Review Special Issues

One world, no longer: the past, the present, and the future of global value chains

  • Global value chains (GVCs) are both a product and a facilitator of the model of globalization that dominated for almost two decades following Soviet collapse in 1991. The North Atlantic Financial Crisis of 2007 onwards undermined that dominance, as did the subsequent economic stagnation and associated rising political and social discord. The reversion to more nationalist modes of discourse and policy marks the return of a more visibly geopolitical dimension to the global political economy. The Covid-19 pandemic has accelerated and accentuated these trends. This paper charts the emergence and consolidation of the era of "one world, ready or not", and employs the work of various critical authors, most prominently William Greider. Greider's extensive critique of US-led globalization, offshoring, and what has since become known as "supply chain capitalism" not only appears prescient by comparison with the work of contemporaneous, high profile representatives of the economics discipline who were its champions, but helps us to locate the sources of its unravelling. The implications of this for GVCs are outlined in the final section, which foresees a fragmentation of the world into spheres of influence dominated by regional powers, each of varying strength and cohesion. This will most likely result in the reconfiguration of many GVCs along more regional lines, as the dictates of efficiency clash with the requirements of supply chain resilience and the associated prerogatives of national security, as defined by those states at the centre of the new regional power blocs. Common to all phases of development discussed in this paper is the subordination of the peoples of the Global South, as the mechanisms of imperialism are adjusted and adapted to the changing conditions arising from the irreconcilable contradictions of global capitalism.

    Citation: Michael Keaney. One world, no longer: the past, the present, and the future of global value chains[J]. National Accounting Review, 2021, 3(1): 1-49. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2021001

    Related Papers:

    [1] Gonca Durmaz Güngör, Ishak Altun . Fixed point results for almost (ζθρ)-contractions on quasi metric spaces and an application. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(1): 763-774. doi: 10.3934/math.2024039
    [2] Hieu Doan . A new type of Kannan's fixed point theorem in strong b- metric spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(7): 7895-7908. doi: 10.3934/math.2021458
    [3] Pragati Gautam, Vishnu Narayan Mishra, Rifaqat Ali, Swapnil Verma . Interpolative Chatterjea and cyclic Chatterjea contraction on quasi-partial b-metric space. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(2): 1727-1742. doi: 10.3934/math.2021103
    [4] Shaoyuan Xu, Yan Han, Suzana Aleksić, Stojan Radenović . Fixed point results for nonlinear contractions of Perov type in abstract metric spaces with applications. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(8): 14895-14921. doi: 10.3934/math.2022817
    [5] Abdullah Shoaib, Poom Kumam, Shaif Saleh Alshoraify, Muhammad Arshad . Fixed point results in double controlled quasi metric type spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(2): 1851-1864. doi: 10.3934/math.2021112
    [6] Mi Zhou, Naeem Saleem, Xiao-lan Liu, Nihal Özgür . On two new contractions and discontinuity on fixed points. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(2): 1628-1663. doi: 10.3934/math.2022095
    [7] Amjad Ali, Muhammad Arshad, Awais Asif, Ekrem Savas, Choonkil Park, Dong Yun Shin . On multivalued maps for φ-contractions involving orbits with application. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(7): 7532-7554. doi: 10.3934/math.2021440
    [8] Tahair Rasham, Abdullah Shoaib, Shaif Alshoraify, Choonkil Park, Jung Rye Lee . Study of multivalued fixed point problems for generalized contractions in double controlled dislocated quasi metric type spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(1): 1058-1073. doi: 10.3934/math.2022063
    [9] Xun Ge, Songlin Yang . Some fixed point results on generalized metric spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(2): 1769-1780. doi: 10.3934/math.2021106
    [10] Qing Yang, Chuanzhi Bai . Fixed point theorem for orthogonal contraction of Hardy-Rogers-type mapping on O-complete metric spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2020, 5(6): 5734-5742. doi: 10.3934/math.2020368
  • Global value chains (GVCs) are both a product and a facilitator of the model of globalization that dominated for almost two decades following Soviet collapse in 1991. The North Atlantic Financial Crisis of 2007 onwards undermined that dominance, as did the subsequent economic stagnation and associated rising political and social discord. The reversion to more nationalist modes of discourse and policy marks the return of a more visibly geopolitical dimension to the global political economy. The Covid-19 pandemic has accelerated and accentuated these trends. This paper charts the emergence and consolidation of the era of "one world, ready or not", and employs the work of various critical authors, most prominently William Greider. Greider's extensive critique of US-led globalization, offshoring, and what has since become known as "supply chain capitalism" not only appears prescient by comparison with the work of contemporaneous, high profile representatives of the economics discipline who were its champions, but helps us to locate the sources of its unravelling. The implications of this for GVCs are outlined in the final section, which foresees a fragmentation of the world into spheres of influence dominated by regional powers, each of varying strength and cohesion. This will most likely result in the reconfiguration of many GVCs along more regional lines, as the dictates of efficiency clash with the requirements of supply chain resilience and the associated prerogatives of national security, as defined by those states at the centre of the new regional power blocs. Common to all phases of development discussed in this paper is the subordination of the peoples of the Global South, as the mechanisms of imperialism are adjusted and adapted to the changing conditions arising from the irreconcilable contradictions of global capitalism.


    In various fields of science, nonlinear evolution equations practically model many natural, biological and engineering processes. For example, PDEs are very popular and are used in physics to study traveling wave solutions. They have played a crucial role in illustrating the nature of nonlinear problems. PDEs are collected to control the diffusion of chemical reactions. In biology, they play a fundamental role in describing various phenomena, such as population growth. In addition, natural phenomena such as fluid dynamics, plasma physics, optics and optical fibers, electromagnetism, quantum mechanics, ocean waves, and others are studied using PDEs. The qualitative and quantitative characteristics of these phenomena can be identified from the behaviors and shapes of their solutions. Therefore, finding the analytic solutions to such phenomena is a fundamental topic in mathematics. Scientists have developed sparse fundamental approaches to find analytic solutions for nonlinear PDEs. Among these techniques, I present integration methods from [1] and [2], the modified F-expansion and Generalized Algebraic methods, respectively. Bekir and Unsal [3] proposed the first integral method to find the analytical solution of nonlinear equations. Kumar, Seadawy and Joardar [4] used the improved Kudryashov technique to extract fractional differential equations. Adomian [5] proposed the Adomian decomposition technique to find the solution of frontier problems of physics. [6] uses an exploratory method to find explicit solutions of non-linear PDEs. Many different methods of solving equations arising from natural phenomena and some of their analytic solutions, such as dark and light solitons, non-local rogue waves, an occasional wave and mixed soliton solutions, are exhibited and can be found in [7,8,9,10,11,12,13,14,15,16,17,18,19,20,21,22,23,24,25,26,27,28,29,30,31,32,33,34,35,36,37,38,39,40].

    The Novikov-Veselov (NV) system [41,42] is given by

    Ψt+αΓxxy+βΦxyy+γΓyΦ+γ(Ψ22)y+λΓΦx+λ(Ψ22)x=0,Γy=Ψx,Ψy=Φx, (1.1)

    where α,β,γ and λ are constants. Barman [42] declared that Eq (1.1) is involved to represent tidal and tsunami waves, electro-magnetic waves in communication cables and magneto-sound and ion waves in plasma. In [42], the generalized Kudryashov method was utilized to have traveling wave solutions for Eq (1.1). According to Croke [43], the Novikov-Veselov system is generalized from the KdV equations which were examined by Novikov and Veselov. Croke [43] used several approaches, (the extended mapping, the Hirota and the extended tanh-function approaches) in the proposed system to achieve numerous soliton solutions, such as breathers, and constrained analytic solutions. Boiti, Leon, and Manna [44] applied the inverse dispersion technique to solve (1.1) for a particular type of initial value. Numerical solutions and a study of the stability of solutions for the proposed equation were presented by Kazeykina and Klein [45]. The Nizhnik-Novikov-Veselov system for two dimensions was also solved using the Kansa technique to find the numerical results [46]. To the best of my knowledge, the stability and error analysis of the numerical scheme presented here has not yet been discussed for system (1.1). Therefore, this has motivated me enormously to do so. The primary purpose is to obtain multiple analytic solutions to system (1.1) by using both the modified F-expansion and Generalized Algebraic methods. In connection with the numerical solution, the method of finite differences is utilized to achieve numerical results for the studied system. I graphically and analytically compare the traveling wave solutions and numerical results. Undoubtedly, the presented results strongly contribute to describing physical problems in practice.

    The outline of this article is provided in this paragraph. Section 2 summarizes the employed methods. All the analytic solutions are extracted in Section 3. The shooting and BVP results for the proposed system are presented in Section 4. In addition, I examine the numerical solution of the system (1.1) in Section 5. Sections 6 and 7 study the stability and error analysis of the numerical scheme, respectively. Section 8 presents the results and discussion.

    Considering the development equation with physical fields Ψ(x,y,t), Φ(x,y,t) and Γ(x,y,t) in the variables x, y and t is given in the following form:

    Q1(Ψ,Ψt,Ψx,Ψy,Γ,Γy,Γxxy,Φ,Φxyy,Φx,)=0. (2.1)

    Step 1. We extract the traveling-wave solutions of System (1.1) that are formed as follows:

    Φ(x,y,t)=ϕ(η),η=x+ywt,Ψ(x,y,t)=ψ(η),Γ(x,y,t)=Θ(η), (2.2)

    where w is the wave speed.

    Step 2. The nonlinear evolution (2.1) is reduced to the following ODE:

    Q2(ψ,ψη,Θ,Θη,Θηηη,ϕ,ϕηηη,ϕη,)=0, (2.3)

    where Q2 is a polynomial in ψ(η),ϕ(η), Θ(η) and their total derivatives.

    According to the modified F-expansion method, the solutions of (2.3) are given by the form

    ψ(η)=ρ0+Nk=1(ρkF(η)k+qkF(η)k), (2.4)

    and F(η) is a solution of the following differential equation:

    F(η)=μ0+μ1F(η)+μ2F(η)2, (2.5)

    where μ0, μ1, μ2, are given in Table 1 [1], and ρk, qk are to be determined later.

    Table 1.  The relations among μ0, μ1, μ2 and the function F(η).
    μ0 μ1 μ2 F(η)
    μ0=0, μ1=1, μ2=1, F(η)=12+12tanh(12η).
    μ0=0, μ1=1, μ2=1, F(η)=1212coth(12η).
    μ0=12, μ1=0, μ2=12, F(η)=coth(η)±csch(η), tanh(η)±sech(η).
    μ0=1, μ1=0, μ2=1, F(η)=tanh(η), coth(η).
    μ0=12, μ1=0, μ2=12, F(η)=sec(η)+tan(η), csc(η)cot(η).
    μ0=12, μ1=0, μ2=12, F(η)=sec(η)tan(η), csc(η)+cot(η).
    μ0=±1, μ1=0, μ2=±1, F(η)=tan(η), cot(η).

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    According to the generalized direct algebraic method, the solutions of (2.3) are given by

    ψ(η)=ν0+Nk=1(νkG(η)k+rkG(η)k), (2.6)

    and G(η) is a solution of the following differential equation:

    G(η)=ε4k=0δkGk(η), (2.7)

    where νk, and rk are to be determined, and N is an integer number obtained by the highest degree of the nonlinear terms and the highest order of the derivatives. ε is user-specified, usually taken with ε=±1, and δk, k=0,1,2,3,4, are given in Table 2 [2].

    Table 2.  The relations among δk, k=0,1,2,3,4, and the function G(η).
    δ0 δ1 δ2 δ3 δ4 G(η)
    δ0=0, δ1=0, δ2>0, δ3=0, δ4<0, G(η)=ε δ2δ4sech(δ2η).
    δ0=δ224c4, δ1=0, δ2<0, δ3=0, δ4>0, G(η)=εδ22δ4tanh(δ22η).
    δ0=0, δ1=0, δ2<0, δ3=0, δ4>0, G(η)=ε δ2δ4 sec (δ2η).
    δ0=δ224δ4, δ1=0, δ2>0, δ3=0, δ4>0, G(η)=ε δ22δ4tan(δ22η).
    δ0=0, δ1=0, δ2=0, δ3=0, δ4>0, G(η)=εδ4η.
    δ0=0, δ1=0, δ2>0, δ30, δ4=0, G(η)=δ2δ3.sech2(δ22η).

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Consider the Novikov-Veselov (NV) system

    Ψt+αΓxxy+βΦxyy+γΓyΦ+γ(Ψ22)y+λΓΦx+λ(Ψ22)x=0,Γy=Ψx,Ψy=Φx, (3.1)

    a system of PDEs in the unknown functions Ψ=Ψ(x,y,t),Φ=Φ(x,y,t), Γ=Γ(x,y,t) and their partial derivatives. I plug the transformations

    Φ(x,y,t)=ϕ(η),η=x+ywt,Ψ(x,y,t)=ψ(η),Γ(x,y,t)=Θ(η), (3.2)

    into Eq (3.1) to reduce it to a system of ODEs given by

    wψη+αΘηηη+βϕηηη+γΘηϕ+γ(ψ22)η+λΘϕη+λ(ψ22)η=0,Θη=ψη,ψη=ϕη. (3.3)

    Integrating Θη=ψη and ϕη=ψη yields

    Θ=ψ,and ϕ=ψ. (3.4)

    Substituting (3.4) into the first equation of (3.3) and integrating once with respect to η yields

    wψ+(α+β)ψηη+(γ+λ)ψ2=0. (3.5)

    Balancing ψηη with ψ2 in (3.5) calculates the value of N=2.

    According to the modified F-expansion method with N=2, the solutions of (3.5) are

    ψ(η)=ρ0+ρ1F(η)+q1F(η)+ρ2F(η)2+q2F(η)2, (3.6)

    and F(η) is a solution of the following differential equation:

    F(η)=μ0+μ1F(η)+μ2F(η)2, (3.7)

    where μ0, μ1, μ2 are given in Table 1. To explore the analytic solutions to (3.5), I ought to follow the subsequent steps.

    Step 1. Placing (3.6) along with (3.7) into Eq (3.5) and gathering the coefficients of F(η)j, j = 4,3,2,1,0,1,2,3,4, to zeros gives a system of equations for ρ0,ρk,qk, k=1,2.

    Step 2. Solve the resulting system using mathematical software: for example, Mathematica or Maple.

    Step 3. Choosing the values of μ0,μ1 and μ2 and the function F(η) from Table 1 and substituting them along with ρ0,ρk,qk, k=1,2, in (3.6) produces a set of trigonometric function and rational solutions to (3.5).

    Applying the above steps, I determine the values of ρ0,ρ1,ρ2,q1,q2 and w as follows:

    (1). When μ0=0, μ1=1 and μ2=1, I have two cases.

    Case 1.

    ρ0=0,ρ1=6(α+β)γ+λ,ρ2=6(α+β)γ+λ,q1=q2=0,andw=α+β. (3.8)

    The solution is given by

    Ψ1(x,y,t)=3(α+β)2(γ+λ)sech2(12(x+y(α+β)t+x0)). (3.9)

    Case 2.

    ρ0=α+βγ+λ,ρ1=6(α+β)γ+λ,ρ2=6(α+β)γ+λ,q1=q2=0,andw=(α+β). (3.10)

    The solution is given by

    Ψ2(x,y,t)=(α+β)2(γ+λ)(3tanh2(12(x+y+t(α+β))+x0)1). (3.11)

    Figure 1 presents the time evolution of the analytic solutions (a) Ψ1 and (b) Ψ2 with t=0,10,20. The parameter values are x0=20, α=0.50,β=0.6, γ=1.5, and λ=1. Figure 2 presents the wave behavior by changing a certain parameter value and fixing the values of the others. Figure 2(a,b) presents the behavior of Ψ1 when I change the values of (a) α or β and (b) γ or λ. In Figure 2(a) it can also be seen that the value of α or β affects the direction and amplitude of the wave, such that a negative value always makes the wave negative, its amplitude decreases when α,β0, and its amplitude increases when α,β. In Figure 2(b) the value of γ or λ affects the direction and amplitude of the wave, such that a negative value always makes the wave negative, and its amplitude decreases when the value of γ or λ increases. In Figure 2, (c) and (d) present the wave behavior of Ψ2.

    Figure 1.  Time evolution of the analytic solutions (a) Ψ1 and (b) Ψ2 with t=0,10,20. The parameter are given by x0=20, α=0.50,β=0.6, γ=1.5, and λ=1.
    Figure 2.  This figure present the wave behavior when changing a certain parameter value and fixing the values of the others. (a) presents the behavior when I change the value of α or β, and (b) presents when I change the value of γ or λ for the solution Ψ1. (c) and (d) are for Ψ2.

    (2). When μ0=0, μ1=1, and μ2=1, I have two cases.

    Case 3. The solution is given by

    Ψ3(x,y,t)=3(α+β)2(γ+λ)csch2(12(x+y(α+β)t)). (3.12)

    Case 4. The solution is given by

    Ψ4(x,y,t)=(α+β)2(γ+λ)(3coth2(12(x+y+t(α+β)))1). (3.13)

    (3). When μ0=1, μ1=0, and μ2=1, I have

    Case 5. The solution is given by

    Ψ5(x,y,t)=8(α+β)γ+λ(cosh(4(16t(α+β)+x+y))+2)csch2(2(16t(α+β)+x+y)). (3.14)

    (4). When μ0=±1, μ1=0, and μ2=±1, I have one case.

    Case 6. The solution is given by

    Ψ6(x,y,t)=24(α+β)γ+λcsc2(2(16t(α+β)+x+y)). (3.15)

    According to the generalized algebraic method, the solutions of (3.5) are given by the form

    ψ(η)=ν0+ν1G(η)+ν2G(η)2+r1G(η)+r2G(η)2, (3.16)

    where νk, rk are to be determined later. G(η) is a solution of the following differential equation:

    G(η)=ε4k=0δkGk(η), (3.17)

    where δk, k=0,1,3,4, are given in Table 2. In all the cases mentioned above and the subsequent solutions, I used the mathematical software Mathematica to find the values of the constants ν0,ν1,ν2,r1,r2 and w. Thus, the analytic solutions to (3.5) using the generalized algebraic method will be presented here with different values of the constants δk, k=0,1,3,4.

    (5). When δ0=δ224δ4, δ1=δ3=0, δ2<0, δ4>0, and ε=±1,

    ν0=±4δ22ε4(α+β)2(γ+λ)23δ2ε4(α+β)2(γ+λ)22δ2ε2(α+β)(γ+λ)(γ+λ)2,ν2=6δ4ε2(α+β)(γ+λ),ν1=r1=r2=0,ε=±1.w=±2(4δ223δ2)ε4(α+β)2(γ+λ)2(γ+λ). (3.18)

    Case 7. The solution is given by

    Ψ7(x,y,t)=1(γ+λ)2(3δ2ε4(α+β)(γ+λ)tanh2(δ2(2tδ2(4δ23)ε4(α+β)2(γ+λ)2γ+λ+x+y)2)+2δ2ε2(α+β)(γ+λ)+δ2(4δ23)ε4(α+β)2(γ+λ)2). (3.19)

    Figure 3 shows the time evolution of the analytic solutions. Figure 3(a) shows Ψ7 with t = 0:2:6. The parameter values are δ2=1, δ4=1, ϵ=1, α=0.50, β=0.6, γ=1.5, λ=1.8 and x0=10. Figure 3(b) shows Ψ8 with t=0:2:8. The parameter values are δ2=1, δ4=1, ϵ=1, α=0.50, β=0.6, γ=1.5, λ=1.8 and x0=10. Figures 46 present the 3D time evolution of the analytic solutions Ψ2 (left) and the numerical solutions (right) obtained employing the scheme 5.1 with t=5,15,25, Mx=1600, Ny=100, x=060 and y=01.

    Figure 3.  Time evolution of the analytic solutions. (a) Ψ7 with t=0:2:6. The parameter values are δ2=1, δ4=1, ϵ=1, α=0.50, β=0.6, γ=1.5, λ=1.8 and x0=10. (b) Ψ8 with t=0:2:8. The parameter values are δ2=1, δ4=1, ϵ=1, α=0.50, β=0.6, γ=1.5, λ=1.8 and x0=10.
    Figure 4.  3D graphs presenting the analytic (left) and the numerical (right) solutions of Ψ2(x,y,t) at t=5. The figures present the strength of agreement between analytic and numerical solutions.
    Figure 5.  3D graphs presenting the analytic (left) and the numerical (right) solutions of Ψ2(x,y,t) at t=15. The figures present the strength of agreement between analytic and numerical solutions.
    Figure 6.  3D graphs presenting the analytic (left) and the numerical (right) solutions of Ψ2(x,y,t) at t=25. The figures present the strength of agreement between analytic and numerical solutions.

    (6). When δ0=0, δ1=δ3=0, δ2>0, δ4<0, and ε=±1,

    ν2=6δ4ε2(α+β)γ+λ,ν1=ν0=r1=r2=0,w=4δ2ε2(α+β). (3.20)

    Case 8. The solution is given by

    Ψ8(x,y,t)=6δ2ϵ4(α+β)sech2(δ2(4δ2ϵ2t(α+β)+x+y))γ+λ (3.21)

    (7). When δ0=0, δ1=δ4=0, δ30, δ2>0, ε=±1

    Set 1.ν1=3δ3ε2(α+β)2(γ+λ),ν0=ν2=r1=r2=0,w=δ2ε2(α+β).Set 2.ν0=δ2ε2(α+β)(γ+λ),ν1=3δ3ε2(α+β)2(γ+λ),ν2=r1=r2=0,w=δ2ε2(α+β). (3.22)

    Case 9.The solution is given by

    Ψ9(x,y,t)=3δ2(α+β)sech2(12δ2(δ2t((α+β))+x+y))2(γ+λ). (3.23)

    Case 10. The solution is given by

    Ψ10(x,y,t)=3δ2(α+β)sech2(12δ2(δ2t(α+β)+x+y))2(γ+λ)δ2(α+β)γ+λ. (3.24)

    In this section I extract numerical solutions to the resulting ODE system (3.5) using several numerical methods. The purpose of this procedure is to guarantee the accuracy of the analytic solutions. I picked one of the analytic solutions above to be a sample, (3.11). The nonlinear shooting and BVP methods, at t=0, are used by taking the value of ψ at the right endpoint of the domain η=0 with guessing the initial value for ψη. The new target is to obtain the second boundary condition of ψ at the left endpoint of a particular domain. Once the numerical result is obtained, I compare it with the analytic solution (3.11). The MATLAB solver ODE15s and FSOLVE [47] are used to get the numerical solution. The resulting ODE (3.5) is discretized as

    f(ψ)=0,f(ψi)=wψi+α+βΔη(ψi+12ψi+ψi1)+γ+λ2Δη(ψ2i+1ψ2i1), (4.1)

    for the BVP method and

    ψηη=1α+β(wψ(γ+λ)ψ2), (4.2)

    for the shooting method. Figure 7 presents the comparison between the numerical solutions obtained using the above numerical methods and the analytic solution. Figure 7 shows that the solutions are identical to the analytic solution.

    Figure 7.  Comparing the numerical solutions resulting from the shooting and BVP methods with the analytic solution (3.11) at t=0. The parameter values are taken as α=0.50, β=0.6, γ=1.5,λ=1.8, with N=600.

    Thus, it is possible to verify the correctness of the analytic solution. I also accept the obtained numerical solution as an initial condition for the numerical scheme in the next section.

    In this section, I use the finite-difference method to obtain the numerical results of system (1.1) over the domain [a,b]×[c,d]. Here, a,b,c and d represent the endpoints of the rectangular domain in the x and y directions, respectively, and Tf is a certain time. The domain [a,b]×[c,d] is split into (Mx+1)×(Ny+1) mesh points:

    xm=a+mΔx,m=0,1,2,,Mx,yn=c+nΔy,n=0,1,2,,Ny,

    where Δx and Δy are the step-sizes of the x and y domains, respectively. The system (1.1) is converted to an ODE system by discretizing the space derivatives while keeping the time derivative continuous. Completing this yields

    Ψt|km,n+α2ΔyΔ2xδ2x(Γk+1m,n+1Γk+1m,n1)+β2ΔxΔ2yδ2y(Φk+1m+1,nΦk+1m1,n)γ4Δy((Φk+1m,n+1+Φk+1m,n)Γk+1m,n+1(Φk+1m,n+Φk+1m,n1)Γk+1m,n1)λ4Δx((Γk+1m+1,n+Γk+1m,n)Φk+1m+1,n(Γk+1m,n+Γk+1m1,n)Φk+1m1,n)+γ4Δy((Ψk+1m,n+1)2(Ψk+1m,n1)2)+λ4Δx((Ψk+1m+1,n)2(Ψk+1m1,n)2)=0,12Δy(Γk+1m,n+1Γk+1m,n1)=12Δx(Ψk+1m+1,nΨk+1m1,n),12Δy(Ψk+1m,n+1Ψk+1m,n1)=12Δx(Φk+1m+1,nΦk+1m1,n), (5.1)

    where

    δ2xΓk+1m,n=(Γk+1m+1,n2Γk+1m,n+Γk+1m1,n),δ2yΦk+1m,n=(Φk+1m,n+12Φk+1m,n+Φk+1m,n1),

    subject to the boundary conditions:

    Ψx(a,y,t)=Ψx(b,y,t)=0,y[c,d],Ψy(x,c,t)=Ψy(x,d,t)=0,x[a,b]. (5.2)

    Equation (5.2) permits us to use fictitious points in estimating the space derivatives at the domain's endpoints. The initial conditions are generated by

    Ψ2(x,y,0)=(α+β)2(γ+λ)(3tanh2(12(x+y+x0)1), (5.3)

    where α,β,γ and λ are user-defined parameters. In all the numerical results shown in this section, the parameter values are fixed as α=0.50,β=0.6,γ=1.50,λ=1.80,x0=45.0, y=01, x=060 and t=025. The above system is solved by using an ODE solver in FORTRAN called the DDASPK solver [48]. This solver used a backward differentiation formula. Since I do not have the initial conditions for the space derivatives, I approximate the Jacobian matrix of the linearized system by using LU-Factorization. The obtained numerical results are acceptable. This can be observed from the Figures 8 and 9.

    Figure 8.  Time change for the numerical results while holding y=0.5 and Mx=1600 at t=0:5:25. The wave at t=25 illustrates that the numerical and the analytic solutions are quite identical.
    Figure 9.  The convergence histories of the scheme with the fixation of both y=0.5 and Mx=1600 at t=5.

    The von Neumann analysis is used to examine the stability of the scheme (5.1). The von Neumann analysis is occasionally called Fourier analysis and is utilized exclusively when the scheme is linear. Hence, I suppose that the linear version is given by

    Ψt+αΓxxy+βΦxyy+s0Γy+s1Ψy+s2Φx+s3Ψx=0,Γy=Ψx,Ψy=Φx, (6.1)

    where s0=γΦ, s1=γΨ, s2=λΓ, s3=λΨ are constants. Since Γy=Ψx, and Ψy=Φx, the first equation of (6.1) is given by

    Ψt+αΨxxx+βΨyyy+s0Ψy+s1Ψy+s2Ψx+s3Ψx=0, (6.2)

    where α,β,γ,λ,s0,s1,s2,s3,l4 are constants. I set directly

    Ψkm,n=μkexp(ιπξ0nΔx)exp(ιπξ1mΔy), (6.3)

    and also I can have

    Ψk+1m,n=μΨkm,n,Ψkm+1,n=exp(ιπξ0Δx)Ψkm,n,Ψkm,n+1=exp(ιπξ1Δy)Ψkm,n,Ψkm1,n=exp(ιπξ0Δx)Ψkm,n,Ψkm,n1=exp(ιπξ1Δy)Ψkm,n,m=1,2,,Nx1,n=1,2,,Ny1.

    Substituting (6.3) into (6.2) and doing some operations, I have

    1=μ(1ιΔt(sin(ξ0πΔx)Δx(4αΔ2xsin2(ξ0πΔx2)s2s3)+sin(ξ1πΔy)Δy(4βΔ2ysin2(ξ1πΔy2)s0s1))).

    Hence,

    μ=11aι, (6.4)

    where

    a=Δt(sin(ξ0πΔx)Δx(4αΔ2xsin2(ξ0πΔx2)s2s3)+sin(ξ1πΔy)Δy(4βΔ2ysin2(ξ1πΔy2)s0s1)).

    Thus,

    |μ|2=11+a21. (6.5)

    The stability condition of the von Neumann analysis is fulfilled. Consequently, from Eq (6.5), the scheme is unconditionally stable.

    To examine the accuracy of the numerical scheme (5.1), I study the truncation error utilizing Taylor expansions. Suppose that the error is

    ek+1m,n=Ψk+1m,nΨ(xm,yn,tk+1), (7.1)

    where Ψ(xm,yn,tk+1) and Ψk+1m,n are the analytic solution and an approximate solution, respectively. Substituting (7.1) into (5.1) gives

    ek+1j,kekj,kΔt=Tk+1m,n(α12Δ3xδ2x(ek+1m+1,nek+1m1,n)+β12Δ3yδ2y(ek+1m,n+1ek+1m,n1)+s2+s32Δx(ek+1m+1,nek+1m1,n)+s0+s12Δy(ek+1m,n+1ek+1m,n1)),

    where

    Tk+1m,n=α2Δ3xδ2x(Ψ(xm+1,yn,tk+1)Ψ(xm1,yn,tk+1))+β2Δ3yδ2y(Ψ(xm,yn+1,tk+1)Ψ(xm,yn1,tk+1))+s2+s32Δx(Ψ(xm+1,yn,tk+1)Ψ(xm1,yn,tk+1))+s0+s12Δy(Ψ(xm,yn+1,tk+1)Ψ(xm,yn1,tk+1)).

    Hence,

    Tk+1m,nΔt22Ψ(xm,yn,ξk+1)t2Δ2x25Ψ(ζm,yn,tk+1)x5Δ2y25Ψ(xm,ηn,tk+1)x5Δ2y63Ψ(xm,ηn,tk+1)x3Δ2x63Ψ(ζm,yn,tk+1)x3.

    Accordingly, the truncation error of the numerical scheme is

    Tk+1m,n=O(Δt,Δ2x,Δ2y).

    I have prosperously employed several analytical methods to extract the traveling wave solutions to the two-dimensional Novikov-Veselov system, confirming the solutions with numerical results obtained using the numerical scheme (5.1). The major highlights of the results are shown in Table 3 and Figures 810, which allow immediate comparison of the analytic solutions with the numerical results. Through these, I can notice that the solutions are identical to a large extent, and the error approaches zero whenever the value of Δx,Δy0. The numerical schemes are unconditionally stable for fixing the parameter values α=0.50,β=0.6,γ=1.50,λ=1.80,x0=45.0, y=01, x=060 and t=025.

    Table 3.  The relative error with L2 norm and CPU at t=20..
    Δx The Relative Error CPU
    0.6000 5.600×103 0.063×103m
    0.3000 2.100×103 0.1524×103s
    0.1500 6.700×104 0.3564×103s
    0.0750 2.100×104 0.8892×103s
    0.0375 6.610×105 1.7424×103s
    0.0187 2.310×105 4.0230×103s

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV
    Figure 10.  The convergence histories measured utilizing the relative error with l2 norm as a function of Δx (see Table 3). Here, I picked a certain value of the variable y=0.5 at t=20 and x=060.

    Figure 1 presents the time evolution of the analytic solutions (a) Ψ1 and (b) Ψ2 with t=0,10,20. The parameter values are x0=20, α=0.50, β=0.6, γ=1.5, and λ=1. Figure 2 presents the wave behavior by changing a certain parameter value and fixing the values of the others. Figure 2(a,b) presents the behavior of Ψ1 when I change the values of (a) α or β and (b) γ or λ. In Figure 2(a) it can also be seen that the value of α or β affects the direction and amplitude of the wave, such that a negative value always makes the wave negative, its amplitude decreases when α,β0, and its amplitude increases when α,β. In Figure 2(b) the value of γ or λ affects the direction and amplitude of the wave, such that a negative value always makes the wave negative, and its amplitude decreases when the value of γ or λ increases. In Figure 2(c,d) present the wave behavior of Ψ2. Figure 3 shows the time evolution of the analytic solutions. Figure 3(a) shows Ψ7 with t=0:2:6. The parameter values are δ2=1, δ4=1, ϵ=1, α=0.50, β=0.6, γ=1.5, λ=1.8 and x0=10. Figure 3(b) shows Ψ8 with t=0:2:8. The parameter values are δ2=1, δ4=1, ϵ=1, α=0.50, β=0.6, γ=1.5, λ=1.8 and x0=10. Figures 46 present the 3D time evolution of the analytic solutions Ψ2 (left) and the numerical solutions (right) obtained employing the scheme 5.1 with t=5,15,25, Mx=1600, Ny=100, x=060 and y=01. These figures provide us with an adequate answer that the numerical and analytic solutions are quite identical. Barman et al. [42] accepted several traveling wave solutions for (1.1) as hyperbolic functions. The authors employed other parameters to develop new forms for the accepted solution. They proposed that Eq (1.1) describes tidal and tsunami waves, electromagnetic waves in transmission cables and magneto-sound and ion waves in plasma. In comparison, I have found numerous solutions also as hyperbolic functions. Furthermore, I obtained the numerical solutions to enhance the assurance that the solutions presented here are correct and accurate.

    I have successfully utilized the generalized algebraic and modified F-expansion methods to acquire the soliton solutions for the two-dimensional Novikov-Veselov system, verifying these solutions with numerical results obtained by employing the numerical scheme (5.1). The major highlights of the results shown in Figures 810 and Table 3, which allow immediate comparison of the analytic solutions with the numerical results. Through these, I can notice that the solutions are identical to a large extent, and the error approaches zero whenever the value of Δx,Δy0. The numerical schemes are unconditionally stable for fixing the parameter values α=0.50,β=0.6,γ=1.50,λ=1.80, x0=45.0, y=01, x=060 and t=025. The Jacobi elliptic functions have effectively deteriorated to hyperbolic functions. The applied numerical schemes have provided reliable numerical solutions when using a small value of Δx,Δy0.

    Ultimately, I can deduce that the methods used are valuable and applicable to extract soliton solutions for other nonlinear evolutionary systems found in chemistry, engineering, physics and other sciences.

    The author declares that he has no potential conflict of interest in this article.



    [1] Abel JR, Deitz R (2019) Why are some places so much more unequal than others? Fed Reserve Bank New York Econ Policy Rev 25: 58–75.
    [2] Adkins L (2015) What are post-Fordist wages? Simmel, labor money, and the problem of value. South Atl Q 114: 331–353. doi: 10.1215/00382876-2862740
    [3] Adler D, Breznitz D (2020) Reshoring supply chains: a practical policy agenda. Am Aff Summer: 6–18.
    [4] Allchin D (1992) Phlogiston after oxygen. Ambix 39: 110–116. doi: 10.1179/amb.1992.39.3.110
    [5] Amin S (1977) Imperialism and Unequal Development, Hassocks, Sussex: Harvester Press.
    [6] Anderson P (2020) Ukania perpetua? New Left Rev 125: 35–107.
    [7] Appelbaum B (2019) The Economists' Hour: False Prophets, Free Markets, and the Fracture of Society, New York: Little, Brown.
    [8] Armstrong R (2020) Business is squeezed in the US-China fight. Financial Times, 28 May.
    [9] Arrighi G, Drangel J (1986) The stratification of the world-economy. Review (Fernand Braudel Center) 10: 9–74.
    [10] Asea PK, Corden WM (1994) The Balassa-Samuelson model: an overview. Rev Int Econ 2: 191–200. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9396.1994.tb00040.x
    [11] Ashford DE (1989) The Whig interpretation of the welfare state. J Policy Hist 1: 24–43. doi: 10.1017/S0898030600004589
    [12] Auerback M, Ritch-Frel J (2020) New fault lines in a post-globalized world. Am Aff. Available from: https://americanaffairsjournal.org/2020/11/new-fault-lines-in-a-post-globalized-world/.
    [13] Bair J (2005) Global capitalism and commodity chains: looking back, going forward. Competition Change 9: 153–180. doi: 10.1179/102452905X45382
    [14] Bair J (2009) Global commodity chains: genealogy and review, In: Bair J, ed. Frontiers of Commodity Chain Research, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1–34.
    [15] Baran PA (1957) The Political Economy of Growth, New York: Monthly Review Press.
    [16] Baran PA, Sweezy PM (1966) Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the American Economic and Social Order, New York: Monthly Review Press.
    [17] Bello W (2017) Asia and finance capital: From the Japanese bubble to China's financial time bomb. Transnational Institute, Finance Working Paper 3. Available from: https://www.tni.org/files/publication-downloads/tni-asia-finance-and-capital-working-paper.pdf (Accessed 17 August 2020).
    [18] Benanav A (2019) Automation and the future of work I. New Left Rev 119: 5–38.
    [19] Benanav A (2020) World asymmetries. New Left Rev 125: 138–149.
    [20] Bhagwati J, Panagariya A, Srinivasan TN (2004) The muddles over outsourcing. J Econ Perspect 18: 93–114. doi: 10.1257/0895330042632753
    [21] Blecker RA (2005) Financial globalization, exchange rates and international trade, In: Epstein GA, Financialization and the World Economy, ed., Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 183–209.
    [22] Boehmer-Christiansen SA, Merten D, Meissner J, et al. (1993) Ecological restructuring or environment friendly deindustrialization: the fate of the East German energy sector and society since 1990. Energ Policy 21: 355–373. doi: 10.1016/0301-4215(93)90276-L
    [23] Boot M (2019) Trump is deconstructing the government, one agency at a time. Washington Post, 2 December.
    [24] Boulding K (1966) The economics of the coming spaceship Earth, In: Jarrett H, Environmental Quality in a Growing Economy, ed., Baltimore, MD: Resources for the Future/Johns Hopkins University Press, 3–14.
    [25] Bovcon M (2011) Françafrique and regime theory. Eur J Int Relations 19: 5–26.
    [26] Brazelton WR (1989) Alvin Harvey Hansen: economic growth and a more perfect society. Am J Econ Sociol 48: 427–440. doi: 10.1111/j.1536-7150.1989.tb02131.x
    [27] Bruszt L, McDermott GA (2009) Transnational integration regimes as development programmes, In: Bruszt L, Holzhacker R, The Transnationalization of Economies, States, and Civil Societies: New Challenges for Governance in Europe, eds., New York: Springer, 23–60.
    [28] Bulmer S, Joseph J (2016) European integration in crisis? Of supranational integration, hegemonic projects and domestic politics. Eur J Int Relations 22: 725–748. doi: 10.1177/1354066115612558
    [29] Caldwell R (2011) HR directors in UK boardrooms: a search for strategic influence or symbolic capital? Employee Relations 33: 40–63. doi: 10.1108/01425451111091645
    [30] Campbell P (2016) Tariffs likely to hit Channel-hopping car parts. Financial Times, 17 October.
    [31] Cashore B (2002) Legitimacy and the privatization of environmental governance: how non-state market-driven (NSMD) governance systems gain rule-making authority. Governance 15: 503–529. doi: 10.1111/1468-0491.00199
    [32] Chaffin J (2020) Fear of a post-pandemic exodus. Financial Times, 27 May.
    [33] Chen H, Kondratowicz M, Yi KM (2005) Vertical specialization and three facts about U.S. international trade. North Am J Econ Financ 16: 35–59.
    [34] Chester L (2013) The failure of market fundamentalism: how electricity sector restructuring is threatening the economic and social fabric. Rev Radical Polit Econ 45: 315–322. doi: 10.1177/0486613413487163
    [35] Christensen J (2017) The Power of Economists within the State, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
    [36] Cilliers J (2001) Still … France versus the rest in Africa? Afr Secur Stud 10: 123–126.
    [37] Cobb C, Halstead T, Rowe J (1995) If GDP is up, why is America down? Atl Monthly 276: 59–78.
    [38] Cohen MJ (1997) Risk society and ecological modernisation: alternative visions for post-industrial nations. Futures 29: 105–119. doi: 10.1016/S0016-3287(96)00071-7
    [39] Cowen D (2014) The Deadly Life of Logistics: Mapping Violence in Global Trade, Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press.
    [40] Cox J (2019a) Real US debt levels could be 2,000% of economy, a Wall Street report suggests. CNBC.com, 9 September. Available from: https://www.cnbc.com/2019/09/09/real-us-debt-levels-could-be-a-shocking-2000percent-of-gdp-report-suggests.html (accessed 17 August 2020).
    [41] Cox J (2019b) Shadow banking is now a $52 trillion industry, posing a big risk to the financial system. CNBC.com, 11 April. Available from: https://www.cnbc.com/2019/04/11/shadow-banking-is-now-a-52-trillion-industry-and-posing-risks.html (accessed 18 August 2020).
    [42] Craig D, Porter D (2004) The third way and the third world: poverty reduction and social inclusion in the rise of 'inclusive' liberalism. Rev Int Polit Economy 11: 387–423. doi: 10.1080/09692290420001672881
    [43] Desai R (2013) Geopolitical Economy: After US Hegemony, Globalization and Empire, London: Pluto Press.
    [44] Dixit A, Grossman G (2005) The limits of free trade. J Econ Perspect 19: 241–244. doi: 10.1257/089533005774357789
    [45] Donoghue M (2020) Adam Smith and the Honourable East India Company. Hist Econ Rev 77: 1–19. doi: 10.1080/10370196.2020.1794559
    [46] Dornbusch R, Krugman P (1976) Flexible exchange rates in the short run. Brookings Pap Econ Act 3: 537–584. doi: 10.2307/2534369
    [47] Drucker PF (1962) The economy's dark continent. Fortune 72: 265–270.
    [48] Edgecliffe-Johnson A (2020) Global threats spark rethink on company supply chains. Financial Times, 10 August.
    [49] Editorial Board (2020) Stranded crews pose a risk to supply chains. Financial Times, 29 September.
    [50] Emmanuel A (1973) Unequal Exchange: A Study of the Imperialism of Trade, New York: Monthly Review Press.
    [51] Fallows J (2020) The 3 weeks that changed everything. The Atlantic, 29 June. Available from: https://www.theatlantic.com/politics/archive/2020/06/how-white-house-coronavirus-response-went-wrong/613591/ (accessed 17 August 2020).
    [52] Ferguson C (2014) Inside Job: The Financiers Who Pulled Off the Heist of the Century, London: Oneworld.
    [53] Flanagan K, Uyarra E (2016) Four dangers in innovation policy studies—and how to avoid them. Ind Innovation 23: 177–188. doi: 10.1080/13662716.2016.1146126
    [54] Fleming S, Peel M (2020) EU urged to build up supply chains. Financial Times, 6 May.
    [55] Foroohar R (2016) Makers and Takers: The Rise of Finance and the Fall of American Business, New York: Crown Business.
    [56] Foroohar R (2020a) Coronavirus speeds up global decoupling. Financial Times, 24 February.
    [57] Foroohar R (2020b) The great global trade unwinding. Financial Times, 10 August.
    [58] Foster JB, Holleman H (2014) The theory of unequal ecological exchange: a Marx-Odum dialectic. J Peasant Stud 41: 199–233. doi: 10.1080/03066150.2014.889687
    [59] Fraser D (2017) The Evolution of the British Welfare State, 5th ed, London: Palgrave.
    [60] Galeano E (1973) Open Veins of Latin America: Five Centuries of the Pillage of a Continent, New York: Monthly Review Press.
    [61] Gallagher J, Robinson R (1953) The imperialism of free trade. Econ Hist Rev 6: 1–15. doi: 10.2307/2591017
    [62] Garten JE (1997a) Can the world survive the triumph of capitalism? Harv Bus Rev 75: 144–148.
    [63] Garten JE (1997b) Business and foreign policy. Foreign Aff 76: 67–79.
    [64] Gassebner M, Gaston N, Lamla M (2008) Relief for the environment? The importance of an increasingly unimportant industrial sector. Econ Inq 46: 160–178. doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2007.00086.x
    [65] Georgescu-Roegen N (1971) The Entropy Law and the Economic Process, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
    [66] Gereffi G (1983) The Pharmaceutical Industry and Dependency in the Third World, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
    [67] Gereffi G (1994) The organization of buyer-driven global commodity chains: how US retailers shape overseas production networks, In: Gereffi G, Korzeniewicz M, Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism, eds., Westport, CT: Praeger, 95–122.
    [68] Gereffi G (1995) Global production systems and third world development, In: Stallings B, Global Change, Regional Response: The New International Context of Development, ed., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 100–142.
    [69] Gereffi G (2014) Global value chains in a post-Washington Consensus world. Rev Int Polit Econ 21: 9–37. doi: 10.1080/09692290.2012.756414
    [70] Gereffi G (2018) Global Value Chains and Development: Redefining the Contours of 21st Century Capitalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    [71] Gereffi G (2020) What does the COVID-19 pandemic teach us about global value chains? The case of medical supplies. J Int Bus Policy 3: 287–301. doi: 10.1057/s42214-020-00062-w
    [72] Gereffi G, Humphrey J, Kaplinsky R, et al. (2001) Introduction: Globalisation, value chains and development. IDS B 32: 1–8. doi: 10.1111/j.1759-5436.2001.mp32003001.x
    [73] Gettleman ME (1974) The Whig interpretation of social welfare history. Smith College Stud Soc Work 54: 149–157.
    [74] Gilpin R (1975) U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment, New York: Basic Books.
    [75] Gilpin R (2001) Global Political Economy: Understanding the International Economic Order. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
    [76] Grahl J (2011) A capitalist contrarian. New Left Rev 69: 35–59.
    [77] Gréau JL (1998) Le Capitalisme Malade de sa Finance, Paris: Gallimard.
    [78] Gréau JL (2005) L'Avenir du Capitalisme, Paris: Gallimard.
    [79] Gréau JL (2008) La Trahison des Economistes, Paris: Gallimard.
    [80] Greider W (1997) One World, Ready or Not: The Manic Logic of Global Capitalism, London: Penguin.
    [81] Güney-Frahm I (2018) Agenda 2030: haunted by the ghost of the Third Way? J Dev Soc 34: 56–76.
    [82] Haas T (2020) From green energy to green car state? The political economy of ecological modernisation in Germany. New Polit Econ, forthcoming.
    [83] Hall B (2020) Brussels treads tricky path between 'resilience' and protectionism. Financial Times, 4 June.
    [84] Hansen A (1939) Economic progress and declining population growth. Am Econ Rev 29: 1–15.
    [85] Harvey D (2003) The New Imperialism, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
    [86] Helleiner GK (1973a) Manufactured exports from less-developed countries and multinational firms. Econ J 83: 21–47. doi: 10.2307/2231098
    [87] Helleiner GK (1973b) Manufacturing for export, multinational firms and economic development. World Dev 1: 13–21.
    [88] Hille K (2020a) Taiwan plans greater state say on future of industrial development. Financial Times, 26 May.
    [89] Hille K (2020b) Why US pressure will multiply supply chains. Financial Times, 7 October.
    [90] Hirsh M (2010) Capital Offense: How Washington's Wise Men Turned America's Future Over to Wall Street, Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons.
    [91] Hirsh M (2019) Economists on the run. Foreign Policy 22 October. Available from: https://foreignpolicy.com/2019/10/22/economists-globalization-trade-paul-krugman-china/ (accessed 17 August 2020).
    [92] Hopkin J (2017) When Polanyi met Farage: market fundamentalism, economic nationalism, and Britain's exit from the European Union. Br J Polit Int Relations 19: 465–478. doi: 10.1177/1369148117710894
    [93] Hopkins TK, Wallerstein I (1977) Patterns of development of the modern world-system. Review (Fernand Braudel Center) 1: 111–145.
    [94] Hopkins TK, Wallerstein I (1986) Commodity chains in the world-economy prior to 1800. Review (Fernand Braudel Center) 10: 157–170.
    [95] Hornborg A (1998) Towards an ecological theory of unequal exchange: articulating world system theory and ecological economics. Ecol Econ 25: 127–136. doi: 10.1016/S0921-8009(97)00100-6
    [96] Hornborg A (2001) The Power of the Machine: Inequalities of Economy, Technology, and Environment, Walnut Creek, CA: AltaMira Press.
    [97] Hornborg A (2009) Zero-sum world: challenges in conceptualizing environmental load displacement and ecologically unequal exchange in the world-system. Int J Comp Soc 50: 237–262. doi: 10.1177/0020715209105141
    [98] Hudson M (2004) Global Fracture: The New International Economic Order, new edition, London: Pluto Press.
    [99] Hummels D, Ishii J, Yo KM (2001) The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. J Int Econ 54: 75–96. doi: 10.1016/S0022-1996(00)00093-3
    [100] Hutton W (1995) The State We're In, London: Jonathan Cape.
    [101] Hyun S, Paradise JF (2019) Why is there no Asian Monetary Fund? ADBI Working Paper 1061. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute.
    [102] Information Services Group (2020) Managed Services and As-a-Service Market Insights. ISG Index, Fourth Quarter 2019. 14 January. Available from: https://isg-one.com/docs/default-source/default-document-library/4q19-global-isg-index.pdf?sfvrsn=53cc631_4 (accessed 11 August 2020).
    [103] Jack A (2020) "Business schools overhaul courses post-Covid." Financial Times, 20 July.
    [104] Jamison DT, Summers LH, Alleyne G, et al. (2013) Global health 2035: a world converging within a generation. Lancet 382: 1898–1955. doi: 10.1016/S0140-6736(13)62105-4
    [105] Jessop B (2002) The Future of the Capitalist State, Cambridge: Polity Press.
    [106] Jessop B (2015a) Crisis construal in the North Atlantic Financial Crisis and the Eurozone crisis. Competition Change 19: 95–112. doi: 10.1177/1024529415571866
    [107] Jessop B (2015b) Comparative capitalisms and/or variegated capitalism, In: Ebenau M, Bruff I, May C, New Directions in Comparative Capitalisms Research: Critical and Global Perspectives, eds., Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 65–82.
    [108] Johnson C (2000) Blowback: The Costs and Consequences of American Empire, New York: Metropolitan Books.
    [109] Johnson HG (1970) The efficiency and welfare implications of the international corporation, In: Kindleberger CP, The International Corporation: A Symposium, ed., Cambridge, MA: M.I.T. Press, 35–56.
    [110] Kaplinsky R (2000) Globalisation and unequalisation: what can be learned from value chain analysis? J Dev Stud 37: 117–146.
    [111] Karabarbounis L, Neiman B (2014) The global decline of the labor share. Q J Econ 129: 61–103. doi: 10.1093/qje/qjt032
    [112] Kay C (1989) Latin American Theories of Development and Underdevelopment, London: Routledge.
    [113] Keaney M (2011) Picking the entrails of the Washington Consensus. World Rev Polit Econ 2: 134–158.
    [114] Kim YK (2020) Household debt accumulation and the Great Recession of the United States: a comparative perspective. Rev Radical Polit Econ 52: 26–49. doi: 10.1177/0486613419868031
    [115] Kirshner J (2014) American Power after the Financial Crisis, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
    [116] Konings M (2011) The Development of American Finance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    [117] Krugman P (n.d.a) Review of One World, Ready or Not, by William Greider. Available from: http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/greider.html (accessed 23 September 2020).
    [118] Krugman P (n.d. b) How I work. Available from: http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/howiwork.html (accessed 18 August 2020).
    [119] Krugman P (1997) The accidental theorist. Available from: https://slate.com/business/1997/01/the-accidental-theorist.html (accessed 13 August 2020).
    [120] Krugman P (2019) What economists (including me) got wrong about globalization. Available from: https://www.bloomberg.com/opinion/articles/2019-10-10/inequality-globalization-and-the-missteps-of-1990s-economics (accessed 13 August 2020).
    [121] Lazonick W (1991) Business Organization and the Myth of the Market Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    [122] Lewis J (2011) The British Empire and world history: welfare imperialism and 'soft' power in the rise and fall of colonial rule, In: Midgley J, Piachaud D, Colonialism and Welfare: Social Policy and the British Imperial Legacy, eds., Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 17–35.
    [123] Lewis L (2020) A new look for national security. Financial Times, 14 May.
    [124] Lewis M (2018) The Fifth Risk, New York: W. W. Norton.
    [125] Lindahl H (2013) Fault Lines of Globalization: Legal Order and the Politics of A-legality, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
    [126] Locke RM (2012) The promise and perils of globalization: the case of Nike. MIT Industrial Performance Center Working Paper Series IPC-02-007, July.
    [127] López Gonzalez J, Munro L, Gourdon J, et al. (2019) Participation and benefits of SMEs in GVCs in Southeast Asia. OECD Trade Policy Paper, No. 231. Paris: OECD.
    [128] Lowe L (2015) The Intimicacies of Four Continents, Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
    [129] MacDonald M, Paul DE (2011) Killing the goose that lays the golden egg: the politics of Milton Friedman's economics. Polit Soc 39: 565–588. doi: 10.1177/0032329211420045
    [130] Macron E (2019) For European renewal. Élysée, 4 March. Available from: https://www.elysee.fr/emmanuel-macron/2019/03/04/for-european-renewal.en (accessed 20 August 2020).
    [131] Mallet V (2020) France pours €8bn into motor industry. Financial Times, 27 May.
    [132] Mankiw NG, Swagel P (2006) The politics and economics of offshore outsourcing. J Monetary Econ 53: 1027–1056. doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2006.05.009
    [133] Martin R (2002) Financialization of Everyday Life, Philadelphia, PA: Temple University Press.
    [134] Maurer SM (2017) The new self-governance: a theoretical framework. Bus Polit 19: 41–67. doi: 10.1017/bap.2016.4
    [135] Mayer F, Gereffi G (2010) Regulation and economic globalization: prospects and limits of private governance. Bus Polit 12: 1–25. doi: 10.2202/1469-3569.1325
    [136] Mazzucato M (2013) The Entrepreneurial State: Debunking Public vs. Private Sector Myths, London: Anthem Press.
    [137] McCarthy K (2020) Pandemic shows US must make vital products at home. Financial Times, 24 August.
    [138] Melnyk SA, Stank TP, Closs DJ (2000) Supply chain management at Michigan State University: the journey and the lessons learned. Prod Inventory Manage J 41: 13–18.
    [139] Mezzadra S, Neilson B (2019) The Politics of Operations: Excavating Contemporary Capitalism, Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
    [140] Milberg W, Winkler D (2013) Outsourcing Economics: Global Value Chains in Capitalist Development, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    [141] Miller J (2020) Volkswagen warns over rising cost of parts as carmaking enters recession. Financial Times, 6 May.
    [142] Milne R (2007) Share options put Porsche on faster path to profit. Financial Times, 13 November.
    [143] Mooney A, Nilsson P (2020) Boohoo debacle breeds doubts on ESG ratings. Financial Times, 27 July.
    [144] National Academy of Medicine (2016) The Neglected Dimension of Global Security: A Framework to Counter Infectious Disease Crises, Washington, DC: The National Academies Press.
    [145] Nye JS (2010) An alliance larger than one issue. New York Times, 6 January.
    [146] Nye JS (2018) Time will tell. Foreign Aff August: 190–192.
    [147] O'Connor J (1973) The Fiscal Crisis of the State, New York: St. Martin's Press.
    [148] O'Connor S (2018) Dark factories: the real price of fast fashion. Financial Times, 19 May.
    [149] O'Connor S (2020) Leicester's dark factories show up a diseased system. Financial Times, 4–5 July.
    [150] Osterholm MT, Olshaker M (2020) Deadliest Enemy: Our War Against Killer Germs, new ed., New York: Little, Brown Spark.
    [151] Palley T (2012) From Financial Crisis to Stagnation: The Destruction of Shared Prosperity and the Role of Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    [152] Panitch L (1998) The State in a Changing World': Social-democratizing global capitalism? Monthly Rev October: 11–22.
    [153] Pattberg P (2005) The institutionalization of private governance: how business and nonprofit organizations agree on transnational rules. Governance 18: 589–610. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0491.2005.00293.x
    [154] Payne S, Manson K (2020) 'Apoplectic' Trump vented fury at UK leader for Huawei decision. Financial Times, 7 February.
    [155] Peck J (2017) Offshore: Exploring the Worlds of Global Outsourcing, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
    [156] Pender J (2001) From 'structural adjustment' to 'comprehensive development framework': conditionality transformed? Third World Q 22: 397–411.
    [157] Peng S, Zhang W, Sun C (2016) 'Environmental load displacement' from the North to the South: a consumption–based perspective with a focus on China. Ecol Econ 128: 147–158. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2016.04.020
    [158] Pincus J, Ramli R (2001) Indonesia: from showcase to basket case. In Chang H-J, Palma G, Whittaker DH, Financial Liberalization and the Asian Crisis, eds., Basingstoke: Palgrave, 124–139.
    [159] Porter ME (1990) The Competitive Advantage of Nations, New York: Free Press.
    [160] Prebisch R (1950) The economic development of Latin America and its principal problems. ECLAC Paper No. E/CN.12/89/Rev.1, New York: United Nations.
    [161] Protts J (2017) Supporting industry post-Brexit: supply chains and the automotive industry, Briefing Note, May. London: Civitas.
    [162] Reuters (2020) U.S., Colombia to bring $5 billion in investment to rural areas. 18 August. Available from: https://www.reuters.com/article/us-colombia-usa-idUSKCN25D2PB (accessed 28 September 2020).
    [163] Samuelson PA (2004) Where Ricardo and Mill rebut and confirm arguments of mainstream economists supporting globalization. J Econ Perspect 18: 135–146.
    [164] Sanderson H (2020) Tesla aims to energise battery supply chain with lithium mining venture. Financial Times, 22 October.
    [165] Sassen S (2007) A Sociology of Globalization, New York: W. W. Norton.
    [166] Scheyvens R, Banks G, Hughes E (2018) The private sector and the SDGs: the need to move beyond 'business as usual'. Sustainability 24: 371–384.
    [167] Schouten G, Glasbergen P (2011) Creating legitimacy in global private governance: the case of the Roundtable on Sustainable Palm Oil. Ecol Econ 70: 1891–1899. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.03.012
    [168] Schäfer D (2008) Porsche makes €6.8bn from VW trades. Financial Times, 8 November.
    [169] Schäfer D (2009) Porsche counts cost of bid fiasco. Financial Times, 26 November.
    [170] Setterfield M (2005) Worker insecurity and U.S. macroeconomic performance during the 1990s. Rev Radical Polit Econ 37: 155–177.
    [171] Sevastopulo D, Williams A (2020) US trade deficit with China undermines Trump strategy. Financial Times, 2 September.
    [172] Shalal A, Garrison C (2020) Exclusive: White House to lure U.S. firms to Latam from Asia in nearshoring drive, senior adviser says. Reuters.com, 30 July. Available from: https://www.reuters.com/article/us-latam-usa-idb-exclusive-idUSKCN24U39E (accessed 23 September 2020).
    [173] Singer HW (1949) Economic progress in under-developed countries. Soc Res 16: 236–266.
    [174] Singer HW (1950) The distribution of gains between investing and borrowing countries. Am Econ Rev 40: 473–485.
    [175] Smith J (2016) Imperialism in the Twenty-First Century: Globalization, Super-Exploitation, and Capitalism's Final Crisis, New York/New Delhi: Monthly Review Press/Dev Publishers.
    [176] Smithers A (2019) Productivity and the Bonus Culture, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
    [177] Smithers A (2020) Investment, productivity, and the bonus culture. Am Aff Summer: 18–31.
    [178] Smyth J (2020) Can the US compete in rare earths? Financial Times, 15 September.
    [179] Stephens P (2020) Cold war is the wrong way to challenge China. Financial Times, 31 July.
    [180] Stern PJ (2011) The Company-State: Corporate Sovereignty and the Early Modern Foundations of the British Empire in India, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
    [181] Stockhammer E (2004) Financialisation and the slowdown of accumulation. Cambridge J Econ 28: 719–741. doi: 10.1093/cje/beh032
    [182] Stockhammer E (2013) Why have wage shares fallen? A panel analysis of the determinants of functional income distribution. Conditions of Work and Employment Series, No. 35. Geneva: International Labour Office.
    [183] Stott M (2020) Costa Rica's debt woes echo across region. Financial Times, 28 October.
    [184] Stratton A (2008) Mandelson calls for 'industrial activism' to revitalise Britain after the recession. The Guardian, 3 December.
    [185] Stringham EP (2015) Private Governance: Creating Order in Economic and Social Life, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
    [186] Suarez-Villa L (2009) Technocapitalism: A Critical Perspective on Technological Innovation and Corporatism, Philadelphia, PA: Temple University Press.
    [187] Summers LH (2020) Accepting the reality of secular stagnation. IMF Financ Dev 57: 17–19.
    [188] Suskind R (2011) Confidence Men: Wall Street, Washington, and the Education of a President, New York: HarperCollins.
    [189] Suwandi I (2019) Value Chains: The New Economic Imperialism, New York: Monthly Review Press.
    [190] Swaney J (1994) So What's Wrong with Dumping on Africa? J Econ Issues 28: 367–377. doi: 10.1080/00213624.1994.11505552
    [191] Ter Wengel J, Rodriguez E (2006) SME export performance in Indonesia after the crisis. Small Bus Econ 26: 25–37. doi: 10.1007/s11187-004-6491-y
    [192] Timothy N (2020) Remaking One Nation: The Future of Conservatism, Cambridge: Polity Press.
    [193] Toia P (2020) EU industrial strategy: more ambition, faster implementation. The Parliament Magazine, 9 April. Available from: https://www.theparliamentmagazine.eu/news/article/eu-industrial-strategy-more-ambition-faster-implementation (accessed 20 August 2020).
    [194] Toye R (2002) 'The gentleman in Whitehall' reconsidered: the evolution of Douglas Jay's views on economic planning and consumer choice, 1937–47. Labour Hist Rev 67: 187–204. doi: 10.3828/lhr.67.2.187
    [195] Tsing A (2012) Ordinary catastrophe: outsourcing risk in supply-chain capitalism, In: Heinlein M, Kropp C, Neumer J, Poferl A, Rö mhild R, Futures of Modernity: Challenges for Cosmopolitical Thought and Practice, eds., Bielefeld: transcript Verlag, 51–64.
    [196] van Apeldoorn B (2002) Transnational Capitalism and the Struggle over European Integration, London, Routledge.
    [197] van der Pijl K (2006) Global Rivalries: From the Cold War to Iraq, London: Pluto Press.
    [198] Verbeke A (2020) Will the COVID-19 pandemic really change the governance of global value chains? Br J Manage 31: 444–446.
    [199] Vernon R (1966) International investment and international trade in the product cycle. Q J Econ 80: 190–207. doi: 10.2307/1880689
    [200] Vernon R (1971) Foreign trade and foreign investment: hard choices for developing countries. Foreign Trade Rev 5: 498–509. doi: 10.1177/0015732515710411
    [201] Vernon R (1993) Sovereignty at bay: twenty years after, In: L. Eden & E.H. Potter, Multinationals in the Global Political Economy, eds., Basingstoke: Macmillan, 19–24.
    [202] Vernon R (1994) Contributing to an international business curriculum: an approach from the flank. J Int Bus Stud 25: 215–227. doi: 10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8490198
    [203] vom Hofe R, Chen K (2006) Whither or not industrial cluster: conclusions or confusions? Ind Geographer 4: 2–28.
    [204] Wade R, Veneroso F (1998) The Asian Crisis: the high debt model versus the Wall Street-Treasury-IMF complex. New Left Rev 228: 3–22.
    [205] Weiss L (2014) America Inc? Innovation and Enterprise in the National Security State, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
    [206] Wolf M (2020) Covid exposes society's dysfunctions. Financial Times, 15 July.
    [207] Wolff EN (2004) What has happened to the Leontief paradox? In: Dietzenbacher E, Lahr ML, Wassily Leontief and Input-Output Economics, eds., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 166–187.
    [208] Wood EM (2005) Empire of Capital, London: Verso.
    [209] Yao Y (2020) China's economic growth in retrospect, In: Dollar D, Huang Y, Yao Y, China 2049: Economic Challenges of a Rising Global Power, eds., Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 3–28.
    [210] Zimmer R (2011) Labour market politics through jurisprudence: the influence of the judgements of the European Court of Justice (Viking, Laval, Rüffert, Luxembourg) on labour market policies. Ger Policy Stud 7: 211–234.
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Erdal Karapinar, Andreea Fulga, Seher Sultan Yeşilkaya, Santosh Kumar, Fixed Points of Proinov Type Multivalued Mappings on Quasimetric Spaces, 2022, 2022, 2314-8888, 1, 10.1155/2022/7197541
    2. Mi Zhou, Xiaolan Liu, Naeem Saleem, Andreea Fulga, Nihal Özgür, A New Study on the Fixed Point Sets of Proinov-Type Contractions via Rational Forms, 2022, 14, 2073-8994, 93, 10.3390/sym14010093
    3. Salvador Romaguera, Basic Contractions of Suzuki-Type on Quasi-Metric Spaces and Fixed Point Results, 2022, 10, 2227-7390, 3931, 10.3390/math10213931
    4. Salvador Romaguera, On Protected Quasi-Metrics, 2024, 13, 2075-1680, 158, 10.3390/axioms13030158
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2021 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(8644) PDF downloads(497) Cited by(3)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog