Research article

Volitional down-regulation of the primary auditory cortex via directed attention mediated by real-time fMRI neurofeedback

  • The present work assessed the efficacy of training volitional down-regulation of the primary auditory cortex (A1) based on real-time functional magnetic resonance imaging neurofeedback (fMRI-NFT). A1 has been shown to be hyperactive in chronic tinnitus patients, and has been implicated as a potential source for the tinnitus percept. 27 healthy volunteers with normal hearing underwent 5 fMRI-NFT sessions: 18 received real neurofeedback and 9 sham neurofeedback. Each session was composed of a simple auditory fMRI followed by 2 runs of A1 fMRI-NFT. The auditory fMRI alternated periods of no auditory with periods of white noise stimulation at 90 dB. A1 activity, defined from a region using the activity during the preceding auditory run, was continuously updated during fMRI-NFT using a simple bar plot, and was accompanied by white noise (90 dB) stimulation for the duration of the scan. Each fMRI-NFT run alternated “relax” periods with “lower” periods. Subjects were instructed to watch the bar during the relax condition and actively reduce the bar by decreasing A1 activation during the lower condition. Average A1 de-activation, representative of the ability to volitionally down-regulate A1, was extracted from each fMRI-NFT run. A1 de-activation was found to increase significantly across training and to be higher in those receiving real neurofeedback. A1 de-activation in sessions 2 and 5 were found to be significantly greater than session 1 in only the group receiving real neurofeedback. The most successful subjects reportedly adopted mindfulness tasks associated with directed attention. For the first time, fMRI-NFT has been applied to teach volitional control of A1 de-activation magnitude over more than 1 session. These are important findings for therapeutic development as the magnitude of A1 activity is altered in tinnitus populations and it is unlikely a single fMRI-NFT session will reverse the effects of tinnitus.

    Citation: Matthew S. Sherwood, Jason G. Parker, Emily E. Diller, Subhashini Ganapathy, Kevin Bennett, Jeremy T. Nelson. Volitional down-regulation of the primary auditory cortex via directed attention mediated by real-time fMRI neurofeedback[J]. AIMS Neuroscience, 2018, 5(3): 179-199. doi: 10.3934/Neuroscience.2018.3.179

    Related Papers:

    [1] Ryo Kinoshita, Sung-mok Jung, Tetsuro Kobayashi, Andrei R. Akhmetzhanov, Hiroshi Nishiura . Epidemiology of coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) in Japan during the first and second waves. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(6): 6088-6101. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022284
    [2] Pannathon Kreabkhontho, Watchara Teparos, Thitiya Theparod . Potential for eliminating COVID-19 in Thailand through third-dose vaccination: A modeling approach. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2024, 21(8): 6807-6828. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2024298
    [3] Weike Zhou, Aili Wang, Fan Xia, Yanni Xiao, Sanyi Tang . Effects of media reporting on mitigating spread of COVID-19 in the early phase of the outbreak. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(3): 2693-2707. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020147
    [4] Sarafa A. Iyaniwura, Musa Rabiu, Jummy F. David, Jude D. Kong . Assessing the impact of adherence to Non-pharmaceutical interventions and indirect transmission on the dynamics of COVID-19: a mathematical modelling study. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(6): 8905-8932. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021439
    [5] Jiangbo Hao, Lirong Huang, Maoxing Liu, Yangjun Ma . Analysis of the COVID-19 model with self-protection and isolation measures affected by the environment. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2024, 21(4): 4835-4852. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2024213
    [6] Hao Wang, Di Zhu, Shiqi Li, Robert A. Cheke, Sanyi Tang, Weike Zhou . Home quarantine or centralized quarantine? A mathematical modelling study on the COVID-19 epidemic in Guangzhou in 2021. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(9): 9060-9078. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022421
    [7] Hamdy M. Youssef, Najat A. Alghamdi, Magdy A. Ezzat, Alaa A. El-Bary, Ahmed M. Shawky . A new dynamical modeling SEIR with global analysis applied to the real data of spreading COVID-19 in Saudi Arabia. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(6): 7018-7044. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020362
    [8] Liping Wang, Jing Wang, Hongyong Zhao, Yangyang Shi, Kai Wang, Peng Wu, Lei Shi . Modelling and assessing the effects of medical resources on transmission of novel coronavirus (COVID-19) in Wuhan, China. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(4): 2936-2949. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020165
    [9] Yong Zhou, Minrui Guo . Isolation in the control of epidemic. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(11): 10846-10863. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022507
    [10] Abdallah Alsammani, Calistus N. Ngonghala, Maia Martcheva . Impact of vaccination behavior on COVID-19 dynamics and economic outcomes. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2025, 22(9): 2300-2338. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2025084
  • The present work assessed the efficacy of training volitional down-regulation of the primary auditory cortex (A1) based on real-time functional magnetic resonance imaging neurofeedback (fMRI-NFT). A1 has been shown to be hyperactive in chronic tinnitus patients, and has been implicated as a potential source for the tinnitus percept. 27 healthy volunteers with normal hearing underwent 5 fMRI-NFT sessions: 18 received real neurofeedback and 9 sham neurofeedback. Each session was composed of a simple auditory fMRI followed by 2 runs of A1 fMRI-NFT. The auditory fMRI alternated periods of no auditory with periods of white noise stimulation at 90 dB. A1 activity, defined from a region using the activity during the preceding auditory run, was continuously updated during fMRI-NFT using a simple bar plot, and was accompanied by white noise (90 dB) stimulation for the duration of the scan. Each fMRI-NFT run alternated “relax” periods with “lower” periods. Subjects were instructed to watch the bar during the relax condition and actively reduce the bar by decreasing A1 activation during the lower condition. Average A1 de-activation, representative of the ability to volitionally down-regulate A1, was extracted from each fMRI-NFT run. A1 de-activation was found to increase significantly across training and to be higher in those receiving real neurofeedback. A1 de-activation in sessions 2 and 5 were found to be significantly greater than session 1 in only the group receiving real neurofeedback. The most successful subjects reportedly adopted mindfulness tasks associated with directed attention. For the first time, fMRI-NFT has been applied to teach volitional control of A1 de-activation magnitude over more than 1 session. These are important findings for therapeutic development as the magnitude of A1 activity is altered in tinnitus populations and it is unlikely a single fMRI-NFT session will reverse the effects of tinnitus.


    In the evolutionary history of natural communities, ecological competition has justifiably been a significant force, which consists of exploitation and interference [1,2,3]. In consequence, there has been increasing studies for consumer-resource competitive models by dynamical systems theory [4,5,6,7]. Mathematically, Gopalsamy [8] developed the following resource-based competition model.

    $ {dxdt=x(t)[bax(t)a1z1(t)a2z2(t)],dz1dt=z1(t)[b1x(t)β1z1(t)μ1z2(t)],dz2dt=z2(t)[b2x(t)β2z2(t)μ2z1(t)],
    $
    (1.1)

    where $ x(t) $ represents the density of a logistically self-renewing resource at time $ t $, $ z_{1}(t) $ and $ z_{2}(t) $ represent the densities at time $ t $ of two species which feed on this resource alone.

    For a population individual, its whole life history generally includes two or more stages, particularly, mammals show two different stages of immaturity and maturity [9,10,11]. Moreover, it takes some time from birth to adulthood which is considered as the maturity time delay. Thus, the competition models and stage structure population models with constant maturity delays have been studied. For example, the two-species competition model and stage-structured single population model established in [12,13] respectively have a constant maturity delay.

    Later, people noticed the biological fact about the maturity time of Antarctic whales and seals around the Second World War. Subsequent to the introduction of factory ships and with it a depletion of the large whale population, there has been a substantial increase in krill for seals and whales. It was then noted that seals took 3 to 4 years to mature and small whales only took 5 years [14]. Hence, their maturation time varies with the number of krill available, which implies that the maturity time delay is state-dependent, not a constant.

    Due to this, Aiello and Freedman [15] formulated the following stage-structured state-dependent delay model, in which the delay $ \tau(z(t)) $ is a bounded increasing function of the total population $ z(t) = x(t)+y(t) $.

    $ {dx(t)dt=αy(t)γx(t)αy(tτ(z(t)))eγτ(z(t)),dy(t)dt=αy(tτ(z(t)))eγτ(z(t))βy2(t).
    $

    Subsequently, the stage-structured and competitive models with state-dependent delays were developed [16,17,18,19,20,21,22,23,24,25,26]. In 2017, Lv and Yuan [27] proposed the competitive model with state-dependent delays:

    $ {dz1dt=b1z1(tτ(z1))eγ1τ(z1)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dz2dt=b2z2(tτ(z2))eγ2τ(z2)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t),
    $

    where the delays $ \tau(z_{i}(t)) $ are bounded increasing functions of the populations $ z_{i}(t) $, $ i = 1, 2 $, respectively.

    It is obvious that the above-mentioned models with state-dependent delays straight change the constant delays into the state-dependent delays, which is not appropriate to population modeling. Therefore, Wang, Liu and Wei [28] proposed the following new single population model with a state-dependent delay and a correction factor.

    $ {dx(t)dt=αy(t)γx(t)α[1τ(z(t))˙z(t)]y(tτ(z(t)))eγτ(z(t)),dy(t)dt=α[1τ(z(t))˙z(t)]y(tτ(z(t)))eγτ(z(t))βy2(t),
    $

    where the delay $ \tau(z(t)) $ is a function of the total population $ z(t) = x(t)+y(t) $.

    However, the aforementioned state-dependent delays are functions of populations, not resources. A worthwhile thought is how to reflect the direct relationship between the resources and maturity time? In view of the biological background above, the time varies with the resources available, that is, the species must spend enough time in the immature stage to accumulate a certain amount of food to reach maturity. To address the question raised above, we consider a stage-structured consumer-resource competition model with a state-dependent maturity time delay, in which the delay involves a correction term, $ 1-\tau'(x)x'(t) $, related to resource changes.

    The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we formulate a resource-based competition model with a state-dependent maturity delay. In section 3, we study the well-posedness properties for the model and prove the existence and uniqueness of all equilibria. In section 4, we analyze the local stabilities of equilibria. In section 5, we discuss the global behaviors of the coexistence equilibrium. Finally, section 6 gives the conclusions of the paper.

    Based on model (1.1), we will formulate the competition model with a state-dependent maturity delay. For each $ i = 1, 2 $, let $ y_{i}(t) $ and $ z_{i}(t) $ be the densities at time $ t $ of the immature and mature consumer species, respectively. Let $ x(t) $ be the density at time $ t $ of a logistically self-renewing resource which is necessary for two consumer species. Motivated by [28,29,30,31], we introduce a threshold age $ \tau (x(t)) $ to distinguish the immature and mature individuals, which depends on the density of the same resource. Suppose that $ \rho_{i}(t, a) $ is the population density of age $ a $ at time $ t $, then the densities of $ y_{i}(t) $ and $ z_{i}(t) $, respectively, are given by

    $ yi(t)=τ(x(t))0ρi(t,a)daandzi(t)=τ(x(t))ρi(t,a)da.
    $

    By virtue of [32,33], we have the following age structure partial differential equations to represent the development of the consumer species.

    $ ρ1(t,a)t+ρ1(t,a)a=γ1ρ1(t,a),ifaτ(x(t)),ρ1(t,a)t+ρ1(t,a)a=(β1z1(t)+μ1z2(t))ρ1(t,a),ifa>τ(x(t)),ρ2(t,a)t+ρ2(t,a)a=γ2ρ2(t,a),ifaτ(x(t)),ρ2(t,a)t+ρ2(t,a)a=(β2z2(t)+μ2z1(t))ρ2(t,a),ifa>τ(x(t)).
    $
    (2.1)

    We suppose that $ y_{1}(t) $ and $ y_{2}(t) $ die at the constant rate $ \gamma_{i} $ ($ i = 1, 2 $). The parameters $ \beta_{i} $ ($ i = 1, 2 $) represent the mature natural death and overcrowding rate for $ z_{i}(t) $, respectively. The parameters $ \mu_{i} $ ($ i = 1, 2 $) represent interspecific competition for $ z_{i}(t) $, respectively.

    Taking the derivatives of $ y_{i}(t) $ and $ z_{i}(t) $, respectively, and combining system (2.1), it then follows that

    $ dy1(t)dt=ρ1(t,0)γ1y1(t)[1τ(x)x(t)]ρ1(t,τ(x(t))),dz1(t)dt=[1τ(x)x(t)]ρ1(t,τ(x(t)))ρ1(t,)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dy2(t)dt=ρ2(t,0)γ2y2(t)[1τ(x)x(t)]ρ2(t,τ(x(t))),dz2(t)dt=[1τ(x)x(t)]ρ2(t,τ(x(t)))ρ2(t,)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t).
    $

    Note that the two primes refer to differentiation with respect to $ x $ and time $ t $, respectively, namely, $ \dot{\tau}(x(t)) = d\tau(x(t))/dt = \tau'(x)x'(t) $.

    Because of the finitude of individual life span, $ \rho_{i}(t, \infty) $ is considered as zero. Assume that the immature consumers' functional response is Holling type I, that is, $ b_{i}x(t) $, then the term $ \rho_{i}(t, 0) = b_{i} x(t)z_{i}(t) $ represents the number of immature individuals born at time $ t $. Therefore, for $ t\geq \tilde{\tau} = \max\{\tau(x(t))\} $, we have

    $ ρi(t,τ(x(t)))=ρi(tτ(x(t)),0)=bix(tτ(x(t)))zi(tτ(x(t)))eγiτ(x(t)),i=1,2.
    $

    Consequently, we obtain the following stage-structured consumer-resource competition model with a state-dependent delay.

    $ {dxdt=rx(t)(1x(t)K)a1x(t)z1(t)a2x(t)z2(t),dy1dt=b1x(t)z1(t)b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)γ1y1(t),dz1dt=b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dy2dt=b2x(t)z2(t)b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)γ2y2(t),dz2dt=b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t),
    $
    (2.2)

    where $ r $ and $ K $ represent the growth rate of the resource and its carrying capacity, respectively. The parameters $ a_{1} $ and $ a_{2} $ represent the capture rate of $ z_{1} $ and $ z_{2} $, respectively. By [28], the inequality, $ 1-\tau'(x)x'(t) > 0 $, holds true, which implies that $ t-\tau(x(t))) $ is a strictly increasing function in $ t $. This shows that mature individuals become immature only by birth.

    For system (2.2), there are the following basic hypotheses:

    ($ \mathcal{A}_{1} $) The constant parameters $ r $, $ K $, $ a_{1} $, $ a_{2} $, $ b_{1} $, $ b_{2} $, $ \gamma_{1} $, $ \gamma_{2} $, $ \beta_{1} $, $ \beta_{2} $, $ \mu_{1} $, $ \mu_{2} $ are all positive;

    ($ \mathcal{A}_{2} $) The state-dependent time delay $ \tau(x) $ is a decreasing differentiable bounded function of the resource $ x $, where $ \tau'(x)\leq0 $, and $ 0\leq\tau_{m} \leq\tau(x)\leq\tau_{M} $ with $ \tau(+\infty) = \tau_{m} $, $ \tau(0) = \tau_{M} $.

    To simplify system (2.2), we can readily scale off $ r $ and $ K $ by proper rescaling of $ t $ and $ x $. Accordingly, system (2.2) becomes

    $ {dxdt=x(t)(1x(t)a1z1(t)a2z2(t)),dy1dt=b1x(t)z1(t)b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)γ1y1(t),dz1dt=b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dy2dt=b2x(t)z2(t)b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)γ2y2(t),dz2dt=b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t).
    $
    (2.3)

    In this paper, we will study the dynamics of system (2.3). The initial data for system (2.3) are

    $ x(s)=Υ(s)0,z1(s)=Φ1(s)0,y1(s)=Ψ1(s)0for all s[τM,0],z2(s)=Φ2(s)0,y2(s)=Ψ2(s)0for all s[τM,0],
    $

    with

    $ Ψ1(0)=0τ(x(0))b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1sdsandΨ2(0)=0τ(x(0))b2x(s)z2(s)eγ2sds,
    $

    which represent the number of immature consumers who survived to time $ t = 0 $.

    In this section, we first study the well-posedness properties of the solution for system (2.3) and then prove the existence and uniqueness of all equilibria.

    Theorem 3.1. Let $ \Upsilon(t) \geq0 $, $ \Phi_{1}(t)\geq0 $ and $ \Phi_{2}(t)\geq0 $ for $ -\tau_{M}\leq t\leq0 $, then the solution $ (x(t), y_{1}(t), z_{1}(t), y_{2}(t), z_{2}(t)) $ of system (2.3) is nonnegative and uniformly ultimate bounded for all $ t\geq 0 $.

    Proof. Consider the first equation in system (2.3).

    $ dxdt=x(t)(1x(t)a1z1(t)a2z2(t)),
    $

    with $ x(0) = \Upsilon(0)\geq0 $. Then

    $ x(t)=x(0)expt0[1x(s)a1z1(s)a2z2(s)]ds0,t0.
    $

    Suppose that there exists $ t > 0 $ such that $ z_{1}(t) = 0 $. Let $ t^{*} = \inf\{t: t > 0, z_{1}(t) = 0\} $, then

    $ z1(t)=b1[1τ(x(t))x(t)]x(tτ(x(t)))z1(tτ(x(t)))eγ1τ(x(t)).
    $

    Since $ \tau(x) > 0, $ $ 1-\tau'(x(t^{*}))x'(t^{*}) > 0 $, $ t^{*}-\tau(x(t^{*})) < t^{*} $, it follows from the definition of $ t^{*} $ that $ z_{1}(t^{*}-\tau(x(t^{*}))) > 0 $, which implies that $ z_{1}'(t^{*}) > 0 $ and is a contradiction. Therefore, there does not exist $ t^{*} $ and $ z_{1}(t) > 0 $ for all $ t > 0 $.

    Integrating the second equation of system (2.3), we have the following integral expression for $ y_{1}(t) $.

    $ y1(t)=eγ1t(Φ1(0)+t0b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1sdstτ(x(t))τ(x(0))b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1sds)=ttτ(x(t))b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1(ts)ds.
    $

    It is easy to see that $ y_{1}(t)\geq0 $ by the nonnegativity $ x(t) $, $ z_{1}(t) $ and $ \tau(x) $. In a similar way, we can prove the nonnegativity of $ z_{2}(t) $ and $ y_{2}(t) $. Hence, the solution $ (x(t), y_{1}(t), z_{1}(t), y_{2}(t), z_{2}(t)) $ of system (2.3) is nonnegative. Especially, when $ \Upsilon(0) > 0, \Psi_{1}(0) > 0, \Phi_{1}(0) > 0 $, the solution of system (2.3) is positive.

    Now we prove uniform ultimate boundedness of the solution. Define the following Lyapunov functional.

    $ V=(b1a1+b2a2)x(t)+z1(t)+z2(t)+ttτ(x(t))b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1(ts)ds+ttτ(x(t))b2x(s)z2(s)eγ2(ts)ds.
    $

    Calculating the time derivative of $ V(t) $ along the solutions of system (2.3), we have

    $ V(t)=(b1a1+b2a2)x(t)[1x(t)a1z1(t)a2z2(t)]+b1x(t)z1(t)+b2x(t)z2(t)γ1ttτ(x(t))b1x(s)z1(s)eγ1(ts)dsβ1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t)γ2ttτ(x(t))b2x(s)z2(s)eγ2(ts)dsβ2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t)<γV+(b1a1+b2a2)[(1+γ)x(t)x2(t)]+γz1(t)β1z21(t)+γz2(t)β2z22(t)γV+M1+M2+M3,
    $

    where $ \gamma = \min\{\gamma_{1}, \gamma_{2}\} $, $ M_{1} $, $ M_{2} $ and $ M_{3} $ are the maximum values of quadratic function $ (b_{1}/a_{1}+b_{2}/a_{2})[(1+\gamma)x(t)-x^{2}(t)] $, $ \gamma z_{1}(t)-\beta_{1} z_{1}^{2}(t) $ and $ \gamma z_{2}(t)-\beta_{2} z_{2}^{2}(t) $, respectively. Obviously, $ M_{1} $, $ M_{2} $ and $ M_{3} $ are positive. Thus, $ \limsup_{t\rightarrow\infty}V(t)\leq (M_{1}+M_{2}+M_{3})/\gamma $ and the solution of system (3.1) is uniformly ultimate bounded. It then follows that the solution of system (2.3) is uniformly ultimate bounded.

    Since variables $ y_{1}(t) $ and $ y_{2}(t) $ of system (2.3) are decoupled from the other equations, we study the following reduced system:

    $ {dxdt=x(t)(1x(t))a1x(t)z1(t)a2x(t)z2(t),dz1dt=b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dz2dt=b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t).
    $
    (3.1)

    In the rest of this section, we will discuss the existence and patterns of equilibria $ (x, z_{1}, z_{2}) $ of system (3.1). The equilibria satisfy the following equations:

    $ {x(1xa1z1a2z2)=0,b1xz1eγ1τ(x)β1z21μ1z1z2=0,b2xz2eγ2τ(x)β2z22μ2z1z2=0.
    $
    (3.2)

    It is easy to see that system (3.1) has one trivial equilibrium $ E_{0} = (0, 0, 0) $ and one semitrivial equilibrium $ E_{1} = (1, 0, 0) $. And we obtain the following result for nontrivial equilibria.

    Theorem 3.2. System (3.1) has exactly two semitrivial equilibria $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $ and $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $. Assume that

    $ min{β1μ2,μ1β2}<b1eγ1τMb2eγ2τm<b1eγ1τmb2eγ2τM<max{β1μ2,μ1β2};min{β1μ1,μ2β2}<a1a2<max{β1μ1,μ2β2}.
    $
    (3.3)

    Then there exists unique coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $.

    Proof. There are three cases to prove the existence of nontrivial equilibria.

    Case 1 If $ z_{2} = 0 $, then Eq (3.2) reduces to

    $ {x(1xa1z1)=0,b1xz1eγ1τ(x)β1z21=0.
    $

    The inequality, $ z_{1} < b_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1}) $, is valid to make sure $ x = 1-a_{1}z_{1} > 0 $, $ y_{1} = \gamma_{1}^{-1}z_{1}(b_{1}-a_{1}b_{1}z_{1}-\beta_{1} z_{1}) > \; 0 $. Thus, we will investigate the existence and uniqueness of nontrivial equilibrium in $ \Lambda = \{z_{1}\in R\mid 0 < z_{1} < b_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1})\}\subset R $. Define $ f:\overline{\Lambda}\rightarrow R $ be a continuous mapping by

    $ f(z1)=b1(1a1z1)eγ1τ(1a1z1)β1z1.
    $

    Clearly, $ f(0) = b_{1} x e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1)} > 0 $, $ f(b_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1})) = b_{1}\beta_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1})[e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\beta_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1}))}-1] < 0 $, which implies that $ f(z_{1}) $ has at least one positive zero point $ \hat{z_{1}} $.

    Note that $ f'(\hat{z_{1}}) = -a_{1}b_{1} e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1-a_{1}\hat{z_{1}})}+a_{1}b_{1}\gamma_{1}(1-a_{1}\hat{z_{1}})e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1-a_{1}\hat{z_{1}})}\tau' (1-a_{1}\hat{z_{1}})-\beta_{1} < 0 $, it then follows that $ f(z_{1}) $ has a unique positive root in the interval $ (0, b_{1}/(a_{1}b_{1}+\beta_{1})) $. Hence, system (3.1) has a unique boundary equilibrium $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $.

    Case 2 If $ z_{1} = 0 $, then system (3.1) has a unique boundary equilibrium $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $ by similar arguments in the case 1.

    Case 3 If $ z_{1}\neq 0 $ and $ z_{2}\neq 0 $, then the coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $ satisfies the following equations:

    $ {1xa1z1a2z2=0,b1xeγ1τ(x)β1z1μ1z2=0,b2xeγ2τ(x)β2z2μ2z1=0.
    $
    (3.4)

    Solving Eq (3.4), we obtain that

    $ {x=11+a1Γ1+a2Γ2;z1=xΓ1,Γ1=β2b1eγ1τ(x)μ1b2eγ2τ(x)β1β2μ1μ2;z2=xΓ2,Γ2=β1b2eγ2τ(x)μ2b1eγ1τ(x)β1β2μ1μ2.
    $
    (3.5)

    In order to make sure the positivity of $ x^{*} $, $ z_{1}^{*} $ and $ z_{2}^{*} $, we get

    $ min{β1μ2,μ1β2}<b1eγ1τMb2eγ2τm<b1eγ1τ(x)b2eγ2τ(x)<b1eγ1τmb2eγ2τM<max{β1μ2,μ1β2}.
    $

    Now we prove the uniqueness of $ E^{*} $. Suppose that $ f(x) = 1-x-a_{1}z_{1}-a_{2}z_{2} $, combining Eq (3.5), we have

    $ f(x)=1xa1z1a2z2=1xxb1eγ1τ(x)a1β2a2μ2β1β2μ1μ2xb2eγ2τ(x)a2β1a1μ1β1β2μ1μ2=1xxf1(x)xf2(x),
    $

    where $ f_{1}(x) = b_{1}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(x)}(a_{1}\beta_{2}-a_{2}\mu_{2})/(\beta_{1}\beta_{2}-\mu_{1}\mu_{2}) $, $ f_{2}(x) = b_{2}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(x)}(a_{2}\beta_{1}-a_{1}\mu_{1})/(\beta_{1}\beta_{2}-\mu_{1}\mu_{2}) $.

    Obviously, $ f(0) = 1 > 0 $ and

    $ f(1) = \frac{-a_{1}\big(\beta_{2} b_{1}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1)}-\mu_{1}b_{2}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(1)}\big)-a_{2}\big(\beta_{1} b_{2}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(1)}-\mu_{2}b_{1}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1)}\big)}{\beta_{1}\beta_{2}-\mu_{1}\mu_{2}} \lt 0, $

    which implies that $ f(x) $ has at least one positive zero point $ x^{*} $.

    It follows from $ f_{1}(x^{*})+f_{2}(x^{*}) = 1/x^{*}-1 $ that

    $ f(x)=1[f1(x)+f2(x)]x[f1(x)+f2(x)]=1xx[f1(x)+f2(x)].
    $

    If $ \min\left\{\beta_{1}/\mu_{1}, \mu_{2}/\beta_{2}\right\} < a_{1}/a_{2} < \max\left\{\beta_{1}/\mu_{1}, \mu_{2}/\beta_{2}\right\} $, then $ f'(x^{*}) < 0 $. Thus, $ f(x) $ has a unique positive root $ x^{*} $ in the interval $ (0, 1) $, and system (3.1) has a unique coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $. This completes the proof.

    In this section, the linearized stability of equilibria will be studied. We utilize the method proposed by Cooke [34] to linearize system (3.1).

    Let $ \tilde{E} = (\tilde{x}, \tilde{z_{1}}, \tilde{z_{2}}) $ be an arbitrary equilibrium. Then the linearization of system (3.1) is

    $ {x(t)=Ax(t)a1˜xz1(t)a2˜xz2(t),z1(t)=A1x+b1eγ1τ(˜x)~z1x(tτ(˜x))+b1eγ1τ(˜x)˜xz1(tτ(˜x))+B1z1+C1z2,z2(t)=A2x+b2eγ2τ(˜x)~z2x(tτ(˜x))+b2eγ2τ(˜x)˜xz2(tτ(˜x))+B2z1+C2z2,
    $
    (4.1)

    where

    $ A=12˜xa1~z1a2~z2,A1=b1˜x~z1τ(˜x)eγ1τ(˜x)(γ1A),A2=b2˜x~z2τ(˜x)eγ2τ(˜x)(γ2A),B1=a1b1(˜x)2~z1τ(˜x)eγ1τ(˜x)2β1~z1μ1~z2,B2=a1b2(˜x)2~z2τ(˜x)eγ2τ(˜x)μ2~z2,C1=a2b1(˜x)2~z2τ(˜x)eγ1τ(˜x)μ1~z1,C2=a2b2(˜x)2~z2τ(˜x)eγ2τ(˜x)2β2~z2μ2~z1.
    $

    The corresponding characteristic equation of system (4.1) is as follows:

    $ \left| λAa1˜xa2˜xA1b1~z1e(γ1+λ)τ(˜x)λB1b1˜xe(γ1+λ)τ(˜x)C1A2b2~z2e(γ2+λ)τ(˜x)B2λC2b2˜xe(γ2+λ)τ(˜x)
    \right| = 0. $

    For the extinction equilibrium $ E_{0} = (0, 0, 0) $, it follows that $ A = 1, $ $ A_{1} = 0, $ $ B_{1} = 0, $ $ C_{1} = 0, $ $ A_{2} = 0, $ $ B_{2} = 0, $ $ C_{2} = 0 $, then $ (\lambda-1)\lambda^{2} = 0 $, and $ \lambda = 1 > 0 $ is one of these eigenvalues. Thus, we have the following result.

    Theorem 4.1. The extinction equilibrium $ E_{0} = (0, 0, 0) $ is unstable.

    For the trivial equilibrium $ E_{1} = (1, 0, 0) $, the characteristic equation is as follows.

    $ (λ+1)(λb1e(γ1+λ)τ(1))(λb2e(γ2+λ)τ(1))=0.
    $

    Obviously, $ \lambda = -1 < 0 $ is one of these eigenvalues. All the other eigenvalues $ \lambda $ satisfy the equations $ \lambda e^{\tau(1)(\gamma_{1}+\lambda)} = b_{1} > 0 $ and $ \lambda e^{\tau(1)(\gamma_{2}+\lambda)} = b_{2} > 0 $, which always have real, positive solutions. Hence, the conclusion about the linearized stability of $ E_{1} $ is as follows.

    Theorem 4.2. The trivial equilibrium $ E_{1} = (1, 0, 0) $ is a saddle point and unstable.

    In order to obtain the linearized stability of $ E_{2} $ and $ E_{3} $, we first give the results on the real positive roots of a quartic equation. Suppose that

    $ v4+K1v3+K2v2+K3v+K4=0.
    $
    (4.2)

    Let

    $ M=12K2316K21,N=132K3118K1K2+K3,Δ=(N2)3+(M2)3,σ=1+3i2,y1=3N2+Δ+3N2Δ,y2=σ3N2+Δ+σ23N2Δ,y3=σ23N2+Δ+σ3N2Δ,zi=yi3K14,i=1,2,3.
    $

    By virtue of [35], we have the following lemma.

    Lemma 4.3. The following statements hold true for Eq (4.2):

    (i) If $ K_{4} < 0 $, then Eq (4.2) has at least one positive root;

    (ii) If $ K_{4}\geq0 $ and $ \Delta\geq0 $, then Eq (4.2) has positive roots if and only if $ z_{1} > 0 $ and $ h(z_{1}) < 0 $;

    (iii) If $ K_{4}\geq0 $ and $ \Delta < 0 $, then Eq (4.2) has positive roots if and only if there exists at least one $ z^{*}\in\{z_{1}, z_{2}, z_{3}\} $ such that $ z^{*} > 0 $ and $ Q(z^{*})\leq0 $, where $ Q(z) = z^{4}+K_{1}z^{3}+K_{2}z^{2}+K_{3}z+K_{4} $.

    We are now in a position to prove the linearized stability of $ E_{2} $.

    Theorem 4.4. If $ \hat{z_{1}} < 3/(4a_{1}) $ and $ b_{1}\mu_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\hat{x})} > b_{2}\beta_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $, then the boundary equilibrium $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $ is locally asymptotically stable.

    Proof. The characteristic equation for the boundary equilibrium $ E_{2} $ is as follows:

    $ (λC2b2ˆxe(γ2+λ)τ(ˆx))[(λA)(λB1b1ˆxe(γ1+λ)τ(ˆx))+a1ˆx(A1+b1^z1e(γ1+λ)τ(ˆx))]=0.
    $
    (4.3)

    It is easy to see that some of the eigenvalues satisfy the following equation:

    $ λ+μ2^z1b2ˆxe(γ2+λ)τ(ˆx)=0.
    $
    (4.4)

    Claim. If $ b_{1}\mu_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\hat{x})} > b_{2}\beta_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $, that is, $ \hat{z_{1}} > \mu_{2}^{-1}b_{2}\hat{x}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $, then all eigenvalues of Eq (4.4) have negative real parts.

    Obviously, if $ \tau(\hat{x}) = 0 $, then Eq (4.4) has a unique negative real root $ \lambda = b_{2}\hat{x}-\mu_{2}\hat{z_{1}} < 0 $. In order to study whether any roots cross the imaginary axis, let $ \lambda = i\omega $ with $ \omega > 0 $ and substitute it into Eq (4.4), it follows from $ \hat{z_{1}} > \mu_{2}^{-1}b_{2}\hat{x}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $ that

    $ ω2=(b2ˆxeγ2τ(ˆx))2(μ2^z1)2<0.
    $

    Therefore, Eq (4.4) has no purely imaginary roots and each root has a negative real part.

    Other roots are given by equation:

    $ G(λ)=(λA)(λB1b1ˆxe(γ1+λ)τ(ˆx))+a1ˆx(A1+b1^z1e(γ1+λ)τ(ˆx))=λ2+H1λ+H2+(N1λ+N2)eλτ(ˆx)=0,
    $
    (4.5)

    where $ H_{1} = -A-B_{1}, $ $ H_{2} = AB_{1}+a_{1}A_{1} \hat{x}, $ $ N_{1} = -\beta_{1} \hat{z_{1}}, $ $ N_{2} = A\beta_{1} \hat{z_{1}}+a_{1}\beta_{1}\hat{z_{1}}^{2}. $

    Since $ \tau'(x)\leq0 $, we have $ G(0) = \beta_{1}\hat{x}\hat{z_{1}}-a_{1}\beta_{1}\gamma_{1} \hat{x}(\hat{z_{1}})^{2}\tau'(\hat{x})+a_{1}\beta_{1}(\hat{z_{1}})^{2} > 0 $, and thus Eq (4.5) has no zero roots.

    Next, we prove that Eq (4.5) has no purely imaginary roots.

    Assume, by contradiction, that Eq (4.5) has a purely imaginary root $ \lambda = iv $, where $ v > 0 $. Substituting it into Eq (4.5) and separating the real and imaginary parts, we have

    $ {v2H2=N1vsin(τ(ˆx)v)+N2cos(τ(ˆx)v),H1v=N1vcos(τ(ˆx)v)N2sin(τ(ˆx)v).
    $

    Considering $ \sin(\tau(\hat{x})v)^{2}+\cos(\tau(\hat{x})v)^{2} = 1 $, it follows that

    $ v4+D1v2+D2=0,
    $
    (4.6)

    where $ D_{1} = H_{1}^{2}-2H_{2}-N_{1}^{2} $, $ D_{2} = H_{2}^{2}-N_{2}^{2}. $

    In view of $ \tau'(\hat{x})\leq0 $, there are the following two cases.

    Case (1). If $ \tau'(\hat{x}) = 0 $, then $ \tau(\hat{x})\geq0 $, since $ \hat{x} > 0 $, it follows from the hypothesis ($ \mathcal{A}_{2} $) that $ \tau(\hat{x})\neq0 $ and $ \tau(\hat{x}) > 0 $. Therefore, $ D_{1} = A^{2}+3\beta_{1}^{2} \hat{z_{1}}^{2} > 0 $, $ D_{2} = \beta_{1}^{2}\hat{z_{1}}^{2}(4\hat{x}-1) = \beta_{1}^{2}\hat{z_{1}}^{2}(3-4a_{1}\hat{z_{1}}) > 0 $, which implies that Eq (4.5) has no purely imaginary roots and each root of characteristic equation has a negative real part.

    Case (2). If $ \tau'(\hat{x}) < 0 $, according to Lemma 4.3, we have $ K_{1} = 0, K_{2} = D_{1}, K_{3} = 0, K_{4} = D_{2} = \beta_{1}^{2}\hat{z_{1}}^{2}(3-4a_{1}\hat{z_{1}})-4 a_{1}\beta_{1}^{2}\gamma_{1} \hat{x}^{2}\hat{z_{1}}^{3}\tau'(\hat{x})+(a_{1}\beta_{1} \gamma_{1} \hat{x}\hat{z_{1}}^{2} \tau'(\hat{x}))^{2} > 0 $ providing $ \hat{z_{1}} < 3/(4a_{1}) $. Hence, Eq (4.6) has positive roots if the equation satisfies the case (ⅰ) or (ⅱ) in Lemma 4.3. However, $ Z_{i} = Y_{i}-3K_{1}/4 = Y_{i} = 0, $ $ i = 1, 2, 3 $. Then neither case (ⅰ) nor case (ⅱ) in Lemma 4.3 holds true, Eq (4.6) has no positive roots, that is, Eq (4.5) has no purely imaginary roots. Therefore, all eigenvalues of Eq (4.3) have negative real parts, and $ E_{2} $ is locally asymptotically stable. This completes the proof.

    Similarly, we have the following observation about the boundary equilibrium $ E_{3} $.

    Theorem 4.5. If $ \tilde{z_{2}} < 3/(4a_{2}) $ and $ b_{2}\mu_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\tilde{x})} > b_{1}\beta_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\tilde{x})} $, then the boundary equilibrium $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $ is locally asymptotically stable.

    In this section, we investigate the global attractivity of the coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} $ by a method of asymptotic estimates.

    Theorem 5.1. Let condition (3.3) hold, and assume that:

    $ 1>a1b1β1eγ1τ(1)+a2b2β2eγ2τ(1);
    $
    (5.1)
    $ b1(1a1b1β1eγ1τ(1)a2b2β2eγ2τ(1))eγ1τ(0)>μ1b2β2eγ2τ(1);
    $
    (5.2)
    $ b2(1a1b1β1eγ1τ(1)a2b2β2eγ2τ(1))eγ2τ(0)>μ2b1β1eγ1τ(1);
    $
    (5.3)
    $ (a1b1β2+a2b1μ2)eγ1τ(0)+(a1b2μ1+a2b2β1)eγ2τ(0)>β1β2μ1μ2.
    $
    (5.4)

    Then the coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} $ is globally attractive.

    Proof. Since $ e^{-\gamma\tau(x)} $ is increase with respect to $ x $, then $ e^{-\gamma\tau(1)} > e^{-\gamma\tau(0)} $. It follows from inequality (5.2) that

    $ b1eγ1τ(1)>b1eγ1τ(0)>b1(1a1b1β1eγ1τ(1)a2b2β2eγ2τ(1))eγ1τ(0)>μ1b2β2eγ2τ(1).
    $

    Similarly, we have

    $ b2eγ2τ(1)>b2eγ2τ(0)>b2(1a1b1β1eγ1τ(1)a2b2β2eγ2τ(1))eγ2τ(0)>μ2b1β1eγ1τ(1).
    $

    Namely,

    $ μ1β2<b1eγ1τMb2eγ2τm<b1eγ1τ(1)b2eγ2τ(1)<b1eγ1τmb2eγ2τM<β1μ2,
    $

    which implies that both the boundary equilibria $ E_{2} $ and $ E_{3} $ are unstable.

    For the system

    $ {dm1dt=m1(t)(1m1(t)),dm(1)1dt=b1[1τ(m1)m1(t)]m1(tτ(m1))m(1)1(tτ(m1))eγ1τ(m1)β1(m(1)1(t))2,dm(2)1dt=b2[1τ(m1)m1(t)]m1(tτ(m1))m(2)1(tτ(m1))eγ2τ(m1)β2(m(2)1(t))2,
    $

    we have the unique positive equilibrium $ m^{*} = (1, b_{1}/\beta_{1}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(1)}, b_{2}/\beta_{2}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(1)}). $

    Clearly, for system (3.1), we obtain that

    $ {dxdt<x(t)(1x(t)),dz1dt<b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x(t)))z1(tτ(x(t)))eγ1τ(x(t))β1z21(t),dz2dt<b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x(t)))z2(tτ(x(t)))eγ2τ(x(t))β2z22(t).
    $
    (5.5)

    By Theorem 3.1, for any $ \epsilon_{1} > 0 $, we can prove that there exists a $ t_{1} > 0 $ such that the following inequalities hold true for all $ t\geq t_{1} $.

    $ {x(t)<M1=1+ϵ1,z1(t)<M(1)1=b1β1eγ1τ(M1)+ϵ12,z2(t)<M(2)1=b2β2eγ2τ(M1)+ϵ12.
    $
    (5.6)

    We first select $ \epsilon_{1} > 0 $ and the corresponding $ t_{1} > 0 $ such that

    $ {1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1>0,b1(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ1τ(M1)>μ1M(2)1,b2(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ2τ(M1)>μ2M(1)1.
    $
    (5.7)

    Conditions (5.1)-(5.3) can guarantee the existence of $ \epsilon_{1} $ to satisfy conditions (5.6) and (5.7). Based on $ \epsilon_{1} > 0, \; t_{1} > 0 $, we choose sufficiently small $ \epsilon_{2} > 0 $ to make that $ \epsilon_{2} < \min\{1/2, \epsilon_{1}\}, $ and

    $ {1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1ϵ2>0,[b1(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ1τ(M1)μ1M(2)1]1β1ϵ22>0,[b2(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ2τ(M1)μ2M(1)1]1β1ϵ22>0.
    $
    (5.8)

    In view of inequality (5.7), it is possible to choose positive number $ \epsilon_{2} $ satisfying inequality (5.8). Combining with inequalities (5.6) and (5.8), we obtain that

    $ {dxdt>x(t)[(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)x(t)],dz1dt>b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x(t)))z1(tτ(x(t)))eγ1τ(x(t))β1z21(t)μ1M(2)1z1(t),dz2dt>b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x(t)))z2(tτ(x(t)))eγ2τ(x(t))β2z22(t)μ2M(1)1z2(t).
    $

    It follows that there exists a $ t_{2} > t_{1} $ to make that

    $ {x(t)>N1=1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1ϵ2,z1(t)>N(1)1=(b1N1eγ1τ(N1)μ1M(2)1)1β1ϵ22,z2(t)>N(2)1=(b2N1eγ2τ(N1)μ2M(1)1)1β2ϵ22.
    $
    (5.9)

    By system (3.1) and inequality (5.9), we have for $ t > t_{2} $,

    $ {dxdt<x(t)[(1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1)x(t)],dz1dt<b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1N(2)1z1(t),dz2dt<b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2N(1)1z2(t).
    $
    (5.10)

    With the first inequality of (5.7), we see that

    $ 1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1=1a1[(b1N1eγ1τ(N1)μ1M(2)1)1β1ϵ22]a2[(b2N1eγ2τ(N1)μ2M(1)1)1β2ϵ22]>1a1b1β1N1eγ1τ(N1)a2b2β2N1eγ2τ(N1)>1a1b1β1M1eγ1τ(M1)a2b2β2M1eγ2τ(M1)>0.
    $
    (5.11)

    Then from inequalities (5.10) and (5.11), there exists a $ t_{3} > t_{2} $ and $ 0 < \epsilon_{3} < \min\{1/3, \epsilon_{2}\} $ such that, for $ t > t_{3} $,

    $ {x(t)<M2=1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1+ϵ3,z1(t)<M(1)2=(b1M2eγ1τ(M2)μ1N(2)1)1β1+ϵ32,z2(t)<M(2)2=(b2M2eγ2τ(M2)μ2N(1)1)1β2+ϵ32.
    $
    (5.12)

    We next prove that the estimates $ M_{2}^{(1)} $ and $ M_{2}^{(2)} $ are positive.

    $ b1M2eγ1τ(M2)μ1N(2)1=b1(1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1+ϵ3)eγ1τ(M2)μ1[(b2N1eγ2τ(N1)μ2M(1)1)1β2ϵ22]>b1(1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1)eγ1τ(M2)μ1b2β2N1eγ2τ(N1)>b1(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ1τ(0)μ1b2β2M1eγ2τ(M1)>0,
    $
    (5.13)

    and

    $ b2M2eγ2τ(M2)μ2N(1)1=b2(1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1+ϵ3)eγ2τ(M2)μ2[(b1N1eγ1τ(N1)μ1M(2)1)1β1ϵ22]>b2(1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1)eγ2τ(M2)μ2b1β1N1eγ1τ(N1)>b2(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)eγ2τ(0)μ2b1β1M1eγ1τ(M1)>0.
    $
    (5.14)

    In view of the upper estimates in equality (5.12), we will get a lower set of estimates. Since $ \epsilon_{3} < \epsilon_{1} $, inequalities (5.13) and (5.14), the following result is valid.

    $ 1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2=1a1[(b1M2eγ1τ(M2)μ1N(2)1)1β1+ϵ32]a2[(b2M2eγ2τ(M2)μ2N(1)1)1β2+ϵ32]>1a1(b1β1M2eγ1τ(M2)+ϵ32)a2(b2β2M2eγ2τ(M2)+ϵ32)>1a1(b1β1M1eγ1τ(M1)+ϵ32)a2(b2β2M1eγ2τ(M1)+ϵ32)>0.
    $
    (5.15)

    Denote $ n_{2}, $ $ n_{2}^{(1)} $, $ n_{2}^{(2)} $ as follows:

    $ {n2=1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2,n(1)2=b1n2eγ1τ(n2)μ1M(2)2,n(2)2=b2n2eγ2τ(n2)μ2M(1)2.
    $
    (5.16)

    By inequalities (5.2) and (5.15) and the second inequality of (5.7), we get that

    $ n(1)2=b1(1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2)eγ1τ(n2)μ1M(2)2>b1(1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2)eγ1τ(0)μ1M(2)1>0.
    $
    (5.17)

    It follows from inequalities (5.3) and (5.15) and the third inequality of (5.7) that

    $ n(2)2=b2(1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2)eγ2τ(n2)μ2M(1)2>b2(1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2)eγ2τ(0)μ2M(1)1>0.
    $
    (5.18)

    Combining with inequalities (5.15)–(5.18), there exists a $ 0 < \epsilon_{4} < \min\{1/4, \epsilon_{3}\} $ satisfying

    $ {n2ϵ4>0,(b1n2eγ1τ(n2)μ1M(2)2)1β1ϵ42>0,(b2n2eγ2τ(n2)μ2M(1)2)1β2ϵ42>0.
    $
    (5.19)

    With the upper estimates in inequality (5.12), we obtain the following comparative system for all $ t > t_{3} $.

    $ {dxdt>x(t)[(1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2)x(t)],dz1dt>b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1M(2)2z1(t),dz2dt>b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2M(1)2z2(t).
    $

    Using inequality (5.19), there exists a $ t_{4} > t_{3} $ such that

    $ {x(t)>N2=1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2ϵ4,z1(t)>N(1)2=(b1N2eγ1τ(N2)μ1M(2)2)1β1ϵ42,z2(t)>N(2)2=(b2N2eγ2τ(N2)μ2M(1)2)1β2ϵ42.
    $

    The estimates $ N_{2} $, $ N_{2}^{(1)} $ and $ N_{2}^{(2)} $ are all positive by inequality (5.19). Therefore, we obtain that, for $ t > t_{2} $,

    $ N1<x(t)<M1,N(1)1<z1(t)<M(1)1,N(2)1<z2(t)<M(2)1,
    $

    and for $ t > t_{4} $,

    $ N2<x(t)<M2,N(1)2<z1(t)<M(1)2,N(2)2<z2(t)<M(2)2.
    $

    Now we compare the obtained estimates, respectively:

    $ M2M1=1a1N(1)1a2N(2)1+ϵ3(1ϵ1)<ϵ3ϵ1<0,M(1)2M(1)1=(b1M2eγ1τ(M2)μ1N(2)1)1β1+ϵ32b1β1eγ1τ(M1)ϵ12<b1β1M2eγ1τ(M2)b1β1M1eγ1τ(M1)+12(ϵ3ϵ1)<b1β1eγ1τ(M1)(M2M1)+12(ϵ3ϵ1)<0.
    $

    Similarly, $ M_{2}^{(2)}-M_{1}^{(2)} < 0. $

    Moreover,

    $ N2N1=1a1M(1)2a2M(2)2ϵ4(1a1M(1)1a2M(2)1)+ϵ2=a1(M(1)2M(1)1)a2(M(2)2M(2)1)+(ϵ2ϵ4)>0,
    $

    and

    $ N(1)2N(1)1=(b1N2eγ1τ(N2)μ1M(2)2)1β1ϵ42(b1N1eγ1τ(N1)μ1M(2)1)1β1+ϵ22>b1β1eγ1τ(N1)(N2N1)μ1β1(M(2)2M(2)1)+12(ϵ2ϵ4)>0.
    $

    Similarly, $ N_{2}^{(2)}-N_{1}^{(2)} > 0. $

    Hence, from the above arguments, we have for $ t > t_{4} $

    $ N1<N2<x(t)<M2<M1,N(1)1<N(1)2<z1(t)<M(1)2<M(1)1,N(2)1<N(2)2<z2(t)<M(2)2<M(2)1.
    $

    By extending the above step, it then follows that

    $ N1<N2<N3<<Nn<x(t)<Mn<<M3<M2<M1,N(1)1<N(1)2<N(1)3<<N(1)n<z1(t)<M(1)n<<M(1)3<M(1)2<M(1)1,N(2)1<N(2)2<N(2)3<<N(2)n<z2(t)<M(2)n<<M(2)3<M(2)2<M(2)1,
    $

    where

    $ Mn=1a1N(1)n1a2N(2)n1+ϵ2n1,M(1)n=(b1Mneγ1τ(Mn)μ1N(2)n1)1β1+ϵ2n12,M(2)n=(b2Mneγ2τ(Mn)μ2N(2)n1)1β2+ϵ2n12,
    $
    (5.20)

    with $ n = 2, 3, 4, \cdots $, and

    $ Nn=1a1M(1)na2M(2)nϵ2n,N(1)n=(b1Nneγ1τ(Nn)μ1M(2)n)1β1ϵ2n2,N(2)n=(b2Nneγ2τ(Nn)μ2M(2)n)1β2ϵ2n12,
    $
    (5.21)

    with $ n = 1, 2, 3, \cdots $.

    Since $ \epsilon_{n} < 1/n $, we have $ \epsilon_{n}\rightarrow 0 $ as $ n\rightarrow\infty $. And the monotone sequences $ N_{n} $, $ N_{n}^{(1)} $, $ N_{n}^{(2)} $, $ M_{n} $, $ M_{n}^{(1)} $, and $ M_{n}^{(2)} $ converge to positive limits as $ n\rightarrow\infty $. Let

    $ M=limnMnandN=limnNn,M(1)=limnM(1)nandN(1)=limnN(1)n,M(2)=limnM(2)nandN(2)=limnN(2)n.
    $
    (5.22)

    By virtue of Eqs (5.20)–(5.22) and $ \lim_{n\rightarrow\infty}\epsilon_{n} = 0 $, it follows that

    $ M=1a1N(1)a2N(2),N=1a1M(1)a2M(2),
    $
    (5.23)

    and

    $ β1M(1)=b1Meγ1τ(M)μ1N(2),β1N(1)=b1Neγ1τ(N)μ1M(2),β2M(2)=b2Meγ2τ(M)μ2N(1),β2N(2)=b2Neγ2τ(N)μ2M(1).
    $
    (5.24)

    From Eq (5.24), we have

    $ M(1)N(1)=b1β2B1+b2μ1B2β1β2μ1μ2,M(2)N(2)=b1μ2B1+b2β1B2β1β2μ1μ2,
    $
    (5.25)

    where $ B_{1} = \Big(M_{*}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(M_{*})}-N_{*}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(N_{*})}\Big) $, $ B_{2} = \Big(M_{*}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(M_{*})}-N_{*}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(N_{*})}\Big). $

    Combining Eqs (5.23) and (5.25), we see that

    $ MN=a1(M(1)N(1))a2(M(2)N(2))=(a1b1β2+a2b1μ2)B1+(a1b2μ1+a2b2β1)B2β1β2μ1μ2.
    $

    Let $ Q_{1} = (a_{1}b_{1}\beta_{2}+a_{2}b_{1}\mu_{2})/(\beta_{1}\beta_{2}-\mu_{1}\mu_{2}) $, $ Q_{2} = (a_{1}b_{2}\mu_{1}+a_{2}b_{2}\beta_{1})/(\beta_{1}\beta_{2}-\mu_{1}\mu_{2}) $, then

    $ M(1Q1eγ1τ(M)Q2eγ2τ(M))=N(1Q1eγ1τ(N)Q2eγ2τ(N)).
    $
    (5.26)

    Denote $ h(x) = x\big(1-Q_{1}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(x)}-Q_{2}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(x)}\big) $, for all $ x\geq0 $. From (5.4) and $ \tau'(x)\leq0 $, we have

    $ h(x)=1Q1eγ1τ(x)Q2eγ2τ(x)+x[Q1γ1τ(x)eγ1τ(x)+Q2γ2τ(x)eγ2τ(x)]<1Q1eγ1τ(x)Q2eγ2τ(x)<1Q1eγ1τ(0)Q2eγ2τ(0)<0,
    $

    and thus, $ h(x) $ is a monotone decrease function with respect to $ x $. It then follows from Eq (5.26) that $ M_{*} = N_{*} $. Therefore, $ M_{*}^{(1)} = N_{*}^{(1)} $ and $ M_{*}^{(2)} = N_{*}^{(2)} $. Further, the relations in Eqs (5.23) and (5.24) are also true for $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $. Then by the uniqueness of the coexistence equilibrium of system (3.1), we know that $ \Big(M_{*}, M_{*}^{(1)}, M_{*}^{(2)}\Big) $ and $ \Big(N_{*}, N_{*}^{(1)}, N_{*}^{(2)}\Big) $ are the coexistence equilibrium of system (3.1), and hence $ M_{*} = N_{*} = x^{*} $, $ M_{*}^{(1)} = M_{*}^{(1)} = z_{1}^{*} $, $ M_{*}^{(2)} = M_{*}^{(2)} = z_{2}^{*} $. Accordingly, $ x^{*} = \lim_{t\rightarrow\infty}x(t) $, $ z_{1}^{*} = \lim_{t\rightarrow\infty}z_{1}(t) $ and $ z_{2}^{*} = \lim_{t\rightarrow\infty}z_{2}(t) $. The proof is complete.

    Next we deduce the global attractivity for the other variables $ y_{1} $ and $ y_{2} $ in system (2.3). By using the integral form for $ y_{1} $ and $ y_{2} $, we obtain that

    $ yi=limtyi(t)=ttτ(x)bixzieγi(ts)ds,i=1,2.
    $

    Therefore, we have the following result.

    Theorem 5.2. Let condition (3.3) hold. Assume that conditions (5.1)-(5.4) hold true, then the coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, y_{1}^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, y_{2}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $ is globally attractive for system (2.3).

    At the end of this section, we give the dynamical results of two boundary equilibria and coexistence equilibrium for the original system (2.2). The reduced system of model (2.2) is as follows.

    $ {dxdt=rx(t)(1x(t)K)a1x(t)z1(t)a2x(t)z2(t),dz1dt=b1[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z1(tτ(x))eγ1τ(x)β1z21(t)μ1z1(t)z2(t),dz2dt=b2[1τ(x)x(t)]x(tτ(x))z2(tτ(x))eγ2τ(x)β2z22(t)μ2z1(t)z2(t).
    $
    (5.27)

    Obviously, system (5.27) has exactly one trivial equilibrium $ E_{0} = (0, 0, 0) $, one semitrivial equilibrium $ E_{1} = (K, 0, 0) $, two boundary equilibria $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $ and $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $. And condition (3.3) holds true, then there exists a unique coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} = (x^{*}, z_{1}^{*}, z_{2}^{*}) $.

    Theorem 5.3. If $ \hat{z_{1}} < 3r/(4a_{1}) $ and $ b_{1}\mu_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\hat{x})} > b_{2}\beta_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $, then the boundary equilibrium $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $ of system (5.27) is locally asymptotically stable.

    Theorem 5.4. If $ \tilde{z_{2}} < 3r/(4a_{2}) $ and $ b_{2}\mu_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\tilde{x})} > b_{1}\beta_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\tilde{x})} $, then the boundary equilibrium $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $ of system (5.27) is locally asymptotically stable.

    Theorem 5.5. Let condition (3.3) hold, and assume that:

    $ r>a1b1β1Keγ1τ(K)+a2b2β2Keγ2τ(K);
    $
    (5.28)
    $ b1(ra1Kb1β1eγ1τ(K)a2Kb2β2eγ2τ(K))eγ1τ(0)1r>μ1b2β2eγ2τ(K);
    $
    (5.29)
    $ b2(ra1Kb1β1eγ1τ(K)a2Kb2β2eγ2τ(K))eγ2τ(0)1r>μ2b1β1eγ1τ(K);
    $
    (5.30)
    $ Kr[(a1b1β2+a2b1μ2)eγ1τ(0)+(a1b2μ1+a2b2β1)eγ2τ(0)]>β1β2μ1μ2.
    $
    (5.31)

    Then the coexistence equilibrium $ E^{*} $ of system (5.27) is globally attractive.

    In this paper, given that the maturity time of Antarctic whales and seals varies with the number of krill available around the Second World War, we formulated a consumer-resource competition model that, for the first time, incorporates a state-dependent maturity time delay associated with resource changes and structured consumer species. The main difference from the state-dependent delay equations previously studied is that model (2.3) directly manifests the relationship between resources and maturity time of consumers through the correction term, $ 1-\tau'(x(t))x'(t) $.

    Besides, the state-dependent delay $ \tau(x(t)) $ reflects exploitation and interference competition effects of two consumer species. On one hand, the exploitative ability of the mature individual is stronger, the juvenile will get more resources, which leads to a shorter maturation time. On the other hand, because of the limited resource, the consumer species spend more time and energy to obtain resource for keeping themselves alive. Unfortunately, what often happens is that there is not enough food for their children and so they take longer time to mature. Further, it is clear that the greater the ability of an adult to intervene is, the shorter the maturity time is.

    From mathematical point of view, firstly, we study the well-posedness of the solution for model (2.3) and the existence and uniqueness of all equilibria. We then show the linear stability of equilibria. The trivial equilibria $ E_{0} = (0, 0, 0) $ and $ E_{1} = (1, 0, 0) $ are always unstable, which can be explained by the fact that since the resource is self-renewing with a logistic growth and two competitive species depend entirely on it, the resource are not used up or maximized. For the linear stability of boundary equilibrium $ E_{2} = (\hat{x}, \hat{z_{1}}, 0) $, according to Theorem 4.4, the first sufficient condition $ \hat{z_{1}} < 3/(4a_{1}) $ is equivalent to $ \hat{x} > 1/4 $, which means the resource must be the specific level to make sure that one of the consumer species survives. For the original system (2.2), in Theorem 5.3, the condition is changed to $ \hat{z_{1}} < 3r/(4a_{1}) $, which is equivalent to $ \hat{x} > K-3K/(4r) $ and implies that the resource must be above a certain value of the interaction between the growth rate of resource and its carrying capacity. And another sufficient condition $ b_{1}\mu_{2}e^{-\gamma_{1}\tau(\hat{x})} > b_{2}\beta_{1}e^{-\gamma_{2}\tau(\hat{x})} $ implies $ (b_{1}\hat{x}e^{-\gamma_{1}\hat{x}})/\beta_{1} > (b_{2}\hat{x}e^{-\gamma_{2}\hat{x}})/\mu_{2} $, on the basis of the threshold resource $ \hat{x} $, when the maximum growth of the first species is large than the interspecific competitive effect on the second species, the second species has a negative growth effect, which illustrates the first species will win the competition. There is a similar biological explanation for the linear stability of $ E_{3} = (\tilde{x}, 0, \tilde{z_{2}}) $. Finally, we discuss the global properties of $ E^{*} $. Theorem 5.1 shows the sufficient conditions for $ E^{*} $ to be globally attractive. The condition (5.1) implies that the number of the two consumers are at their potential maximum, and the maximum self-updating value of the resource is large than the exploitation effects; conditions (5.2) and (5.3) imply that when the resource is at its minimum, the number of the consumers who were born at time $ t-\tau(x(t)) $ and still alive now are enough to make up for the possible interspecific competition effects; condition (5.4) is a technical assumption and has no practical biological significance. For the global properties of $ E^{*} $ in original system (2.2), the condition (5.28) implies that when the maximum carrying capacity $ K $ of the resource is reached, the two consumers are at their potential maximum, and the growth rate $ r $ of the resource is larger than the exploitation effect. Conditions (5.29) and (5.30) have biological explanations similar to conditions (5.2) and (5.3).

    This paper only considers the case of one resource. And since the fitting of state-dependent delay $ \tau(x(t)) $ is very challenging, we are unable to validate theoretical results by numerical simulations. We would like to leave this problem and propose a competition model with state-dependent delay between two species for two resources in the further research.

    This work is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant Nos. 11671327, 11901326). We are grateful to the editor and reviewers for their valuable comments and suggestions that greatly improved the presentation of this paper.

    The authors declared that they have no conflicts of interest to this work.

    [1] Hirsch J, Ruge MI, Kim KH, et al. (2000) An integrated functional magnetic resonance imaging procedure for preoperative mapping of cortical areas associated with tactile, motor, language, and visual functions. Neurosurgery 47: 711–722.
    [2] Yoo SS, Fairneny T, Chen NK, et al. (2004) Brain computer interface using fMRI: Spatial navigation by thoughts. Neuroreport 15: 1591–1595. doi: 10.1097/01.wnr.0000133296.39160.fe
    [3] Sorger B, Reithler J, Dahmen B, et al. (2012) A real-time fMRI-based spelling device immediately enabling robust motor-independent communication. Curr Biol 22: 1333–1338. doi: 10.1016/j.cub.2012.05.022
    [4] Yoo JJ, Hinds O, Ofen N, et al. (2012) When the brain is prepared to learn: Enhancing human learning using real-time fMRI. Neuroimage 59: 846–852. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2011.07.063
    [5] Weiskopf N, Veit R, Erb M, et al. (2003) Physiological self-regulation of regional brain activity using real-time functional magnetic resonance imaging (fMRI): Methodology and exemplary data. Neuroimage 19: 577–586. doi: 10.1016/S1053-8119(03)00145-9
    [6] Mak JN, Wolpaw JR (2009) Clinical applications of brain-computer interfaces: Current state and future prospects. IEEE Rev Biomed Eng 2: 187–199. doi: 10.1109/RBME.2009.2035356
    [7] Logothetis NK, Pauls J, Augath M, et al. (2001) Neurophysiological investigation of the basis of the fMRI signal. Nature 412: 150–157. doi: 10.1038/35084005
    [8] Longden TA, Dabertrand F, Koide M, et al. (2017) Capillary K+-sensing initiates retrograde hyperpolarization to increase local cerebral blood flow. Nat Neurosci 20: 717–726. doi: 10.1038/nn.4533
    [9] Hamilton JP, Glover GH, Hsu JJ, et al. (2011) Modulation of subgenual anterior cingulate cortex activity with real-time neurofeedback. Hum Brain Mapp 32: 22–31. doi: 10.1002/hbm.20997
    [10] Zotev V, Krueger F, Phillips R, et al. (2011) Self-regulation of amygdala activation using real-time fMRI neurofeedback. PLoS One 6: e24522. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0024522
    [11] Caria A, Veit R, Sitaram R, et al. (2007) Regulation of anterior insular cortex activity using real-time fMRI. Neuroimage 35: 1238–1246. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2007.01.018
    [12] Veit R, Singh V, Sitaram R, et al. (2012) Using real-time fMRI to learn voluntary regulation of the anterior insula in the presence of threat-related stimuli. Soc Cogn Affect Neurosci 7: 623–634. doi: 10.1093/scan/nsr061
    [13] Lee JH, Kim J, Yoo SS (2012) Real-time fMRI-based neurofeedback reinforces causality of attention networks. Neurosci Res 72: 347–354. doi: 10.1016/j.neures.2012.01.002
    [14] Mccaig RG, Dixon M, Keramatian K, et al. (2011) Improved modulation of rostrolateral prefrontal cortex using real-time fMRI training and meta-cognitive awareness. Neuroimage 55: 1298–1305. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2010.12.016
    [15] Zhang G, Yao L, Zhang H, et al. (2013) Improved working memory performance through self-regulation of dorsal lateral prefrontal cortex activation using real-time fMRI. PLoS One 8: e73735. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0073735
    [16] Sherwood MS, Kane JH, Weisend MP, et al. (2016) Enhanced control of dorsolateral prefrontal cortex neurophysiology with real-time functional magnetic resonance imaging (rt-fMRI) neurofeedback training and working memory practice. Neuroimage 124: 214–223. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2015.08.074
    [17] Sherwood MS, Weisend MP, Kane JH, et al. (2016) Combining real-time fMRI neurofeedback training of the DLPFC with N-Back practice results in neuroplastic effects confined to the neurofeedback target region. Front Behav Neurosci 10: 1–9.
    [18] Sitaram R, Veit R, Stevens B, et al. (2012) Acquired control of ventral premotor cortex activity by feedback training: An exploratory real-time fMRI and TMS study. Neurorehabil Neural Repair 26: 256–265. doi: 10.1177/1545968311418345
    [19] Berman BD, Horovitz SG, Venkataraman G, et al. (2012) Self-modulation of primary motor cortex activity with motor and motor imagery tasks using real-time fMRI-based neurofeedback. Neuroimage 59: 917–925. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2011.07.035
    [20] Chiew M, Laconte SM, Graham SJ (2012) Investigation of fMRI neurofeedback of differential primary motor cortex activity using kinesthetic motor imagery. Neuroimage 61: 21–31. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2012.02.053
    [21] Haller S, Birbaumer N, Veit R (2010) Real-time fMRI feedback training may improve chronic tinnitus. Eur Radiol 20: 696–703. doi: 10.1007/s00330-009-1595-z
    [22] Haller S, Kopel R, Jhooti P, et al. (2013) Dynamic reconfiguration of human brain functional networks through neurofeedback. Neuroimage 81: 243–252. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2013.05.019
    [23] Yoo SS, O'Leary HM, Fairneny T, et al. (2006) Increasing cortical activity in auditory areas through neurofeedback functional magnetic resonance imaging. Neuroreport 17: 1273–1278. doi: 10.1097/01.wnr.0000227996.53540.22
    [24] Johnston S, Linden DE, Healy D, et al. (2011) Upregulation of emotion areas through neurofeedback with a focus on positive mood. Cogn it Affective Behav Neurosci 11: 44–51. doi: 10.3758/s13415-010-0010-1
    [25] Johnston SJ, Boehm SG, Healy D, et al. (2010) Neurofeedback: A promising tool for the self-regulation of emotion networks. Neuroimage 49: 1066–1072. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2009.07.056
    [26] Rota G, Sitaram R, Veit R, et al. (2010) Self-regulation of regional cortical activity using real-time fMRI: The right inferior frontal gyrus and linguistic processing. Hum Brain Mapp 30: 1605–1614.
    [27] Scharnowski F, Hutton C, Josephs O, et al. (2012) Improving visual perception through neurofeedback. J Neurosci 32: 17830–17841. doi: 10.1523/JNEUROSCI.6334-11.2012
    [28] Shibata K, Kawato M (2011) Perceptual learning incepted by decoded fmri neurofeedback without stimulus presentation. Science 334: 1413–1415. doi: 10.1126/science.1212003
    [29] Decharms RC, Maeda F, Glover GH, et al. (2005) Control over brain activation and pain learned by using real-time functional MRI. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A 102: 18626–18631. doi: 10.1073/pnas.0505210102
    [30] Ruiz S, Lee S, Soekadar SR, et al. (2013) Acquired self-control of insula cortex modulates emotion recognition and brain network connectivity in schizophrenia. Hum Brain Mapp 34: 200–212. doi: 10.1002/hbm.21427
    [31] Subramanian L, Hindle JV, Johnston S, et al. (2011) Real-time functional magnetic resonance imaging neurofeedback for treatment of Parkinson's disease. J Neurosci 31: 16309–16317. doi: 10.1523/JNEUROSCI.3498-11.2011
    [32] Linden DEJ, Habes I, Johnston SJ, et al. (2012) Real-time self-regulation of emotion networks in patients with depression. PLoS One 7: e38115. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0038115
    [33] Decharms RC, Christoff K, Glover GH, et al. (2004) Learned regulation of spatially localized brain activation using real-time fMRI. Neuroimage 21: 436–443. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2003.08.041
    [34] Yoo SS, Lee JH, O'Leary H, et al. (2008) Neurofeedback fMRI-mediated learning and consolidation of regional brain activation during motor imagery. Int J Imaging Syst Technol 18: 69–78. doi: 10.1002/ima.20139
    [35] Birbaumer N, Cohen LG (2007) Brain-computer interfaces: Communication and restoration of movement in paralysis. J Physiol 579: 621–636. doi: 10.1113/jphysiol.2006.125633
    [36] Daly JJ, Wolpaw JR (2008) Brain-computer interfaces in neurological rehabilitation. Lancet Neurol 7: 1032–1043. doi: 10.1016/S1474-4422(08)70223-0
    [37] Ros T, Munneke MAM, Ruge D, et al. (2010) Endogenous control of waking brain rhythms induces neuroplasticity in humans. Eur J Neurosci 31: 770–778. doi: 10.1111/j.1460-9568.2010.07100.x
    [38] Orlov ND, Giampietro V, O'Daly O, et al. (2018) Real-time fMRI neurofeedback to down-regulate superior temporal gyrus activity in patients with schizophrenia and auditory hallucinations: A proof-of-concept study. Transl Psychiatry 8: 46. doi: 10.1038/s41398-017-0067-5
    [39] Paret C, Kluetsch R, Ruf M, et al. (2014) Down-regulation of amygdala activation with real-time fMRI neurofeedback in a healthy female sample. Front Behav Neurosci 8: 299.
    [40] Saliba J, Al-Reefi M, Carriere JS, et al. (2016) Accuracy of mobile-based audiometry in the evaluation of hearing loss in quiet and noisy environments. Otolaryngol Neck Surg 156: 706–711.
    [41] Thompson GP, Sladen DP, Borst BJ, et al. (2015) Accuracy of a tablet audiometer for measuring behavioral hearing thresholds in a clinical population. Otolaryngol Neck Surg 153: 838–842. doi: 10.1177/0194599815593737
    [42] Worsley KJ, Friston KJ (1995) Analysis of fMRI time-series revisited-again. Neuroimage 2: 173–181. doi: 10.1006/nimg.1995.1023
    [43] Ashby F Gregory (2011) Statistical analysis of fMRI data. MIT press.
    [44] Smith SM, Jenkinson M, Woolrich MW, et al. (2004) Advances in functional and structural MR image analysis and implementation as FSL. Math Brain Imaging 23: S208–S219.
    [45] Woolrich MW, Jbabdi S, Patenaude B, et al. (2009) Bayesian analysis of neuroimaging data in FSL. Math Brain Imaging 45: S173–S186.
    [46] Jenkinson M, Bannister P, Brady M, et al. (2002) Improved optimization for the robust and accurate linear registration and motion correction of brain images. Neuroimage 17: 825–841. doi: 10.1006/nimg.2002.1132
    [47] Smith SM (2002) Fast robust automated brain extraction. Hum Brain Mapp 17: 143–155. doi: 10.1002/hbm.10062
    [48] Greve DN, Fischl B (2009) Accurate and robust brain image alignment using boundary-based registration. Neuroimage 48: 63–72. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2009.06.060
    [49] Collins DL, Holmes CJ, Peters TM, et al. (2004) Automatic 3-D model-based neuroanatomical segmentation. Hum Brain Mapp 3: 190–208.
    [50] Mazziotta J, Toga A, Evans A, et al. (2002) A probabilistic atlas and reference system for the human brain: International Consortium for Brain Mapping (ICBM). Brain Mapp Methods 356: 1293–1322.
    [51] Young KD, Zotev V, Phillips R, et al. (2014) Real-time fMRI neurofeedback training of amygdala activity in patients with major depressive disorder. PLoS One 9: e88785. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0088785
    [52] Sulzer J, Haller S, Scharnowski F, et al. (2013) Real-time fMRI neurofeedback: Progress and challenges. Neuroimage 76: 386–399. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroimage.2013.03.033
    [53] Cox RW, Jesmanowicz A, Hyde JS (1995) Real-time functional magnetic resonance imaging. Magn Reson Med 33: 230–236. doi: 10.1002/mrm.1910330213
    [54] Weiskopf N, Sitaram R, Josephs O, et al. (2007) Real-time functional magnetic resonance imaging: Methods and applications. Proc Int Sch Magn Reson Brain Funct 25: 989–1003.
    [55] Folmer RL, Griest S, Martin W (2001) Chronic tinnitus as phantom auditory pain. Otolaryngol-Head Neck Surg 124: 394–400. doi: 10.1067/mhn.2001.114673
    [56] Berliner KI, Shelton C, Hitselberger WE, et al. (1992) Acoustic tumors: Effect of surgical removal on tinnitus. Otol Neurotol 13: 13.
    [57] Gu JW, Halpin CF, Nam EC, et al. (2010) Tinnitus, diminished sound-level tolerance, and elevated auditory activity in humans with clinically normal hearing sensitivity. J Neurophysiol 104: 3361–3370. doi: 10.1152/jn.00226.2010
    [58] Seydellgreenwald A, Leaver AM, Turesky TK, et al. (2012) Functional MRI evidence for a role of ventral prefrontal cortex in tinnitus. Brain Ress 1485: 22–39. doi: 10.1016/j.brainres.2012.08.052
    [59] Wang H, Tian J, Yin D, et al. (2001) Regional glucose metabolic increases in left auditory cortex in tinnitus patients: A preliminary study with positron emission tomography. Chin Med J 114: 848–851.
    [60] Langguth B, Eichhammer P, Kreutzer A, et al. (2006) The impact of auditory cortex activity on characterizing and treating patients with chronic tinnitus-first results from a PET study. Acta Otolaryngol 126: 84–88. doi: 10.1080/03655230600895317
    [61] Schecklmann M, Landgrebe M, Poeppl TB, et al. (2013) Neural correlates of tinnitus duration and Distress: A positron emission tomography study. Hum Brain Mapp 34: 233–240. doi: 10.1002/hbm.21426
    [62] Geven LI, de Kleine E, Willemsen ATM, et al. (2014) Asymmetry in primary auditory cortex activity in tinnitus patients and controls. Neuroscience 256: 117–125. doi: 10.1016/j.neuroscience.2013.10.015
    [63] Kim SG, Ogawa S (2012) Biophysical and physiological origins of blood oxygenation level-dependent fMRI signals. J Cereb Blood Flow Metab 32: 1188–1206. doi: 10.1038/jcbfm.2012.23
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Biao Tang, Kexin Ma, Yan Liu, Xia Wang, Sanyi Tang, Yanni Xiao, Robert A. Cheke, Kimberly M. Pepin, Managing spatio-temporal heterogeneity of susceptibles by embedding it into an homogeneous model: A mechanistic and deep learning study, 2024, 20, 1553-7358, e1012497, 10.1371/journal.pcbi.1012497
    2. Laura J. Faherty, Pedro Nascimento de Lima, Jing Zhi Lim, Derek Roberts, Sarah Karr, Emily Lawson, Henry H. Willis, Effects of non-pharmaceutical interventions on COVID-19 transmission: rapid review of evidence from Italy, the United States, the United Kingdom, and China, 2024, 12, 2296-2565, 10.3389/fpubh.2024.1426992
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2018 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(5387) PDF downloads(1082) Cited by(5)

Figures and Tables

Figures(6)  /  Tables(7)

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog