Research article Special Issues

Synthesis, characterization and quantitative analysis of porous metal microstructures: Application to microporous copper produced by solid state foaming

  • Porous metals can be created through a wide variety of processing techniques, and the pore morphology resulting from these processes is equally diverse. The structural and functional properties of metal foams are directly dependent on the size, shape, interconnectedness and volume fraction of pores, so accurately quantifying the pore characteristics is of great importance. Methods for analyzing porous materials are presented here and applied to a copper-based metallic foam generated through solid state foaming via oxide reduction and expansion. This process results in large voids (10s of microns) between sintered particles and small pores (10 microns to less than 50 nm) within particles. Optical and electron microscopy were used to image the porosity over this wide range, and the pore characteristics were quantified using image segmentation and statistical analysis. Two-dimensional pore analysis was performed using the Chan-Vese method, and two-point correlation and lineal path functions were used to assess three-dimensional reconstructions from FIB tomography. Two-dimensional analysis reveals distinct size and morphological differences in porosity between particles and within them. Three-dimensional analysis adds further information on the high level interconnectedness of the porosity and irregular shape it takes, forming tortuous pathways rather than spherical cells. Mechanical polishing and optical microscopy allow large areas to be created and analyzed quickly, but methods such as focused ion beam (FIB) sectioning can provide additional insight about microstructural features. In particular, after FIB milling is used to create a flat surface, that surface can be analyzed for structural and compositional information.

    Citation: Mark A. Atwater, Kris A. Darling, Mark A. Tschopp. Synthesis, characterization and quantitative analysis of porous metal microstructures: Application to microporous copper produced by solid state foaming[J]. AIMS Materials Science, 2016, 3(2): 573-590. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2016.2.573

    Related Papers:

    [1] An-Hsing Chang, Li-Kai Yang, Rua-Huan Tsaih, Shih-Kuei Lin . Machine learning and artificial neural networks to construct P2P lending credit-scoring model: A case using Lending Club data. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(2): 303-325. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022013
    [2] Tzu-Chien Wang . Deep Learning-Based Prediction and Revenue Optimization for Online Platform User Journeys. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(1): 1-28. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024001
    [3] Shagufta Henna, Shyam Krishnan Kalliadan, Mohamed Amjath . Optimizing B2B customer relationship management and sales forecasting with spectral graph convolutional networks: A quantitative approach. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2025, 9(2): 449-478. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2025015
    [4] David Alaminos, M. Belén Salas, Ángela M. Callejón-Gil . Managing extreme cryptocurrency volatility in algorithmic trading: EGARCH via genetic algorithms and neural networks. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(1): 153-209. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024007
    [5] Lukáš Pichl, Taisei Kaizoji . Volatility Analysis of Bitcoin Price Time Series. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2017, 1(4): 474-485. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2017.4.474
    [6] David Anderson, Urban Ulrych . Accelerated American option pricing with deep neural networks. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(2): 207-228. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023011
    [7] Larysa Dokiienko, Nataliya Hrynyuk, Igor Britchenko, Viktor Trynchuk, Valentyna Levchenko . Determinants of enterprise's financial security. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(1): 52-74. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024003
    [8] Andrea Ferrario, Massimo Guidolin, Manuela Pedio . Comparing in- and out-of-sample approaches to variance decomposition-based estimates of network connectedness an application to the Italian banking system. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(3): 661-701. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.3.661
    [9] Yonca Erdem Demirtaş, Neslihan Fidan Keçeci . The efficiency of private pension companies using dynamic data envelopment analysis. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(2): 204-219. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020009
    [10] Luís Miguel Marques, Flávio Morais, Zélia Serrasqueiro . How does society satisfaction affect the capital structure of firms? A two-part fractional regression approach. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2024, 8(2): 210-234. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2024008
  • Porous metals can be created through a wide variety of processing techniques, and the pore morphology resulting from these processes is equally diverse. The structural and functional properties of metal foams are directly dependent on the size, shape, interconnectedness and volume fraction of pores, so accurately quantifying the pore characteristics is of great importance. Methods for analyzing porous materials are presented here and applied to a copper-based metallic foam generated through solid state foaming via oxide reduction and expansion. This process results in large voids (10s of microns) between sintered particles and small pores (10 microns to less than 50 nm) within particles. Optical and electron microscopy were used to image the porosity over this wide range, and the pore characteristics were quantified using image segmentation and statistical analysis. Two-dimensional pore analysis was performed using the Chan-Vese method, and two-point correlation and lineal path functions were used to assess three-dimensional reconstructions from FIB tomography. Two-dimensional analysis reveals distinct size and morphological differences in porosity between particles and within them. Three-dimensional analysis adds further information on the high level interconnectedness of the porosity and irregular shape it takes, forming tortuous pathways rather than spherical cells. Mechanical polishing and optical microscopy allow large areas to be created and analyzed quickly, but methods such as focused ion beam (FIB) sectioning can provide additional insight about microstructural features. In particular, after FIB milling is used to create a flat surface, that surface can be analyzed for structural and compositional information.


    Cooperation can be found in many contexts and at many scales, both in nature and human societies, and can occur even between species [1,2]. Cooperation, defined as the giving up of individual reproductive success (fitness) to provide some fitness benefit to other individual(s), appears on the surface to be incompatible with Darwinian natural selection [3,4]. However, cooperative groups may have a higher average fitness than defective (or selfish) groups. Herein lies the paradox: how can cooperation, which once established is better for everyone, succeed in the face of individual incentive to defect?

    The emergence and fixation of cooperation has been explained through a number of mechanisms, including kin selection [5], reciprocity [6], reputation (indirect reciprocity) [7,8], cooperator recognition (green beards) [9], assortative encounter (direct or network-based)[10] and various forms of punishment [11,15,12,14], as well as more complex network effects [18,17,16].These mechanisms, though promoting cooperation, tend to foster higher levels of cooperation between members in the same local community, family group, or language group (in the case of indirect reciprocity). For example, network-based assortment allows clusters of cooperators to avoid contact with the rest of the population [19,20,21]. Indirect reciprocity works by letting players know each other's reputations; players choose whether to cooperate or defect based on whether the prospective player has cooperated or defected in previous interactions; reputation is more easily spread within members of the same language group. Direct reciprocity requires that players have a high probability of encountering one another again, while such repeated interactions are more likely within social groups. Kin selection allows levels of cooperation between individuals according to their relatedness [19]. Clearly, these mechanisms are not as effective at promoting cooperation between individuals which are genetically, spatially, or socially distant. Such mechanisms (or network configurations) are often associated with lower bounds on the benefit/cost ratio [19] for which cooperation can persist [22].

    Ever since the first diversification in life forms, the potential for conflict between different groups of individuals has been present. In systems with social structures or groupings, such as ant colonies or human societies, various degrees of cooperation and conflict occur. Consequently, groups are often separated by large distances or unsuitable terrains, so that conflict between groups can be intentionally or unintentionally reduced [23]. Unfortunately, this is not always the case.

    Humans are set apart in the sheer number of functional groups we form, such as companies, tribes and nations, and group divisions hold enormous influence in our everyday lives. Conflicts between groups have driven some of the most destructive patterns of human behavior, despite the fact that individuals within groups (who are in effect acting out the conflict) may not even want to support inter-group conflict [24]. Importantly, in most such cases, group membership is viscous but remains exchangeable (e.g. moving into another company or migrating to another country). In reality, the boundaries between groups can range from highly fluid (e.g. company employees) to nearly unbreachable (e.g. ethnic groups). Here we focus on the unbreachable end of this spectrum. While the contexts of inter-group conflicts vary, they share on the individual scale at least one common driver: people are more cooperative with members of their own groups. Studies in social psychology have shown that people are more trusting, more communicative, and less selfish when interacting with a member of a designated 'in-group' even when the group allocation is nothing more than a label given by experimenters [25]; these effects are stronger for pre-existing social identity groupings such as families, ethnic groups, and citizens of a country [26], and functional group identities such as corporate teams, school peer-groups, or neighborhood improvement organizations [27].

    A typical paradox of cooperation is the tragedy of the commons [28], in which a shared resource is vulnerable to over-use by unscrupulous individuals. This situation has been encoded mathematically in the form of the public goods game and its philosophically equivalent two-player game, the prisoner's dilemma [6]. While the prisoner's dilemma is a standard tool for explaining the evolution of cooperation, and represents the hardest problem to solve from a game theory perspective, empirical studies have suggested that many scenarios often characterized as prisoner's dilemmas may in fact be better classified as stag hunts, depending on the parameters involved [31,29,30]. The stag hunt represents a scenario where the players must cooperate to achieve a higher goal, such as hunting a stag, but may be assured of some lesser payoff if they choose to act alone, hunting hares instead [32]. A player in a stag hunt is better off 'defecting' (acting alone) if they expect that the other player will defect, but should cooperate if they expect that the other player will cooperate. The lack of consensus regarding which game best represents real social interactions is hardly surprising considering their enormous complexity. Our model lies somewhere between the camps of this dispute.

    Evolutionary game theory has looked at the problem of cooperation within and between recognizable groups (often referred to as 'groups with tags') through two broad lenses. One lens looks at the simultaneous evolution of group structure and cooperation [33,34,35], while the other looks at the evolutionary dynamics of identity, conflict and cooperation in the context of pre-existing groups [36,39,38,37]. Studies using spatial models have found that in the context of recognizable group divisions, ethnocentrism - cooperation within the group - dominates, followed by humanitarianism - cooperating regardless of group membership [33,40].

    The aim of this work is to develop a simple, tractable model of socio-economic power dynamics and cooperation in a system with two recognizable population groups. The generality of our model places it in an ideal position to be further developed in order to refine restrictive assumptions and address more specific scenarios. The rest of this paper is structured as follows. First, we describe the two social scenarios that we consider, each one a limiting case of certain real-life group dynamics. We then specify the rules governing the dynamics of the system, and analyze the resulting system of differential equations, focusing on conditions for cooperation and group coexistence.

    Our model describes the prevalence of cooperation within two distinct, recognizable groups and the relative socio-economic power of the two groups. People in the model ('players') engage in two-player games, in which each must choose whether to 'cooperate' (C) or 'defect' (D). Players can identify whether they are playing with a member of their own group ('within-group games') or the other group ('cross-group games'). We will focus on two scenarios concerning the difference between within-group and cross-group games.

    Payoffs in our model are in terms of socio-economic power, and group size represents the agammaegate socio-economic power of a group. 'Socio-economic power' may take the form of economic, social or cultural influence, and is used interchangeably with 'power'. These are connected in real societies by production and consumption of different sets of practical and artistic products. Our model assumes a ''well-mixed" population, in which encounter rates are determined by group-level socio-economic power and strategy prevalence in each group. In other words, the total socio-economic power of a group determines the rate at which players encounter players of that group.

    There is significant evidence to suggest that group membership is an important factor for establishing role-models, and within-group understanding facilitates the copying of successful strategies from fellow group members [41,24]. Following this line of reasoning, players in our model copy successful strategies that they observe being played by other members of their group. Group identities are distinguished by fixed, recognizable characteristics, so that players do not (rather, are unable to) switch groups. Groups shift in relative power due to payoffs, but this does not directly affect the prevalence of cooperators in either group.

    In the 'group cohesion' scenario, the payoffs for mutual cooperation within a group are enhanced (see Table 1). This reflects the evidence that members of the same group are able to communicate more effectively with one another and trust each other more [25]. Many real-life groups have institutions (formal or social) which support initiatives of the group, punish defectors in the group (thus lowering the effective benefit of defection) or support victims of defection from within the group (thus lowering effective cost of cooperation when the other player defects). We incorporate these into a net enhancement of the payoffs for mutual cooperation within the group, though the magnitude can differ between groups.

    Table 1.  Payoffs for a player of group i choosing the row strategy in cross-group games (left) and within-group games (right), where $ \alpha_i > 1 $ is the cohesiveness of group i, and $ b > c > 0 $. Notice that when $ \alpha_i > \frac{b}{b-c} $ the within-group game becomes a stag hunt for group i.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    Almost every real system has at least some of these properties. This scenario is particularly well-suited to systems in which different groups speak different languages and/or have very different cultural norms, and in which social support is provided primarily by fellow group members. We summarize these effects in a parameter $ \alpha_i > 1 $ we call 'cohesiveness' (see Table 1). Note that cooperators need not act the same way with co-players from a different group and in general cooperate less in cross-group games due to prejudice (see sub-section 2.3).

    In the 'inter-dependence' scenario, the payoffs of cross-group cooperation are enhanced (see Table 2). This reflects the fact that in many situations with two groups, each group has something uniquely valuable to offer, though the enhancement to cooperation may not be the same for both groups. This manifests itself in traditional family dynamics (with complementary though unequal roles for men and women), as well as the current trends of inter-disciplinary research teams and multi-cultural offices of leading technology companies. Studies on group identity have shown that people tend to punish defecting members of their own group less, leading to a higher relative payoff of defection [42,24]. These are just a few examples of factors that would contribute to increased payoffs for cross-group cooperation. A group's $ \alpha_i $-value in the inter-dependence scenario is referred to as the group's 'privilege'.

    Table 2.  Payoffs for a player of group i choosing the row strategy in cross-group games (left) and within-group games (right), where $ \alpha_{i} > 1 $ is the privilege of group i and $ b > c > 0 $. Notice that when $ \alpha_i > \frac{b}{b-c} $ the cross-group game becomes a stag hunt for group i.

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    The regions of applicability of the two scenarios are of course not entirely disjoint. We analyze them separately to get a better understanding of the dynamics implied by each. In either case, the enhanced cooperation can shift the within-group or cross-group interactions from a prisoner's dilemma, where defection is always favored, to a stag hunt.

    Each group consists of 'cooperators' and 'defectors'. Cooperators always cooperate in within-group games and cooperate in cross-group games with probability $ 0 < \beta_i \leq 1 $ (for group i). We refer at times to $ \beta $-values (trust), but also to prejudice levels $ = 1-\beta_{i} $. Defectors always defect. The strategy-update rule is as follows. Players compare their expected payoffs from a single round to the average payoffs of other players in their group. If the average payoff of other players is larger, they update their strategy with a probability proportional to the difference in payoffs between themselves and the average payoff, otherwise they keep playing the same strategy. The rate of change in frequency of strategists* in each group under the strategy update rule is given by the replicator equations[10,43]:

    *For the sake of simplicity we describe the within-group dynamics as strategy dynamics, but based on our rule for encounter rates the within-group dynamics could also describe pure power dynamics with no strategy update, or a mixture of strategy update and power dynamics.

    $ ˙n1C=n1C(P1C¯P1)
    $
    (2.1)
    $ ˙n1D=n1D(P1D¯P1)
    $
    (2.2)
    $ ˙n2C=n2C(P2C¯P2)
    $
    (2.3)
    $ ˙n2D=n2D(P2D¯P2),
    $
    (2.4)

    where $ n_{iS} $ represents the frequency of players in group $ i $ playing strategy $ S $ in within-group games, while $ P_{iS} $ denotes the expected payoff of those players (e.g. $ P_{2D} $ is the expected payoff of group 2 defectors). Note that the frequencies above are within each group, so that $ n_{1C}+n_{1D} = n_{2C}+n_{2D} = 1 $. The expected payoffs of each group are given by $ \bar{P_1} = n_{1C} P_{1C} + n_{1D} P_{1D} $ and $ \bar{P_2} = n_{2C} P_{2C}+n_{2D}P_{2D} $ [22]. Changes in socio-economic power are governed by the replicator equations:

    $ ˙n1=n1(¯P1ˉP)
    $
    (2.5)
    $ ˙n2=n2(¯P2ˉP),
    $
    (2.6)

    where $ n_1 $ and $ n_2 $ denote the share (or prevalence) of socio-economic power wielded by group 1 and group 2 respectively; $ n_1+n_2 = 1 $, and we set $ \bar{P} = n_1 \bar{P_1} + n_2 \bar{P_2} $. Notice that the distribution of socio-economic power $ n_i $ (due to its effect on encounter rates) as well as the levels of cooperation in either group determine the expected payoffs at both the strategy ($ P_{iS} $) and actually also at the population ($ \bar{P_i} $) level (see next section).

    Note that the definition of the state variables as relative frequencies (and the corresponding form of the replicator equations) allow us to define the system using just three equations and three variables. The state of the system can be specified by a three-tuple $ (n_{1C}, n_{2C}, n_1) $ and the dynamics of the system are defined by Eqs 2.1, 2.3 and 2.5.

    The results of a preliminary analysis in which we assume a separation of timescales between strategy-update dynamics (Eqs 2.1, 2.3) and group-power dynamics (Eq 2.5) are displayed in Table 3 (see Appendix for details).

    Table 3.  Summary of conditions for cooperation and coexistence. The first two rows show results when we assume separate timescales for strategy (Eqs 2.1, 2.3) and group dynamics (Eq 2.5), while the third row shows results for the full system. Note that there exist equivalent requirements, symmetric with respect to group indices, which for the sake of brevity we have not listed here. The condition without group indices (third row second column) is derived for groups with equal prejudice and privilege ($ \beta_1 = \beta_2 = \beta $ and $ \alpha_1 = \alpha_2 = \alpha $).
    Group Cohesion Scenario Inter-dependence Scenario
    Strategy Dynamics (cooperation) $ \frac{n_1(\alpha_1 -1)}{\beta_1 n_2 + n_1 \alpha_1} b > c $ $ \frac{(\alpha_1 -1)\beta_1 \beta_2 n_2}{n_1 + \beta_2(1+\beta_1) n_2} b > c $
    Group Dynamics (Coexistence) $ \frac{\alpha_2 - \beta_2}{\alpha_2 - \beta_1} b < c $ $ \frac{\beta_1 \beta_2 (\alpha_2 - 1) - (1-\beta_1) }{\beta_1 \beta_2 (\alpha_2 - 1) - (1-\beta_2)} b > c $
    Cooperation and Coexistence Not attainable $ \alpha > 1 + \frac{1 - \beta}{\beta^2} $ and $ \frac{(\alpha - 1)\beta ^2}{1 + \beta + \beta^2 (\alpha - 1)}b > c $

     | Show Table
    DownLoad: CSV

    We focus here on the three dimensional 'full system', with no separation of timescales. We solve the system of replicator equations to find fixed points of the system. We analyze the stability of the fixed points analytically where possible. In the non-symmetric case ($ \alpha_1 \neq \alpha_2 $ and/or $ \beta_1 \neq \beta_2 $), this is not possible for all fixed points, so we explore the system numerically. Notice that by model construction if both groups are fully defective the distinction between the two groups becomes irrelevant (i.e. there is a line of trivial attractors, see Figures 1, 2).

    Figure 1.  Representative trajectories of the symmetric group cohesion scenario, with $ \alpha_1 = \alpha_2 = 5 $, $ \beta_1 = \beta_2 = 0.7 $, $ b = 2 $, $ c = 0.5 $. Blue dots and thick lines represent stable fixed points, green diamonds represent saddle points and crosses represent unstable fixed points.
    Figure 2.  Fixed points and their stability for various parameter settings in the inter-dependence scenario. Blue dot and thick lines represent stable fixed points, green diamonds represent saddle points and crosses mark unstable fixed points. $ b = 3 $ and $ c = 1 $.

    Based on the payoff structure for the group cohesion scenario, in which the payoffs for within-group cooperation are enhanced (Table 1), we calculate the expected payoffs of group 1 cooperators, group 1 defectors, group 2 cooperators and group 2 defectors:

    The expected payoffs for defectors are the same in both scenarios so are not repeated in the next section.

    $ P1C=n1(n1Cα1(bc)+n1D(c))+n2(n2C(β1β2(bc)+β1(1β2)(c)+(1β1)β2b)+n2Dβ1(c))
    $
    (3.1)
    $ P1D=n1n1Cb+n2n2Cβ2b
    $
    (3.2)
    $ P2C=n2(n2Cα2(bc)+n2D(c))+n1(n1C(β1β2(bc)+β1(1β2)b+(1β1)β2(c))+n1Dβ2(c))
    $
    (3.3)
    $ P2D=n2n2Cb+n1n1Cβ1b.
    $
    (3.4)

    Each term in the expected payoffs represents the probability of a certain type of encounter, multiplied by its payoff for the subject player. For example, the $ n_2 n_{2C} \beta_1 \beta_2 (b-c) $ term in $ P_{1C} $ is the probability that a given group 1 cooperator will encounter a group 2 cooperator ($ n_2 n_{2C} $) multiplied by the probability that both players cooperate ($ \beta_1 \beta_2 $), multiplied by the payoff for the group 1 cooperator when both players cooperate $ (b-c) $. The $ \alpha_i $ values appear in the terms corresponding to within-group cooperation.

    We then substitute these values into the replicator Eqs 2.1, 2.3 and 2.5. We find the fixed points of the system by setting Eqs 2.1, 2.3, 2.5 to zero and solving for $ n_{1C} $, $ n_{2C} $ and $ n_{1} $. We use the Jacobian eigenvalues and eigenvectors to classify the local stability of each fixed point.

    There are 19 analytic solutions to the resulting system of equations. Of these solutions, two correspond to a negative share of power for one group and are discarded. 11 of the 17 realistic solutions do not correspond to the extinction (complete loss of socio-economic power) of one of the groups.

    We find that cooperation with group coexistence is not possible. The cooperation and coexistence equilibrium is a saddle point, while the only two non-trivial attractors of the system occur when there is one group dominating and cooperating, and one group extinct and defecting. In symmetric games, while high levels of group cohesion ($ \alpha $) allow one group to become cooperative, it is inevitably at the expense of eliminating the other group. More prejudiced groups (small $ \beta $-values) are more likely to dominate. Initial advantage, however, moves each group's threshold of cooperation according to the ratio of the other group's initial power to its own, while an increase in prejudice (decrease in $ \beta $) corresponds to a linear decrease of the cooperation threshold.

    We continue our exploration by examining a few particular cases. In all cases we set $ b = 2 $ and $ c = 0.5 $. We begin with a group-symmetric model, setting $ \alpha_1 = \alpha_2 $, $ \beta_1 = \beta_2 $. The initially more powerful group dominates, after which the losing group moves gradually towards defection (Figure 1). We then break the symmetry of the system to examine the context in which one group has strong within-group cohesiveness and high levels of prejudice, but the results do not differ qualitatively from those of the symmetric case; the basin of attraction for dominance of a group increases as it gets relatively stronger and more prejudiced (high $ \alpha_i $ and low $ \beta_i $). Thus, in the group cohesion scenario, only one group will dominate and cooperate, while the other will lose all of its power and defect.

    We now examine the scenario in which cooperation between groups has enhanced payoffs, while within-group game has the payoff structure of the standard prisoner's dilemma (Table 2). Following the same procedure, we calculate the expected payoffs of group 1 cooperators and group 2 cooperators:

    Payoffs for defectors are still given by Eqs 3.2 and 3.4

    $ P1C=n1(n1C(bc)+n1D(c))+n2(n2C(β1β2α1(bc)+β1(1β2)(c)+(1β1)β2b)+n2Dβ1(c))P2C=n2(n2C(bc)+n2D(c))+n1(n1C(β1β2α2(bc)+β1(1β2)b+(1β1)β2(c))+n1Dβ2(c)),
    $

    and substitute these values into the replicator Eqs 2.1, 2.3 and 2.5.

    The system has 15 fixed points, two of which correspond to negative group power. Seven fixed points correspond to extinction of one group. Interestingly, none of these are asymptotically stable. There are fixed points where one group cooperates while the other defects and goes extinct, but the inter-dependence means that the cooperation of the dominating group is not stable. The defection of the extinct group is unstable if (for group 2 defecting and extinct) $ \beta_1 (\alpha_2 - 1)(b-c) > c $. This and its group-symmetric equivalent (obtained by swapping group indices) are in fact the conditions for the stability of cooperation (or instability of defection) of the extinct group at all the extinction fixed points. The fact that dominant groups have unstable cooperation while extinct groups may have stable cooperation agrees qualitatively with existing results using density-dependent replicator dynamics [4,22].

    Fixed points where one group cooperates while the other defects, but both coexist, enter the system when both $ \beta_i < \frac{b-c}{b} $. These points are however always unstable in at least one direction. Stability would require, for example, that $ \frac{b-c}{\beta_2}-b < -\beta_1 c - \beta_1 \beta_2 (\alpha_1 -1)(b-c) $, which cannot be satisfied with allowed parameter values while the point is in the positive unit cube.

    A full-cooperation fixed point occurs at

    $ n_1 = \frac{b(\beta_2-1) - c(\beta_1 -1) + \beta_1 \beta_2 (b-c)(\alpha_1 - 1) }{(b - c)(\beta_1 + \beta_2 - 2 + \beta_1 \beta_2 (\alpha_1 + \alpha_2 -2))}. $

    When the system is symmetrical ($ \alpha_1 = \alpha_2 = \alpha $ and $ \beta_1 = \beta_2 = \beta $) the full-cooperation fixed point is stable if $ -(b-c)(\beta + \alpha \beta^2 - \beta^2 -1) < 0 $ and $ c(1+\beta) - \beta^2(b-c)(\alpha-1) < 0 $. Together these lead to the conditions: $ \alpha > 1+ \frac{1-\beta}{\beta^2} $ for stability in strategy dynamics and $ \alpha > 1+ \frac{c(1+\beta)}{(b-c)\beta^2} $ for stability in group power dynamics. The second condition is usually harder to reach, but for large $ (b-c) $ and high $ \beta $ it may be achieved with lower $ \alpha $. The stability of cooperative coexistence depends approximately hyperbolically on prejudice ($ 1-\beta $).

    Unfortunately the analytic forms of the eigenvalues of the full-cooperation fixed point are prohibitively complicated in the non-symmetrical case, but a scan of parameter space assures us that the full-cooperation fixed point can remain stable with non-symmetric parameter values, provided $ \alpha_i $ and $ \beta_i $ values are large enough; stability of full-cooperation is much more sensitive to $ \beta_i $ values, as in the separated-timescales analysis (Figure 2).

    We modeled the shifts of socio-economic power in a system with two recognizable groups interacting with prejudice. We considered two scenarios: in the group cohesion scenario players received increased payoffs for within-group cooperation, while in the inter-dependence scenario players received increased payoffs for cooperating with members of the other group.

    As might be expected, our analysis suggests very different results for the two scenarios. The results for the group cohesion scenario paint a grim picture: while high levels of group cohesion ($ \alpha $) allow one group to become cooperative, it is inevitably at the expense of eliminating the other group. More prejudiced groups (small $ \beta $-values) are more likely to dominate. Initial advantage, however, moves each group's threshold of cooperation according to the ratio of the other group's initial power to its own, while an increase in prejudice (decrease in trust $ \beta $) corresponds to a linear decrease of the cooperation threshold.

    The inter-dependence scenario allows stable coexistence of the two groups, but is highly sensitive to prejudice. Even relatively small increases in prejudice (decreases in trust $ \beta $) may necessitate large increases in privilege ($ \alpha $) in order to maintain stable coexistence. Provided prejudice is controlled, stable coexistence can be maintained even with high privilege difference (e.g. $ \alpha_1 > > \alpha_2 $). Hence we observe that in the context of our model, for cooperative coexistence, prejudice plays a stronger role than privilege.

    Our work provides a number of suggestions for successful reconciliation and reduction of inequality. Two results stand out: the first is that members of opposite groups should have some incentive to cooperate with one another, and cross-group cooperation must be highly productive, particularly when mutual trust is low (prejudice levels are high). The second is that even moderate levels of prejudice necessitate large incentives, while low levels of prejudice allow cooperation even with modest incentives and inequality.

    Organizations working to foster cross-group cooperation should note that that initiatives to increase trust (reduce prejudice) may be needed in order to make a difference; prejudice reduction in high-prejudice contexts is likely to be much more cost effective than direct subsidy of cross-group cooperation. If for example a government were to consider subsidizing multi-group businesses, our model would suggest that this would be effective only when prejudice levels are already reasonably low.

    In multi-ethnic societies, affirmative action is sometimes enacted to facilitate economic upliftment of underprivileged groups through integration into sectors of the economy mostly dominated by privileged groups [44]. This in the context of our model can be thought of as incentivizing cross-group cooperation. Despite its significant successes, the practical implementation of affirmative action has come under criticism for its narrow scope of impact and for perpetuating racialist dynamics [44,46,45]. Our model would suggest that affirmative action cannot efficiently drive broad social transformation while prejudice levels remain high, and while different ethnic groups are unable to effectively communicate (necessary for productive cross-group cooperation). In this regard our model agrees qualitatively with other theorists who have suggested that improving mutual language literacy between groups would increase the possibilities for productive cross-group cooperation, and thus move the society toward higher levels of cooperative coexistence [47,48]. These interpretations should not be taken as scientific comments on social issues, but rather as food for thought and inspiration for deeper investigations.

    Our model differs from other models of dynamics between recognizable groups in a number of ways. Firstly we assume two discrete recognizable groups, rather than continuous traits [40,49]. The heterogeneity within groups is limited to strategy choice, so we do not address issues of adoption or rejection of group identity within groups (eg self-racialisation and assimilation in [36] or ethnocentric vs humanitarian in [50]). Thirdly, in our model the two groups exist a priori, and players do not change groups (Eqs 2.1–2.4).

    Of particular interest to this work is the theory of green beards (so dubbed by Dawkins [51]), which explores the potential for cooperation to emerge amongst bearers of a recognizable set of genes. Bearers of green beard genes (green beards) have a tendency to treat other green beards differently from non-green beards, for example by cooperating only with fellow green beards and thus reducing their chances of cooperating with a defector (see [52,53]).

    The model proposed in this paper is intentionally simple, paving the way for a number of natural extensions, many of which could be combined. Assortative encounter could increase the amount of within-group interactions, or could increase the probability that cooperators encounter other cooperators (the usual assumption), with a stronger effect for within-group encounters. The second obvious step would be to include changing prejudice, for example using adaptive dynamics [54], and to relate this to the group-level assortment (more prejudiced people avoid the other group). Real processes are constantly co-evolving, and this type of thinking could be incorporated into many aspects of the model and extensions (see [55] for a recent review).

    The effect of population size could be incorporated; while models involving finite populations and stochasticity are more realistic they preclude certain useful analyses and converge to infinite-population models under a range of assumptions [19]. Density-dependent selection, as opposed to frequency dependent selection, may be a more relevant modification to the population structure of our model, where the size of the economy along with opportunities for economic, social and artistic innovation and development take the place of the carrying capacity in traditional ecological models [4,22]. Another layer of realism could be captured by incorporating different payoffs for strategy update than for power transfer, allowing for the inclusion of perception of benefit based on group membership.

    These extensions - some of which would implicitly emerge - could then be studied in the context of networks of interacting agents, opening new and interesting avenues for research [56]. Networks naturally support the incorporation of complex and varied strategy-update rules [16], variability in the individual tendencies to separately assimilate and reproduce social norms [57], and form a natural bridge to methods of statistical physics [17]. A significant step towards reality is made with the consideration of complex self-forming social network structures [58]: the list of phenomena which might emerge is near-endless, particularly with complex individual rules for the development of the network [16]. As well as providing extraordinary flexibility, evolutionary game theory on networks has displayed a variety of realistic features including criticality [59], spatial chaos [60], self-organized punishment and rewarding, and territorial competition [17]. Most extensions would however mean sacrificing the analytic tractability of results.

    We suggest that those interested in empirical work related to this model look to social media and other online interaction spaces - news site comment sections, forums, etc. - for data. Automated data collection (web crawlers) could be used along with classification techniques to identify sentiments and group membership within such environments - for example the comments, likes, views and endorsements of beauty bloggers on youtube - and observe the progression of these behaviors. Government surveys could also provide valuable data for analysis with a more economic emphasis. A number of experimental methods for the calibration and evaluation of cooperation models have recently been proposed, including accessible and scalable online alternatives to traditional experiments [61,62,63].

    We described a socio-economic system of two recognizable groups in two hypothetical scenarios. In the group cohesion scenario, people benefit most from cooperating within their group, while in the inter-dependence scenario cross-group cooperation is more productive. We found that in the group cohesion scenario, one group always dominates the other. In the inter-dependence scenario the groups can both cooperate, even with high inequality, but only if they have low prejudice levels.

    The relevance of cooperation between groups is clear in many societies worldwide. Models such as ours may yield insights into the complex dynamics that govern the course of society, and should be developed with the aim of overcoming the barriers inherent to coexistence of multiple groups.

    Our findings suggest that, while equitable distribution of the benefits from cooperative behavior plays an important role, organizations working towards improving inter-group relations should focus first on increasing group inter-dependence and reducing prejudice.

    The authors are grateful to the editorial team for the opportunity to contribute to this special issue, and to the four anonymous reviewers for sharing their time and expertise. P.L. and C.H. acknowledge support from the National Research Foundation (NRF) of South Africa (grant nos. 89967, 109244 and 109683). J.B. acknowledges support from the National Research Foundation (NRF) of South Africa, the African Institute for Mathematical Sciences (AIMS) South Africa and the Southern African Center for Epidemiological Modeling and Analysis (SACEMA).

    All authors declare no conflicts of interest in this paper.

    [1] Banhart J (2001) Manufacture, characterisation and application of cellular metals and metal foams. Prog Mater Sci 46: 559–632. doi: 10.1016/S0079-6425(00)00002-5
    [2] Banhart J (2013) Light-Metal Foams - History of Innovation and Technological Challenges. Adv Eng Mater15: 82–111.
    [3] Ashby MF, Evans AG, Fleck NA, et al. (2000) Metal Foams: A Design Guide. Boston: Butterworth-Heineman.
    [4] Lefebvre L-P, Banhart J, Dunand DC (2008) Porous Metals and Metallic Foams: Current Status and Recent Developments. Adv Eng Mater 10: 775–787. doi: 10.1002/adem.200800241
    [5] Ashby MF, Tianjian LU (2003) Metal foams: A survey. Science In China (Series B) 46: 521–532. doi: 10.1360/02yb0203
    [6] Banhart J (2007) Metal Foams - from Fundamental Research to Applications. In: Raj B, Ranganathan S, Rao KBS, Matthew MD, Shankar P, eds. Frontiers in the Design of Materials: Universities Press (India).
    [7] Banhart J (2006) Metal Foams: Production and Stability. Adv Eng Mater 8:781–794.
    [8] Ashby MF (1983) Mechnical properties of cellular solids. Metallurgical Transactions A 14A: 1755–1769.
    [9] Davies GJ, Zhen S (1983) Metallic foams: their production, properties and applications. J Mater Sci 18: 1899–1911.
    [10] Garcia-Avila M, Rabiei A (2015) Effect of Sphere Properties on Microstructure and Mechanical Performance of Cast Composite Metal Foams. Metals 5: 822–835.
    [11] Shin H-C, Dong J, Liu M (2003) Nanoporous Structures Prepared by an Electrochemical Deposition Process. Adv Mater 15:1610–1614.
    [12] Shin H-C, Liu M (2004) Copper Foam Structures with Highly Porous Nanostructured Walls. Chem Mater 16: 5460–5464. doi: 10.1021/cm048887b
    [13] Nam D, Kim R, Han D, et al. (2011) Effects of (NH4)2SO4 and BTA on the nanostructure of copper foam prepared by electrodeposition. Electrochim Acta 56: 9397–9405. doi: 10.1016/j.electacta.2011.08.025
    [14] Kim JH, Kim RH, Kwon HS (2008) Preparation of copper foam with 3-dimensionally interconnected spherical pore network by electrodeposition. Electrochemistry Communications 10: 1148–1151. doi: 10.1016/j.elecom.2008.05.035
    [15] Kennedy A (2012) Porous Metals and Metal Foams Made from Powders. In: Kondoh K, ed. Powder Metallurgy Rijeka,Croatia InTech.
    [16] Torres Y, Pavón JJ, Rodríguez JA (2012) Processing and characterization of porous titanium for implants by using NaCl as space holder. J Mater Process Tech 212: 1061–1069. doi: 10.1016/j.jmatprotec.2011.12.015
    [17] Wenjuan N, Chenguang B, GuiBao Q, et al. (2009) Processing and properties of porous titanium using space holder technique. Mater Sci Eng A 506: 148–151. doi: 10.1016/j.msea.2008.11.022
    [18] Xie S, Evans JRG (2004) High porosity copper foam. J Mater Sci 39: 5877–5880.
    [19] Torres Y, Lascano S, Bris J, et al. (2014) Development of porous titanium for biomedical applications: A comparison between loose sintering and space-holder techniques. Mat Sci Eng C 37: 148–155.
    [20] Laptev A, Bram M, Buchkremer HP, et al. (2004) Study of production route for titanium parts combining very high porosity and complex shape. Powder Metallurgy 47: 85–92. doi: 10.1179/003258904225015536
    [21] Paserin V, Marcuson S, Shu J, et al. (2004) CVD technique for Inco nickel foam production. Adv Eng Mater 6: 454–459. doi: 10.1002/adem.200405142
    [22] Hodge AM, Biener J, Hsiung LL, et al. (2005) Monolithic nanocrystalline Au fabricated by the compaction of nanoscale foam. J Mater Res 20: 554–557.
    [23] Tai MC, Gentle A, Silva KSBd, et al. (2015) Thermal Stability of Nanoporous Raney Gold Catalyst. Metals 5: 1197–1211.
    [24] Lin B, Kong L, Hodgson PD, et al. (2014) Impact of the De-Alloying Kinetics and Alloy Microstructure on the Final Morphology of De-Alloyed Meso-Porous Metal Films. Nanomaterials 4: 856–878.
    [25] Davis NG, Teisen J, Schuh C, et al. (2001) Solid-state foaming of titanium by superplastic expansion of argon-filled pores. J Mater Res 16: 1508–1519.
    [26] Dunand DC. (2004) Processing of Titanium Foams. Adv Eng Mater 6: 369–376.
    [27] Elzey DM, Wadley HNG (2001) The Limits Of Solid State Foaming. Acta Mater 49: 849–859.
    [28] Kearns MW (1987) inventor Formation of Porous Bodies patent 4,659,546.
    [29] Oppenheimer S, Dunand DC (2010) Solid-state foaming of Ti–6Al–4V by creep or superplastic expansion of argon-filled pores. Acta Mater 58: 4387–4397.
    [30] Li H, Oppenheimer SM, Stupp SI, et al. (2004) Effects of Pore Morphology and Bone Ingrowth on Mechanical Properties of Microporous Titanium as an Orthopaedic Implant Material. Mater T JIM 45: 1124–1131. doi: 10.2320/matertrans.45.1124
    [31] Atwater MA, Darling KA, Tschopp MA (2016) Solid-State Foaming by Oxide Reduction and Expansion: Tailoring the Foamed Metal Microstructure in the Cu–CuO System with Oxide Content and Annealing Conditions. Adv Eng Mater 18: 83–95.
    [32] Atwater MA, Darling KA, Tschopp MA (2014) Towards Reaching the Theoretical Limit of Porosity in Solid State Metal Foams: Intraparticle Expansion as a Primary and Additive Means to Create Porosity. Adv Eng Mater 16: 190–195. doi: 10.1002/adem.201300431
    [33] Caselles V, Kimmel R, Sapiro G (1997) Geodesic active contours. Int J Comput Vision 22: 61–79. doi: 10.1023/A:1007979827043
    [34] Whitaker RT (1998) A level-set approach to 3d reconstruction from range data. Int J Comput Vision 29: 203–231. doi: 10.1023/A:1008036829907
    [35] Chan TF, Vese LA (2001) Active contours without edges. IEEE T Image Process 10: 266–277.
    [36] Samuels LE (2003) Metallographic Polishing by Mechanical Methods. 4th ed. Materials Park, OH: ASM International.
    [37] Mingard KP, Jones HG, Gee MG (2013) Metrological challenges for reconstruction of 3-D microstructures by focused ion beam tomography methods. J Microsc 253: 93–108.
    [38] Volkert CA, Minor AM (2007) Focused Ion Beam Microscopy and Micromachining. MRS Bull 32: 389–395. doi: 10.1557/mrs2007.62
    [39] Suryanarayana C, Ivanob E, Boldyrev VV. (2001) The science and technology of mechanical alloying. Mater Sci Eng A 304–306:151–158.
    [40] Suryanarayana C (2001) Mechanical alloying and milling. Prog Mater Sci 46:1–184.
    [41] Suryanarayana C, Koch CC (2000) Nanocrystalline materials – Current research and future directions. Hyperfine Interact 130:5–44.
    [42] Koch CC (1989) Materials synthesis by mechanical alloying. Annu Rev Mater Sci 19: 121–143
    [43] Koch CC (1993) The synthesis and structure of nanocrystalline materials produced by mechanical attrition: A review. Nanostruct Mater 2: 109–129.
    [44] Koch CC, Cho YS (1992) Nanocrystals by high energy ball milling. Nanostruct Mater 1: 207–212. doi: 10.1016/0965-9773(92)90096-G
    [45] Lü L, Lai MO (1998) Mechanical alloying. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
    [46] Krill CE, Klein R, Janes S, et al. (1995) Thermodynamic stabilization of grain boundaries in nanocrystalline alloys. Mater Sci Forum 181: 443–448.
    [47] Koch CC, Scattergood RO, Darling KA, et al. (2008) Stabilization of nanocrystalline grain sizes by solute additions. J Mater Sci 43: 7264–7272.
    [48] Trelewicz JR, Schuh CA (2009) Grain boundary segregation and thermodynamically stable binary nanocrystalline alloys. Phys Rev B 79:1–13.
    [49] Li J, Wang J, Yang G (2009) On the stagnation of grain growth in nanocrystalline materials. Scripta Mater 60: 945–948. doi: 10.1016/j.scriptamat.2009.02.015
    [50] Rajgarhia RK, Saxena A, Spearot DE, et al. (2010) Microstructural stability of copper with anitmony dopants at grain boundaries: experiments and molecular dynamics simulations. J Mater Sci 45: 6707–6718. doi: 10.1007/s10853-010-4764-1
    [51] Rajgarhia RK, Spearot DE, Saxena A (2010) Plastic deformation of nanocrystalline copper-antimony alloys. J Mater Res 25: 411–421. doi: 10.1557/JMR.2010.0072
    [52] Rajgarhia RK, Spearot DE, Saxena A. (2010) Behavior of dopant-modified interfaces in metallic nanocrystalline materials. JOM 62: 70–74.
    [53] Atwater MA, Mula S, Scattergood RO, et al. (2013) Thermal Stability of Nanocrystalline Copper Alloyed with Antimony. Metall Mater Trans A 44: 5611–5616.
    [54] Liu XJ, Wang CP, Ohnuma I, et al. (2000) Thermodynamic assessment of the phase diagrams of the Cu-Sb and Sb-Zn systems. J Phase Equilib 21: 432–442. doi: 10.1361/105497100770339608
    [55] MSIT®, Bätzner C, Ferro R, et al. (2007) Cu-Sb-Zn (Copper-Antimony-Zinc). In: Ilyenko GES, ed. Non-Ferrous Metal Ternary Systems Selected Copper Systems: Phase Diagrams, Crystallographic and Thermodynamic Data: Springer-Verlag.
    [56] Banhart J, Baumeister J (1998) Production Methods for Metallic Foams. MRS Proceedings 521.
    [57] Murray NGD, Dunand DC. (2003) Microstructure evolution during solid-state foaming of titanium. Compos Sci Technol 63: 2311–2316.
    [58] Zhang Z, Wang Y, Qi Z, et al. (2009) Generalized Fabrication of Nanoporous Metals (Au, Pd, Pt, Ag, and Cu) through Chemical Dealloying. J Phys Chem C 113: 12629–12636. doi: 10.1021/jp811445a
    [59] Cheng I-C, Hodge A (2013) Strength scale behavior of nanoporous Ag, Pd and Cu foams. Scripta Mater 69: 295–298. doi: 10.1016/j.scriptamat.2013.04.023
    [60] Liu R, Antoniou A (2012) A relation between relative density, alloy composition and sample shrinkage for nanoporous metal foams. Scripta Mater 67: 923–926. doi: 10.1016/j.scriptamat.2012.07.046
    [61] Spowart JE (2006) Automated serial sectioning for 3-D analysis of microstructures. Scripta Mater 55: 5–10. doi: 10.1016/j.scriptamat.2006.01.019
    [62] Bart-Smith H, Bastawros A-F, Mumm DR, et al. (1998) Compressive deformation and yielding mechanisms in cellular Al alloys determined using X-ray tomography and surface strain mapping. Acta Mater 46: 3583–3592. doi: 10.1016/S1359-6454(98)00025-1
    [63] Maire E (2012) X-Ray Tomography Applied to the Characterization of Highly Porous Materials. Ann Rev Mater Res 42: 163–178.
    [64] Rack A, Haibel A, Bütow A, et al. Characterization of Metal Foams with Synchrotron Tomography and 3D Image Analysis. 16th World Conference on Nondestructive Testing.
    [65] Elmoutaouakkil A, Salvo L, Maire E, et al. (2002) 2D and 3D Characterization of Metal Foams Using X-ray Tomography. Adv Eng Mater 4: 803–807.
    [66] Midgley PA, Weyland M, Yates TJV, et al. (2006) Nanoscale scanning transmission electron tomography. J Microsc 223: 185–190.
    [67] Rösner H, Parida S, Kramer D, et al. (2007) Reconstructing aNanoporousMetal in Three Dimensions: An Electron Tomography Study of Dealloyed Gold Leaf. Adv Eng Mater 9: 535–541.
    [68] Tschopp MA, Darling KA, Atwater MA (2014) Surpassing the Theoretical Limit of Porosity in Conventional Solid-State Foaming: Microstructure Characterization of Length Scales in a Copper Metal Foam. Army Research Laboratory, ARL-TR-7139.
    [69] VanLeeuwen BK, Darling KA, Koch CC, et al. (2011) Novel technique for the synthesis of ultra-fine porosity metal foam via the inclusion of condensed argon through cryogenic mechanical alloying. Mater Sci Eng A 528: 2192–2195. doi: 10.1016/j.msea.2010.11.057
    [70] Vázquez M, Moore D, He X, et al. (2014) Focussed ion beam serial sectioning and imaging of monolithic materials for 3D reconstruction and morphological parameter evaluation. Analyst 139: 99–104.
    [71] Xu W, Ferry M, Mateescu N, et al. (2007) Techniques for generating 3-D EBSD microstructures by FIB tomography. Mater Charact 58: 961–967. doi: 10.1016/j.matchar.2006.10.001
    [72] Kubis AJ, Shiflet GJ, Dunn DN, et al. (2004) Focused Ion-Beam Tomography. Metall Mater Trans A 35:1935–1943. doi: 10.1007/s11661-004-0142-4
    [73] Yazzie KE, Williams JJ, Phillips NC, et al. (2012) Multiscale microstructural characterization of Sn-rich alloys by three dimensional (3D) X-ray synchrotron tomography and focused ion beam (FIB) tomography. Mater Charact 70: 33–41.
    [74] Vivet N, Chupin S, Estrade E, et al. (2011) 3D Microstructural characterization of a solid oxide fuel cell anode reconstructedby focused ion beam tomography. J Power Sources 196: 7541–7549.
    [75] Nagasekhar AV, Cáceres CH, Kong C (2010) 3D characterization of intermetallics in a high pressure die cast Mg alloy using focused ion beam tomography. Mater Charact 61: 1035–1042.
    [76] West GD, Thomson RC (2009) Combined EBSD/EDS tomography in a dual-beam FIB/FEG–SEM. J Microsc 233: 442–450.
    [77] Winter DAMd, Schneidenberg CTWM, Lebbink MN, et al. (2009) Tomography of insulating biological and geological materials using focused ion beam (FIB) sectioning and low-kV BSE imaging. J Microsc 233: 372–383 doi: 10.1111/j.1365-2818.2009.03139.x
    [78] Kizilyaprak C, Daraspe J, Humbel BM (2014) Focused ion beam scanning electron microscopy in biology. J Microsc 254: 109–114.
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Dehao Ruan, Zhehao Huang, Xiaoxia Guo, Inequalities and stability of stochastic Hopfield neural networks with discrete and distributed delays, 2020, 407, 09252312, 281, 10.1016/j.neucom.2020.05.005
    2. Qinghua Zhou, Li Wan, Hongbo Fu, Qunjiao Zhang, Exponential stability of stochastic Hopfield neural network with mixed multiple delays, 2021, 6, 2473-6988, 4142, 10.3934/math.2021245
    3. Dehao Ruan, Weiguo Liu, Minran Yang, Zhehao Huang, Xiaoxia Guo, Novel Stability Results for Halanay Inequality and Applications to Delay Neural Networks, 2020, 8, 2169-3536, 19504, 10.1109/ACCESS.2020.2968760
    4. Lean Yu, Lihang Yu, Kaitao Yu, A high-dimensionality-trait-driven learning paradigm for high dimensional credit classification, 2021, 7, 2199-4730, 10.1186/s40854-021-00249-x
    5. Fanhong Zhang, Chen Fei, Weiyin Fei, Stability of stochastic Hopfield neural networks driven by G-Brownian motion with time-varying and distributed delays, 2023, 520, 09252312, 320, 10.1016/j.neucom.2022.10.065
    6. Li Wan, Qinghua Zhou, Hongbo Fu, Qunjiao Zhang, Exponential stability of Hopfield neural networks of neutral type with multiple time-varying delays, 2021, 6, 2473-6988, 8030, 10.3934/math.2021466
    7. Huahai Qiu, Li Wan, Zhigang Zhou, Qunjiao Zhang, Qinghua Zhou, Global exponential periodicity of nonlinear neural networks with multiple time-varying delays, 2023, 8, 2473-6988, 12472, 10.3934/math.2023626
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2016 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(9474) PDF downloads(1536) Cited by(9)

Figures and Tables

Figures(9)  /  Tables(2)

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog