , \times ){\mkern 1mu} d\mu }\\ {}&{ = \frac{1}{2}\int_M | {\alpha _f}|_{{g^*}}^2d\mu = :\widehat {\cal E}({\alpha _f}).} \end{array} (4.1)

    We note that if v_1, \dots, v_k \in D_x and w_1, \dots, w_n \in E_{f(x)} are respective orthonormal bases then

    |df |_{g^* \otimes f^*h}^2(x) = \sum\limits_{i = 1}^k | df(v_i) |_h^2 = \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n \sum\limits_{i = 1}^k \langle w_j, df(v_i) \rangle_h^2.

    We would generalize the definition of harmonic maps from [5] to the sub-Riemannian setting, saying that f is harmonic if it is a critical value of \mathscr{E} . Instead, we use the Darboux derivative to make this definition precise. For \alpha \in \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} , we define a variation \alpha_s of \alpha as a differentiable curve (- \varepsilon, \varepsilon) \to \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} , s \mapsto \alpha_s , such that \alpha_0 = \alpha .

    Definition 4.1. We say that \alpha \in \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} is harmonic if it is a critical point of \hat {\mathscr{E}} , i.e., for every variation \alpha_s of \alpha , we have \frac{d}{ds} \hat {\mathscr{E}}(\alpha_s)|_{s = 0} = 0 . We say that f is harmonic if \alpha_f is harmonic.

    We have the following result.

    Theorem 4.2. Let M be a simply connected, compact manifold, and \nabla a connection compatible with the sub-Riemannian measure space (M, g^*, d\mu) . Let the map \sharp = \sharp^{h}_1: \mathfrak{g}^* \to \mathfrak{e} correspond to the sub-Riemannian metric h at the identity. Assume that \alpha \in \mathcal{A}_{D, E} is harmonic. Then at least one of the following statements holds.

    \rm (a) (Abnormal case) There exists form a \eta \in \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}^*) with \eta|D non-zero, satisfying \sharp \eta|D = 0 and

    \delta_D \eta - {\rm{tr}}_{g} {\rm{ad}}^*(\alpha(\times) )\eta(\times) = 0.

    with \delta_D \eta = - {\rm{tr}}_{g} \nabla_\times\eta(\times) .

    \rm (a) (Normal case) There exists a form \lambda \in \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}^*) satisfying \sharp \lambda|D = \alpha|D and

    \delta_D \lambda - {\rm{tr}}_{g} {\rm{ad}}^*(\alpha(\times) )\lambda(\times) = 0.

    with \delta_D \lambda = - {\rm{tr}}_{g} \nabla_\times\lambda(\times) .

    Recall that {\rm{ad}}^* denotes the adjoint representation of \mathfrak{g} on \mathfrak{g}^* given by ({\rm{ad}}^*(A) \beta)(B) = - \beta([A, B]) for any A, B \in \mathfrak{g} , \beta \in \mathfrak{g}^* .

    Remark 4.3. We remark the following about the result of Theorem 4.2.

    ● Case (a), which we call abnormal, occurs when \alpha = \alpha_f \in \mathcal{A}_{D, E} is singular. It is a property that holds for all singular elements, and it is not related to optimality. The proof of the result in (a) does not use the property that \alpha is a harmonic form.

    ● Case (b), which is called normal, occurs when \alpha = \alpha_f \in \mathcal{A}_{D, E} is both regular and is a critical value of \hat {\mathscr{E}} . However, there are also singular forms \alpha \in \mathcal{A}_{D, E} that are critical values of \hat {\mathscr{E}} and also have a corresponding \lambda \in \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}^*) satisfying the equations as in (b), but such an extremal form \alpha is not called normal. Thus, Cases (a) and (b) are not completely disjoint.

    ● We remark also that the results of Theorem 4.2 only depend on restrictions \alpha|D and \lambda|D of forms to D and do not depend on their extension to the entire tangent bundle. Hence, we could have stated Theorem 4.2 by using only the restrictions \alpha|D and \lambda|D .

    Before proceeding to the proof, we observe how the result of Theorem 4.2 satisfies known examples in literature.

    Example 4.4. We note that if E = TG , so that G is a Riemannian Lie group, then there cannot exist any abnormal harmonic maps. Indeed, since \sharp is now is a bijective map, we cannot have that \eta|D \neq 0 , while still having that \sharp \eta|D = 0 .

    For the normal case, we have \sharp \lambda = \alpha and if \alpha = \alpha_f , then

    \begin{equation} \delta_D \alpha + {\rm{tr}}_g {\rm{ad}}(\alpha(\times))^{\dagger}\alpha(\times) = 0, \end{equation} (4.2)

    where {\rm{ad}}(\alpha(\times))^{\dagger} is the transpose map with respect to left-invariant metric h on G . This is just the classical tension field equation for harmonic maps. In order to explain this, we write (4.2) as

    \begin{equation} \tau(f) = {\rm{tr}}_{g} {\pmb{\nabla}}_{\times} df(\times) = 0, \qquad {\pmb{\nabla}} = \nabla \otimes f^* \nabla^h. \end{equation} (4.3)

    Here, \nabla^h is the Levi-Civita connection on G , which for left-invariant vector fields, can be written as,

    2\nabla_A^h B = {\rm{ad}}(A)B - {\rm{ad}}(A)^{\dagger} B - {\rm{ad}}(B)^{\dagger} A.

    Furthermore, {\pmb{\nabla}} is the induced connection on T^*M \otimes f^* TG , which can be described by

    ({\pmb{\nabla}}_{X} df)(Y) = \nabla_{df(X)}^h df(Y) - df(\nabla_X Y).

    Equation (4.3) coincides with the tension field \tau(f) for maps between the Riemannian manifolds in [5] or from sub-Riemannian manifolds to Riemannian manifolds in [7,9]. For the special case G = \mathbb{R} , we have that \tau(f) = \Delta_{g, d\mu} f .

    Example 4.5. Consider M = [0, 1] . Although this is not within the scope of the theorem, as M is a Riemannian manifold with boundary, the theorem is still valid under the assumption that any variation is constant on \partial M = \{0, 1\} . Define \nabla^\ell to be the left-invariant connection on G , i.e., the connection such that \nabla^\ell A = 0 for any left-invariant vector field A . This connection is compatible with the sub-Riemannian structure (E, h) . Let T^\ell be the torsion of \nabla^\ell , given for left-invariant vector fields by

    T^\ell(A, B) = -{\rm{ad}}(A) B.

    We say that the adjoint connection to \nabla^\ell is given by \hat \nabla_A^\ell B = \nabla_A^\ell B - T^\ell(A, B) . For the special case of \nabla^\ell , its adjoint will be the right invariant connection. If f\colon [0, 1] \to G , then the equation in Theorem 4.2 (a) is written as

    \hat \nabla_{\dot f} \eta = 0, \qquad \sharp^h \eta = 0,

    where \eta is a one-form along f(t) . The equation in Theorem 4.2 (b) becomes

    \hat \nabla_{\dot f} \lambda = 0, \qquad \sharp^h \lambda = \dot f.

    These are the respective equations for abnormal curves and normal geodesics see [31,32] for details.

    Proof of Theorem 4.2. Recall that we have defined L^2 -forms with respect to a taming metric \bar{g} and an inner product on \mathfrak{g} . Assume that \alpha \in \mathcal{A}_{D, E} is harmonic. Write

    \begin{align*} Q & = \{ \eta \in \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}^*) \, : \eta(D) \subseteq {\rm{Ann}}(\mathfrak{e}) \}, \\ \Lambda_{\alpha} & = \{ \lambda \in \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}^*) \, : \, \sharp \lambda|D = \alpha|D \}. \end{align*}

    Note that Q is a vector space, while \Lambda_{\alpha} is an affine space with \lambda_1 - \lambda_2 \in Q for \lambda_1, \lambda_2 \in \Lambda_\alpha . We first observe the following. Consider the operator L_\alpha F : = dF + [\alpha, F] . Then for any \eta \in L^2 \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}^*) , we note that

    \begin{align*} \int_M {\rm{tr}}_g \eta(\times) dF( \times) d\mu & = \int_M {\rm{tr}}_g \eta(\times) \nabla_{\times} F d\mu = \int_M (\delta_D\eta) F d\mu; \end{align*}

    hence

    \begin{align*} \int_M {\rm{tr}}_g \eta(\times) (L_\alpha F)(\times)\, d\mu & = \int_M {\rm{tr}}_g \eta(\times)( dF(\times) + [\alpha(\times), F] ) \\ & = \int_M (\delta_D \eta - {\rm{tr}}_{g} {\rm{ad}}^*(\alpha(\times) )\eta(\times)) F d\mu = : \int_M (L_\alpha^* \eta) F d\mu. \end{align*}

    If \alpha \in \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} is singular, then there is a non-zero form \check{\eta} \in L^2 \Omega^1(D, \mathfrak{g}/\mathfrak{e}) orthogonal to the image of D_\alpha P(T_\alpha \mathcal{A}) where P is given in (3.3). Define \eta = \langle \check{\eta}, D_\alpha P \cdot \rangle_{L^2} \in \bar{Q} . Then for any element L_\alpha F in T_\alpha \mathcal{A} , F \in C^\infty(M, \mathfrak{g}) , we have

    0 = \langle \eta, D_\alpha P L_\alpha F \rangle = \int_M \eta(L_\alpha F)\, d\mu = \int_M (L_\alpha^* \eta) F\, d\mu.

    As this holds for any F \in C^\infty(M, \mathfrak{g}) , the result in (a) follows.

    If \alpha is regular, then \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} is locally a manifold with T_\alpha \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} being the closure of elements L_\alpha F such that L_\alpha F(D) \subseteq \mathfrak{e} . In other words, elements in T_\alpha \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} are in the closure of elements L_\alpha F , F \in C^\infty(M, \mathfrak{g}) , that are orthogonal to Q , which can be written as

    T_{\alpha} \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} = \overline{\left\{ L_\alpha F \, :\, \langle F, \phi \rangle_{L^2} = 0 \text{ for any } \phi \in L_\alpha^* Q \right\}}.

    Let F be an arbitrary such element in C^\infty(M, \mathfrak{g}) that is orthogonal to L_\alpha^* Q . For such a tangent vector in T_{\alpha} \overline{ \mathcal{A}_{D, E}} , let \alpha_s be the corresponding variation with \alpha_0 = \alpha and \frac{d}{ds} \alpha_s |_{s = 0} = L_\alpha F . We observe that for any smooth \tilde \lambda \in \Lambda_\alpha ,

    \begin{align*} \frac{d}{ds} \hat {\mathscr{E}}(\alpha_s) |_{s = 0} & = \int_M {\rm{tr}}_g \langle \alpha(\times) , dF(\times) + [\alpha(\times), F] \rangle d\mu = \int_M (L_\alpha^* \tilde \lambda) F d\mu. \end{align*}

    If this vanishes for all such variations, then L_\alpha^* \tilde \lambda \in (C^\infty(M, \mathfrak{g}) \cap (L_\alpha^* Q)^\perp)^\perp . We remark that since the elements of L^2(M, \mathfrak{g}) can be considered as equivalence classes of sequences (\phi_n)_{n = 1}^\infty of smooth functions convergent in L^2 , we have

    ( C^\infty(M, \mathfrak{g}) \cap (L_\alpha^* Q)^\perp)^\perp = \overline{L_\alpha^* Q}, \qquad \text{ and } \qquad \overline{L_\alpha^* Q} \cap C^\infty(M, \mathfrak{g}) = L_\alpha^* Q.

    Furthermore, since \tilde \lambda is smooth, then so is L_\alpha^* \tilde \lambda ; hence we can write L_\alpha^* \tilde \lambda = L_\alpha^* \eta \in L_\alpha^* Q . By defining \lambda = \tilde \lambda - \eta \in \Lambda_\alpha , we find that \lambda satisfies L_\alpha^* \lambda = 0 .

    Remark 4.6. The results in Theorem 4.2 can be generalized to a non simply connected manifold. If M is not simply connected, we consider its universal cover \Pi\colon \tilde M \to M . We note that \tilde M might not be compact, but, as mentioned in our introduction, we can consider compact subdomains. We can then lift functions from M to \tilde M as f \mapsto f \circ \Pi . By using a partition of unity, we decompose an integral over \tilde M or one of its compact subdomains as integrals over open sets that are mapped bijectively to an open set in M . It leads to the conclusion that if f is a harmonic map, then so is f \circ \Pi . Looking at the equations in Theorem 4.2, we see that they are all local and can hence be projected to M .

    We consider the case of harmonic maps f\colon M \to H^{n} . Let (a, b, c) be the coordinates on H^n as described in Example 2.8. We then have the following corollary.

    Proposition 4.7. Let f\colon M \to H^n be a horizontal map from (M, D, g, d\mu) into the Heisenberg group (H^n, E, h) with its standard sub-Riemannian structure. Write

    (u, v, w) = (a, b, c) \circ f, \qquad \zeta = u +iv.

    Then f is a normal harmonic if and only if for some horizontal vector field Y \in \Gamma(M) satisfying {\rm{dv}}_{d\mu} Y = 0 we have

    (\Delta_{g, d\mu} - i Y)\zeta = 0.

    We note that the operator \Delta_{g, d\mu} - iY is hypoelliptic by [33]. However, recall that we are also assuming that f is horizontal, meaning that

    \left(dw + \frac{1}{2} \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n (v_j du_j - u_j dv_j)\right) |D = 0.

    Note that if {\rm{rank}}\ D \leq 2n , then all harmonic maps are normal by Example 3.6. and Proposition 3.7.

    Proof. Since f is horizontal, then

    \alpha|D = \alpha_f|D = \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n du_j|D \otimes A_j + \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n dv_j|D \otimes B_j.

    From the requirement that \sharp \lambda|_D = \alpha|D , we have that

    \lambda|D = \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n du_j|D \otimes da_j + \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n dv_j|D \otimes db_j + \lambda_0|D \otimes \theta,

    where \lambda_0 is a one-form on M . Write Y = \sharp^g \lambda_0 as a vector field. The harmonic equation is given by

    \begin{align*} & 0 = \delta_D \lambda - {\rm{tr}}_{g} {\rm{ad}}^*(\alpha(\times) )\lambda(\times) \\ & = - \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n {\rm{tr}}_g (\nabla_{\times} du_j)(\times) \otimes da_j - \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n {\rm{tr}}_g (\nabla_{\times} dv_j)(\times) \otimes db_j + (\nabla_{\times} \lambda_0)(\times) \otimes \theta \\ & \qquad + {\rm{tr}}_g \lambda_0(\times) \left(du_j(\times) \otimes db_j \right) - {\rm{tr}}_g \lambda_0(\times) \left(dv_j(\times) \otimes da_j \right) \\ & = - \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n (\Delta_D u_j + Yv_j) \otimes da_j - \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n (\Delta_D v_j - Y u_j) \otimes db_j + ({\rm{dv}}_\mu Y) \otimes \theta. \end{align*}

    It follows that {\rm{dv}}_\mu Y = 0 and

    \Delta_{g, \mu} \zeta = (\Delta_{g, \mu} u_j + i \Delta_{g, \mu} v_j )_j = (- Yv_j + i Yu_j)_j = i Y\zeta,

    completing the proof.

    Example 4.8. If we choose M = [0, 1] in Proposition 4.7, allowing a manifold with boundary, we obtain the normal sub-Riemannian geodesics on the Heisenberg group. More precisely, the horizontality requirement for f can be written as

    \dot w = - \frac{1}{2} \sum\limits_{j = 1}^n (v_j \dot u_j - u_j \dot v_j),

    while \zeta = u + iv now has to satisfy

    \ddot \zeta + i y\dot \zeta = 0, \qquad \text{for some constant}\ y .

    In other words \dot \zeta = e^{iyt} \dot \zeta(0) , which is exactly the equation for normal geodesics on the Heisenberg group with solutions being the horizontal lifts of circular arcs on the (u, v) -plain.

    We recall here the definition of brackets of forms with values in a Lie algebra \mathfrak{g} . Let \alpha \in \Omega^k(M, \mathfrak{g}) be a \mathfrak{g} valued k -form, that is a section of the vector bundle \wedge^k T^*M \otimes \mathfrak{g} . Note that all such elements can be written as a finite sum of elements \check{\alpha} \otimes A where \check{\alpha} \in \Omega^k(M) is a real valued k -form, and A \in \mathfrak{g} . For \check \alpha \in \Omega^k(M) , \check \beta \in \Omega^l(M) and A, B \in \mathfrak{g} , we define

    \left[ \check{\alpha} \otimes A, \check{\beta} \otimes B\right] = (\check{\alpha} \wedge \check{\beta}) \otimes [A, B].

    We can extend this definition by linearity to arbitrary forms \alpha \in \Omega^k(M, \mathfrak{g}) and \beta \in \Omega^l(M, \mathfrak{g}) , to obtain a form [\alpha, \beta] \in \Omega^{k+l}(M, \mathfrak{g}) . We note that [\alpha, \beta] = (-1)^{kl+1} [\beta, \alpha] . We look at the particular case when k = l = 1 . For \alpha, \beta \in \Omega^1(M, \mathfrak{g}) and a basis A_1, \dots, A_n of \mathfrak{g} , we write \alpha = \sum_{j = 1}^n \check \alpha_j \otimes A_j and \beta = \sum_{j = 1}^n \check \beta_j \otimes A_j . We then observe that for any v, w \in TM ,

    \begin{align*} & {[\alpha, \beta]}(v, w) = [\beta, \alpha](v, w) = \sum\limits_{i, j = 1}^n (\check \alpha_i(v) \check \beta_j(w) - \check \beta_j(v) \check \alpha_i(w)) [A_i, A_j] \\ & = [\alpha(v), \beta(w)] - [\alpha(w), \beta(v)] = [\alpha(v), \beta(w)] + [\beta(v), \alpha(w)]. \end{align*}

    In particular, [\alpha, \alpha](v, w) = 2 [\alpha(v), \alpha(w)] . If \alpha is a one-form and F is a zero-form, i.e., a function, then [\alpha, F](v) = [\alpha(v), F(x)] for every v \in T_xM .

    The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.

    The first author was by Trond Mohn Foundation-Grant TMS2021STG02 (GeoProCo). The work of both authors was partially supported by the project Pure Mathematics in Norway, funded by the Trond Mohn Foundation and Tromsø Research Foundation. We thank Pierre Pansu and Mauricio Godoy Molina for helpful discussions.

    The authors declare there is no conflict of interest.



    [1] Acharya VV, Pedersen LH (2005) Asset pricing with liquidity risk. J Financ Econ 77: 375-410. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.06.007
    [2] Al-Awadhi AM, Alsaifi K, Al-Awadhi A, et al. (2020) Death and contagious infectious diseases: Impact of the COVID-19 virus on stock market returns. J Behav Exper Financ 27: 100326. doi: 10.1016/j.jbef.2020.100326
    [3] Amihud Y, Mendelson H (1989) The Effects of Beta, Bid-Ask Spread, Residual Risk, and Size on Stock Returns. J Financ 44: 479-486. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1989.tb05067.x
    [4] Amihud Y, Mendelson H (1991) Liquidity, Maturity, and the Yields on U.S. Treasury Securities. J Financ 46: 1411-1425. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1991.tb04623.x
    [5] Amihud Y, Hameed A, Kang W, et al. (2015) The Illiquidity Premium: International Evidence. J Financ Econ 117: 350-368. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2015.04.005
    [6] Amihud Y, Mendelson H, Lauterbach B (1997) Market microstructure and securities values: Evidence from the Tel Aviv Stock Exchange. J Financ Econ 45: 365-390. doi: 10.1016/S0304-405X(97)00021-4
    [7] Aparicio FM, Estrada J (2001) Empirical distributions of stock returns: European securities markets. Eur J Financ 7: 1-21. doi: 10.1080/13518470121786
    [8] Bekaert G, Harvey CR, Lundblad C (2007) Liquidity and Expected Returns: Lessons from Emerging Markets. Rev Financ Stud 20: 1783-1831. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhm030
    [9] Brennan MJ, Chordia T, Subrahmanyam A (1998) Alternative factor specifications, security characteristics, and the cross-section of expected stock returns. J Financ Econ 49: 345-373. doi: 10.1016/S0304-405X(98)00028-2
    [10] Cervelló-Royo R, Guijarro F (2020) Forecasting stock market trend: a comparison of machine learning algorithms. Financ Mark Valuat 6: 37-49. doi: 10.46503/NLUF8557
    [11] Chiang TC, Zheng D (2015) Liquidity and stock returns: Evidence from international markets. Glob Financ J 27: 73-97. doi: 10.1016/j.gfj.2015.04.005
    [12] Chikore R, Gachira W, Nkomo D, et al. (2014) Stock liquidity and returns: Evidence from Zimbabwe Stock Exchange. Interdiscip J Contemp Res Bus 6: 20-35.
    [13] Corwin SA, Schultz P (2012) A Simple Way to Estimate Bid-Ask Spreads from Daily High and Low Prices. J Financ 67: 719-760. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2012.01729.x
    [14] David SA, Inácio Jr CMC, Machado JAT (2021) The recovery of global stock markets indices after impacts due to pandemics. Res Inter Bus Financ 55: 101335. doi: 10.1016/j.ribaf.2020.101335
    [15] Degennaro R, Robotti C (2007) Financial Market Frictions. Econ Rev 92: 1-16.
    [16] Demsetz H (1968) The Cost of Transacting. Q J Econ 82: 33-53. doi: 10.2307/1882244
    [17] Dinh MT (2017) The returns, risk and liquidity relationship in high frequency trading: Evidence from the Oslo stock market. Res Inter Bus Financ 39: 30-40. doi: 10.1016/j.ribaf.2016.07.013
    [18] Easley D, O'Hara M (2004). Information and the cost of capital. J Financ 59: 1553-1583. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2004.00672.x
    [19] Glosten LR, Milgrom PR (1985) Bid, ask and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed traders. J Financ Econ 14: 71-100. doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(85)90044-3
    [20] Goodell JW (2020) COVID-19 and finance: Agendas for future research. Financ Res Lett 35: 101512. doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101512
    [21] Gorton G, Metrick A (2010) Haircuts. Fed Reserve Bank St Louis Rev 92: 507-520.
    [22] Goyenko RY, Holden CW, Trzcinka CA (2009) Do liquidity measures measure liquidity? J Financ Econ 92: 153-181. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2008.06.002
    [23] Gubareva M (2020) The impact of Covid-19 on liquidity of emerging market bonds. Financ Res Lett, 101826.
    [24] Guijarro F, Moya-Clemente I, Saleemi J (2019) Liquidity Risk and Investors' Mood: Linking the Financial Market Liquidity to Sentiment Analysis through Twitter in the S & P500 Index. Sustainability 11: 7048. doi: 10.3390/su11247048
    [25] Haroon O, Rizvi SAR (2020) Flatten the Curve and Stock Market Liquidity—An Inquiry into Emerging Economies. Emerg Mark Financ Trade 56: 2151-2161. doi: 10.1080/1540496X.2020.1784716
    [26] Hartian KR, Sitorus RE (2015) Liquidity and Returns: Evidences from Stock Indexes around the World. Asian Econ Financ Rev 5: 33-45. doi: 10.18488/journal.aefr/2015.5.1/102.1.33.45
    [27] Hasbrouck J (2009) Trading Costs and Returns for U.S. Equities: Estimating Effective Costs from Daily Data. J Financ 64: 1445-1477. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01469.x
    [28] Hicks JR (1962) Liquidity. Econ J 72: 787-802. doi: 10.2307/2228351
    [29] Ho T, Stoll H (1981) Optimal dealer pricing under transactions and return uncertainty. J Financ Econ 9: 47-73. doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(81)90020-9
    [30] Jacoby G, Fowler D, Gottesman AA (2000) The capital asset pricing model and the liquidity effect: A theoretical approach. J Financ Mark 3: 69-81. doi: 10.1016/S1386-4181(99)00013-0
    [31] Just M, Echaust K (2020) Stock market returns, volatility, correlation and liquidity during the COVID-19 crisis: Evidence from the Markov switching approach. Financ Res Lett 37: 101775. doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101775
    [32] Korajczyk RA, Sadka R (2008) Pricing the commonality across alternative measures of liquidity. J Financ Econ 87: 45-72. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2006.12.003
    [33] Lam KS, Tam LH (2011) Liquidity and asset pricing: Evidence from the Hong Kong stock market. J Bank Financ 35: 2217-2230. doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2011.01.015
    [34] Le H, Gregoriou A (2020) How do you capture liquidity? A review of the literature on Low-frequency stock liquidity. J Econ Surveys 34: 1170-1186. doi: 10.1111/joes.12385
    [35] Leirvik T, Fiskerstrand SR, Fjellvikå s AB (2017) Market liquidity and stock returns in the Norwegian stock market. Financ Res Lett 21: 272-276. doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2016.12.033
    [36] Liu W (2006) A liquidity-augmented capital asset pricing model. J Financ Econ 82: 631-671. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.10.001
    [37] Lybek T, Sarr A (2002) Measuring liquidity in financial markets. Inter Mon Fund 2: 1-64.
    [38] Marozva G (2019) Liquidity and Stock Returns: New Evidence From Johannesburg Stock Exchange. J Devel Areas 53: 79-90.
    [39] Norli Ø, Ostergaard C, Schindele I (2015) Liquidity and Shareholder Activism. Rev Financ Stud 28: 486-520. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhu070
    [40] Pástor Ľ, Stambaugh RF (2003) Liquidity Risk and Expected Stock Returns. J Pol Econ 111: 642-685. doi: 10.1086/374184
    [41] Roll R (1984) A Simple Implicit Measure of the Effective Bid-Ask Spread in an Efficient Market. J Financ 39: 1127-1139. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1984.tb03897.x
    [42] Saleemi J (2014) An Empirical Analysis of Cost-Based Market Liquidity Measures for US & Norwegian Banks. Universitetet I Nordland.
    [43] Saleemi J (2020a) In COVID-19 outbreak, correlating the cost-based market liquidity risk to microblogging sentiment indicators. Nation Account Rev 2: 249-262.
    [44] Saleemi J (2020b). An estimation of cost-based market liquidity from daily high, low and close prices. Financ Mark Valuat 6: 1-11. doi: 10.46503/VUTL1758
    [45] Schnabel I, Shin HS (2004) Liquidity and Contagion: The Crisis of 1763. J Europ Econ Assoc 2: 929-968. doi: 10.1162/1542476042813887
    [46] Severo T (2012) Measuring Systemic Liquidity Risk and the Cost of Liquidity Insurance. Inter Mon Fund 12/194: 3-35.
    [47] Vo XV, Bui HT (2016) Liquidity, liquidity risk and stock returns: evidence from Vietnam. Inter J Mon Econ Financ 9: 67-89. doi: 10.1504/IJMEF.2016.074586
    [48] Vu V, Chai D, Do V (2015) Empirical tests on the liquidity-adjusted capital asset pricing model. Pacific-Basin Financ J 35: 73-89. doi: 10.1016/j.pacfin.2014.10.007
    [49] Zaremba A, Aharon DY, Demir E, et al. (2021) COVID-19, government policy responses, and stock market liquidity around the world: A note. Res Inter Bus Financ 56: 101359. doi: 10.1016/j.ribaf.2020.101359
    [50] Zhang D, Hu M, Ji Q (2020) Financial markets under the global pandemic of COVID19. Financ Res Lett 36: 101528. doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101528
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2021 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(4632) PDF downloads(338) Cited by(8)

Figures and Tables

Figures(10)  /  Tables(13)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog