Research article

Scientific method for assessing "Real Madrid DNA": merely a catchy journalistic term or reality?

  • The purpose of this study was to evaluate whether the frequent references to "Real Madrid DNA", when a team comes from behind in the last minutes of a match, could be understood as merely a journalistic surrogate for truth or having simply degenerated into a catchy phrase without much meaning. We took, as a case study, clubs playing in the top division of the Spanish league between the 2010–2011 and 2021-2022 seasons, resulting in an unbalanced panel with 34 clubs that played at least one season in that category. As for the methodology, a variable was created to measure the percentage of times a club comes from behind in the last minutes of a match and explained using a model that included the economic power of the club, other match-specific variables, and fixed effects to assess whether a differentiating effect for Real Madrid (RM) was detected. Concerning empirical findings, it can be asserted that RM's undoubted ability to improve its results in the final stretch of matches comes mainly from money but also from something else hard to explain. Put differently, finding support to RM having something special, which we can refer to as its DNA. RM's fixed effect is not only positive and different from zero but also higher than any other team. Indeed, it differs from the remaining ones from a statistical point of view.

    Citation: Adolfo Maza. Scientific method for assessing 'Real Madrid DNA': merely a catchy journalistic term or reality?[J]. National Accounting Review, 2024, 6(2): 291-313. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2024013

    Related Papers:

    [1] Md Hasanuzzaman, Mohammad Imdad . Relation theoretic metrical fixed point results for Suzuki type ZR-contraction with an application. AIMS Mathematics, 2020, 5(3): 2071-2087. doi: 10.3934/math.2020137
    [2] Noor Muhammad, Ali Asghar, Samina Irum, Ali Akgül, E. M. Khalil, Mustafa Inc . Approximation of fixed point of generalized non-expansive mapping via new faster iterative scheme in metric domain. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(2): 2856-2870. doi: 10.3934/math.2023149
    [3] Aftab Hussain . Fractional convex type contraction with solution of fractional differential equation. AIMS Mathematics, 2020, 5(5): 5364-5380. doi: 10.3934/math.2020344
    [4] Muhammad Tariq, Muhammad Arshad, Mujahid Abbas, Eskandar Ameer, Saber Mansour, Hassen Aydi . A relation theoretic m-metric fixed point algorithm and related applications. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(8): 19504-19525. doi: 10.3934/math.2023995
    [5] Ahmed Alamer, Faizan Ahmad Khan . Boyd-Wong type functional contractions under locally transitive binary relation with applications to boundary value problems. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(3): 6266-6280. doi: 10.3934/math.2024305
    [6] Hongyan Guan, Jinze Gou, Yan Hao . On some weak contractive mappings of integral type and fixed point results in b-metric spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(2): 4729-4748. doi: 10.3934/math.2024228
    [7] Fatima M. Azmi . New fixed point results in double controlled metric type spaces with applications. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(1): 1592-1609. doi: 10.3934/math.2023080
    [8] Iqra Shamas, Saif Ur Rehman, Thabet Abdeljawad, Mariyam Sattar, Sami Ullah Khan, Nabil Mlaiki . Generalized contraction theorems approach to fuzzy differential equations in fuzzy metric spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(6): 11243-11275. doi: 10.3934/math.2022628
    [9] Faruk Sk, Faizan Ahmad Khan, Qamrul Haq Khan, Aftab Alam . Relation-preserving generalized nonlinear contractions and related fixed point theorems. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(4): 6634-6649. doi: 10.3934/math.2022370
    [10] Hanadi Zahed, Zhenhua Ma, Jamshaid Ahmad . On fixed point results in F-metric spaces with applications. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(7): 16887-16905. doi: 10.3934/math.2023863
  • The purpose of this study was to evaluate whether the frequent references to "Real Madrid DNA", when a team comes from behind in the last minutes of a match, could be understood as merely a journalistic surrogate for truth or having simply degenerated into a catchy phrase without much meaning. We took, as a case study, clubs playing in the top division of the Spanish league between the 2010–2011 and 2021-2022 seasons, resulting in an unbalanced panel with 34 clubs that played at least one season in that category. As for the methodology, a variable was created to measure the percentage of times a club comes from behind in the last minutes of a match and explained using a model that included the economic power of the club, other match-specific variables, and fixed effects to assess whether a differentiating effect for Real Madrid (RM) was detected. Concerning empirical findings, it can be asserted that RM's undoubted ability to improve its results in the final stretch of matches comes mainly from money but also from something else hard to explain. Put differently, finding support to RM having something special, which we can refer to as its DNA. RM's fixed effect is not only positive and different from zero but also higher than any other team. Indeed, it differs from the remaining ones from a statistical point of view.



    The first significant result in metric fixed point theory about contractive mappings, the Banach contraction principle (BCP) was established by S. Banach [1] in 1922. Due to its simplicity, this theorem vest as a conventional research tool in many different fields of mathematics. Then, several researchers proposed various types of fixed point theorems concerning different kinds of contractive mappings, see [2,3,4] and references therein. In 1968, R. Kannan [5] introduced the concept of K-contractions, and then in 1972, S. K Chatterjea [6] initiated the idea of C-contractions.

    Definition 1.1. [5,6] Let (X,d) be a metric space and f a self-mapping on X. Then,

    (i) A mapping f is said to be K-contraction if there exists β[0,12) such that

    d(fx,fy)β[d(x,fx)+d(y,fy)]x,yX;

    (ii) A mapping f is said to be C-contraction if there exists β[0,12) such that

    d(fx,fy)β[d(x,fy)+d(y,fx)]x,yX.

    Kannan [5] proved that every K-contraction mapping in a complete metric space has a unique fixed point. Chatterjea [6] proved a similar fixed theorem using C-contraction mappings.

    Further, generalizations of C-contraction and K-contraction mappings were introduced by B. S. Choudhury [7] and Razani and Parvaneh [8] respectively as follows:

    Definition 1.2. [7,8] Let (X,d) be a metric space, f:XX a self-mapping and ϕ:[0,)2[0,) a continuous mapping with ϕ(x,y)=0 if and only if x=y=0. Then,

    (i) f is said to be a weak C-contraction if

    d(fx,fy)12[d(x,fy)+d(y,fx)]ϕ(d(x,fy),d(y,fx)) x,yX;

    (ii) f is said to be a weak K-contraction if

    d(fx,fy)12[d(x,fx)+d(y,fy)]ϕ(d(x,fx),d(y,fy)) x,yX.

    In 2009, Choudhury [7] established a fixed point theorem using weak C-contraction as follows:

    Theorem 1.3. [7] Every weak C-contraction in a complete metric space has a unique fixed point.

    On the other hand, in 2015, Alam and Imdad [9] established another generalization of the classical Banach contraction principle using an amorphous (arbitrary) binary relation. In this context, many relation-theoretic variants of existing fixed point results have been reported for both linear and nonlinear contractions, see [10,11,12] and references therein. For nonlinear contractions, the underlying binary relation should be transitive. To make the transitivity condition weaker, Alam and Imdad [13] introduced the concept of locally f-transitivity.

    Fixed point theory is used as a requisite tool in investigating the existence and uniqueness of solutions of differential and integral equations, see [14,15,16] and references therein. Also, the fixed point theorems for contractive mappings are used in economics, game theory, and many branches of mathematics. For instance, consider the following integral equation

    f(x)=g(x)+x0k(x,s)u(s,f(s))ds,x[0,1]. (1.1)

    where g:[0,1]R, k:[0,1]×[0,1][0,) and u:[0,1]×RR are three continuous functions. The Eq (1.1) can be studied by means of fixed point theory in view of the fact that f(x) is a solution of (1.1) if and only if f(x) is a fixed point of T where T is defined by

    Tf(x)=g(x)+x0k(x,s)u(s,f(s))ds,x[0,1].

    This paper aims to establish some coincidence point theorems for weak C-contraction and K-contraction mappings involving a new auxiliary function in a metric space endowed with a locally f-transitive binary relation. We also deduce related fixed point theorems. As a consequence, these results improve and sharpen some existing fixed point results. Further, we give an example that shows the effectiveness of our results.

    In this section, we recall some basic definitions which will be required in proving our main results. We denote N {0} as N0 throughout the paper.

    Definition 2.1. [17,18] Let X be a nonempty set and (f,g) be a pair of self-mappings on X. Then

    (i) an element xX is called a coincidence point of f and g if

    f(x)=g(x),

    (ii) if xX is a coincidence point of f and g and ˉxX such that ˉx=g(x)=f(x), then ˉx is called a point of coincidence of f and g,

    (iii) if xX is a coincidence point of f and g such that x=f(x)=g(x), then x is called a common fixed point of f and g,

    (iv) the pair (f,g) is said to be commuting if

    g(fx)=f(gx) xX,

    (v) the pair (f,g) is said to be weakly compatible (or partially commuting or coincidentally commuting) if f and g commute at their coincidence points, i.e.,

    g(fx)=f(gx) whenever g(x)=f(x).

    Definition 2.2. [19] Let X be a nonempty set. A subset R of X2 is called a binary relation on X. The subsets, X2 and of X2 are called the universal relation and empty relation respectively.

    Definition 2.3. [9] Let R be a binary relation on a nonempty set X. For x,yX, we say that x and y are R-comparative if either (x,y)R or (y,x)R. We denote it by [x,y]R.

    Definition 2.4. [19,20,21,22,23,24] A binary relation R defined on a nonempty set X is called

    (i) amorphous if R has no specific property at all,

    (ii) reflexive if (x,x)RxX,

    (iii) symmetric if (x,y)R (y,x)R,

    (iv) anti-symmetric if (x,y)R and (y,x)R x=y,

    (v) transitive if (x,y)R and (y,w)R (x,w)R,

    (vi) complete, connected or dichotomous if [x,y] R x,y X,

    (vii) a partial order if R is reflexive, anti-symmetric and transitive.

    Definition 2.5. [19] Let X be a nonempty set and R be a binary relation on X.

    (i) The inverse, transpose or dual relation of R, denoted by R1 is defined by,

    R1 = {(x,y)X2:(y,x)R}.

    (ii) Symmetric closure of R, denoted by Rs, is defined to be the set R R1(i.e., Rs=RR1).

    Proposition 2.6. [9] For a binary relation R defined on a nonempty set X,

    (x,y)Rs[x,y]R.

    Definition 2.7. [25] Let X be a nonempty set, EX and R be a binary relation on X. Then, the restriction of R to E, denoted by R|E, is defined to be the set RE2 (i.e. R|E=RE2). Indeed, R|E is a relation on E induced by R.

    Definition 2.8. [9] Let X be a nonempty set and R be a binary relation on X. A sequence {xn} X is called R-preserving if

    (xn,xn+1)RnN0.

    Definition 2.9. [9] Let X be a nonempty set and f be a self-mapping on X. A binary relation R on X is called f-closed if x,yX,

    (x,y)R(fx,fy)R.

    Definition 2.10. [26] Let X be a nonempty set and f and g be two self-mappings in X. A binary relation R defined on X is called (f,g)-closed if x,yX

    (gx,gy)R (fx,fy)R.

    Note that under the restriction g=I, the identity mapping on X, Definition 2.10 reduces to the notion of f-closedness of R defined in Definition 2.9.

    Definition 2.11. [26] Let (X,d) be a metric space and R be a binary relation on X. We say that (X,d) is R-complete if every R-preserving Cauchy sequence in X converges.

    Clearly, every complete metric space is R-complete with respect to a binary relation R but not conversely. For instance, Suppose X=(1,1] together with the usual metric d. Notice that (X,d) is not complete. Now endow X with the following relation:

    R={(x,y)X2:x,y0}.

    Then, (X,d) is a R-complete metric space. Particularly, under the universal relation, the notion of R-completeness coincides with usual completeness.

    Definition 2.12. [26] Let (X,d) be a metric space and R be a binary relation on X with xX. A mapping f:XX is called R-continuous at x if for any R-preserving sequence {xn} such that xndx, we have f(xn)df(x). Moreover, f is called R-continuous if it is R-continuous at each point of X.

    Clearly, every continuous mapping is R-continuous under any binary relation R. Particularly, under the universal, relation the notion of R-continuity coincides with usual continuity.

    Definition 2.13. [27,28] Let (X,d) be a metric space and (f,g) be a pair of self-mappings on X. The the pair (f,g) is said to be compatible if

    limnd(gfxn,fgxn)=0,

    whenever {xn} is a sequence in X such that

    limng(xn)=limnf(xn).

    Definition 2.14. [26] Let (X,d) be a metric space and R be a binary relation on X and let f and g be two self-mappings on X. Then the mappings f and g are R-compatible if for any sequence {xn}X such that {fxn} and {gxn} are R-preserving and limngxn=limnfxn, we have

    limnd(gfxn,fgxn)=0.

    Remark 2.15. [26] In a metric space (X,d) endowed with a binary elation R,

    commutativitycompatibilityRcompatibilityweakcompatibility.

    In particular, under the universal relation, the notion of R-compatibility coincides with usual compatibility.

    Definition 2.16. [9] Let (X,d) be a metric space. A binary relation R defined on X is called d-self-closed if whenever {xn} is an R-preserving sequence and

    xndx,

    then there exists a subsequence {xnk} of {xn} with [xnk,x] R k N0.

    Definition 2.17. [26] Let (X,d) be a metric space, and let g be a self-mapping on X. A binary relation R defined on X is called (g,d)-self-closed if for any R-preserving sequence {xn} such that {xn}x, there exists a subsequence {xnk} of {xn} with [gxnk,gx]R kN0.

    Note that under the restriction g=I, the identity mapping on X, Definition 2.17 reduces to the notion of d-self-closedness of R.

    Definition 2.18. [29] Given a mapping f:XX, a binary relation R defined on X is called f-transitive if for any x,y,zX,

    (fx,fy),(fy,fz)R (fx,fz)R.

    Later, Alam and Imdad [13] introduced the concept of locally f-transitivity.

    Definition 2.19. [13] Let X be a nonempty set, and f be a self-mapping on X. A binary relation R on X is called locally f-transitive if for each (effectively) R-preserving sequence {xn}f(X) (with range E={xnN0}), the binary relation R|E is transitive.

    Clearly, for a given self-mapping f and a binary relation R on a nonempty set X,

    transitivityftransitivitylocallyftransitivity.

    Definition 2.20. [24] Let X be a nonempty set and R a binary relation on X. A subset E of X is called R-directed if for each x,yE, there exists zX such that (x,z)R and (y,z)R.

    Now we recollect the following lemma which will be required in the proof of our main results.

    Lemma 2.21. [30] Let (X,d) be a metric space and {xn} be a sequence in X. If {xn} is not a Cauchy sequence, then there exist ϵ>0 and two subsequence {xnk} and {xmk} of {xn} such that

    (i) k<mk<nk kN,

    (ii) d(xmk,xnk)ϵ,

    (iii) d(xmk,xnk1)<ϵ.

    In addition to this, if {xn} also satisfies limnd(xn,xn+1)=0, then

    limkd(xmk,xnk)=limkd(xmk1,xnk)=limkd(xmk,xnk1)=ϵ.

    Now we are equipped to prove our main results.

    In what follows, we define a family of functions as follows:

    Φ={ϕ:[0,)2[0,):ϕis a function such thatlim infnϕ(an.bn)>0whenever the pair(an,bn)(a,b)(0,0)}.

    Consider a function ϕ:[0,)2[0,) defined by

    ϕ(x,y)={16(x6+3y+1),whenx,y[0,1]1,others.

    Notice that ϕΦ but ϕ is not continuous, which establishes the fact that the family of functions Φ is larger than the family of functions considered by Choudhury [7] and Razani and Parvaneh [8].

    Now we present our first result on the existence of coincidence points under weak C-contractions.

    Theorem 3.1. Let (X,d) be a R-complete metric space endowed with a binary relation R and f, g be two self-mappings on X. Suppose that the following conditions hold:

    (a) f(X)g(X),

    (b) R is (f,g)-closed and locally f-transitive,

    (c) there exists x0X such that (gx0,fx0)R,

    (d) f and g are R-compatible,

    (e) g is R-continuous,

    (f) either f is R-continuous or R is (g,d)-self-closed,

    (g) there exists ϕΦ such that

    d(fx,fy)12[d(gx,fy)+d(gy,fx)]ϕ(d(gx,fy),d(gy,fx))

    x,yX with (gx,gy)R.

    Then f and g have a coincidence point.

    Proof. By assumption (c), there exists x0X such that (gx0,fx0)R. If f(x0)=g(x0), then we are done. Otherwise, by (a) we can choose x1X such that g(x1)=f(x0). Again from f(X)g(X) there exists x2X such that g(x2)=f(x1). Continuing this process inductively, we can define a sequence {xn} X of joint iterates such that

    g(xn+1)=f(xn)nN0. (3.1)

    Now, we assert that {gxn} is a R-preserving sequence, i.e.,

    (gxn,gxn+1)RnN0. (3.2)

    We prove the fact by mathematical induction. On using assumption (c) and Eq (3.1) with n=0, we have

    (gx0,gx1)R.

    Thus (3.2) holds for n=0. Now suppose (3.2) holds for n=r>0, i.e.,

    (gxr,gxr+1)R, (3.3)

    then we have to show that (3.2) holds for n=r+1. since R is (f,g)-closed, we have from (3.3),

    (gxr,gxr+1)R(fxr,fxr+1)R(gxr+1,gxr+2)R,

    that is, (3.2) holds for n=r+1 also. Thus, by induction (3.2) holds nN0. In view of (3.1) and (3.2), the sequence {fxn} is also R-preserving, i.e.,

    (fxn,fxn+1)RnN0.

    If g(xn0)=g(xn0+1) for some n0N, then using (3.1) we have g(xn0)=f(xn0), i.e., xn0 is a coincidence point of f and g and hence we are done.

    On the other hand, if g(xn)g(xn+1) nN0 then d(gxn,gxn+1)0, then we can define a sequence {dn}n=0 (0,) by

    dn=d(gxn,gxn+1).

    Applying (3.1), (3.2) and assumption (g),

    dn+1=d(gxn+1,gxn+2)=d(fxn,fxn+1)12[d(gxn,fxn+1)+d(gxn+1,fxn)]ϕ(d(gxn,fxn+1),d(gxn+1,fxn))12[d(gxn,gxn+2)+d(gxn+1,gxn+1)]ϕ(d(gxn,gxn+2),d(gxn+1,gxn+1))=12d(gxn,gxn+2)ϕ(d(gxn,gxn+2),0) (3.4)
    12d(gxn,gxn+2) (3.5)
    12d(gxn,gxn+1)+12d(gxn+1,gxn+2) (3.6)

    which gives

    dn+112dn+12dn+1dn+1dn.

    Therefore, the sequence {dn} is a decreasing sequence of non-negative real numbers and hence it is convergent. Suppose there exists r0 such that

    dnr,i.e.,d(gxn,gxn+1)r. (3.7)

    We will show that r=0. Suppose r>0, then letting n in (3.5) and (3.6) we get

    rlimn12d(gxn,gxn+2)12(r+r)=rlimnd(gxn,gxn+2)=2r. (3.8)

    Again, taking upper limit in (3.4) and using (3.7) and (3.8), we get

    lim supnd(gxn+1,gxn+2)lim supn12d(gxn,gxn+2)+lim supn(ϕ(d(gxn,gxn+2),0)).

    Using the fact that for any sequence {xn}, lim sup(xn)=lim inf(xn), we get

    lim supnd(gxn+1,gxn+2)12lim supnd(gxn,gxn+2)lim infnϕ(d(gxn,gxn+2),0)r12.2rlim infnϕ(d(gxn,gxn+2),0)

    which gives lim infnϕ(d(gxn,gxn+2),0)0 which is a contradiction to the property of ϕ, since (d(gxn,gxn+2),0) (2r,0)(0,0). Hence,

    limnd(gxn,gxn+1)=0. (3.9)

    Now, we show that {gxn} is a Cauchy sequence. Suppose that {gxn} is not a Cauchy sequence. Therefore, by Lemma 2.21, there exist ϵ>0 and two subsequences {gxnk} and {gxmk} such that

    d(gxmk,gxnk)ϵ (3.10)

    for nk>mk>k, further, corresponding to mk we can choose nk in such a way that it is the smallest integer nk>mk and satisfy (3.10). Then,

    d(gxmk,gxnk1)<ϵ. (3.11)

    Further, in view of (3.9), (3.10), (3.11) and Lemma 2.21, we have

    limnd(gxmk,gxnk)=limnd(gxmk,gxnk1)=limnd(gxmk1,gxnk)=ϵ. (3.12)

    As {gxn} is R-preserving and {gxn}f(X), by the local f-transitivity of R, we have (gxmk,gxnk)R. Hence, applying contractivity condition (g), we obtain

    (gxmk,gxnk)=d(fxmk1,fxnk1)12[d(gxmk1,fxnk1)+d(gxnk1,fxmk1)]ϕ(d(gxmk1,fxnk1),d(gxnk1,fxmk1))=12[d(gxmk1,gxnk)+d(gxnk1,gxmk)]ϕ(d(gxmk1,gxnk),d(gxnk1,gxmk)).

    Taking the upper limit in the above equation and in view of (3.12), we get

    limsupnd(gxmk,gxnk)12[limsupnd(gxmk1,fxnk1)+limsupnd(gxnk1,fxmk1)]+limsupn(ϕ(d(gxmk1,fxnk1),d(gxnk1,fxmk1)))

    Since for any sequence {xn}, lim sup(xn)=lim inf(xn), we get using (3.12)

    ϵ12(ϵ+ϵ)lim infnϕ(d(gxmk1,fxnk1),d(gxnk1,fxmk1))
    lim infnϕ(d(gxmk1,fxnk1),d(gxnk1,fxmk1))0

    which is a contradiction to the property of ϕ, since

    (d(gxmk1,fxnk1),d(gxnk1,fxmk1))(ϵ,ϵ)(0,0).

    Hence, {gxn} is a Cauchy sequence. Now since {gxn} is a R-preserving sequence and X is R-complete, {gxn} converges to an element zX, i.e.,

    limng(xn)=z. (3.13)

    Also, from (3.1),

    limnf(xn)=z. (3.14)

    By R-continuity of g,

    limng(gxn)=g(limngxn)=g(z). (3.15)

    Utilizing (3.14) and R-continuity of g,

    limng(fxn)=g(limnfxn)=g(z). (3.16)

    Since {fxn} and {gxn} are R-preserving and

    limnfxn=limngxn=z,

    by the R-compatibility of f and g,

    limnd(gfxn,fgxn)=0. (3.17)

    Now, we prove that z is a coincidence point of f and g.

    Suppose that f is R-continuous. Using (3.2), (3.13) and R-continuity of f,

    limnf(gxn)=f(limngxn)=f(z). (3.18)

    Applying (3.16), (3.17) and continuity of d,

    d(gz,fz)=d(limngfxn,limnfgxn)=limnd(gfxn,fgxn)=0

    so that g(z)=f(z). Hence, z is a coincidence point of f and g.

    Alternately, suppose that R is (g,d)-self-closed. As {gxn} is R-preserving and gxnz, due to (g,d)-self-closedness of R, there exists a subsequences {gxnk} of {gxn} such that

    [ggxnk,gz]RkN0. (3.19)

    Since gxnkz, Eqs (3.13)–(3.17) also holds for {xnk} instead of {xn}. In view of (3.19) and using assumption (g), we get

    d(fgxnk,fz)12[d(ggxnk,fz)+d(gz,fgxnk)]ϕ(d(ggxnk,fz),d(gz,fgxnk))12[d(ggxnk,fz)+d(gz,fgxnk)]12[d(ggxnk,fz)+d(gz,gfxnk)+d(gfxnk,fgxnk)]. (3.20)

    Now using triangle inequality and (3.20) we get

    (gz,fz)d(gz,gfxnk)+d(gfxnk,fgxnk)+d(fgxnk,fz)d(gz,gfxnk)+d(gfxnk,fgxnk)+12[d(ggxnk,fz)+d(gz,gfxnk)+d(gfxnk,fgxnk)].

    Letting k in the above equation, we get

    d(gz,fz)d(gz,gz)+12[d(gz,fz)+d(gz,gz)]12d(gz,fz)12d(gz,fz)0

    which gives d(gz,fz)=0, i.e, z is a coincidence point of f and g.

    Theorem 3.2. In addition to Theorem 3.1, if we consider the following condition:

    (h) f(X) is Rsg(X)-directed,

    then f and g have a unique point of coincidence.

    Proof. Suppose there exist x,yX such that

    f(x)=g(x)=ˉxandf(y)=g(y)=ˉy. (3.21)

    We show that ˉx=ˉy. As f(x),f(y)f(X)g(X), by assumption (h), there exist g(z) such that

    [fx,gz]R[gx,gz]R (3.22)

    and

    [fy,gz]R[gy,gz]R. (3.23)

    Now define the constant sequences: z0n=x and z2n=y nN0, then using (3.21),

    g(z0n+1)=f(z0n)=ˉx, (3.24)
    g(z2n+1)=f(z2n)=ˉy. (3.25)

    Suppose z10=z. Since f(X)g(X), we can define a sequence {z1n} such that g(z1n+1)=f(z1n) nN0. Therefore,

    g(zin+1)=f(zin)nN0andi=0,1. (3.26)

    We claim that

    [g(zin),g(zi+1n)]RnN0andi=0,1. (3.27)

    We prove this fact by mathematical induction. It follows from (3.22) and (3.23) that (3.27) holds for n=0. Suppose that (3.27) holds for n=r>0, i.e.,

    [g(zir),g(zi+1r)]Randi=0,1.

    As R is (f,g)-closed, we have

    [f(zir),f(zi+1r)]Randi=0,1,

    which gives in view of (3.26), we get

    [g(zir+1),g(zi+1r+1)]Randi=0,1.

    Therefore, (3.27) holds for n=r+1 also. Hence, (3.27) holds nN0. Now in view of (3.27) and using (3.26) and assumption (g), we get

    d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1)=d(fz0n,fz1n)12[d(gz0n,fz1n)+d(gz1n,fz0n)]ϕ(d(gz0n,fz1n),d(gz1n,fz0n))=12[d(gz0n,gz1n+1)+d(gz1n,gz0n+1)]ϕ(d(gz0n,gz1n+1),d(gz1n,gz0n+1))

    which gives

    (gz0n+1,gz1n+1)12[d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1)+d(gz1n,gz0n)]ϕ(d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1),d(gz1n,gz0n)) (3.28)

    which implies

    d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1)12[d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1)+d(gz1n,gz0n)]

    which implies

    d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1)d(gz0n,gz1n).

    Therefore, the sequence {d(gz0n,gz1n)} is decreasing non-negative sequence which converges to a non-negative real number r, i.e,

    {d(gz0n,gz1n)} r.

    We will show that r=0. Suppose that r>0, then taking upper limit in (3.28) and utilizing the same method as used earlier in this proof, we get

    r12(r+r)lim infnϕ(d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1),d(gz1n,gz0n))

    which gives lim infnϕ(d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1),d(gz1n,gz0n))0, which is a contradiction to the property of ϕ. Hence,

    limnd(gz0n,gz1n)=0. (3.29)

    Similarly, we can show that

    limnd(gz1n,gz2n)=0. (3.30)

    Now, using triangle inequality, (3.24) and (3.25), we get

    d(ˉx,ˉy)=d(gz0n,gz2n)d(gz0n,gz1n)+d(gz1n,gz2n).

    Letting n and in view of (3.29) and (3.30), we get

    d(ˉx,ˉy)=0.

    Hence, f and g have unique point of coincidence.

    Now we present coincidence point results for mappings satisfying weak K-contraction.

    Theorem 3.3. Let (X,d) be a R-complete metric space endowed with a binary relation R. Let f and g be two self-mappings on X. Suppose that the following conditions hold:

    (a) f(X)g(X),

    (b) R is (f,g)-closed and locally f-transitive,

    (c) there exists x0X such that (gx0,fx0)R,

    (d) f and g are R-compatible,

    (e) g is R-continuous,

    (f) either f is R-continuous or R is (g,d)-self-closed,

    (g) there exists ϕΦ such that

    d(fx,fy)12[d(gx,fx)+d(gy,fy)]ϕ(d(gx,fx),d(gy,fy))

    x,yX with (gx,gy)R.

    Then f and g have a coincidence point.

    Proof. Following the proof of Theorem 3.1, we can construct the sequence {gxn} defined in (3.1) and claim that the sequences {gxn} and {fxn} are R-preserving. If g(xn0)=g(xn0+1) for some n0N, then using (3.1) we have g(xn0)=f(xn0) i.e. xn0 is a coincidence point of f and g, hence we are done. On the other hand, if g(xn)g(xn+1) nN0 then d(gxn,gxn+1)0. On using (3.1), (3.2) and assumption (g), we have

    (gxn+1,gxn+2)=d(fxn,fxn+1)12[d(gxn,fxn)+d(gxn+1,fxn+1)]ϕ(d(gxn,fxn),d(gxn+1,fxn+1))=12[d(gxn,gxn+1)+d(gxn+1,gxn+2)]ϕ(d(gxn,gxn+1),d(gxn+1,gxn+2)) (3.31)

    which gives

    d(gxn+1,gxn+2)12[d(gxn,gxn+1)+d(gxn+1,gxn+2)]d(gxn+1,gxn+2)d(gxn,gxn+1).

    Hence, the sequence {d(gxn,gxn+1)} is a decreasing sequence which converges to r0. Using the same technique as in Theorem 3.1, we get

    limnd(gxn,gxn+1)=0. (3.32)

    Now, we show that {gxn} is a Cauchy sequence. Following the lines of Theorem 3.1, there exist subsequences {gxnk} and {gxmk} of {gxn} such that (gxmk,gxnk)R. Then applying condition (g), we obtain

    (gxmk,gxnk)=d(fxmk1,fxnk1)12[d(gxmk1,fxmk1)+d(gxnk1,fxnk1)]ϕ(d(gxmk1,fxmk1),d(gxnk1,fxnk1))=12[d(gxmk1,gxmk)+d(gxnk1,gxnk)]ϕ(d(gxmk1,gxmk),d(gxnk1,gxnk)).

    Letting k in the above equation and using the property of ϕ, we get that the sequence {gxn} is Cauchy. The rest of the proof is similar to Theorem 3.1.

    Theorem 3.4. In addition to Theorem 3.3, if we consider the following condition:

    (h) f(X) is Rsg(X)-directed,

    then f and g have a unique point of coincidence.

    Proof. The proof is almost similar to Theorem 3.2. Here,

    d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1)=d(fz0n,fz1n)12[d(gz0n,fz0n)+d(gz1n,fz1n)]ϕ(d(gz0n,fz0n),d(gz1n,fz1n))=12[d(gz0n,gz0n+1)+d(gz1n,gz1n+1)]ϕ(d(gz0n,gz0n+1),d(gz1n,gz1n+1))=12d(gz1n,gz1n+1)ϕ(0,d(gz1n,gz1n+1)) (3.33)

    which gives

    d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1)12d(gz1n,gz1n+1) (3.34)
    12[d(gz1n,gz0n)+d(gz0n,gz1n+1)12[d(gz1n,gz0n)+d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1) (3.35)
    d(gz0n+1,gz1n+1)d(gz1n,gz0n). (3.36)

    Therefore, the sequence {d(gz1n,gz0n)} is decreasing non-negative sequence which converges to a non-negative real number, i.e.,

    limnd(gz1n,gz0n)=r.

    Also in view of (3.34) and (3.35), we get

    limnd(gz1n,gz1n+1)=2r.

    Now taking the upper limit in (3.33) and using the property of ϕ, we get

    limnd(gz0n,gz1n)=0

    Similarly,

    limnd(gz1n,gz2n)=0.

    Now the conclusion is immediate following Theorem 3.2.

    Remark 3.5. Theorem 3.2 (Theorem 3.4) also guarantees the existence of a unique common fixed point of f and g.

    Proof. Let x be a coincidence point of f and g. So we have, g(x)=f(x)=ˉx. Using Remark 2.15, every R-compatible pair is weakly compatible. Therefore, ˉx is also a coincidence point of f and g. In view of Theorem 3.2 (Theorem 3.4), we get g(x)=g(ˉx) which gives

    ˉx=g(ˉx)=f(ˉx).

    Hence, ˉx is a common fixed point of f and g. To claim the uniqueness, we assume x be another common fixed point of f and g. Using Theorem 3.2 (Theorem 3.4), we get

    x=g(x)=g(ˉx)=ˉx

    which concludes the proof.

    Under universal relation (i.e. R=X2), Theorem 3.1 together with Theorems 3.2, 3.3, 3.4 reduce to the following coincidence point theorems

    Corollary 3.6. Let (X,d) be a complete metric space and f, g be two self-mappings on X. Suppose that the following conditions hold:

    (a) f(X)g(X),

    (b) f and g are compatible,

    (c) g is continuous,

    (c) there exists ϕΦ such that

    d(fx,fy)12[d(gx,fy)+d(gy,fx)]ϕ(d(gx,fy),d(gy,fx))

    x,yX.

    Then f and g have a unique point of coincidence.

    Corollary 3.7. Let (X,d) be a complete metric space and f, g be two self-mappings on X. Suppose that the following conditions hold:

    (a) f(X)g(X),

    (b) f and g are compatible,

    (c) g is continuous,

    (d) there exists ϕΦ such that

    d(fx,fy)12[d(gx,fx)+d(gy,fy)]ϕ(d(gx,fx),d(gy,fy))

    x,yX.

    Then f and g have a unique point of coincidence.

    In this section, we derive several fixed point results of the existing literature as consequences of our newly proved results.

    Taking g=I, the identity map on X in Theorems 3.1, 3.2, 3.3 and 3.4, we obtain

    Corollary 4.1. Let (X,d) be a R-complete metric space endowed with a binary relation R and f a self-mappings on X. Suppose that the following conditions hold:

    (a) R is f-closed and locally f-transitive,

    (b) there exists x0X such that (x0,fx0)R,

    (c) either f is R-continuous or R is d-self-closed,

    (d) there exists ϕΦ such that

    d(fx,fy)12[d(x,fy)+d(y,fx)]ϕ(d(x,fy),d(y,fx))

    x,yX with (x,y)R.

    Then f has a fixed point. Moreover, if

    (e) f(X) is Rs-directed,

    then f has a unique fixed point.

    Corollary 4.2. Let (X,d) be a R-complete metric space endowed with a binary relation R and f a self-mappings on X. Suppose that the following conditions hold:

    (a) R is f-closed and locally f-transitive,

    (b) there exists x0X such that (x0,fx0)R,

    (c) either f is R-continuous or R is d-self-closed,

    (d) there exists ϕΦ such that

    d(fx,fy)12[d(x,fx)+d(y,fy)]ϕ(d(x,fx),d(y,fy))

    x,yX with (x,y)R.

    Then f has a fixed point. Moreover, if

    (e) f(X) is Rs-directed,

    then f has a unique fixed point.

    Under universal relation (i.e. R=X2), taking g=I, the identity map on X in Theorems 3.1, 3.2, 3.3 and 3.4, we obtain:

    Corollary 4.3. Let (X,d) be a complete metric space and f be a self-mapping on X. If there exists ϕΦ such that

    d(fx,fy)12[d(x,fy)+d(y,fx)]ϕ(d(x,fy),d(y,fx))

    x,yX. Then, f has a unique fixed point.

    Corollary 4.4. Let (X,d) be a complete metric space and f a self-mapping on X. If there exists ϕΦ such that

    d(fx,fy)12[d(x,fx)+d(y,fy)]ϕ(d(x,fx),d(y,fy))

    x,yX. Then, f has a unique fixed point.

    Taking R=⪯, the partial order and g=I, the identity map on X in Theorem 3.1 we obtain the following result:

    Corollary 4.5. Let (X,d,) be a complete metric space endowed with usual partial order and f a self-mapping on X. Suppose the following conditions hold:

    (a) there exists x0X such that x0fx0,

    (b) f is nondecreasing with respect to ,

    (c) f is continuous or (X,d,) is regular,

    (d) there exists ϕΦ such that

    d(fx,fy)12[d(x,fy)+d(y,fx)]ϕ(d(x,fy),d(y,fx)) xy,

    then, f has a fixed point.

    Notice that Corollary 4.1 improves and sharpens Theorem 1.3 and Theorem 2.1 of Harjani et al. [30] since the auxiliary function ϕ considered here is relatively weaker than the existing one.

    Remark 4.6. Taking ϕ(x,y)=k(x+y), where 0<k<1 in Corollaries 4.3 and 4.4 we obtain the classical fixed point theorems given by Kannan [5] and Chatterjea [6] respectively.

    Consider the metric space (X,d) with X=(1,1] with the usual metric d. Define two functions f,g:XX by

    f(x)={1x4,ifx(1,0)x3,ifx[0,1]andg(x)=3x4.

    Now endow X with the following binary relation

    R={(x,y)X2:xy0}.

    Obviously, X is R-complete metric space. Consider a function ϕ:[0,)2[0,) defined by

    ϕ(x,y)={14(x5+2y),whenx,y[0,1]1,others.

    For x,yX with (gx,gy)R,

    d(fx,fy)=x3y3=112[4xy]112[9209x4y]112[(12120)9x4y]112[(12120)9x4y+(1212)9y4x]112[12{9x4y+9y4x}14{159x4y+29y4x}]12{9x4y12+9y4x12}14{159x4y12+29y4x12}=12[d(gx,fy)+d(gy,fx)]ϕ(d(gx,fy),d(gy,fx)).

    Therefore, the condition (g) of Theorem 3.1 is satisfied. Also, by routine calculation, it can be observed that all the other conditions of Theorems 3.1 and 3.2 are satisfied, and f and g have a unique point of coincidence, namely: x=0, which is also a unique common fixed point of f and g in view of Remark 3.5.

    Notice that condition (g) of Theorem 3.1 does not hold for the whole space (for example, take x=0andy=1). Also, the used auxiliary function ϕ in this example is discontinuous. Therefore, this example cannot be solved by the existing results, which establishes the importance of our results.

    In this paper, we observed that some of the conditions of the auxiliary function ϕ are not necessary for weak C-contractions and weak K-contractions. Moreover, we established the relation-theoretic variants of some coincidence point as well as fixed point theorems for these contractions. Also, the presented example shows the effectiveness of our newly proved results over corresponding several noted results. Now, for possible problems, one can attempt to prove related contractions like weakly f-Kannan, weakly f-Chatterjea etc., with the newly introduced family of auxiliary functions.

    The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees for their comments that helped us improve this article. The first author would like to thank the Council of Scientific and Industrial Research (CSIR), Government of India for JRF (File No. 09/112(0604)/2018-EMR-I).

    The authors declare no conflict of interest.



    [1] Apesteguia J, Palacios-Huerta I (2010) Psychological pressure in competitive environments: Evidence from a randomized natural experiment. Am Econ Rev 100: 2548–2564. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.5.2548 doi: 10.1257/aer.100.5.2548
    [2] Arrondel L, Duhautois R, Laslier JF (2019) Decision under psychological pressure: The shooter's anxiety at the penalty kick. J Econ Psychol 70: 22–35. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2018.10.008 doi: 10.1016/j.joep.2018.10.008
    [3] Badiella L, Puig P, Lago-Peñas C, et al. (2023) Influence of red and yellow cards on team performance in elite soccer. Ann Oper Res 325: 149–165. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-022-04733-0 doi: 10.1007/s10479-022-04733-0
    [4] Baena V (2023) Impossible is nothing even in times of COVID-19. Effective strategy lessons from the Real Madrid F.C. Soccer Soc 25: 289–306. https://doi.org/10.1080/14660970.2023.2248909 doi: 10.1080/14660970.2023.2248909
    [5] Baker R, McHale IG (2022) 'Form is temporary, class is permanent': identifying a longer-term hot hand in golf. J Quant Anal Sports 18: 241–251. https://doi.org/10.1515/jqas-2022-0051 doi: 10.1515/jqas-2022-0051
    [6] Banko L, Leeds EM, Leeds MA (2016) Gender differences in response to setbacks: Evidence from professional tennis. Soc Sci Q 97: 161–176. https://doi.org/10.1111/ssqu.12230 doi: 10.1111/ssqu.12230
    [7] Bar-Eli M, Krumer A, Morgulev E (2020) Ask not what economics can do for sports-Ask what sports can do for economics. J Behav Exp Econ 89: 101597. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2020.101597 doi: 10.1016/j.socec.2020.101597
    [8] Bilek G, Ulas E (2019) Predicting match outcome according to the quality of opponent in the English premier league using situational variables and team performance indicators. Int J Perform Anal Sport 19: 930–941. https://doi.org/10.1080/24748668.2019.1684773 doi: 10.1080/24748668.2019.1684773
    [9] Binder JJ, Findlay M (2012) The effects of the Bosman ruling on national and club teams in Europe. J Sport Econ 13: 107–129. https://doi.org/10.1177/1527002511400278 doi: 10.1177/1527002511400278
    [10] Bucciol A, Hu A, Zarri L (2019) The effects of prior outcomes on managerial risk taking: Evidence from Italian professional soccer. J Econ Psychol 75: 102090. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2018.07.006 doi: 10.1016/j.joep.2018.07.006
    [11] Cabras S, Tena JD (2023) Implicit institutional incentives and individual decisions: Causal inference with deep learning models. Manag Decis Econ 44: 3739–3754. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3905 doi: 10.1002/mde.3905
    [12] Calero J, del Corral J (2014) Is human capital protection effective? The case of the Basque Country in Spanish football. Sport Bus Manag 4: 223–236. https://doi.org/10.1108/SBM-07-2013-0025 doi: 10.1108/SBM-07-2013-0025
    [13] Carmichael F, McHale I, Thomas D (2011) Maintaining market position: Team performance, revenue and wage expenditure in the English Premier League. Bull Econ Res 63: 464–497. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8586.2009.00340.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8586.2009.00340.x
    [14] Caruso R, Bellavite Pellegrini C, Di Domizio M (2016) Does diversity in the payroll affect soccer teams' performance? Evidence from the Italian Serie A. MPRA (Working paper no. 75644), University Library of Munich, Germany.
    [15] Cohen-Zada D, Krumer A, Rosenboim M, et al. (2017) Choking under pressure and gender: Evidence from professional tennis. J Econ Psychol 61: 176–190. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2017.04.005 doi: 10.1016/j.joep.2017.04.005
    [16] De Paola M, Scoppa V (2017) Gender differences in reaction to psychological pressure: Evidence from tennis players. Eur J Work Organ Psychol 26: 444–456. https://doi.org/10.1080/1359432X.2017.1307178 doi: 10.1080/1359432X.2017.1307178
    [17] Dimitrov D, Helmenstein C, Kleissner A, et al. (2006) Die makroökonomischen effekte des sports in Europa. Studie in Auftrag des Bundeskanzleramts, Viena: Sektion Sport.
    [18] Fløtnes T (2011) Factors of success for Norwegian top football clubs—And why profit making is difficult for European football clubs. Available from: http://studenttheses.cbs.dk/handle/10417/2923.
    [19] Forrest D, Simmons R (2002) Team salaries and playing success in sports: A comparative perspective, In: Albach, H., Frick, B., Sportökonomie. ZfB—Ergänzungshefte, Wiesbaden: Gabler Verlag. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-663-07711-4_12
    [20] Frick B (2005) "... und Geld schiesst eben doch Tore". Die voraussetzungen sportlichen und wirtschaftlichen erfolges in der fussball-Bundesliga[in German]. Sportwissenschaft 35: 250–270.
    [21] Frick B (2013) Team wage bills and sporting performance: Evidence from (major and minor) European football leagues. In: Rodríguez, P., Kesenne, S., Garcia Villar, J., The Econometrics of Sport, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. https://doi.org/10.4337/9781781002865.00012
    [22] García C (2021) Real Madrid and public relations: applying the circuit of culture to organizational values. Soccer Soc 22: 442–456. https://doi.org/10.1080/14660970.2020.1824909 doi: 10.1080/14660970.2020.1824909
    [23] Garcia-del-Barrio P, Szymanski S (2009) Goal! Profit maximization and win maximization in football leagues. Rev Ind Organ 34: 45–68. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-009-9203-6 doi: 10.1007/s11151-009-9203-6
    [24] Gásquez R, Royuela V (2014) Is football an indicator of development at the international level? Soc Indic Res 117: 827–848. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-013-0368-x doi: 10.1007/s11205-013-0368-x
    [25] Gásquez R, Royuela V (2016) The determinants of international football success: A panel data analysis of the Elo rating. Soc Sci Q 97: 125–141. https://doi.org/10.1111/ssqu.12262 doi: 10.1111/ssqu.12262
    [26] Iso-Ahola SE, Dotson CO (2016) Psychological momentum-a key to continued success. Front Psychol 31: 1328. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2016.01328 doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2016.01328
    [27] Kuper S, Szymanski S (2009) Soccereconomics: why England loses, why Germany and Brazil win, and why the US, Japan, Australia, Turkey and even Iraq are destined to become the kings of the world's most popular sport, New York: Nation Books.
    [28] Lei X, Humphreys BR (2013) Game importance as a dimension of uncertainty of outcome. J Quant Anal Sports 9: 25–36. https://doi.org/10.1515/jqas-2012-0019 doi: 10.1515/jqas-2012-0019
    [29] Leite W, Silva CD (2023) Can socio-cultural predictors help explain the home advantage gap in European men's and women's football? Soccer Soc 24: 725–736. https://doi.org/10.1080/14660970.2022.2116012 doi: 10.1080/14660970.2022.2116012
    [30] Llorca M, Teste T (2016) Dépenses salariales et performance dans l'industrie du football[in French]. Revue Française d'Économie 21: 125. https://doi.org/10.3917/rfe.162.0125
    [31] Madsen DØ, Stenheim T, Boas Hansen S, et al. (2018) Wage expenditures and sporting success: An analysis of Norwegian and Swedish football 2010–2013. Cogent Soc Sci 4: 1457423. https://doi.org/10.1080/23311886.2018.1457423 doi: 10.1080/23311886.2018.1457423
    [32] Marcén M (2016) The Bosman ruling and the presence of native football players in their home league: the Spanish case. Eur Law Econ 42: 209–235. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-016-9541-4 doi: 10.1007/s10657-016-9541-4
    [33] Martins HSR, Duarte AR, Barbosa JJ, et al. (2023) Home team's advantage reduced without crowd support after the COVID-19 outbreak. Soccer Soc 24: 636–653. https://doi.org/10.1080/14660970.2022.2088526 doi: 10.1080/14660970.2022.2088526
    [34] Meier P, Flepp E, Ruedisser M, et al. (2020) Separating psychological momentum from strategic momentum: Evidence from men's professional tennis. J Econ Psychol 78: 102269. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2020.102269 doi: 10.1016/j.joep.2020.102269
    [35] Morgulev E (2023) Streakiness is not a theory: On "momentums" (hot hands) and their underlying mechanisms. J Econ Psychol 96: 102627. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2023.102627 doi: 10.1016/j.joep.2023.102627
    [36] Morgulev E, Azar OH, Bar-Elia M (2019) Does a "comeback" create momentum in overtime? Analysis of NBA tied games. J Econ Psychol 75: 102126. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2018.11.005 doi: 10.1016/j.joep.2018.11.005
    [37] Osso F, Szymansky S (1991) Who are the champions? (An analysis of football and architecture). Bus Strategy Rev 2: 113–130. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8616.1991.tb00155.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8616.1991.tb00155.x
    [38] Pérez L (2021) Will we lose if we lose you? Players' absence, teams' performance and the overlapping of competitions. J Sport Econ 22: 722–734. https://doi.org/10.1177/15270025211008499 doi: 10.1177/15270025211008499
    [39] Ransom K, Weinberg R (1985) Effect of situation criticality on performance of elite male and female tennis players. J Sport Behav 8 (3): 144–148.
    [40] Rodriguez-Pomeda J, Casani F, Alonso-Almeida M (2017) Emotions' management within the Real Madrid football club business model. Soccer Soc 18: 431–444. https://doi.org/10.1080/14660970.2014.980736 doi: 10.1080/14660970.2014.980736
    [41] Rosenqvist O (2019) Are the most competitive men more resilient to failures than the most competitive women? Evidence from professional golf tournaments. Soc Sci Q 100: 578–591. https://doi.org/10.1111/ssqu.12606 doi: 10.1111/ssqu.12606
    [42] Royuela V, Gásquez R (2019) On the influence of foreign players on the success of football clubs. J Sport Econ 20: 718–741. https://doi.org/10.1177/1527002518807960 doi: 10.1177/1527002518807960
    [43] Scelles N, Durand C, Bonnal L, et al. (2013) Competitive balance versus competitive intensity before a match: Is one of these two concepts more relevant in explaining attendance? The case of the French football Ligue 1 over the period 2008–2011. Appl Econ 45: 4184–4192. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2013.770124 doi: 10.1080/00036846.2013.770124
    [44] Sonnabend H (2020) On discouraging environments in team contests: Evidence from top-level beach volleyball. Manag Decis Econ 41: 986–997. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3153 doi: 10.1002/mde.3153
    [45] Steeger GM, Dulin JL, Gonzalez GO (2021) Winning and losing streaks in the National Hockey League: Are teams experiencing momentum or are games a sequence of random events? J Quant Anal Sports 17: 155–170. https://doi.org/10.1515/jqas-2020-0077 doi: 10.1515/jqas-2020-0077
    [46] Szymanski S (2003) The economic design of sporting contest. J Econ Lit 41: 1137–1187. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.41.4.1137 doi: 10.1257/jel.41.4.1137
    [47] Szymanski S, Smith R (1997) The English football industry: Profit, performance and industrial structure. Int Rev Appl Econ 11: 135–153. https://doi.org/10.1080/02692179700000008 doi: 10.1080/02692179700000008
    [48] The Economist (2014) Everything to play for. Good managers matter, but not as much as money does. Available from: http://www.economist.com/news/britain/21601873-goodmanagers-matter-not-much-money-does-everything-play.
    [49] Triguero-Ruiz F, Avila-Cano A (2018) Measuring competitive balance in the major European soccer leagues. J Phys Educ Sport 18: 1335–1340. https://doi.org/10.7752/jpes.2018.s3198 doi: 10.7752/jpes.2018.s3198
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Faizan Ahmad Khan, Faruk Sk, Maryam Gharamah Alshehri, Qamrul Haq Khan, Aftab Alam, Cristian Chifu, Relational Meir-Keeler Contractions and Common Fixed Point Theorems, 2022, 2022, 2314-8888, 1, 10.1155/2022/3550923
    2. Alexander Greshnov, Vladimir Potapov, About coincidence points theorems on 2-step Carnot groups with 1-dimensional centre equipped with Box-quasimetrics, 2023, 8, 2473-6988, 6191, 10.3934/math.2023313
    3. Nifeen Hussain Altaweel, Faizan Ahmad Khan, Relation-Theoretic Fixed Point Theorems Involving Certain Auxiliary Functions with Applications, 2022, 14, 2073-8994, 2614, 10.3390/sym14122614
    4. Asik Hossain, Faizan Ahmad Khan, Qamrul Haq Khan, A Relation-Theoretic Metrical Fixed Point Theorem for Rational Type Contraction Mapping with an Application, 2021, 10, 2075-1680, 316, 10.3390/axioms10040316
    5. Asik Hossain, Mohammad Arif, Salvatore Sessa, Qamrul Haque Khan, Nonlinear Relation-Theoretic Suzuki-Generalized Ćirić-Type Contractions and Application to Fractal Spaces, 2022, 6, 2504-3110, 711, 10.3390/fractalfract6120711
    6. Asik Hossain, Aftab Alam, Salvatore Sessa, Qamrul Haque Khan, Relation-Theoretic Weak Contractions and Applications, 2023, 11, 2227-7390, 1976, 10.3390/math11091976
    7. Doaa Filali, Faizan Ahmad Khan, Relation-Preserving Functional Contractions Involving a Triplet of Auxiliary Functions with an Application to Integral Equations, 2024, 16, 2073-8994, 691, 10.3390/sym16060691
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2024 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1748) PDF downloads(57) Cited by(0)

Figures and Tables

Figures(2)  /  Tables(5)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog