A composite analysis is used to evaluate the teleconnections between the long term (June- August) rainfall anomalies with east and west phases of quasi-biennial oscillation (QBO) in the stratospheric zonal winds from 1979–2017. Applying the lower equatorial stratospheric zonal wind index in JJA rainfall prediction is based on its tendency to persist for several months after the phase change from easterly to westerly and vice versa. Below normal condition rainfall used to coin drought. This study is important because, the Upper Blue Nile region is one of the most inviting areas for different activities like agriculture and hydroelectric power; therefore, timely prediction of June-August rainfall serves farmers and other concerned sectors. The aim of this analysis is to establish the global signal quasi-biennial oscillation contribution alone at different time lags and its association among Southern Oscillation Index (SOI) for estimation June-August rainfall of the Upper Blue Nile. The rainfall used as predictand while quasi-biennial oscillation & SOI datasets are used as predictors in regression model after testing collinearity of these two independent variables. Performance of regression model and actual value is tested by using statistical techniques: Root Mean Square Error, Mean Absolute Error and bias. The performance is seen reasonably high between actual and estimated values show strong agreement.
Citation: Abebe Kebede Habtegebreal, Abebaw Bizuneh Alemu, U. Jaya Prakash Raju. Examining the Role of Quasi-biennial Oscillation on Rainfall patterns over Upper Blue Nile Basin of Ethiopia[J]. AIMS Environmental Science, 2021, 8(3): 190-203. doi: 10.3934/environsci.2021013
[1] | Zhiqiang Hang, Xiaolin Wang, Fangfei Li, Yi-ang Ren, Haitao Li . Learning-based DoS attack game strategy over multi-process systems. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2024, 4(4): 424-438. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2024034 |
[2] | Hassan Alsuhabi . The new Topp-Leone exponentied exponential model for modeling financial data. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2024, 4(1): 44-63. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2024005 |
[3] | Anita T. Kurniawati, Fatmawati, Chidozie W. Chukwu, Windarto, Faishal F. Herdicho . Optimal control of dengue fever model with a logistically growing human population. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2025, 5(1): 48-60. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2025004 |
[4] | Xue Zhang, Bo Sang, Bingxue Li, Jie Liu, Lihua Fan, Ning Wang . Hidden chaotic mechanisms for a family of chameleon systems. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2023, 3(4): 400-415. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2023032 |
[5] | Salma Al-Tuwairqi, Asma Badrah . A qualitative analysis of a model on alpha-synuclein transport and aggregation in neurons. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2023, 3(2): 104-115. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2023010 |
[6] | Yaxin Ren, Yakui Xue . Modeling and optimal control of COVID-19 and malaria co-infection based on vaccination. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2024, 4(3): 316-335. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2024026 |
[7] | Benjamin Zhang . Limiting behaviors of a bi-virus model with two interaction factors. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2024, 4(1): 64-70. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2024006 |
[8] | Xiaoyu Ren, Ting Hou . Pareto optimal filter design with hybrid H2/H∞ optimization. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2023, 3(2): 80-87. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2023008 |
[9] | Xianhao Zheng, Jun Wang, Kaibo Shi, Yiqian Tang, Jinde Cao . Novel stability criterion for DNNs via improved asymmetric LKF. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2024, 4(3): 307-315. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2024025 |
[10] | Weisong Zhou, Kaihe Wang, Wei Zhu . Synchronization for discrete coupled fuzzy neural networks with uncertain information via observer-based impulsive control. Mathematical Modelling and Control, 2024, 4(1): 17-31. doi: 10.3934/mmc.2024003 |
A composite analysis is used to evaluate the teleconnections between the long term (June- August) rainfall anomalies with east and west phases of quasi-biennial oscillation (QBO) in the stratospheric zonal winds from 1979–2017. Applying the lower equatorial stratospheric zonal wind index in JJA rainfall prediction is based on its tendency to persist for several months after the phase change from easterly to westerly and vice versa. Below normal condition rainfall used to coin drought. This study is important because, the Upper Blue Nile region is one of the most inviting areas for different activities like agriculture and hydroelectric power; therefore, timely prediction of June-August rainfall serves farmers and other concerned sectors. The aim of this analysis is to establish the global signal quasi-biennial oscillation contribution alone at different time lags and its association among Southern Oscillation Index (SOI) for estimation June-August rainfall of the Upper Blue Nile. The rainfall used as predictand while quasi-biennial oscillation & SOI datasets are used as predictors in regression model after testing collinearity of these two independent variables. Performance of regression model and actual value is tested by using statistical techniques: Root Mean Square Error, Mean Absolute Error and bias. The performance is seen reasonably high between actual and estimated values show strong agreement.
Reinsurance is an effective risk management tool in which the insurer transfers part of the underwriting risk to the reinsurer to reduce the underwriting risk. It is characterized by an indemnity function f and a premium π, where f means the amount paid by the reinsurer when the insurer suffers losses and π is the reinsurance premium.
Optimal insurance policies have been investigated extensively in the literature. The optimal criteria commonly used are risk minimization, expected utility maximization, or some combination of them. The classic result of the common expected utility maximization criterion can be found in Borch [1], Arrow [2] and Raviv [3]. The results of minimizing insurer risk were measured by variance, Value-at-Risk(VaR) and general distortion risk measures can be found in Cai et al. [4], Assa [5], Zhuang et al. [6], Lo [7] and the references therein.
In almost all of the articles mentioned above, one implicit assumption is that the information between the insurer and the reinsurer is symmetrical. Such, the reinsurer knows clearly the risk that insurer may face, and can be targeted to design the policy to maximize their own interests. But in practice, the reinsurer gets only partial information from the insurer. The reinsurer cannot identify the risk distribution and the risk preference of the insurer. In the case of information asymmetry, the situation where the reinsurer dominates the policy is no longer valid, the insurer may benefit strictly from the transaction by imitating the information of others.
Most of the literature on information asymmetry in insurance market mainly focuses on adverse selection. Groundbreaking works such as Rothschild and Stiglitz [8] and Stiglitz [9] laid the foundation for information asymmetry modeling. They proposed a principal-agent model with only two types of insureds and a monopolistic insurer where the risks or utility functions of the two types of insurers were different. This model was extended along many ways in the past few decades. We refer the interested readers to, for example, Young and Browne [10], Ryan and Vaithianathan [11], Jeleva and Villeneuve [12], Chade and Schlee [13]. In recent years, Cheung et al. [14] considered the adverse selection reinsurance design problem when the insurers adopted the VaR measures to quantify their risks. Cheung et al. [15] extended this model further to some concave distortion risk measure. Another closely related study is Boonen and Zhang [18] which considered an information asymmetry reinsurance model without assuming the parametric form of the indemnity function. In this article, we continue using the classical model to study the optimal stop-loss reinsurance policies under asymmetric information. We assume that the insurers adopt VaR measures but the reinsurer can't know ahead of time which risk distribution and risk preference the insurer will be using. The optimization problem is solved under the individual rationality and incentive compatibility constraints.
The rest of this article is organized as follows. Section 2 states some pertinent definitions and notions. Section 3 and 4 study the optimal solutions for two policy design strategies of separating equilibrium and pooling equilibrium, respectively. Some numerical examples are given in Section 5 to further illustrate our results. Section 6 concludes the paper and puts forward the research direction in the future.
Throughout the paper, all random variables are defined on a probability space (Ω,F,P). Let X denote the non-negative total potential loss for which the insurer seeks reinsurance coverage. Assume that the variable X is supposed to realizations on [0,∞) and which has cumulative distribution function FX and survival function SX.
For simplicity, we consider that there are only two types of insurers and one monopolistic reinsurer in the market.The insurer often decides to reduce the risk exposure through purchasing a reinsurance contract (f,π) where f is known as the indemnity function and π is the non-negative premium. To partially exclude the moral hazard, we consider the following admissible set of ceded loss functions F={f:[0,∞)→[0,∞)∣f(0)=0,0≤f(x)−f(y)≤x−y,0≤y≤x}. This setting is common in relevant literature, seen for instance Huberman et al. [16], Denuit and Vermandele [17], Boonen et al. [18]. Any ceded loss function f in F satisfies the incentive-compatible condition, which guarantees the non-negative of the ceded risk and less than the loss itself. Furthermore, growth rate in ceded loss function is lower than the incurred loss which further reduces moral hazard.
Based on the points discussed above, we set the reinsurer provides a stop-loss policy for two types of insurers. The insurers are confronted with different risks, denoted by X1 and X2, respectively. And then we can define the ceded loss function by fi=(Xi−di)+, for i=1,2.
In today's financial world, VaR has become the most widely used risk measure. Its importance is uncontroversial since regulators accept this model as the basis for setting capital requirements for market risk exposure. Accordingly, we assume that both of the insurers adopt VaR measure to evaluate their risk position. Given a risk X and a confidence level α∈(0,1), the corresponding VaR at level 1−α, denoted by VaRα(X), is defined as
VaRα(X)=inf{x≥0:P(X>x)≤α}=S−1X(α). |
The popularity of VaR ascribes to its nice properties, some of them are useful to us are illustrated below.
1. Translation invariance: for a random variable X and a constant c, VaRα(X+c)=VaRα(X)+c.
2. Comonotonic additivity: for any two comonotonic random variables X and Y, VaRα(X+Y)=VaRα(X)+VaRα(Y).
3. Monotonicity: for two random variables X and Y if P(X≤Y)=1 holds, VaRα(X)≤VaRα(Y).
4. For any increasing left-continuous function f and a random variable X, VaRα(f(X))=f(VaRα(X)).
In the next section, we present the setup for the optimal reinsurance problem under the asymmetric information.
In this section, we give the optimal stop-loss policies offered by a reinsurer when the insurers adopt VaR measures for the risk assessment. We assume that two types of insurers have different confidence level, which are denoted by α and β, respectively.
On the condition of information asymmetry, the type of each insurer is hidden information to the reinsurer. In other words, the reinsurer can't know ahead of time which risk distribution and risk preference the insurer will be using. But the reinsurer still knows that the proportions of the first and the second types of insurers in the market are p and 1−p respectively. More precisely, the reinsurer knows that the probability of the insurer adopting VaRα measure is p, while the probability of adopting VaRβ measure is 1−p.
In this paper, the reinsurer is assumed to be monopoly and risk-neutral. In order to maximize its expected profit, the reinsurer offers a reinsurance menu to the insurers which is given by {(f1,π1);(f2,π2)} and consists of two stop-loss policies. In this menu, fi is the indemnity function for the i-th type of the insurer and πi is the corresponding premium charged from the i-th type of the insurer, i=1 or 2. We can design this menu which makes insurers can freely choose the one that minimizes their risk exposures. Such a design makes the reinsurer knows the identity of the insurers when the policy is chosen by the insurers. Then the expected profit of the reinsurer is formulated as follows
p(π1−(1+θ)E[f1(X1)])+(1−p)(π2−(1+θ)E[f2(X2)]), | (2.1) |
where θ≥0 denotes the risk safety loading.
In order to better address the problem of maximizing the expected profit of the reinsurer, we follow the standard arguments in Principal–Agent models to impose further restraint on a feasible policy {(f1,π1);(f2,π2)} by using individual rationality (IR) constraints and incentive compatibility (IC). More specifically, the constraint (IR) ensures that the insurers who are no worse off for buying the designated reinsurance contract. The constraint (IC) ensure that the insurance contract are tailor-made for specific insureds. Under this restriction, the insurers will follow the suggestion of the reinsurer such that the insurer of type 1 may just choose the policy (f1,π1) rather than choose the policy (f2,π2) which is designed for the type 2 insurer, and vice versa. On the basis of the above-mentioned analysis, the reinsurer's wealth optimization problem is formalized as follows.
Problem 2.1.
max{(f1,π1);(f2,π2)} p(π1−(1+θ)E[f1(X1)])+(1−p)(π2−(1+θ)E[f2(X2)]), | (2.2) |
subject to the following constraints:
IR1: VaRα(X1−f1(X1)+π1)≤VaRα(X1), | (2.3a) |
IR2: VaRβ(X2−f2(X2)+π2)≤VaRβ(X2), | (2.3b) |
IC1: VaRα(X1−f1(X1)+π1)≤VaRα(X1−f2(X1)+π2), | (2.3c) |
IC2: VaRβ(X2−f2(X2)+π2)≤VaRβ(X2−f1(X2)+π1). | (2.3d) |
For the further improvement, we have the following assumptions. When IC1 holds with an equality, the insurer of type 1 would select the policy (f1,π1); when IC2 holds with an equality, the insurer of type 2 would select the policy (f2,π2). This is a standard assumption in asymmetric information models, for example, Landsberger and Meilijson [19] and Laffont and Martimort [20].
We can easily see that the reinsurer provides different contracts for the different insurers in Problem 2.1, this strategy is known as separating equilibrium. In the next section, we propose a strategy to solve Problem 2.1.
In this section, we study Problem 2.1 that yields the optimal reinsurance contracts. Firstly, we try to further simplify this model by some reasonable assumptions.
Assumption 1. (i). (1+θ)E(X)≤VaRκ(X),κ∈{α,β}. (ii). VaRα(X1)≤VaRβ(X2).
The first hypothesis ensured the cost of reinsurance is lower than the risk measure of the loss for the insurer so that purchases reinsurance for the loss is effective. What needs to be emphasized is that the asymmetric information model we studied is a common case where the two types of insurers have different risk preferences and they are not divided into high or low risk types. Because there must be an order between VaRα(X1) and VaRβ(X2), we assume VaRα(X1)≤VaRβ(X2) without losing generality. The second hypothesis means that the type 2 insurer regard their losses riskier than do the type 1 insurer.
By observing the Problem 2.1, we find that the four constraints (2.3a)∼(2.3d) can be simplified further by using the comonotonic additivity and translational invariance of the VaR measure. Then, Problem 2.1 reduces to the following problem.
Problem 3.1. Maximizing the objective function in (2.2) subject to the following constraints:
IR1: π1≤VaRα(f1(X1)), | (3.1a) |
IR2: π2≤VaRβ(f2(X2)), | (3.1b) |
IC1: π1−VaRα(f1(X1))≤π2−VaRα(f2(X1)), | (3.1c) |
IC2: π2−VaRβ(f2(X2))≤π1−VaRβ(f1(X2)). | (3.1d) |
Remark 3.1. We assume here that the premiums as constants because that will make it easier to simplify the IC and IR constraints. If we treat premiums as functions of the deductibles governed by some premium principle, rather than as independent decision variables. Then the decision variables of the objective function are changed from four to two, i.e d1 and d2. Then this optimization problem may become infeasible because it has four constraints.
We can show by inspecting Problem 3.1 that the objective function is increasing with respect to π1 and π2. Obviously to maximize the expected profit, both π1 and π2 need to be taken the maximum within the limit of reasonable values.
Through IR1 and IC1, possible values of π1 are described below
π1≤min{VaRα(f1(X1)),π2−VaRα(f2(X1))+VaRα(f1(X1))}. |
Through IR2 and IC2, possible values of π2 are described below
π2≤min{VaRβ(f2(X2)),π1−VaRβ(f1(X2))+VaRβ(f2(X2))}. |
Therefore, in order to maximize the objective function, π1 must reach either VaRα(f1(X1)) or π2−VaRα(f2(X1))+VaRα(f1(X1)) and π2 must reach either VaRβ(f2(X2)) or π1−VaRβ(f1(X2))+VaRβ(f2(X2)). We can consider four possible scenarios.
Case 1: IR1 combines with IR2.
π1=VaRα(f1(X1)), π2=VaRβ(f2(X2)). |
Case 2: IR1 combines with IC2.
π1=VaRα(f1(X1)),π2=π1−VaRβ(f1(X2))+VaRβ(f2(X2)). |
Case 3: IC1 combines with IR2.
π1=π2−VaRα(f2(X1))+VaRα(f1(X1)),π2=VaRβ(f2(X2)). |
Case 4: IC1 combines with IC2.
π1=π2−VaRα(f2(X1))+VaRα(f1(X1)),π2=π1−VaRβ(f1(X2))+VaRβ(f2(X2)). |
The upper bounds of π1 and π2 are not given in Case 4, their values are interacted on each other. Actually, the reinsurer could still increase π1 and π2 in the pursuit of greater profits until one of them reaches up to the maximum premium which is accepted by the relevant insurer. In other words, the premium will be increasing until reaches the upper bound of the IR constraint. Based on the above analysis, Case 4 could be considered as a special case of Case 1∼3. Now, we can break down Problem 3.1 into the following three sub-problems.
Problem A. (Case 1)
max{f1,f2} p(VaRα(f1(X1))−(1+θ)E[f1(X1)])+(1−p)(VaRβ(f2(X2))−(1+θ)E[f2(X2)]), |
subject to the following constraints:
IC1: VaRα(f2(X1))≤VaRβ(f2(X2)),IC2: VaRβ(f1(X2))≤VaRα(f1(X1)). |
Problem B. (Case 2)
max{f1,f2} p(VaRα(f1(X1))−(1+θ)E[f1(X1)])+(1−p)(VaRα(f1(X1))+VaRβ(f2(X2))−VaRβ(f1(X2))−(1+θ)E[f2(X2)]), |
subject to the following constraints:
IR2: VaRα(f1(X1))≤VaRβ(f1(X2)),IC1: VaRα(f2(X1))−VaRβ(f2(X2))≤VaRα(f1(X1))−VaRβ(f1(X2)). |
Problem C. (Case 3)
max{f1,f2} p(VaRα(f1(X1))+VaRβ(f2(X2))−VaRα(f2(X1))−(1+θ)E[f1(X1)])+(1−p)(VaRβ(f2(X2))−(1+θ)E[f2(X2)]), |
subject to the following constraints:
IR1: VaRβ(f2(X2))≤VaRα(f2(X1)),IC2: VaRα(f2(X1))−VaRβ(f2(X2))≤VaRα(f1(X1))−VaRβ(f1(X2)). |
Then we will analyze the above three sub-problems, obviously the solution to the maximum of the three objective functions is also the solution to Problem 3.1. The next theorem gives the optimal premium scheme for Problem 3.1.
Theorem 3.1. Under Assumption 1, any optimal solution of Problem 3.1 should satisfy
(i). π1=VaRα(f1(X1)),
(ii). π2=π1−VaRβ(f1(X2))+VaRβ(f2(X2)).
Proof. First, we should simplify these three sub-problems. Because f(x)=(x−d)+ is a monotonous increasing function, based on Assumption 1(ⅱ) and property 4 of the VaR we can get
VaRα(fi(X1))≤VaRβ(fi(X2)), i=1 or 2. |
From the analysis above, constraints in Problem A are equivalent to
VaRβ(f1(X2))=VaRα(f1(X1)), |
constraints in Problem B are equivalent to
VaRα(f2(X1))−VaRβ(f2(X2))≤VaRα(f1(X1))−VaRβ(f1(X2))≤0 , |
constraints in Problem C are equivalent to
{VaRα(f2(X1))=VaRβ(f2(X2)),VaRα(f1(X1))=VaRβ(f1(X2)). |
Then Problem A∼C could be rewritten as follows.
Problem A′.
max{f1,f2} p(VaRα(f1(X1))−(1+θ)E[f1(X1)])+(1−p)(VaRβ(f2(X2))−(1+θ)E[f2(X2)]), |
s.t.VaRβ(f1(X2))=VaRα(f1(X1)). | (3.2) |
Problem B′.
max{f1,f2} VaRα(f1(X1))−[p(1+θ)E[f1(X1)]+(1−p)VaRβ(f1(X2))]+(1−p)(VaRβ(f2(X2))−(1+θ)E[f2(X2)]), |
s.t.VaRα(f2(X1))−VaRβ(f2(X2))≤ VaRα(f1(X1))−VaRβ(f1(X2))≤0. | (3.3) |
Problem C′.
max{f1,f2} p(VaRα(f1(X1))−(1+θ)E[f1(X1)])+(1−p)(VaRβ(f2(X2))−(1+θ)E[f2(X2)]), |
s.t.VaRα(f2(X1))=VaRβ(f2(X2)),VaRα(f1(X1))=VaRβ(f1(X2)). | (3.4) |
Next, we will compare the optimal values of the objective functions in Problems A′∼C′, and show that the solution corresponding to the Problem B′ is also the solution to Problem 3.1.
Now use VA, VB and VC to denote the optimal values of the objective functions in Problem A′, B′ and C′, respectively. By comparing the Problem A′ with Problem C′, we notice that these two problems have the same objective function. Nonetheless, the constraints of (3.2) are looser than the constraints of (3.4). So the solution of Problem C′ is by no means better than the solution of Problem A′. That is, VC≤VA.
Under Assumption 1(ⅱ), when VaRα(f1(X1))−VaRβ(f1(X2))=0, we have VaRα(f2(X1))−VaRβ(f2(X2))≤VaRα(f1(X1))−VaRβ(f1(X2))≤0 but not vice-versa. So the constraints of (3.3) are looser than the constraints of (3.2).
Note that we can get VaRα(f1(X1))−VaRβ(f1(X2))=0 when tighten the constraint of (3.3), then the objective function of Problem B′ could be rewritten as
p(VaRα(f1(X1))−(1+θ)E[f1(X1)])+(1−p)(VaRβ(f2(X2))−(1+θ)E[f2(X2)]), |
that is precisely the objective function of Problem A′. Therefore, Problem A′ could be considered as a special case of Problem B′. That is, VA≤VB.
To sum up, VC≤VA≤VB.
Remark 3.2. According to Theorem 3.1 and Assumption 1(i), we have π1=VaRα(f1(X1))≥E[f1(X1)]. It shows that the premium π1 satisfies the non-negative safety loading principle. However, it is possible that
π2=VaRα(f1(X1))−VaRβ(f1(X2))+VaRβ(f2(X2))≤E[f2(X2)]. |
It suggests that the premium π2 may violate the principle of the non-negative safety loading. We notice that under the complete information conditions, the optimal premium designed for the type 2 insurer is π′2=VaRβ(f2(X2)). Compare π2 and π′2, we have π′2−π2=VaRβ(f1(X2))−VaRα(f1(X1))≥0. It shows that the reinsurer pays higher costs to attract the type 2 insurer under asymmetric information, which can be explained as the cost of information.
Based on the Theorem 3.1, we have a new problem formulation of the original Problem 3.1.
Problem 3.2.
max{f1,f2} [VaRα(f1(X1))−p(1+θ)E[f1(X1)]−(1−p)VaRβ(f1(X2))]+(1−p)(VaRβ(f2(X2))−(1+θ)E[f2(X2)]) ,s.t.VaRβ(f2(X2))−VaRα(f2(X1))≥VaRβ(f1(X2))−VaRα(f1(X1)). |
For the sake of simplicity, we denote S−1Xi(α) by ai and denote S−1Xi(β) by bi. So the Assumption 1(ⅱ) is redescribed as a1≤b2, and VaRα(fj(Xi))=fj(ai)=(ai−dj)+, VaRβ(fj(Xi))=fj(bi)=(bi−dj)+, i, j∈{1,2}. Then the Problem 3.2 can be rewritten as
Problem 3.3.
max{d1,d2}[(a1−d1)+−p(1+θ)E[(X1−d1)+]−(1−p)(b2−d1)+]+(1−p)((b2−d2)+−(1+θ)E[(X2−d2)+]),s.t.(b2−d2)+−(a1−d2)+≥(b2−d1)+−(a1−d1)+. |
There di∈[0,∞], i∈{1, 2}, when di=+∞, then fi=0 that is null policy, . In fact, the range of di can be reduced. We find that the reinsurer will provide a null policy to the corresponding insurer when di exceeds a certain size.
Theorem 3.2. Given that (d∗1,π∗1;d∗2,π∗2) is the optimal reinsurance menu. If d1∈(a1,∞], then (∞,0;d∗2,π∗2) is optimal; similarly, if d2∈(b2,∞], then (d∗1,π∗1;∞,0) is optimal.
Proof. Given that (d∗1,π∗1;d∗2,π∗2) is optimal, then it satisfies all the constraints in original Problem 3.1. When d1>a1 such that d∗1>a1, by the IR1 constraint, we have
π∗1≤(a1−d∗1)+=0⇒π∗1=0. |
Then, 0=π∗1≤(a1−d∗1)+=0=(a1−∞)+, so (∞,0;d∗2,π∗2) satisfies the IR1 and IR2 constraints.
It is easy to find that
0−(a1−∞)+=0=π∗1−(a1−d∗1)+≤π∗2−(a1−d∗2)+, |
and
π∗2−(b2−d∗2)+≤π∗1−(b2−d∗1)+=−(b2−d∗1)+≤−(b2−∞)+. |
So (∞,0;d∗2,π∗2) satisfies the IC1 and IC2 constraints. Evidenced by the same token, (d∗1,π∗1;∞,0) satisfies all the constraints when d2∈(b2,∞]. We can prove that the objective function of Problem 3.3 is an increasing function of di over a given range, then the value can only get better if we replace d∗i by ∞, where i=1 or 2.
Now, we rule out the null policy and only deal with the region where d1∈[0,a1] and d2∈[0,b2].
With this condition, we have
(b2−d2)+−(a1−d2)+≥(b2−d1)+−(a1−d1)+⇔(b2−d2)−(a1−d2)+≥b2−a1. |
Moreover, with (b2−d2)−(a1−d2)+≥b2−a1, we have either (i) d2≥a1 then b2−d2≥b2−a1⇒d2≤a1; or (ii) d2≤a1 then (b2−d2)−(a1−d2)+≥b2−a1 always holds. With d2≤a1, we have (b2−d2)−(a1−d2)+=(b2−d2)−(a1−d2)≥b2−a1.
Hence, (b2−d2)−(a1−d2)+≥b2−a1 is equivalent to d2≤a1, and problem 4 can be simplified as follows.
Problem 3.4.
max{d1,d2}p(a1−d1−(1+θ)E[(X1−d1)+])−(1−p)(b2−a1)+(1−p)(b2−d2−(1+θ)E[(X2−d2)+]),s.t.0≤di≤a1,i=1or2 |
Let us define θ∗1 is the solution of the equation (1+θ)SX1(θ∗1)=1 and θ∗2 is the solution of the equation (1+θ)SX2(θ∗2)=1.We are now able to present the complete solution to Problem 3.4 in the next theorem.
Theorem 3.3. Let (d∗1,π∗1;d∗2,π∗2) be optimal for Problem 3.4. Then, the optimal solution to Problem 3.4 is summarized as follows.
(i). If θ∗2≤a1, then (d∗1,π∗1;d∗2,π∗2)=(θ∗1,a1−θ∗1;θ∗2,a1−θ∗2).
(ii). If θ∗2>a1, then (d∗1,π∗1;d∗2,π∗2)=(θ∗1,a1−θ∗1;a1,0).
Proof. Let t1(d1)=a1−d1−(1+θ)E[(X1−d1)+], we have t′1(d1)=−1+(1+θ)SX1(d1). Obviously t1(d1) is a concave function on [0,a1], and there must exist a unique θ∗1∈[0,a1] such that (1+θ)SX1(θ∗1)=1. It can be seen that t′1(d1)>0 for d1∈[0,θ∗1) and t′1(d1)<0 for d1∈(θ∗1,a1]. Therefore, t1(d1) attains its maximum at d∗1=θ∗1.
Let t2(d2)=b2−d2−(1+θ)E[(X2−d2)+], the same argument can be applied to this case. There must exist a unique θ∗2∈[0,b2] such that (1+θ)SX2(θ∗2)=1, then t2(d2) attains its maximum at d∗2=θ∗2.
Note that solving Problem 3.4 is equivalent to solving the following two sub-problems
{maxt1(d1), s.t. 0≤d1≤a1,{maxt2(d2), s.t. 0≤d2≤a1. |
For the first sub-problem, clearly there d∗1=θ∗1 such that t1(d∗1)≥t1(d1) for all d1∈[0,θ∗1].
For the second sub-problem, we consider the following two cases
Case 1: If θ∗2≤a1, then t2(d2) is increasing for d2∈[0,θ∗2) and is decreasing for d2∈(θ∗2,a1]. Therefore, t2(d2) attains its maximum at d∗2=θ∗2 for all d2∈[0,a1].
Case 2: If θ∗2>a1, then t2(d2) is increasing for d2∈[0,a1]. Therefore, t2(d2) attains its maximum at d∗2=a1 for all d2∈[0,a1].
Now, we summarize the results as follows.
(ⅰ). When θ∗2≤a1, then d∗1=θ∗1, d∗2=θ∗2, π∗1=a1−d∗1=a1−θ∗1, π∗2=(a1−d∗1)+(b2−d∗2)−(b2−d∗1)=a1−θ∗2.
(ⅱ). When θ∗2>a1, then d∗1=θ∗1, d∗2=a1, π∗1=a1−d∗1=a1−θ∗1, π∗2=a1−d∗2=0.
Hence, we obtain the desired results.
Now we give the expected net profit of the reinsurer in the optimal reinsurance menu. For convenience, we relabel it as TS and the definition of expected net profit can be seen in (2.1). Based on Theorem 3.2, if θ∗2≤a1 we have
TS=p(a1−θ∗1−(1+θ)E[(X1−θ∗1)+])+(1−p)(a1−θ∗2−(1+θ)E[(X2−θ∗2)+]). | (3.5) |
and if θ∗2>a1 we have
TS=p(a1−θ∗1−(1+θ)E[(X1−θ∗1)+])−(1−p)(1+θ)E[(X2−θ∗2)+]. | (3.6) |
Next, we discuss the welfare gain for two types of insurers from the optimal reinsurance menu and relabel it as W. For the type 1 insurer, we have
W1=VaRα(X1)−VaRα(X1−f1(X1)+π∗1)=VaRα(X1)−VaRα(X1)+(a1−d∗1)+−π∗1=(a1−θ∗1)−(a1−θ∗1)=0. |
For the type 2 insurer, if θ∗2≤a1,
W2=VaRβ(X2)−VaRβ(X2−f2(X2)+π∗2)=VaRβ(X2)−VaRβ(X2)+(b2−d∗2)+−π∗2=(b2−θ∗2)+−(a1−θ∗2)≥0. |
and if θ∗2>a1,
W2=(b2−d∗2)+−π∗2=(b2−a1)+−0≥0. |
We found that the type 2 insurer may strictly benefit from reinsurance transactions. Conversely, the type 1 insurer seems insouciant about buying reinsurance or not buying reinsurance. This finding implies asymmetric information benefits the type 2 insurer. Maybe they can mimic to be of type 1 and appears to indifferent about insurance transactions to gain a larger benefit.
In this section, the reinsurer can design only one policy that maximize his expected profit. More specifically, the reinsurer always offers the same contract (π,f) regardless of the identity of the insurer. This strategy we defined as pooling equilibrium.
We again assume that Assumption 1 holds and continue with the symbolic settings from section 3. According to the different markets' demands, we summarize three possible scenarios which are formalized as follows.
Problem 4.1. (Close the type 2 insurer market)
max(d,π)∈[0,+∞]×[0,+∞) P(π−(1+θ)E[(X1−d)+]), | (4.1) |
s.t.(b2−d)+<π≤(a1−d)+. | (4.2) |
Problem 4.2. (Close the type 1 insurer market)
max(d,π)∈[0,+∞]×[0,+∞) (1−p)(π−(1+θ)E[(X2−d)+]), | (4.3) |
s.t.(a1−d)+<π≤(b2−d)+. | (4.4) |
Problem 4.3. (Open all markets)
max(d,π)∈[0,+∞]×[0,+∞) p(π−(1+θ)E[(X1−d)+])+(1−p)(π−(1+θ)E[(X2−d)+]), | (4.5) |
s.t.π≤min{(a1−d)+,(b2−d)+}. | (4.6) |
It is pretty easy to find that IC constraints are invalid by designing only one contract. The disappearance of IC constraints makes the design of insurance policies more flexible. If the proportion of one type of insurer in the market is too high, the reinsurer will often close the business of another type of insurer in pursuit of greater profits, which can be achieved by limiting the range of premiums.
Under the Assumption 1(ⅱ), i.e.a1≤b2, we can conclude that the constraint (4.2) in Problem 4.1 cannot hold. This result agrees with the facts of the situation. The largest premium that the type 2 insurer can accept is higher than that of the type 1 insurer because they believe they are facing higher risk.
Similar to separating equilibrium, in Problem 4.2 and Problem 4.3, we only deal with nontrivial solution for d∈[0,b2], d∈[0,a1] respectively. So (4.4) is equivalent to π=b2−d and (4.6) is equivalent to π=a1−d. After all, the reinsurer always pursue high premiums.
Before giving the solution of Problem 4.2 and Problem 4.3, we define θ∗3 is the solution of the equation
(1+θ)SX1(d)+(1−v)(1+θ)SX2(d)−1=0. |
Theorem 4.1. Let (d∗,π∗) is optimal, then (θ∗2,b2−θ∗2) is optimal for Problem 4.2 and (θ∗3,a1−θ∗3) is optimal for Problem 4.3.
Proof. In Problem 4.2, if π=b2−d, let t2(d)=b2−d2−(1+θ)E[(X2−d2)+], and from the proof of Theorem 3.2 we know that t2(d∗) attains its maximum at d∗=θ∗2. Then π∗=b2−d∗=b2−θ∗2.
In Problem 4.3, if π=a1−d, the objective function (4.5) can be reduced to t3(d)=(a1−d)−p(1+θ)E(X1−d)+−(1−p)(1+θ)E(X2−d)+. and its derivative is t′3(d)=−1+p(1+θ)SX1(d)+(1−p)(1+θ)SX2(d). Obviously t3(d) is a concave function on [0,a1] and there must exist a unique θ∗3∈[0,a1] such that t′3(d)>0 for d1∈[0,θ∗3) and t′3(d)<0 for d1∈(θ∗3,a1]. Therefore, t3(d) attains its maximum at d∗=θ∗3. Then π∗=a1−d∗=a1−θ∗3.
Now we give the expected net profit of the reinsurer in the optimal reinsurance policy and relabel it as TP. In Problem 4.2, we have
TP1=(1−p)(b2−θ∗2−(1+θ)E[(X2−θ∗2)+]). | (4.7) |
and in Problem 4.3, we have
TP2=p(a1−θ∗3−(1+θ)E[(X1−θ∗3)+])+(1−p)(a1−θ∗3−(1+θ)E[(X2−θ∗3)+]). | (4.8) |
Moreover, under the Problem 7, the welfare gains of the type 2 is given by W2=(b2−θ∗2)−(b2−θ∗2)=0. Under the Problem 4.3, the welfare gains of the type 1 and type 2 insurer are given by W1=(a1−θ∗3)−(a1−θ∗3)=0 and W2=(b2−θ∗3)−(a1−θ∗3)≥0, respectively. We get a similar result to the section 3.
This section presents some examples to analyze the conclusions of sections 3 and 4. We shall discuss and compare the optimal expected profit when the reinsurer adopts separating equilibrium or pooling equilibrium strategy.
Example 5.1. Both types of insurers apply VaR risk measures. Suppose that α=0.01, β=0.05, and θ=0.3. The random losses X1 and X2 follow the Pareto distribution where
SX1(x)=(20x)5 and SX2(x)=(20x)3. |
(i). Given p=0.5. Then a1=50.2377, b2=54.2883, θ∗1=21.0775, θ∗2=21.8279, θ∗3=21.3675. Here θ∗2≤a1. Through the Eqs (3.5), (4.7) and (4.8), we have TS=20.6934, Tp1=10.7733, Tp2=10.7733.
(ii). If set p=0.1, we have TS=18.1354, Tp1=19.3919, Tp2=18.1301.
We can observe that if the two risks X1 and X2 are not significantly different (i.e. θ∗2≤a1) and the difference of the market share of two types of insurers are not obvious, we have Ts>TP2>TP1. At this point, the reinsurer's profit under separating equilibrium is maximum and it is unwise to design policy only for the second type of insurer.
If we increase the weight of the type 2 insurer, we have TP1>Ts>TP2. In this extreme case the type 2 insurer market is crucial, it is optimal for reinsurer to abandon the type 1 insurer and only provides policy to the type 2 insurer. We need to stress that the pooling equilibrium strategy is never better than the separating equilibrium strategy under the premise of considering both insurer markets.
Example 5.2. Suppose that α=0.01, β=0.05, and θ=0.3, X1 and X2 follow the Pareto distribution where
SX1(x)=(20x)5andSX2(x)=(50x)3. |
(i). Given p=0.6. Then a1=50.2377, b2=135.72, θ∗1=21.0775, θ∗2=54.5696, θ∗3=40.5183. Here a1<θ∗2. Through the Eqs (3.6), (4.7) and (4.8), we have TS=1.4572, Tp1=21.5466, Tp2=−10.3082.
(ii). If set p=0.8, we have TS=12.6741, Tp1=10.7733, Tp2=1.6148.
In Example 5.2, the risk of type 2 is significantly higher than that of type 1 such that a1<θ∗2. Therefore, the two types of insurers are divided into high-risk and low-risk types. When the proportion of low-risk type has no obvious advantage, it is unreasonable to design the same policy for two types of insurers because the benefits of lowering premiums to attract high-risk insurers are not enough to offset the risks. In the market of asymmetric information, it is optimal to directly reduce the coverage ratio for the low-risk insurers or even to open the market only to high-risk insurers in order to prevent high-risk insurer from imitating low-risk insurer. However, separating equilibrium strategy is optimal when low-risk insurer dominate the market.
In this article, we study the optimal reinsurance problem between the monopoly reinsurer and two types of insurers who adopt the VaR as the risk assessment tools under asymmetric information. We consider and analyze two strategies, separating equilibrium and pooling equilibrium. In general, separating equilibrium strategy is optimal in an unrestricted market. But when insurers can be divided into high-risk and low-risk, reinsurer tends to design policies only for high-risk insurer if low-risk insurer does not dominate the market. The design of optimal policies depends mainly on the composition of the market and the difference in risk between the two groups.
For convenience, this article focuses on VaR. However, due to the defects of VaR that discourage the practitioners from applying it for risk assessment. One possible research direction is to study optimal policies under TVaR or distortion risk measures, we decide to leave such problem for future research.
The research was supported by Social Science Planning Project of Shandong Province (No.20CTJJ02, No.21CTJJ01).
The author declares that there is no conflicts of interest in this paper.
[1] |
Geller MA, Zhou T, Shindell D, et al. (2016) Modeling the qboimprovements resulting from higher-model vertical resolution. J Adv model earth syst 8: 1092-1105. doi: 10.1002/2016MS000699
![]() |
[2] |
Dunkerton TJ (1997). The role of gravity waves in the quasi-biennial oscillation. J Geophys Res-Atmos 102: 26053-26076. doi: 10.1029/96JD02999
![]() |
[3] | Liang C, Eldering A, Gettelman A, et al. (2011) Record of tropical interannual variability of temperature and water vapor from a combined airs-mls data set. J Geophys Res-Atmos 116. |
[4] |
Randel WJ, Wu F, Oltmans SJ, et al. (2004) Interannual changes of stratospheric water vapor and correlations with tropical tropopause temperatures. J Atmos Sci 61: 2133-2148. doi: 10.1175/1520-0469(2004)061<2133:ICOSWV>2.0.CO;2
![]() |
[5] |
Collimore CC, Martin DW, Hitchman MH, et al. (2003) On the relationship between the qbo and tropical deep convection. J climate 16: 2552-2568. doi: 10.1175/1520-0442(2003)016<2552:OTRBTQ>2.0.CO;2
![]() |
[6] | Ho CH, Kim HS, Jeong JH, et al. (2009) Influence of stratospheric quasi-biennial oscillation on tropical cyclone tracks in the western north pacific. Geophys Res Lett 36. |
[7] | Liess S, Geller MA (2012) On the relationship between qbo and distribution of tropical deep convection. J Geophys Res-Atmos 117. |
[8] |
Yuan W, Geller MA, Love PT (2014) Enso influence on qbo modulations of the tropical tropopause. Q J Roy Meteor Soc 140: 1670-1676. doi: 10.1002/qj.2247
![]() |
[9] |
Gray WM, Sheaffer JD, Knaff JA. (1992) Influence of the stratospheric qbo on enso variability. J Meteorol Soc Jpn 70: 975-995. doi: 10.2151/jmsj1965.70.5_975
![]() |
[10] |
Camberlin P, Philippon N (2002) The east african march-may rainy season: Associated atmospheric dynamics and predictability over the 1968-97 period. J Climate 15: 1002-1019. doi: 10.1175/1520-0442(2002)015<1002:TEAMMR>2.0.CO;2
![]() |
[11] | Ngongolo HK, Smyshlyaev SP (2010) The statistical prediction of east african rainfalls using quasi-biennial oscillation phases information. Nat Sci 2: 1407. |
[12] | Seleshi Y, Zanke U. (2004) Recent changes in rainfall and rainy days in ethiopia. International Journal of Climatology: A J Royal Meteorol Soc 24: 973-983. |
[13] |
Korecha D, Barnston AG (2007) Predictability of june-september rainfall in ethiopia. Mon Weather Rev 135: 628-650. doi: 10.1175/MWR3304.1
![]() |
[14] | Awulachew SB, Yilma AD, Loulseged M, et al. (2007) Water resources and irrigation development in Ethiopia 123. Iwmi. |
[15] |
Block P, Rajagopalan B (2007) Interannual variability and ensemble forecast of upper blue nile basin kiremt season precipitation. J Hydrometeorol 8: 327-343. doi: 10.1175/JHM580.1
![]() |
[16] |
Cane MA (2005) The evolution of el niño, past and future. Earth Planet Sc Lett 230: 227-240. doi: 10.1016/j.epsl.2004.12.003
![]() |
[17] | Wolde-Georgis T (1997) El nino and drought early warning in ethiopia. Int J Afr Stud 2. |
[18] |
Trenberth K E (1997) The definition of el nino. B Am Meteorol Soc 78: 2771-2778. doi: 10.1175/1520-0477(1997)078<2771:TDOENO>2.0.CO;2
![]() |
[19] |
Zaroug MAH, Eltahir EAB, Giorgi F (2014) Droughts and floods over the upper catchment of the Blue Nile and their connections to the timing of El Niño and La Niña events. Hydrol Earth Syst Sci 18: 1239-1249. doi: 10.5194/hess-18-1239-2014
![]() |
[20] |
Zebiak SE, Cane MA (1987) A model el nino-southern oscillation. Mon Weather Rev 115: 2262-2278. doi: 10.1175/1520-0493(1987)115<2262:AMENO>2.0.CO;2
![]() |
[21] |
Abtew W, Melesse AM, Dessalegne T (2009) El niño southern oscillation link to the blue nile river basin hydrology. Hydrol Process 23: 3653-3660. doi: 10.1002/hyp.7419
![]() |
[22] | Charney JG, Drazin PG (1990) Propagation of planetary-scale disturbances from the lower into the upper atmosphere. The Atmosphere—A Challenge. American Meteorological Society, Boston, MA, 1990: 295-321. |
[23] |
Conway D (1997) A water balance model of the upper blue nile in ethiopia. Hydrolog Sci J 42:2 65-286. doi: 10.1080/02626669709492024
![]() |
[24] | Steenhuis TS, Collick AS, Easton ZM, et al. (2009) Predicting discharge and sediment for the abay (blue nile) with a simple model. Hydrol Process 23: 3728-3737. |
[25] |
Conway D (2000) The climate and hydrology of the upper blue nile river. Geogr J 166: 49-62. doi: 10.1111/j.1475-4959.2000.tb00006.x
![]() |
[26] |
Tesemma ZK, Mohamed YA, Steenhuis TS (2010) Trends in rainfall and runoff in the blue nile basin: 1964-2003. Hydrol Process 24: 3747-3758. doi: 10.1002/hyp.7893
![]() |
[27] |
Habtegebreal AK, Alemu AB (2019) Identification of rainfall intensity by using bahir dar c-band weather radar products. Int J Comput Sci Appl Math 5: 35-40. doi: 10.12962/j24775401.v5i2.4935
![]() |
[28] |
Ayehu G, Tadesse T, Gessesse B, et al. (2018) Validation of new satellite rainfall products over the upper blue nile basin, ethiopia. Atmo Meas Tech 11: 1921-1936. doi: 10.5194/amt-11-1921-2018
![]() |
[29] | Hall G (2015) Pearsons correlation coefficient. other words 1. |
[30] | Cohen J, Cohen P (1983) Applied multiple regression/correlation analysis for the behavioral sciences (2td eu.). Hillsdale, N]: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. |
[31] | Rogerson PA (2001) A statistical method for the detection of geographic clustering. Geogr Anal 33: 215-227. |
[32] | Bayissa YA, Moges SA, Xuan Y, et al. (2015) Spatio-temporal assessment of meteorological drought under the in- fluence of varying record length: The case of upper blue nile basin, ethiopia. Hydrolog Sci J 60: 1927-1942. |