
Citation: Kevin R Caffrey, Mari S Chinn, Matthew W Veal. Biomass supply chain management in North Carolina (part 1): predictive model for cropland conversion to biomass feedstocks[J]. AIMS Energy, 2016, 4(2): 256-279. doi: 10.3934/energy.2016.2.256
[1] | Longfei Wei, Lu Liu, Jialong Hou . Pricing hybrid-triggered catastrophe bonds based on copula-EVT model. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(2): 223-243. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022010 |
[2] | Lianzhang Bao, Guangliang Zhao, Zhuo Jin . A new equilibrium trading model with asymmetric information. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(1): 217-229. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.1.217 |
[3] | Manuela Larguinho, José Carlos Dias, Carlos A. Braumann . Pricing and hedging bond options and sinking-fund bonds under the CIR model. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(1): 1-34. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022001 |
[4] | Jie Xiong, Geng Deng, Xindong Wang . Extension of SABR Libor Market Model to handle negative interest rates. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(1): 148-171. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020007 |
[5] | Lichao Tao, Yuefu Lai, Yanting Ji, Xiangxing Tao . Asian option pricing under sub-fractional vasicek model. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(3): 403-419. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023020 |
[6] | Richard J. Cebula, Don Capener . The impact of federal income tax rate cuts on the municipal bond market in the U.S.: A brief exploratory empirical note. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(2): 407-412. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.2.407 |
[7] | Serçin ŞAHİN, Serkan ÇİÇEK . Interest rate pass-through in Turkey during the period of unconventional interest rate corridor. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2018, 2(4): 837-859. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2018.4.837 |
[8] | Guillermo Peña . Interest rates affect public expenditure growth. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2023, 7(4): 622-645. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2023030 |
[9] | Bonang N. Seoela . Efficacy of monetary policy in a currency union? Evidence from Southern Africa's Common Monetary Area. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2022, 6(1): 35-53. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022002 |
[10] | Mustafa Tevfik Kartal, Özer Depren, Serpil Kılıç Depren . The determinants of main stock exchange index changes in emerging countries: evidence from Turkey in COVID-19 pandemic age. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2020, 4(4): 526-541. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2020025 |
Predator-prey models are highly important in general and mathematical ecology [1]. In the past decades, many factors have been considered to describe the ecological predator-prey system more correctly and reasonably [2,3]. Notably, population models in the real world is inevitably influenced by numerous unpredictable environmental noise, and deterministic systems are fairly challenged in describing the fluctuation accurately [4,5]. Hence, an increasing number of researchers have paid attention to stochastic models and proposed various population models with stochastic perturbations, such as in [6,7,8,9,10]. Liu and Wang [10] introduced a stochastic non-autonomous predator-prey model for one species with white noise as follows:
$ dx(t)=r(t)[x(t)−a(t)x(t)]dt+σ(t)x(t)dB(t). $ | (1.1) |
The group analyzed the conditions for extinction and species persistence in Eq (1.1). On the basis of the theoretical and practical significance of this stochastic model, many results have been presented, particularly, in [11,12,13]. However, the influence of the functional response to systems has been rarely considered in previous stochastic population models.
Generally, two types of functional response exist, that is, prey- and predator-dependent responses. The first functional response considers only the prey density, whereas the other accounts for both prey and predator densities [2]. When investigating biological phenomena, one must not ignore the predator's functional response to prey because of such response's effect on dynamical system properties [14,15,16,17,18]. Among many different forms of predator-dependent functional responses, the three classical ones include the Beddington-DeAngelis, Hassell-Varley and Crowley-Martin types. We let $ x_{1}(t) $ and $ x_{2}(t) $ denote the prey and predator population densities, respectively, at time $ t $. Then, $ \frac{\omega(t) x_{1}(t)}{1+a(t)x_{1}(t)+b(t)x_{2}(t)+a(t)b(t)x_{1}(t)x_{2}(t)} $ becomes the Crowley-Martin functional response, where $ a(t) $, $ b(t) $ and $ \omega(t) $ represent the effects of handling time, the magnitude of interference among predators, and capture rate, respectively. Interestingly, if $ a(t) = 0 $ and $ b(t) = 0 $, then the Crowley-Martin functional response becomes a linear mass-action functional response. If $ a(t) = 0 $ and $ b(t) > 0 $, the response represents a saturation response; if $ a(t) > 0 $ and $ b(t) = 0 $, then the response becomes a Michaelis-Menten functional response (or Holling type-II functional response) [1,19,20]. Given its importance and appeal, some scholars have studied stochastic predator-prey models incorporating Crowley-Martin functional response [21,22,23] and in this paper, we consider the Crowley-Martin functional response to embody interference among predators and provide insight into the dynamics of the predator-prey population model.
Meanwhile, the theory of impulsive differential equation was well developed recently, and impulsive differential equations were found as a more effective method for describing species and the ecological systems more realistically. Many important and peculiar results have been obtained regarding the dynamical behavior of these systems, including the permanence, extinction of positive solution and dynamical complexity. However, few studies have addressed the population dynamics of two species both with stochastic and impulsive perturbations, except in [24,25,26]. In [25], Zhang and Tan considered a stochastic autonomous predator-prey model in a polluted environment with impulsive perturbations and analyzed the extinction and persistence of the system. By contrast, the model proposed is autonomous, that is, the parameters are assumed as constants and independent of time. In [26], Wu, Zou, and Wang proposed a stochastic Lotka-Volterra model with impulsive perturbations. The asymptotic properties of the model were examined. However, their model was based on the prey-dependent functional response and did not consider the predator's functional response to prey. In addition, there are four approaches to introduce stochastic perturbations to the model as usual, through time Markov chain model, parameter perturbation, being proportional to the variables, and robusting the positive equilibria of deterministic models [27]. In this paper, we adopt the third approach to include stochastic effects to Eq (1.2).
Inspired by the above discussion and [11,25,26], we consider the possible effects of impulsive and stochastic perturbations on the system and propose the following non-autonomous stochastic differential equation:
$ {dx1(t)=x1(r(t)−k(t)x1−ω(t)x21+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2)dt+x1σ1(t)dB1(t),dx2(t)=x2(−g(t)−h(t)x2+f(t)x11+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2)dt+x2σ2(t)dB2(t),t≠τk,x1(τ+k)=(1+ρ1k)x1(τk),x2(τ+k)=(1+ρ2k)x2(τk),t=τk,k=1,2,3,… $ | (1.2) |
The parameters are defined as follows: $ r(t) $ and $ g(t) $ denote the intrinsic growth rate of the prey and predator population at time $ t $; $ k(t) $ and $ h(t) $ are the density-dependent coefficients of prey and predator populations, respectively; $ f(t) $ represents the conversion rate of nutrients into the reproductive predator population; $ \sigma_{i}^{2}(t) $ $ (i = 1, 2) $ refers to the intensities of the white noises at time $ t $; $ \dot{B}_{1}(t) $ and $ \dot{B}_{2}(t) $ are standard white noises, in particular, $ B_{1}(t), B_{2}(t) $ are Brownian motions defined on a complete probability space $ (\Omega, \mathcal{F}, \mathbb{ P}) $ [6].
Throughout this paper, all the coefficients are assumed to be positive and continuously bounded on $ \mathbb{R}_{+} = [0, +\infty) $. The impulsive points satisfy $ 0 < \tau_{1} < \tau_{2} < \ldots < \tau_{k} < \ldots $ and $ \lim\limits_{k\rightarrow +\infty} \tau_{k} = +\infty $. According to biological meanings, $ \rho_{1k} > -1, \rho_{2k} > -1 $. Moreover, we assume that there are some positive constants $ m $, $ M $, $ \widetilde{m} $ and $ \widetilde{M} $ that satisfy $ 0 < m\leq \prod\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t} (1+\rho_{1k})\leq M $ and $ 0 < \widetilde{m}\leq \prod\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t} (1+\rho_{2k})\leq \widetilde{M} $, for all $ t > 0 $.
The remaining portion of this paper is arranged as follows. In the next section, some preliminaries are introduced. We analyze the impulsive stochastic differential model and obtain the existence, uniqueness and stochastically ultimate boundness of the positive solution in Section 3. In Section 4, sufficient conditions for extinction and a set of persistence in the mean, including non-persistence, weak persistence, and strong persistence in the mean, are presented. Additionally, we provide conditions to guarantee the stochastic permanence of the system. In Section 5, the global attractiveness of Eq (1.2) is studied. Finally, some numerical simulations, which verify our theoretical results, are given in Section 6. We compare the results of stochastic models under positive or negative impulsive perturbations with those without such disturbances, as well as, the figures with different stochastic perturbations and same impulse. By doing so, we clearly show that the impulsive and stochastic perturbations are of great importance to species permanence and extinction.
To proceed, we list some appropriate definitions, notations, and lemmas as follows. For convenience, we denote
$ f^{u} = \sup\limits_{t\geq 0} f(t), \quad\ f^{l} = \inf\limits_{ t\geq 0} f(t), \quad\langle f(t)\rangle = \frac{1}{t}\int_{0}^{t}f(s)ds, \quad f^{*} = \limsup\limits_{ t\rightarrow +\infty}f(t), \quad f_{*} = \liminf\limits_{ t\rightarrow +\infty}f(t), $ |
where $ f(t) $ is a continuous and bound function defined on $ [0, +\infty) $. $ X(t) $ represents $ (x_{1}(t), x_{2}(t)) $ and $ |X(t)| = (x_{1}^{2}(t)+x_{2}^{2}(t))^{\frac{1}{2}} $. $ \mathbb{N} $ is the set of positive integers and $ \mathbb{R}_{+}^{n} = \{x\in \mathbb{R}^{n}: x_{i} > 0, i = 1, 2, 3...n\} $.
Definition 2.1.
(a) If $ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow +\infty}x(t) = 0 $ a.s., then the species $ x(t) $ is said to go to extinction.
(b) If $ \langle x\rangle^{*} = 0 $ a.s., then the population $ x(t) $ is said to be non-persistent in the mean.
(c) If $ \langle x\rangle^{*} > 0 $ a.s., then the population $ x(t) $ is said to be weakly persistent in the mean.
(d) If $ \langle x\rangle_{*} > 0 $ a.s., then the population $ x(t) $ is said to be strongly persistent in the mean.
(e) If $ x^{*} > 0 $ a.s., then the population $ x(t) $ is said to be weakly persistent.
Definition 2.2 ([28]) Solution $ X(t) = (x_{1}(t), x_{2}(t)) $ of Eq (1.2) is said to be stochastically ultimately bound, if for arbitrary $ \varepsilon \in (0, 1) $, a positive constant $ \delta = \delta(\varepsilon) $ exists, such that for any given initial value $ X_{0} = (x_{1}(0), x_{2}(0)) \in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $, the solution $ X(t) $ to Eq (1.2) satisfies $ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \text{P}\{|X(t)| > \delta\} < \varepsilon. $
Definition 2.3 ([28]) Solution $ X(t) = (x_{1}(t), x_{2}(t)) $ of Eq (1.2) is said to be stochastically permanent, if for any $ \varepsilon \in (0, 1) $, there is a pair of positive constants $ \delta = \delta(\varepsilon) $ and $ \chi = \chi(\varepsilon) $ such that for any initial value $ X_{0} = (x_{1}(0), x_{2}(0))\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $, the solution $ X(t) $ to Eq (1.2) satisfies $ \liminf\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \text{P}\{|X(t)|\geq\delta\}\geq 1-\varepsilon $, $ \liminf\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \text{P}\{|X(t)|\leq\chi\}\geq 1-\varepsilon $.
Definition 2.4. Eq (1.2) is said to be globally attractive if
$ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow +\infty}|x_{1}(t)-\overline{x}_{1}(t)| = 0, \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow +\infty}|x_{2}(t)-\overline{x}_{2}(t)| = 0, $ |
for any two solutions $ (x_{1}(t), x_{2}(t)) $, $ (\overline{x}_{1}(t), \overline{x}_{2}(t)) $ of Eq (1.2).
Definition 2.5. ([29]) Consider the impulsive stochastic equation
$ dx(t)=F(t,x(t))dt+G(t,x(t))dB(t),t≠tk,t>0,x(t+k)−x(tk)=αkx(tk),t=tk,k=1,2,⋯ $ | (2.1) |
with the initial value $ x(0) = x_{0}\in \mathbb{R}^{n} $. A stochastic process $ x(t) = (x_{1}(t), x_{2}(t), \cdots, x_{n}(t))^{T} $, $ t\in[0, +\infty) $ is the solution of Eq (2.1) if
(a) $ x(t) $ is $ \mathcal{F}_{t} $ adapted and continuous on $ (0, t_{1}) $ and each interval $ (t_{k}, t_{k+1}) $, $ k\in \mathbb{N} $ and $ F(t, x(t))\in L^{1}(\mathbb{R}^{+}, \mathbb{R}^{n}) $, $ G(t, x(t))\in L^{2}(\mathbb{R}^{+}, \mathbb{R}^{n}) $.
(b) For each $ t_{k} $, $ x(t^{+}_{k}) = \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow t^{+}_{k}}x(t) $ and $ x(t^{-}_{k}) = \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow t^{-}_{k}}x(t) $ and $ x(t_{k}) = x(t^{-}_{k}) $ a.s..
(c) $ x(t) $ obeys the equivalent integral Eq (2.1) for almost every $ t\in \mathbb{R}_{+}\setminus t_{k} $ and satisfies the impulsive conditions at $ t = t_{k} $ a.s..
Lemma 2.1. ([5]) Suppose that $ x(t) \in \bf{C}[\Omega \times\mathbb{ R}_{+}, \mathbb{R}_{+}^{0}] $, where $ \mathbb{R}_{+}^{0} = (0, +\infty) $ and $ B_{i}(t) $ $ (i = 1, 2, 3, \ldots, n) $ are independent Brownian motions defined on a complete probability space $ (\Omega, \mathcal{F}, \mathbb{ P}) $, then
$ (a) $ If there are positive constants $ \lambda_{0}, T $ and $ \lambda \geq 0 $ satisfying
$ \text{ln} x(t) \leq \lambda t-\lambda_{0}\int_{0}^{t}x(s) \text{d}s+\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n}\beta_{i} B_{i}(t), $ |
for all $ t \geq T $, where $ \beta_{i} $ is a constant, $ 1\leq i\leq n $, then, $ \langle x\rangle^{*} \leq \lambda/\lambda_{0} $ a.s.
$ (b) $ If there are positive constants $ \lambda_{0}, T $ and $ \lambda \geq 0 $ satisfying
$ \text{ln} x(t) \geq \lambda t-\lambda_{0}\int_{0}^{t}x(s) \text{d}s+\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n}\beta_{i} B_{i}(t), $ |
for all $ t \geq T $, where $ \beta_{i} $ is a constant, $ 1\leq i\leq n $, then, $ \langle x\rangle_{*} \geq \lambda/\lambda_{0} $ a.s.
Lemma 2.2. ([30]) Let $ f $ be a non-negative function defined on $ \mathbb{R}_{+} $ such that $ f $ is integrate and is uniformly continuous. Then $ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow +\infty} f(t) = 0 $.
In this section, the existence, uniqueness, and stochastically ultimate boundedness of the global positive solution are obtained.
Firstly, we denote
$ x_{1}(t) = \prod\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t}(1+\rho_{1k})y_{1}(t), \quad x_{2}(t) = \prod\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t}(1+\rho_{2k})y_{2}(t), $ |
$ \lambda(t) = 1+a(t)\prod\limits\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t}(1+\rho_{1k})y_{1} +b(t)\prod\limits\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t}(1+\rho_{2k})y_{2} +a(t)b(t)\prod\limits\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t}(1+\rho_{1k})\prod\limits\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t}(1+\rho_{2k})y_{1} y_{2}, $ |
then by virtue of Lemma 2.1 in [30], the following lemma can be obtained.
Lemma 3.1. For the stochastic equations without impulses
$ dy1(t)=y1(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2)dt+y1σ1(t)dB1(t),dy2(t)=y2(−g(t)−h(t)∏0<ρ2k<t(1+ρ1k)y2+f(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1)dt+y2σ2(t)dB2(t), $ | (3.1) |
$ (y_{1}(t), y_{2}(t)) $ is a solution of Eq (3.1) if and only if $ (x_{1}(t), x_{2}(t)) $ is a solution of Eq (1.2) with initial value $ (x_{1}(0), x_{2}(0)) = (y_{1}(0), y_{2}(0)) $.
The proof can be given easily as in [31], but such approach is not applied herein.
Theorem 3.1 For any given value $ (x_{1}(0), x_{2}(0)) = X_{0} $$ \in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $, a unique solution $ (x_{1}(t), x_{2}(t)) $ exists for Equation (1.2) on $ t\geq 0 $ and the solution will remain in $ \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $ with probability one.
The proof of Theorem 3.1 is standard and is presented in Appendix A.
Theorem 3.2 The solutions of Eq (1.2) are stochastically ultimately bounded for any initial value $ X_{0} = (x_{1}(0), x_{2}(0))\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $.
The proof of Theorem 3.2 is presented in Appendix A.
In this section, sufficient conditions for extinction and a series of persistence in the mean, such as non-persistence, weak persistence and strong persistence in the mean, are established. Furthermore, we obtain conditions to guarantee the stochastic permanence of the system. Before giving the main theorems, we introduce a lemma essential to our proofs.
Lemma 4.1. If $ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{\prod\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t}(1+\rho_{1k})}{ \text{ln}t} < \infty $, $ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{\prod\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t}(1+\rho_{2k})}{ \text{ln}t} < \infty $ hold, then for any initial value $ (x_{1}(0), x_{2}(0)) \in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $, the solution $ X_{1}(t) = (x_{1}(t), x_{2}(t)) $ of Eq (1.2) satisfies
$ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}x_{1}(t)}{t}\leq 0, \quad\limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}x_{2}(t)}{t}\leq 0, \qquad a.s. $ |
The proof of Lemma 4.1 is given in Appendix A.
The results about persistence in the mean and extinction of the prey and predator populations are presented in Theorems 4.1.1 and 4.1.2.
Theorem 4.1.1 For the prey population $ x_{1} $ of Eq (1.2), we have
(a) If $ \widehat{r}_{1} < 0 $, then the prey population $ x_{1} $ is extinct with probability 1, where $ r_{1}(t) = r(t)-0.5\sigma_{1}^{2}(t) $, $ \widehat{r}_{1} = \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow+\infty}\frac{1}{t}[\sum\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{1k})+\int_{0}^{t}r_{1}(s)ds] $.
(b) If $ \widehat{r}_{1} = 0 $, then the prey population $ x_{1} $ is non-persistent in the mean with probability 1.
(c) If $ \widehat{r}_{1} > 0 $ and $ \widehat{r}_{2} < 0 $, then the prey population $ x_{1} $ is weakly persistent in the mean with probability 1, where $ \widehat{r}_{2} = \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow+\infty}\frac{1}{t}[\sum\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{2k})+\int_{0}^{t}r_{2}(s)ds] $.
(d) If $ \check{r}_{1}-\langle \frac{\omega}{b}\rangle^{*} > 0 $, then the prey population $ x_{1} $ is strongly persistent in the mean with probability 1, where $ \check{r}_{1} = \liminf\limits_{t\rightarrow+\infty}\frac{1}{t}[\sum\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{1k})+\int_{0}^{t}r_{1}(s)ds] $.
(e) If $ \widehat{r}_{1} > 0 $, the prey population $ x_{1}(t) $ holds a superior bound in time average, that is, $ \langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*}\leq\frac{\widehat{r_{1}}}{k^{l}}\triangleq M_{x} $.
Proof. (a) According to $ It\hat{o} $'s formula and Eq (3.1), the function can be expressed as
$ dlny1=[r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2]dt−0.5σ21(t)dt+σ1(t)dB1(t)=[r1(t)−k(t)x1−ω(t)x21+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2]dt+σ1(t)dB1(t),dlny2=[−g(t)−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2+f(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1]dt−0.5σ22(t)dt+σ2(t)dB2(t)=[r2(t)−h(t)x2+f(t)x11+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2]dt+σ2(t)dB2(t). $ | (4.1) |
Taking integral on both sides of Eq (4.1) results in
$ lny1(t)−lny1(0)=∫t0r1(s)ds−∫t0k(s)x1(s)ds−∫t0ω(s)x2(s)1+a(s)x1(s)+b(s)x2(s)+a(s)b(s)x1(s)x2(s)ds+N1(t),lny2(t)−lny2(0)=∫t0r2(s)ds−∫t0h(s)x2(s)ds+∫t0f(s)x1(s)1+a(s)x1(s)+b(s)x2(s)+a(s)b(s)x1(s)x2(s)ds+N2(t). $ |
We let $ N_{1}(t) = \int_{0}^{t}\sigma_{1}(s) \text{d}B_{1}(s) $, $ N_{2}(t) = \int_{0}^{t}\sigma_{2}(s) \text{d}B_{2}(s) $, where $ N_{i}(t) (i = 1, 2) $ is a local martingale with a quadratic variation satisfying $ \langle N_{1}, N_{1}\rangle_{t} = \int_{0}^{t}\sigma^{2}_{1}(s)ds\leq (\sigma^{u}_{1})^{2}t $, $ \langle N_{2}, N_{2}\rangle_{t} = \int_{0}^{t}\sigma^{2}_{2}(s)ds\leq (\sigma^{u}_{2})^{2}t $. Using the strong law of large numbers for martingales, we show that
$ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{N_{i}(t)}{t} = 0, \quad a.s. \quad i = 1, 2. $ | (4.2) |
Thus
$ lnx1(t)−lnx1(0)t=∑0<τk<tln(1+ρ1k)t+lny1(t)−lny1(0)t=∑0<τk<tln(1+ρ1k)+∫t0r1(s)dst−1t∫t0k(s)x1(s)ds+N1(t)t−1t∫t0ω(s)x2(s)1+a(s)x1(s)+b(s)x2(s)+a(s)b(s)x1(s)x2(s)ds, $ |
$ lnx2(t)−lnx2(0)t=∑0<τk<tln(1+ρ2k)t+lny2(t)−lny2(0)t=∑0<τk<tln(1+ρ2k)+∫t0r2(s)dst−1t∫t0h(s)x2(s)ds+N2(t)t+1t∫t0f(s)x1(s)1+a(s)x1(s)+b(s)x2(s)+a(s)b(s)x1(s)x2(s)ds. $ | (4.3) |
Therefore,
$ lnx1(t)−lnx1(0)t≤∑0<τk<tln(1+ρ1k)+∫t0r1(s)dst+N1(t)t. $ | (4.4) |
Making use of Eq (4.2) and the superior limit as $ t\rightarrow\infty $ in Eq (4.4), we get $ \Big[\frac{ \text{ln}x_{1}(t)- \text{ln}x_{1}(0)}{t}\Big]^{*}\leq \widehat{r}_{1} < 0 $ which results in $ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}x_{1}(t) = 0 $.
(b). According to the definition of superior limit and Eq (4.2), for an arbitrary $ \varepsilon > 0 $, there is a $ T > 0 $ satisfying $ \frac{1}{t}[\sum_{0 < \tau_{k} < t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{1k})+\int_{0}^{t}r_{1}(s) \text{d}s]\leq \widehat{r}_{1}+\frac{\varepsilon}{2} $, $ \frac{N_{1}(t)}{t}\leq \frac{\varepsilon}{2} $ for all $ t > T $. Substituting the above inequalities into the first equation of (4.4), we easily show that
$ lnx1(t)−lnx1(0)t≤ˆr1−k∗⟨x1⟩+ε≤ε−k∗⟨x1⟩. $ | (4.5) |
By virtue of Lemma 2.1, we obtain $ \langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*}\leq\frac{\varepsilon}{k_{*}} $. In accordance with the arbitrariness of $ \varepsilon $, we achieve the result.
(c). By virtue of Eq (4.2), superior limit and Lemma 4.1, we show that
$ ku⟨x1⟩∗+ωu⟨x2⟩∗≥[lnx1(t)−lnx1(0)t]∗+⟨k(t)x1⟩∗+⟨ω(t)x21+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2⟩∗≥ˆr1>0. $ | (4.6) |
Thus, $ \langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*} > 0 $ a.s. By reduction to absurdity, we can assume that for any $ \upsilon\in \{\langle x_{1}(t, \upsilon)\rangle^{*} = 0\} $, by Equation (4.6), we obtain $ \langle x_{2}(t, \upsilon)\rangle^{*} > 0 $. Meanwhile, using the superior limit for the second equation of (4.3) and $ \langle x_{1}(t, v)\rangle^{*} = 0 $ leads to
$ [lnx2(t,υ)−lnx2(0)t]∗≤ˆr2+fu⟨x1(t,υ)⟩∗+hl⟨−x2(t,υ)⟩∗<0. $ |
Therefore, $ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} x_{2}(t, \upsilon) = 0 $. This expression is a contradiction. Then, $ \langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*} > 0 $ a.s.
(d). Under the condition $ \check{r}_{1}-\langle \frac{\omega}{b}\rangle^{*} > 0 $, an arbitrary $ \varepsilon > 0 $ satisfying $ \check{r}_{1}-\langle \frac{\omega}{b}\rangle^{*}-\varepsilon > 0 $ exists. According to the definition of superior limit, interior limit and Eq (4.2), for the above-mentioned positive constant $ \varepsilon $, there is a $ T > 0 $ satisfying $ \frac{1}{t}\big(\sum\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{1k})+\int_{0}^{t}r_{1}(s) \text{d}s\big) > \check{r}_{1}-\frac{\varepsilon}{3}, \langle \frac{\omega}{b}\rangle < \langle \frac{\omega}{b}\rangle^{*}+\frac{\varepsilon}{3}, \frac{N_{1}(t)}{t} > -\frac{\varepsilon}{3} $, for all $ t > T $. Then, from Eq (4.3),
$ lnx1(t)−lnx1(0)t≥ˇr1−⟨ωb⟩∗−ε−ku⟨x1⟩. $ |
Using Lemma 2.1 and the arbitrariness of $ \varepsilon $, we have that
$ \langle x_{1}(t)\rangle_{*}\geq\frac{\check{r}_{1}- \langle \frac{\omega}{b}\rangle^{*} }{k^{u}}\triangleq m_{x} \gt 0. $ | (4.7) |
(e). Passing to the first equation of (4.3), we yield
$ \frac{ \text{ln}x_{1}(t)- \text{ln}x_{1}(0)}{t} \leq \frac{1}{t}\big(\sum\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{1k}) +\int_{0}^{t}r_{1}(s) \text{d}s\big)-k^{l}\langle x_{1}(t)\rangle+\frac{N_{1}(t)}{t}. $ | (4.8) |
Thus, $ \langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*}\leq\frac{\widehat{r}_{1} }{k^{l}}\triangleq M_{x} $, which is obtained by a similar process in the proof of conclusion (2) and is omitted.
Let $ (\bar{x}_{1}(t), \bar{x}_{2}(t)) $ be the solution of the following comparison equation
$ dˉx1=ˉx1(r(t)−k(t)ˉx1)dt+ˉx1σ1(t)dB1(t),dˉx2=ˉx2(−h(t)ˉx2+f(t)a(t))dt+ˉx2σ2(t)dB2(t). $ | (4.9) |
with initial value $ (x_{1}(0), x_{2}(0))\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $, then we hold the following theorem.
Theorem 4.1.2. For the predator population $ x_{2} $ of Eq (1.2),
(a) if $ k_{*}\widehat{r}_{2}+f^{*}\widehat{r}_{1} < 0 $, then the predator population $ x_{2} $ is extinct with probability 1;
(b) if $ k_{*}\widehat{r}_{2}+f^{*}\widehat{r}_{1} = 0 $, then the predator population $ x_{2} $ is non-persistent in the mean with probability 1;
(c) if $ \widehat{r}_{2}+\langle \frac{f\bar{x}_{1}}{1+a\bar{x}_{1}+b\bar{x}_{2}+ab\bar{x}_{1}\bar{x}_{2}}\rangle^{*} > 0 $, then the predator population $ x_{2} $ is weakly persistent in the mean with probability 1;
(d) if $ \widehat{r}_{2}+\langle \frac{f}{a}\rangle^{*} > 0 $, then the predator population $ x_{2}(t) $ has a superior bound in time average, that is, $ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*}\leq\frac{\widehat{r}_{2}+\langle \frac{f}{a}\rangle^{*}}{h^{l}}\triangleq M_{y} $;
(e) if $ \widehat{r}_{2} > 0, \widehat{r}_{1}\leq0 $, then the predator population $ x_{2} $ is weakly persistent.
Proof. (a). Case I. If $ \widehat{r}_{1}\leq 0 $, then by virtue of Theorem 4.1.1, we obtain $ \langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*} = 0 $. According to the definition of superior limit, for an arbitrary $ \varepsilon > 0 $, there is a $ T > 0 $ satisfying $ \frac{1}{t}[\sum\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{2k})+\int_{0}^{t}r_{2}(s) \text{d}s] < \widehat{r}_{2}+\frac{\varepsilon}{2} $, $ \frac{N_{2}(t)}{t} < \frac{\varepsilon}{2} $ for all $ t > T $. By the second equation of (4.3), we noted
$ \Big[\frac{ \text{ln}x_{2}(t)- \text{ln}x_{2}(0)}{t}\Big]^{*}\leq \widehat{r }_{2}+f^{*}\langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*}+\varepsilon = \widehat{r}_{2}+\varepsilon \lt 0, $ |
then $ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}x_{2}(t) = 0 $.
Case II. If $ \widehat{r}_{1} > 0 $, by Eq (4.3), for the above constant $ \varepsilon > 0 $, there is a $ T_{1} > 0 $ such that $ \frac{ \text{ln}x_{1}(t)- \text{ln}x_{1}(0)}{t}\leq \widehat{ r}_{1}- k_{*}\langle x_{1}(t)\rangle +\varepsilon $, for all $ t > T_{1} $. Applying Lemma 2.1, we show that
$ \langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*}\leq \frac{\widehat{r}_{1}+\varepsilon}{k_{*}}. $ | (4.10) |
Substituting the above inequality into the second equation of (4.3) and using the arbitrariness of $ \varepsilon $, we yield
$ [lnx2(t)−lnx2(0)t]∗≤ˆr2+f∗⟨x1(t)⟩∗≤k∗ˆr2+f∗(ˆr1+ε)k∗<0. $ | (4.11) |
Thus, $ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}x_{2}(t) = 0 $.
(b). In (1), we prove that if $ \widehat{r}_{1}\leq 0 $, then $ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}x_{2}(t) = 0 $, consequently, $ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*} = 0 $. At this point, we only need to show that if $ \widehat{r}_{1} > 0 $, then $ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*} = 0 $ is also valid. Otherwise, $ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*} > 0 $, and by Lemma 4.1, we obtain that $ [\frac{ \text{ln}x_{2}(t)}{t}]^{*} = 0 $. From Eq (4.11), we note that
$ 0 = \Big[\frac{ \text{ln}x_{2}(t)- \text{ln}x_{2}(0)}{t}\Big]^{*}\leq \widehat{r}_{2} +f^{*}\langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*}. $ |
Meanwhile, for any constant $ \varepsilon > 0 $, there is a $ T > 0 $ satisfying $ \frac{1}{t}[\sum_{0 < \tau_{k} < t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{2k})+\int_{0}^{t}r_{2}(s) \text{d}s] < \widehat{r}_{2}+\frac{\varepsilon}{3} $, $ \langle f(t) x_{1}(t)\rangle \leq f^{*}\langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*}+\frac{\varepsilon}{3} $, $ \frac{N_{2}(t)}{t}\leq \frac{\varepsilon}{3} $ for all $ t > T $. By the second equation of (4.3),
$ lnx2(t)−lnx2(0)t≤1t[∑0<τk<tln(1+ρ2k)+∫t0r2(s)ds]+⟨f(t)x1(t)⟩−⟨h(t)x2(t)⟩+N2(t)t≤ˆr2+f∗⟨x1(t)⟩∗+ε−h∗⟨x2(t)⟩. $ |
Then, making use of Lemma 2.1, we achieve $ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*}\leq\frac{\widehat{r}_{2} +f^{*}\langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*}+\varepsilon}{h_{*}} $, which indicates that $ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*}\leq\frac{\widehat{r}_{2} +f^{*}\langle x_{1}(t)\rangle^{*}}{h_{*}} $. By virtue of Eq (4.10) and the arbitrariness of $ \varepsilon $, we obtain $ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*}\leq\frac{k_{*}\widehat{r}_{2} +f^{*}\widehat{r}_{1}}{h_{*}k_{*}} = 0 $. This is a contradiction. Therefore, $ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*} = 0 \quad a.s. $
(c). In the following, we show that $ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*} > 0 $ a.s.. By reduction to absurdity, for arbitrary $ \varepsilon_{1} > 0 $ and initial value $ (x_{1}(0), x_{2}(0))\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $, there is a solution $ (\check{x}_{1}(t), \check{x}_{2}(t)) $ of Eq (1.2) satisfying $ P\{\langle \check{x}_{2}(t)\rangle^{*} < \varepsilon_{1}\} > 0. $ Let $ \varepsilon_{1} $ be sufficiently small that
$ \widehat{r_{2}}+\Big\langle \frac{f\bar{x}_{1}}{1+a\bar{x}_{1}+b\bar{x}_{2}+ab\bar{x}_{1}\bar{x}_{2}}\Big\rangle^{*} \gt 2(\frac{f^{u}\omega^{u}}{k^{l}}+h^{u}+1)\varepsilon_{1}. $ |
From the second equation of (4.3), it can be shown that
$ lnˇx2(t)−lnx2(0)t=1t[∑0<τk<tln(1+ρ2k)+∫t0r2(s)ds]+⟨f(t)ˉx11+a(t)ˉx1+b(t)ˉx2+a(t)b(t)ˉx1ˉx2⟩+N2(t)t+⟨f(t)ˇx11+a(t)ˇx1+b(t)ˇx2+a(t)b(t)ˇx1ˇx2−f(t)ˉx11+a(t)ˉx1+b(t)ˉx2+a(t)b(t)ˉx1ˉx2⟩−⟨h(t)ˇx2(t)⟩. $ |
Herein, $ \check{x}_{1}(t)\leq \bar{x}_{1}(t) $, $ \check{x}_{2}(t)\leq \bar{x}_{2}(t) $, a.s. for $ t\in [0, +\infty) $. Note that
$ f(t)ˇx11+a(t)ˇx1+b(t)ˇx2+a(t)b(t)ˇx1ˇx2−f(t)ˉx11+a(t)ˉx1+b(t)ˉx2+a(t)b(t)ˉx1ˉx2=f(t)−(ˉx1−ˇx1)+a(t)b(t)ˉx1ˇx1(ˉx2−ˇx2)+b(t)ˇx1(ˉx2−ˇx2)−b(t)ˇx2(ˉx1−ˇx1)(1+a(t)ˇx1+b(t)ˇx2+a(t)b(t)ˇx1ˇx2)(1+a(t)ˉx1+b(t)ˉx2+a(t)b(t)ˉx1ˉx2)≥−2f(t)(ˉx1−ˇx1), $ |
then
$ lnˇx2(t)−lnx2(0)t≥1t[∑0<τk<tln(1+ρ2k)+∫t0r2(s)ds]−⟨h(t)ˇx2(t)⟩+N2(t)t+⟨f(t)ˉx11+a(t)ˉx1+b(t)ˉx2+a(t)b(t)ˉx1ˉx2⟩−2⟨f(t)(ˉx1−ˇx1)⟩. $ | (4.12) |
Construct the Lyapunov function $ V_{3}(t) = | \text{ln}\bar{x}_{1}(t)- \text{ln}\check{x}_{1}(t)| $, where $ V_{3}(t) $ is a positive function on $ \mathbb{R}_{+} $. By virtue of It$ \hat{o} $'s formula and Eq (4.9), we achieve the following expression:
$ D+V3(t)≤sgn(ˉx1−ˇx1){−k(ˉx1−ˇx1)+ω(t)ˇx21+a(t)ˇx1+b(t)ˇx2+a(t)b(t)ˇx1ˇx2}. $ | (4.13) |
Moreover, integrating the above inequality from 0 to $ t $ and dividing by $ t $ on both sides of the above inequality result in $ \frac{V_{3}(t)-V_{3}(0)}{t}\leq \omega^{u}\langle \check{x}_{2}(t)\rangle-k^{l}\langle |\bar{x}_{1}-\check{x}_{1}|\rangle $. Then we achieve
$ \langle \bar{x}_{1}-\check{x}_{1}\rangle\leq\frac{\omega^{u}}{k^{l}}\langle \check{x}_{2}(t)\rangle. $ |
By substituting the above inequality into Eq (4.12) and taking the superior limit of the inequality, we obtain
$ [lnˇx2(t)−lnx2(0)t]∗≥ˆr2−hu⟨ˇx2(t)⟩∗+N2(t)t+⟨f(t)ˉx11+a(t)ˉx1+b(t)ˉx2+a(t)b(t)ˉx1ˉx2⟩∗−2fuωukl⟨ˇx2(t)⟩∗≥ˆr2+⟨f(t)ˉx11+a(t)ˉx1+b(t)ˉx2+a(t)b(t)ˉx1ˉx2⟩∗−2(fuωukl+hu+1)ε1>0, $ | (4.14) |
Equation (4.14) contradicts Lemma 4.1, therefore $ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*} > 0 $ a.s. The proof is hence completed.
(d). By the second equation of (4.3), we obtain the following equation
$ \frac{ \text{ln}x_{2}(t)- \text{ln}x_{2}(0)}{t}\leq \widehat{r}_{2}+\langle \frac{f}{a}\rangle^{*}-h^{l}\langle x_{2}(t)\rangle+\frac{N_{2}(t)}{t}. $ | (4.15) |
Moreover, from the definition of superior limit and Eq (4.2), for the given positive number $ \varepsilon $, there is a $ T_{2} > 0 $ satisfying $ \frac{1}{t}[\sum\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{2k})+\int_{0}^{t}r_{2}(s) \text{d}s] < \widehat{r}_{2}+\frac{\varepsilon}{3}, \langle \frac{f}{a}\rangle < \langle \frac{f}{a}\rangle^{*}+\frac{\varepsilon}{3}, \frac{N_{2}(t)}{t} < \frac{\varepsilon}{3} $, for all $ t > T_{2} $. In accordance with Lemma 2.1 and the arbitrariness of $ \varepsilon $, we easily achieve
$ \langle x_{2}(t)\rangle^{*}\leq\frac{\widehat{r }_{2}+ \langle \frac{f}{a}\rangle^{*} }{h^{l}}\triangleq M_{y}. $ |
The desired result is obtained.
(e). If $ x_{2}^{*} > 0 $ a.s is false, let $ \Omega = \{x_{2}^{*} = 0\} $, then $ P(\Omega) > 0 $. For an arbitrary $ \nu \in \Omega $, we have $ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}x_{2}(t, \nu) = 0 $. From the second equation of (4.3) and by virtue of Eq (4.2), we show that $ [\frac{ \text{ln}x_{2}(t, \nu)}{t}]^{*} = \widehat{r_{2}} > 0 $ a.s. Then we follow that $ P\{[\frac{ \text{ln}x_{2}(t, \nu)}{t}]^{*} > 0\} > 0 $, which contradicts with Lemma 4.1. The result is then concluded.
Remark 1. By the proof of Theorem 4.1.2, we observe that if $ \widehat{r}_{1} < 0 $, then $ k_{*}\widehat{r}_{2}+f^{*} \widehat{r}_{1} < 0 $. Thus, if the prey species is extinct, then the predator species will also be extinct. This notion is consistent with the reality. Moreover, if $ \widehat{r}_{1} > 0 $ and $ k_{*}\widehat{r}_{2}+f^{*} \widehat{r}_{1} < 0 $, then even if the prey population is persistent, the predators end in extinction because of an excessively large diffusion coefficient $ \sigma_{2}^{2} $.
Remark 2. According to conclusion (5) of Theorem 4.1.2, with the effect of impulsive perturbations despite the regression of the prey population to extinction, the predator may remain weakly persistent.
Theorem 4.2.1 If $ (\max\{\sigma_{1}^{u}, \sigma_{2}^{u}\})^{2}+2(\frac{\omega^{u}}{b^{l}}+g^{u}) < 2 \min\{r^{l}, \frac{f^{l}}{a^{u}}\} $ holds, then Eq (1.2) is stochastically permanent.
Proof. The whole proof is divided into two parts. First, we must prove that for arbitrary $ \varepsilon > 0 $, there is a constant $ \delta > 0 $ satisfying $ \text{P}_{*}\{|X_{1}(t)|\geq \delta\}\geq 1-\varepsilon $, where $ X_{1}(t) = (x_{1}(t), x_{2}(t)) $.
At this point, we show that for any initial value $ \overline{X}(0) $ $ = (y_{1}(0), y_{2}(0))\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $, the solution $ \overline{X}(t) = (y_{1}(t), y_{2}(t)) $ holds the property that
$ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \text{E}(\frac{1}{|\overline{X}(t)|^{\theta}})\leq M_{0}, $ |
where $ \theta > 0 $ is a sufficiently small constant, such that
$ \min\{r^{l}, \frac{f^{l}}{a^{u}}\} \gt (\frac{\omega^{u}}{b^{l}}+ g^{u})+\frac{(\theta+1)}{2}(\max\{\sigma_{1}^{u}, \sigma_{2}^{u}\})^{2} . $ | (4.16) |
By virtue of Eq (4.16), there is an arbitrary constant $ p > 0 $ such that
$ \min\{r^{l}, \frac{f^{l}}{a^{u}}\}-\frac{(\theta+1)}{2}(\max\{\sigma_{1}^{u}, \sigma_{2}^{u}\})^{2}-(\frac{\omega^{u}}{b^{l}}+ g^{u})-p \gt 0 . $ | (4.17) |
Define $ V(y_{1}, y_{2}) = y_{1}+y_{2} $, then
$ dV(y1,y2)=y1(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2)dt+y1σ1(t)dB1(t)+y2(−g(t)−h(t)∏0<ρ2k<t(1+ρ1k)y2+f(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1)dt+y2σ2(t)dB2(t). $ |
Let $ U(y_{1}, y_{2}) = \frac{1}{V(y_{1}, y_{2})} $, according to the $ It\hat{o} $'s formula, we obtain
$ dU(¯X)=−U2(¯X)[y1(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2)dt]−U2(¯X)y2(−g(t)−h(t)∏0<ρ2k<t(1+ρ1k)y2+f(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1)dt+U3(¯X)[y21σ21(t)+y22σ22(t)]dt−U2(¯X)σ1(t)y1dB1(t)+σ2(t)y2dB2(t)=LU(¯X)dt−U2(¯X)[σ1(t)y1dB1(t)+σ2(t)y2dB2(t)]. $ |
Under the condition of this theorem, a positive constant $ \theta $ can be chosen to satisfy Eq (4.16). By the Itô formula,
$ L(1+U(¯X))θ=θ(1+U(¯X))θ−1LU(¯X)+12θ(θ−1)(1+U(¯X))θ−2U4(¯X)+(y21σ21(t)+y22σ22(t)). $ |
Then we choose $ p > 0 $ to be sufficiently small such that the term satisfies Eq (4.17). We define $ W(\overline{X}) = e^{pt}(1+U(\overline{X}))^{\theta} $ and consequently achieve
$ LW(¯X)=pept(1+U(¯X))θ+eptL(1+U(¯X))θ=ept(1+U(¯X))θ−2{p(1+U(¯X))2−θU2(¯X)y1(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2)−θU2(¯X)y2(−g(t)−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2+f(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1)−θU3(¯X)y2(−g(t)−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2)−θU3(¯X)[y1(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2)+f(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1]+θU3(¯X)[y21σ21(t)+y22σ22(t)]+θ(θ+1)2U4(¯X)[y21σ21(t)+y22σ22(t)]}≤ept(1+U(¯X))θ−2{(p+θmax{kuM,hu˜M})+[2p−θmin{rl,flau}+θmax{kuM,hu˜M}]U(¯X)+[p+θ(ωubl+gu)−θmin{rl,flau}+θ(θ+1)2(max{σu1,δu1})2]U2(¯X)}. $ |
By Eq (4.17), a positive constant $ S $ satisfying $ \text{L}W(\overline{X})\leq Se^{pt} $ is easily noted. Consequently, $ \text{E}[e^{pt}(1+U(\overline{X}))^{\theta}]\leq (1+U(0))^{\theta}+\frac{S(e^{pt}-1)}{p} $ and then
$ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \text{E}[U^{\theta}(\overline{X}(t))]\leq \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \text{E}[(1+U(\overline{X}(t))^{\theta}]\leq \frac{S}{p}. $ |
Notably, $ (y_{1}+y_{2})^{\theta}\leq 2^{\theta}(y_{1}^{2}+y_{2}^{2})^{\frac{\theta}{2}} = 2^{\theta}|\overline{X}|^{\theta} $, where $ \overline{X} = (y_{1}, y_{2})\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $. Then, we obtain
$ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \text{E}[\frac{1}{|\overline{X}(t)|^{\theta}}]\leq 2^{-\theta}\limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \text{E}U^{\theta}(\overline{X})\leq 2^{-\theta}\frac{S}{p}: = M_{0}, $ |
and
$ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \text{E}[\frac{1}{|X_{1}(t)|^{\theta}}]\leq \overline{m}^{-\theta}\limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}EU^{\theta}(\overline{X})\leq\overline{m}^{-\theta}M_{0} : = \overline{M_{0}}, $ |
where $ \overline{m} = \min\{m, \widetilde{m}\} $. Therefore, for arbitrary $ \varepsilon > 0 $, we let $ \delta = (\varepsilon\setminus \overline{M_{0}})^{\frac{1}{\theta}} $ in accordance with Chebyshev's inequality, thereby yielding
$ \text{P}\{|X_{1}(t)| \lt \delta\} = \text{P}\{|X_{1}(t)|^{-\theta} \gt \delta^{-\theta}\}\leq \text{E}[|X_{1}(t)|^{-\theta}]/\delta^{-\theta} = \delta^{\theta} \text{E}[|X_{1}(t)|^{-\theta}], $ |
thus, $ \text{P}_{*}\{|X_{1}(t)|\geq\delta\}\geq 1-\varepsilon $.
In the following relations, we prove that for any $ \varepsilon > 0 $, there exists $ \chi > 0 $ satisfying $ \text{P}_{*}\{|X_{1}(t)|\leq\chi\}\geq 1-\varepsilon $. Define $ V_{4}(\overline{X}) = y_{1}^{q}+y_{2}^{q} $, herein $ 0 < q < 1 $ and $ \overline{X} = (y_{1}, y_{2})\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $, then by virtue of $ It\hat{o} $'s formula, we obtain the expression
$ dV4(¯X(t))=qyq1[r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1+q−12σ21(t)−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2]dt+qyq2[−g(t)−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)+q−12σ22(t)y2+f(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1]dt+qyq1σ1(t)dB1(t)+qyq2σ2(t)dB2(t). $ |
Let $ n_{0} $ be a sufficiently large constant, such that $ y_{1}(0) $, $ y_{2}(0) $ remain within the internal $ [\frac{1}{n_{0}}, n_{0}] $. For each integer $ n\geq n_{0} $, we define the stopping time $ t_{n} = \inf \{t\geq 0: y_{1}(t) {\not \in}(1/n, n)\, \, or \, \, y_{2}(t) {\not \in}(1/n, n)\} $. Obviously, $ t_{n} $ increases as $ n\rightarrow +\infty $. Using $ It\hat{o} $'s formula again for $ \exp\{t\}V_{4}(\overline{X}) $ and accounting for the expectations on both sides, we show that
$ E[exp{t∧tn}¯Xq(t∧tn)]−¯Xq(0)≤qE∫t∧tn0exp{s}yq1(s)[1+q(r(s)−k(s)∏0<τk<s(1+ρ1k)y1(s)−1−q2σ21(s))]ds+qE∫t∧tn0exp{s}φq(s)[1+q(−g(s)−h(s)∏0<τk<s(1+ρ2k)y2(s)+f(s)a(s)−1−q2σ22(s))]ds≤E∫t∧tn0(K1+K2)exp{s}ds≤(K1+K2)(exp{t}−1), $ |
where $ K_{1}, K_{2} $ are positive constants. Letting $ n\rightarrow +\infty $ yields
$ \exp\{t\} \text{E}[\overline{X}^{q}(t)]\leq \overline{X}^{q}(0)+(K_{1}+K_{2})(\exp\{t\}-1). $ |
Then, we achieve $ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow+\infty} \text{E}[\overline{X}^{q}(t)]\leq K_{1}+K_{2} $ and $ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow+\infty} \text{E}[X_{1}^{q}(t)]\leq \overline{M}^{q}(K_{1}+K_{2}) $, where $ \overline{M} = \max\{M, \widetilde{M}\} $. Therefore, at any given $ \varepsilon > 0 $, we let $ \chi = \frac{\overline{M}(K_{1}+K_{2})^{1/q}}{\varepsilon^{1/q}} $, by virtue of the Chebyshev inequality, we easily show that
$ \text{P}\{|X_{1}(t)| \gt \chi\} = \text{P}\{|X_{1}(t)|^{q} \gt \chi^{q}\}\leq \text{E}[|X_{1}(t)|^{q}]/\chi^{q}. $ |
Consequently, $ \text{P}_{*}\{|X_{1}(t)|\leq\chi\}\geq 1-\varepsilon $.
Theorem 4.2.1 is proven.
Remark 3. From the conditions of Theorem 4.2.1, we find that although the stochastic disturbance greatly influence the dynamical property of the system, the bounded impulsive perturbations do not affect the stochastic permanence of the model.
Remark 4. We should point out that the definition of stochastically permanent which requires that all species have positive upper bounds and at least one species has a positive lower bound, cannot demonstrate the permanence of all species. It has some limitations and deficiency. If there is only one species having a positive lower bound and all the other species go extinction, the system is still permanent. A new definition of stochastic permanence [31] may be more appropriate.
In this section, we provide some sufficient criteria to ensure the global attractiveness of the Equation (1.2).
Theorem 5.1. For any initial value $ (y_{1}(0), y_{2}(0))\in \mathbb{R}_{2}^{+} $, $ (y_{1}(t), y_{2}(t)) $ is a solution of Eq (3.1) on $ [0, +\infty) $. Then almost every sample path of $ (y_{1}(t), y_{2}(t)) $ is uniformly continuous.
The proof of Theorem 5.1 is given in Appendix A.
Theorem 5.2. Suppose that constants $ \mu_{i} > 0 \, (i = 1, 2) $ satisfying $ \liminf\limits_{t\rightarrow \infty} A_{i}(t) > 0 $ exist, where
$ A1(t)=μ1[mk(t)−2ω(t)a(t)b(t)]−2μ2f(t),A2(t)=μ2[˜mh(t)−2f(t)b(t)a(t)]−2μ1ω(t), $ | (5.1) |
then Eq (1.2) is globally attractive.
Proof. Let $ (y_{1}(t), y_{2}(t)) $, $ (\tilde{y}_{1}(t), \tilde{y}_{2}(t)) $ be two arbitrary solutions of Eq (3.1) with initial value $ (y_{1}(0), y_{2}(0)) $, $ (\tilde{y}_{1}(0), \tilde{y}_{2}(0))\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $. Denote $ \tilde{\lambda}(t) = 1+a(t)\prod\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t}(1+\rho_{1k})\tilde{y}_{1}+b(t)\prod\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t}(1+\rho_{2k})\tilde{y}_{2} +a(t)b(t)\prod\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t}(1+\rho_{1k})\prod\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < t}(1+\rho_{2k})\tilde{y}_{1}\tilde{y}_{2} $ and define a Lyapunov function as follows:
$ V(t) = \mu_{1} | \text{ln}y_{1}(t)- \text{ln}\tilde{y}_{1}(t)|+\mu_{2} | \text{ln}y_{2}(t)- \text{ln}\tilde{y}_{2}(t)|. $ |
Then,
$ D+(V(t))=μ1sgn(y1−˜y1)([r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−0.5σ21(t)−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2]dt−[r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)˜y1−0.5σ21(t)−ω(t)˜λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)˜y2]dt+μ2sgn(y2−˜y2)([−g(t)−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2−0.5σ22(t)+f(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1]dt−[−g(t)−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)˜y2−0.5σ22(t)+f(t)˜λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)˜y1]dt)≤μ1sgn(y1−˜y1)(−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)(y1−˜y1)+ω(t)[∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)˜y2˜λ(t)−∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2λ(t)])dt+μ2sgn(y2−˜y2)(−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)(y2−˜y2)+f(t)[∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1λ(t)−∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)˜y1˜λ(t)])≤−[μ1(mk(t)−2ω(t)a(t)b(t))−2μ2f(t)]|y1−˜y1|−[μ2(˜mh(t)−2f(t)b(t)a(t))−2μ1ω(t)]|y2−˜y2|. $ |
By the condition $ \liminf\limits_{t\rightarrow \infty} A_{i}(t) > 0 \, (i = 1, 2) $, constants $ \alpha > 0 $ and $ T_{0} > 0 $ satisfying $ A_{i}(t)\geq \alpha \, (i = 1, 2) $ exist for all $ t\geq T_{0} $. Moreover, we obtain the following relation
$ \text{D}^{+}(V(t))\leq-\alpha(|y_{1}-\tilde{y}_{1}|+|y_{2}-\tilde{y}_{2}|), $ | (5.2) |
for all $ t\geq T_{0} $. By integrating Eq (5.2) from $ T_{0} $ to $ t $, we achieve
$ V(t)-V(T_{0})\leq -\alpha\int_{T_{0}}^{t}\left(|y_{1}(s)-\tilde{y}_{1}(s)|+|y_{2}(s)-\tilde{y}_{2}(s)|\right)ds. $ |
Consequently,
$ V(t)+\alpha\int_{T_{0}}^{t}\left(|y_{1}(s)-\tilde{y}_{1}(s)|+|y_{2}(s)-\tilde{y}_{2}(s)|\right)ds \leq V(T_{0}) \lt +\infty. $ | (5.3) |
Then by $ V(t)\geq 0 $, we note that $ |y_{1}(t)-\tilde{y}_{1}(t)|\in \text{L}^{1}[0, +\infty), \quad|y_{2}(t)-\tilde{y}_{2}(t)|\in \text{L}^{1}[0, +\infty) $. Thus,
$ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow +\infty}|y_{1}(t)-\tilde{y}_{1}(t)| = 0, \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow +\infty}|y_{2}(t)-\tilde{y}_{2}(t)| = 0. $ |
Next,
$ limt→+∞|x1(t)−˜x1(t)|=limt→+∞∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)|y1(t)−˜y1(t)|≤Mlimt→+∞|y1(t)−˜y1(t)|=0,a.s.limt→+∞|x2(t)−˜x2(t)|=limt→+∞∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)|y2(t)−˜y2(t)|≤˜Mlimt→+∞|y2(t)−˜y2(t)|=0.a.s. $ |
Therefore, the desired assertion is obtained by Theorem 5.1 and Lemma 2.2.
In this section, some numerical simulations and examples are given to illustrate and augment our theoretical findings of Eq (1.2) by means of the Milstein method mentioned in Higham [35]. Moreover, the effects of impulsive and stochastic perturbations on population dynamics are discussed.
Example 1.
$ {dx1(t)=x1[r(t)−(0.7+0.01sint)x1−(0.1+0.02sint)x21+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2]dt+x1σ1(t)dB1(t),dx2(t)=x2[−(0.2+0.05sint)−(0.2+0.01sint)x2+(0.2+0.02sint)x11+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2]dt+x2σ2(t)dB2(t),t≠τk,x1(τ+k)=(1+ρ1k)x1(τk),x2(τ+k)=(1+ρ2k)x2(τk),t=τk,k=1,2,3,… $ | (6.1) |
We set $ r(t) = 0.2+0.01 \sin t $, $ a(t) = 0.1+0.04 \sin t $, $ b(t) = 0.5+0.05 \sin t $, $ \frac{\sigma_{1}^{2}(t)}{2} = \frac{\sigma_{2}^{2}(t)}{2} = 0.3+0.02\sin t $, $ \rho_{1k} = \rho_{2k} = e^{(-1)^{k+1}\frac{1}{k}}-1 $ and $ \tau_{k} = k $, then it can be obtained that $ \widehat{r}_{1} = -0.1 < 0 $. By Theorems 4.1.1 and 4.1.2, both prey and predator populations ($ x_{1} $ and $ x_{2} $, respectively) regress to extinction, which is also further confirmed by Figure 1.
We then choose $ \frac{\sigma_{1}^{2}(t)}{2} = 0.3+0.02\sin t $, $ \frac{\sigma_{2}^{2}(t)}{2} = 0.4+0.02\sin t $, $ \rho_{1k} = \rho_{2k} = e^{(-1)^{k+1}\frac{1}{k}}-1 $, and $ r(t) = 0.4+0.01 \sin t $. The other parameters are the same as that in example 1, then $ \widehat{r}_{1} = 0.1 > 0 $, $ \widehat{r}_{2} = -0.6 < 0 $, and $ k_{*}\widehat{r}_{2}+f^{*}\widehat{r}_{1} = -0.116 < 0 $. In Figure 2, although the prey population $ x_{1} $ is weakly persistent in the mean, the predator population $ x_{2} $ end in extinction because of the effects of the white noises, which are of great importance in maintaining the coexistence of populations.
Example 2.
$ {dx1(t)=x1[(0.6+0.1sint))−(0.7+0.01sint)x1−(0.1+0.02sint)x21+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2]dt+x1σ1(t)dB1(t),dx2(t)=x2[−(0.2+0.05sint)−(0.2+0.01sint)x2+(0.62+0.02sint)x11+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2]dt+x2σ2(t)dB2(t),t≠τk,x1(τ+k)=(1+ρ1k)x1(τk),x2(τ+k)=(1+ρ2k)x2(τk),t=τk,k=1,2,3,… $ | (6.2) |
We let $ \frac{\sigma_{1}^{2}(t)}{2} = 0.1+0.05\sin t $, $ \frac{\sigma_{2}^{2}(t)}{2} = 0.1+0.02\sin t $, $ a(t) = 0.1+0.04 \sin t $, $ b(t) = 0.5+0.05 \sin t $ $ \rho_{1k} = \rho_{2k} = e^{-\frac{1}{k^{2}}}-1 $, and $ \tau_{k} = k $, then $ \widehat{r}_{1} = 0.5 > 0 $, $ \widehat{r}_{2} = -0.3 < 0 $. Both the prey and predator populations ($ x_{1} $ and $ x_{2} $, respectively) are weakly persistent in the mean of Figure 3.
Example 3.
$ {dx1(t)=x1[(1.21+0.01sint))−(0.7+0.01sint)x1−(0.1+0.02sint)x21+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2]dt+x1σ1(t)dB1(t),dx2(t)=x2[−(0.2+0.05sint)−(0.2+0.01sint)x2+(0.62+0.02sint)x11+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2]dt+x2σ2(t)dB2(t),t≠τk,x1(τ+k)=(1+ρ1k)x1(τk),x2(τ+k)=(1+ρ2k)x2(τk),t=τk,k=1,2,3,… $ | (6.3) |
In Figure 4, we choose $ \sigma_{1}(t) = 0.2+0.02\sin t $, $ \sigma_{2}(t) = 0.3+0.02\sin t $, $ a(t) = 0.1+0.04 \sin t $, $ b(t) = 0.5+0.05 \sin t $, and the impulsive perturbations are (a) $ \rho_{1k} = \rho_{2k} = e^{\frac{(-1)^{k+1}}{k}}-1 $, (b)$ \rho_{1k} = \rho_{2k} = e^{\frac{1}{k^{2}}}-1 $, (c)$ \rho_{1k} = \rho_{2k} = 0 $. The conditions of Theorem 4.2.1 are satisfied in all of those cases and the Eq (1.2) displays stochastic permanence in Figure 4. Moreover, in Figure 4(a)-4(c), the bounded impulsive perturbations do not affect the stochastic permanence of the model.
Example 4.
$ {dx1(t)=x1[(1.8+0.01sint))−(0.7+0.01sint)x1−(0.1+0.02sint)x21+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2]dt+x1σ1(t)dB1(t),dx2(t)=x2[−(0.2+0.05sint)−(0.8+0.01sint)x2+(1.12+0.02sint)x11+a(t)x1+b(t)x2+a(t)b(t)x1x2]dt+x2σ2(t)dB2(t),t≠τk,x1(τ+k)=(1+ρ1k)x1(τk),x2(τ+k)=(1+ρ2k)x2(τk),t=τk,k=1,2,3,… $ | (6.4) |
Set $ \frac{\sigma_{1}^{2}(t)}{2} = 0.1+0.05\sin t $, $ \frac{\sigma_{2}^{2}(t)}{2} = 0.6+0.02\sin t $, $ x_{1}(0) = 2 $, $ x_{2}(0) = 3 $, $ \tilde{x}_{1}(0) = 0.5 $, and $ \tilde{x}_{2}(0) = 0.3 $. We then observe from Figure 5 that Eq (1.2) is globally attractive.
In the following instance, the effects of negative and positive impulses on the species are investigated. We let $ \rho_{1k} = e^{-1.92}-1 $, $ \rho_{2k} = e^{-0.02}-1 $, and $ \tau_{k} = k $. The other parameters are the same as those in Example 3, then we obtain that $ \widehat{r}_{1} = -0.03 < 0 $ and $ \widehat{r}_{2} = -0.36 < 0 $. On the basis of Theorems 4.1.1 and 4.1.2, both the prey and predator populations end in extinction, which is further confirmed by Figure 6(b). By comparing Figure 6(a) with Figure 6(b), we observe that the negative impulses do not benefit species coexistence. Moreover, considering the impulsive perturbations are (a) $ \rho_{1k} = \rho_{2k} = 0 $, (b) $ \rho_{1k} = e^{\frac{1}{k^{2}}}-1 $, $ \rho_{2k} = e^{0.8}-1 $, (c) $ \rho_{1k} = \rho_{2k} = e^{0.8}-1 $ and the other parameters are the same as those in Example 1. Hence, the system can be altered from extinction to persistence with the effects of positive impulsive perturbations (Figure 7(a)-7(c)). Herein, persistence can be divided into two cases as follows: first, the predator population $ x_{2}(t) $ is weakly persistent and the prey population $ x_{1}(t) $ proceeds to extinction and second, both of the populations are persistent. Therefore, positive impulses are advantageous for the coexistence of ecosystems. Moreover, comparing figures 3 and 6, figures 1 and 7, we can derive that if the impulsive perturbations are unbounded, some properties may be changed significantly.
In this paper, we propose a stochastic non-autonomous predator-prey system with impulsive perturbations and investigate the qualitative dynamic properties of the model. Under some sufficient conditions, we present the extinction and a series of persistence in the mean of the system, including non-persistence, weak persistence and strong persistence in the mean. Furthermore, we obtain the global attractivity of the model. From the assumptions of Theorems 4.1.1, 4.1.2 and 4.2.1, we demonstrate that the stochastic and impulsive disturbances greatly influence the extinction and persistence of the system. Positive impulses are advantageous for the coexistence of ecosystem, whereas negative impulses are not beneficial for species coexistence. Moreover, the results show that the bounded impulsive perturbations do not affect all the properties, such as the stochastic permanence of the model. However, if the impulsive perturbations are unbounded, some properties may be changed significantly.
Some interesting topics require further investigations. If we also consider the effects of time delays and telephone noise [36,37,38] on Eq (1.2) to propose a more realistic model, then how will the properties change? We leave it for future investigation.
This work is supported by The National Natural Science Foundation of China (11901110, 11961003), and the National Natural Science Foundation of Jiangxi (20192BAB211003, 20192ACBL20004).
The authors declare that they have no competing of interests regarding the publication of this paper.
Proof of Theorem 3.1. From Lemma 3.1, it suffices to show that Eq (3.1) has a unique solution, $ (y_{1}(t), y_{2}(t)) $, for all $ t\geq 0 $ and will remain in $ \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $ with probability one. The proof of this theorem is standard.
Let $ n_{0} > 0 $ be sufficiently large such that $ y_{1}(0) $, $ y_{2}(0) $ lie within the interval $ [1/n_{0}, n_{0}] $. For each integer $ n > n_{0} $, define the stopping times $ t_{n} = \inf \{t \in[0, t_{e}]: y_{1}(t) {\not \in}(1/n, n) \, or\, y_{2}(t) {\not \in}(1/n, n)\} $. Obviously, $ t_{n} $ is increasing as $ n\rightarrow +\infty $. Denote $ t_{+\infty} = {\lim\limits_{n\rightarrow +\infty}}t_{n} $, thus $ t_{+\infty}\leq t_{e} $. To complete the proof, it only needs to show $ t_{+\infty} = +\infty $ a.s. If the statement is not true, there exist two constants $ T > 0 $ and $ \varepsilon \in (0, 1) $, such that $ \text{P}\{t_{+\infty} < + \infty\} > \varepsilon $. Therefore, there is an integer $ n_{1}\geq n_{0} $ satisfying $ \text{P}\{t_{n}\leq T\}\geq\varepsilon $, for all $ n > n_{1} $.
Define a $ \bf{C}^{2} $-function $ V: \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2}\rightarrow \mathbb{R}_{+} $ by $ V(y_{1}, y_{2}) = (y_{1}-1- \text{ln}y_{1})+(y_{2}-1- \text{ln}y_{2}) $, then we obtain that $ V(y_{1}, y_{2}) $ is nonnegative. By virtue of $ It\hat{o} $'s formula, we achieve that
$ dV(y1,y2)=Vy1dy1+0.5Vy1y1(dy1)2+Vy2dy2+0.5Vy2y2(dy2)2=[(1−1/y1)y1(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2)+(1−1/y2)y2(−g(t)−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2+f(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1)]dt+0.5(σ21(t)+σ22(t))dt+(1−1/y1)y1σ1(t)dB1(t)+(1−1/y2)y2σ2(t)dB2(t)≤[(ru+kuM)y1−klmy21−rl+ωubl+gu+(˜Mhu+fual−gl)y2−˜mhly22]dt+0.5[(σu1)2+(σu2)2]dt+(y1−1)σ1(t)dB1(t)+(y2−1)σ2(t)dB2(t). $ |
According to the negative coefficients of the quadratic terms, there is a positive number $ G $ satisfying
$ dV(y1,y2)≤Gdt+(y1−1)σ1(t)dB1(t)+(y2−1)σ2(t)dB2(t). $ |
Thus
$ ∫tn∧T0dV(y1,y2)≤∫tn∧T0Gdt+∫tn∧T0[(y1(t)−1)σ1(t)dB1(t)+(y2(t)−1)σ2(t)dB2(t)], $ |
where $ t_{n}\wedge T = \min\{t_{n}, T\} $. Taking expectation yields that
$ \text{E}V(y_{1}(t_{n}\wedge T), y_{2}(t_{n}\wedge T))\leq V(y_{1}(0), y_{2}(0))+G \text{E}(t_{n}\wedge T)\\ \leq V(y_{1}(0), y_{2}(0))+GT. $ |
Let $ \Omega_{n} = \{t_{n}\leq T\} $, then $ \text{P}(\Omega_{n})\geq \varepsilon $. For any $ w \in \Omega_{n} $, $ y_{1}(t_{n}, w) $ or $ y_{2}(t_{n}, w) $ equals either $ n $ or $ 1/n $, thus
$ V(y_{1}(t_{n}, w), y_{2}(t_{n}, w))\geq \min\{n-1- \text{ln}n, 1/n-1+ \text{ln}n\}. $ |
Therefore it can be shown that
$ V(y1(0),y2(0))+G1T≥E[1Ωn(w)V(y1(tn,w),y2(tn,w))]≥εmin{n−1−lnn,1/n−1+lnn}, $ |
where $ 1_{\Omega_{n}} $ is the indicator function of $ \Omega_{n} $. Letting $ n \rightarrow +\infty $ leads to the contradiction.
So we obtain that $ t_{+\infty} = +\infty $ a.s. This completes the proof.
Proof of Theorem 3.2. Define $ V_{1}(y_{1}) = y_{1}^{p} $ and $ V_{2}(y_{2}) = y_{2}^{p} $, respectively, for $ (y_{1}, y_{2})\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $ and $ p > 1 $. According to the $ It\hat{o} $'s formula, we have
$ d(yp1)=pyp−11dy1+0.5p(p−1)yp−21(dy1)2=pyp1(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2+0.5(p−1)σ21(t))dt+pyp1σ1(t)dB1(t)≤pyp1[ru−mkly1+0.5(p−1)(σu1)2]dt+pyp1σ1(t)dB1(t). $ |
and
$ d(yp2)=pyp2(−g(t)−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2+f(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1+0.5(p−1)σ22(t))dt+pyp2σ2(t)dB2(t)≤pyp2[fual+0.5p(σu2)2−˜mhly2]dt+pyp2σ2(t)dB2(t). $ |
Taking expectation and then
$ dE[yp1(t)]dt≤p{[ru+0.5(p−1)(σu1)2]E[yp1(t)]−mklE[yp+11(t)]}≤p{[ru+0.5(p−1)(σu1)2]E[yp1(t)]−mkl[E(yp1(t))]1+1p}≤pE[yp1(t)]{[ru+0.5p(σu1)2]−mkl[E(yp1(t))]1p} $ | (A.1) |
and
$ dE[yp2(t)]dt≤pE[yp2(t)]{[fual+0.5p(σu2)2]−˜mhl[E(yp2(t))]1p}. $ | (A.2) |
For Eq (A.1), considering the following equation
$ dv(t)dt=pv(t){[ru+0.5p(σu1)2]−mklv1p(t)} $ |
with initial value $ v(0) = v_{0} $. Obviously, we can obtain that
$ v(t)=(v1/p0(ru+0.5p(σu1)2)[ru+0.5p(σu1)2]e−(ru+0.5p(σu1)2)t+mklv1/p0(1−e−(ru+0.5p(σu1)2)t))p. $ |
Let $ t\rightarrow \infty $ and thus $ \lim\limits_{t\rightarrow +\infty}v(t) = \Big(\frac{r^{u}+0.5p(\sigma_{1}^{u})^{2}}{mk^{l}}\Big)^{p} $. Using the comparison theorem yields that $ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow +\infty} \text{E}[y_{1}^{p}(t)]\leq G_{1} < +\infty $, where $ G_{1} = (\frac{r^{u}+0.5p(\sigma_{1}^{u})^{2}}{mk^{l}})^{p} $. In the same way, we can achieve $ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow +\infty} \text{E}[y_{2}^{p}(t)]\leq G_{2} < +\infty $ and $ G_{2} = (\frac{f^{u}/a^{l}+0.5p(\sigma_{2}^{u})^{2}}{\widetilde{m}h^{l}})^{p} $.
Consequently, for a given constant $ \varepsilon > 0 $, there is a $ T > 0 $ satisfying $ \text{E}[y_{1}^{p}(t)]\leq G_{1}+\varepsilon $, $ \text{E}[y_{2}^{p}(t)]\leq G_{2}+\varepsilon $, for all $ t > T $. Considering the continuity of $ \text{E}[y_{1}^{p}(t)] $ and $ \text{E}[y_{2}^{p}(t)] $, there exist $ \overline{G_{1}}(p), \overline{G_{2}}(p) > 0 $ such that $ \text{E}[y_{1}^{p}(t)]\leq \overline{G_{1}}(p) $ and $ \text{E}[y_{2}^{p}(t)] \leq \overline{G_{2}}(p) $ for $ t\leq T $. Denote $ M_{1}(p) = \max\{\overline{G_{1}}(p), G_{1}+\varepsilon\} $, $ M_{2}(p) = \max\{\overline{G_{2}}(p), G_{2}+\varepsilon\} $, then for all $ t\in \mathbb{R}_{+} $,
$ \text{E}[y_{1}^{p}(t)]\leq M_{1}(p), \quad \text{E}[y_{2}^{p}(t)]\leq M_{2}(p) $ |
and
$ \text{E}[x_{1}^{p}(t)] = \text{E}\Big[\big(\prod\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t}(1+\rho_{1k})y_{1}(t)\big)^{p}\Big]\leq M^{p}M_{1}(p), \quad \text{E}[x_{2}^{p}(t)] = \text{E}\Big[\big(\prod\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t}(1+\rho_{2k})y_{2}(t)\big)^{p}\Big]\leq \widetilde{M}^{p}M_{1}(p). $ |
Thus, for $ X_{1}(t) = (x_{1}(t), x_{2}(t))\in \mathbb{R}_{+}^{2} $, it is obvious that $ |X_{1}(t)|^{p}\leq 2^{\frac{p}{2}}[x_{1}^{p}(t)+x_{2}^{p}(t)] $. Therefore,
$ E|X_{1}(t)|^{p}\leq M_{p} \lt +\infty, $ |
herein, $ M_{p} = 2^{\frac{p}{2}}(M^{p}M_{1}(p)+\widetilde{M}^{p}M_{2}(p)) $. By virtue of the Chebyshev inequality, the proof is completed.
Proof of Theorem 4.2. From Eq (3.1), we have
$ dy1≤ y1(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1)dt+y1σ1(t)dB1(t),dy2≤y2(−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2+f(t)a(t))dt+y2σ2(t)dB2(t). $ | (A.3) |
Construct the comparison equation
$ dˉy1=ˉy1(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)ˉy1)dt+ˉy1σ1(t)dB1(t),dˉy2=ˉy2(−h(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)ˉy2+f(t)a(t))dt+ˉy2σ2(t)dB2(t), $ | (A.4) |
where $ (\bar{y}_{1}(t), \bar{y}_{2}(t)) $ is a solution of Eq (A.4) with initial value $ (y_{1}(0), y_{2}(0))\in \mathbb{R}_{2}^{+} $. According to the comparison theorem for stochastic differential equations ([33]) and Theorem 4.1 ([34]), we can obtain that $ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ { \text{ln}}y_{1}(t)}{ \text{ln}t} \leq \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}\bar{y}_{1}(t)}{ \text{ln}t}\leq 1 $, $ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}y_{2}(t)}{ \text{ln}t}\leq \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}\bar{y}_{2}(t)}{ \text{ln}t}\leq 1 $, a.s. Then,
$ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}y_{1}(t)}{t}\leq\limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}y_{1}(t)}{ \text{ln}t}. \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}t}{t}\leq \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}t}{t} = 0. $ |
Similarly, we have that $ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}y_{2}(t)}{t}\leq 0 $. Therefore,
$ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}x_{1}(t)}{t} = \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \frac{\sum\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{1k})+ \text{ln}y_{1}(t)}{t} = \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}y_{1}(t)}{t}+\limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \frac{\sum\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{1k})}{ \text{ln}t}.\frac{ \text{ln}t}{t}\leq0, $ |
$ \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty}\frac{ \text{ln}x_{2}(t)}{t} = \limsup\limits_{t\rightarrow\infty} \frac{\sum\limits_{0 \lt \tau_{k} \lt t} \text{ln}(1+\rho_{2k})+ \text{ln}y_{2}(t)}{t}\leq0. $ | (A.5) |
The proof is completed.
Proof of Theorem 5.1. The first equation of Eq (3.1) is equivalent to the following stochastic integral equation
$ y1(t)=y1(0)+∫t0y1(s)(r(s)−k(s)∏0<τk<s(1+ρ1k)y1(s)−ω(s)λ(s)∏0<τk<s(1+ρ2k)y2(s))ds+∫t0y1(s)σ1(s)dB1(s), $ |
Denote $ f_{1}(s) = y_{1}(s)\big(r(s)-k(s)\prod\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < s}(1+\rho_{1k})y_{1}(s) -\frac{\omega(s)}{\lambda(s)}\prod\limits_{0 < \tau_{k} < s}(1+\rho_{2k})y_{2}(s)\Big) $, $ f_{2}(s) = y_{1}(s)\sigma_{1}(s), $ then
$ E|f1(t)|p=E|y1(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2)|p=E[|y1|p⋅|(r(t)−k(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ1k)y1−ω(t)λ(t)∏0<τk<t(1+ρ2k)y2)|p]≤12E|y1|2p+12E|ru+Mkuy1+˜Mωuy2|2p≤12E|y1|2p+1232p−1[(ru)2p+(Mku)2pE|y1|2p+(˜Mωu)2pE|y2|2p]≤12M1(2p)+32p−12[(ru)2p+(Mku)2pM1(2p)+(˜Mωu)2pM2(2p)]≜F1(p), $ | (A.6) |
$ E|f2(t)|p=E|y1σ1(t)|p≤σu1E|y1|p≤σu1M1(p)≜F2(p). $ | (A.7) |
By virtue of the moment inequality for stochastic integrals, we can show that for $ 0\leq t_{1}\leq t_{2} $ and $ p > 2 $,
$ \text{E}|\int_{t_{1}}^{t_{2}}f_{2}(s) \text{d}B_{1}(s)|^{p}\leq(\frac{p(p-1)}{2})^{\frac{p}{2}}(t_{2}-t_{1})^{\frac{p-2}{2}}\int_{t_{1}}^{t_{2}} \text{E}|f_{2}(s)|^{p} \text{d}s\leq(\frac{p(p-1)}{2})^{\frac{p}{2}}(t_{2}-t_{1})^{\frac{p}{2}}F_{2}(p). $ |
Thus, for $ 0 < t_{1} < t_{2} < \infty $, $ t_{2}-t_{1}\leq 1 $, $ \frac{1}{p}+\frac{1}{q} = 1 $ and by Eqs (A.6) and (A.7), we achieve
$ E|y1(t2)−y1(t1)|p=E|∫t2t1f1(s)ds+∫t2t1f2(s)dB1(s)|p≤2p−1E|∫t2t1f1(s)ds|p+2p−1E|∫t2t1f2(s)dB1(s)|p $ |
$ ≤2p−1(t2−t1)pqE[∫t2t1|f1(s)|pds]+2p−1(p(p−1)2)p2(t2−t1)p2F2(p)≤2p−1(t2−t1)pqF1(p)(t2−t1)+2p−1(p(p−1)2)p2(t2−t1)p2F2(p)=2p−1(t2−t1)pF1(p)+2p−1(p(p−1)2)p2(t2−t1)p2F2(p)=2p−1(t2−t1)p2{(t2−t1)p2F1(p)+(p(p−1)2)p2F2(p)}≤2p−1(t2−t1)p2{1+(p(p−1)2)p2}F(p), $ |
where $ F(p) = \max\{F_{1}(p), F_{2}(p)\} $. By Lemma 5 in [11] and the definition in [30], we obtain that almost every sample path of $ y_{1}(t) $ is locally but uniformly $ H\ddot{o}lder $-continuous with exponent $ \upsilon $ for every $ \upsilon \in (0, \frac{p-2}{2p}) $. Similarly, it can be proved that almost every sample path of $ y_{2}(t) $ is also uniformly continuous on $ t\geq 0 $. The proof is completed.
[1] | U.S. House (2007) Energy Independence and Security Act of 2007. 100th Congress, 1st session, HR 6.4. |
[2] | U.S. DOE (2012) Monthly Energy Review: October 2012. US Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration, Independent Statistics & Analysis, DOE/EIA-0035(2012/10). |
[3] | McKendry P (2002) Energy production from biomass (part 2): conversion technologies. Bioresource Technology 83.1: 47-54. |
[4] | U.S. DOE (2005) Biomass as Feedstock for a Bioenergy and Bioproducts Industry: The Technical Feasibility of a Billion-Ton Annual Supply. R.D. Perlack, B.J. Stokes, and D.C. Erbach (Leads). United States Department of Energy, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, ORNL/TM-2005/66. |
[5] | U.S. DOE (2011) U.S. Billion-Ton Update: Biomass Supply for a Bioenergy and Bioproducts Industry. R.K. Perlack and B.J. Stokes (Leads), United States Department of Energy, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, ORNL/TM-2011/224. |
[6] | Green JD, Witt WW, Margin JR (2006) Weed Management in Grass Pastures, Hayfields, and Other Farmstead Sites (AGR-172). University of Kentucky Cooperative Extension Service. |
[7] | Wright L, Turhollow A (2010) Switchgrass Selection as a “Model” Bioenergy Crop: A History of the Process. Biomass & Bioenergy 34: 851-868. |
[8] | Greef JM, Deuter M, Jung C, et al. (1997) Genetic diversity of European Miscanthus species revealed by Aflp finger printing. Genetic Resource & Crop Evolution 44: 185-195. |
[9] | West NM, Matlaga DP, Davis AS (2014) Managing Spread from Rhizome Fragments is Key to Reducing Invasiveness of Miscanthus x giganteus. Invasive Plant Science & Management 7: 517-525. |
[10] |
Boose AB, Holt JS (1999) Environmental effects on asexual reproduction in Arundo onax. Weed Research 39: 117-127. doi: 10.1046/j.1365-3180.1999.00129.x
![]() |
[11] | Palmer IE, Gehl RJ, Ranney TG, et al. (2014) Biomass Yield, Nitrogen Response, and Nutrient Uptake of Perennial Bioenergy Grasses in North Carolina. Biomass & Bioenergy 63: 218-228. |
[12] | Gill JR, Burks PS, Staggenborg SA, et al. (2014) Yield Results and Stability Analysis form the Sorghum Regional Biomass Feedstock Trial. Bioenergy Research 7: 1026-1034. |
[13] | Whitfield M, Chinn M, Veal M (2012) Processing of materials derived from sweet sorghum for biobased products. Industrial Crops & Products 37: 362-375. |
[14] | Köppen S, Reinhardt G, Gärtner S (2009) Assessment of energy and greenhouse gas inventories of Sweet Sorghum for first and second generation bioethanol. Environment and Natural Resources Management Working Paper, 30. Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations. |
[15] |
Griffey C, Brooks W, Kurantz M, et al. (2010) Grain composition of Virginia winter barley and implications for use in feed, food, and biofuels production. Journal of Cereal Sciences 51: 41-49. doi: 10.1016/j.jcs.2009.09.004
![]() |
[16] | Han M, Kang KE, Kim Y, et al. (2013) High efficiency bioethanol production from barley straw using a continuous pretreatment reactor. Process Biochemistry 48: 488-495. |
[17] | Zentková I, Cvengrošová E (2013) The utilization of rapeseed for biofuels production in the EU. Visegrad Journal on Bioeconomy & Sustainable Development 2: 11-14. |
[18] | U.S. DOE (2002) Lignocellulosic Biomass to Ethanol Process Design and Economics Utilizing Co-Current Dilute Acid Prehydrolysis and Enzymatic Hydrolysis for Corn Stover. A. Aden, M. Ruth, K. Ibsen, J. Jechura, K. Neeves, J. Sheehan, B. Wallace, L. Montague, A. Slayton, J. Lukas. United States Department of Energy, National Renewable Energy Laboratory, NREL/TP-510-32438. |
[19] | Searchinger T, Heinlich R, Houghton RA, et al. (2008) Use of U.S. Croplands for Biofuels Increases Greenhouse Gases Through Emissions from Land-Use Change. Science 319: 1238-1240. |
[20] | Dale VH, Kline KL, Wiens J, et al. (2010) Biofuels: Implications for Land Use and Biodiversity. Ecological Society of America, Biofuels and Sustainability Reports. |
[21] | Mayer ML (2012) Assessment of Bioenergy Crop Production Feasibility along North Carolina Department of Transportation Highway Right-of-Ways. NCSU MS Thesis. |
[22] | Babcock BA, Iqbal Z (2014) Using Recent Land Use Change to Validate Land Use Change Models. Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University. Staff Report 14-SR 109. |
[23] | Deininger K, Byerlee D, Lindsay J, et al. (2011) Rising Global Interest in Farmland: Can it Yield Sustainable and Equitable Benefits? The World Bank, Agriculture and Rural Development. |
[24] | Crouse D (2003) Realistic yields and nitrogen application factors for North Carolina crops. North Carolina State University, North Carolina Department of Agriculture and Consumer Services, North Carolina Department of Environment and Natural Resources, Natural Resources Conservation Service. Raleigh NC. Available from: http://nutrients.soil.ncsu.edu/yields/. |
[25] | USDA (2014) Web Soil Survey. Soil Survey Staff, National Resources Conservation Service, United States Department of Agriculture. Available from: http://websoilsurvey.nrcs.usda.gov. Accessed: October 2014. |
[26] | USDA (2014) Cropland Data Layer 2013. Published crop-specific data layer [online]. United States Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service. Available from: http://nassgeodata.gmu.edu/CropScape. Accessed: July 2014. |
[27] |
USDA (2013) 2013 State Agriculture Overview: North Carolina. United States Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service. Available from: http://www.nass.usda.gov/Quick_Stats/Ag_Overview/. Accessed: Nov 2014. |
[28] | George N, Tungate K, Beec, C, et al. (2010) An Evaluation of winter canola in North Carolina. North Carolina State University, Department of Crop Science, Official Variety Trials. Available from: http://www.ncovt.com/. Accessed: July 2014. |
[29] | Bullen G, Weddington E (2012) Enterprise Budgets: Corn- Conventional Till-NC, Coastal Plain 2012. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[30] | Bullen G, Weddington E (2012) Enterprise Budgets: Corn- No Till-NC, Coastal Plain 2012. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[31] | Bullen G (2013) Enterprise Budgets: Cotton- Conventional Tillage- 2013. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[32] | Bullen G (2013) Enterprise Budgets: Cotton- Strip Tillage- 2013. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[33] | Bullen G, Jordan D (2013) Enterprise Budgets: Peanuts- Conventional Virginia 2013. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[34] | Bullen G, Jordan D (2013) Enterprise Budgets: Peanuts- Strip Till 2013. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[35] | Bullen G, Dunphy J (2012) Enterprise Budgets: Soybeans- Full Season, Conventional Tillage 2012. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[36] | Bullen G, Dunphy J (2012) Enterprise Budgets: Soybeans- Full Season, No Till 2012. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[37] | Bullen G, Fisher L (2013) Enterprise Budgets: Flue-Cured Tobacco-Hand Harvested Piedmont- 2013. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[38] | Bullen G, Fisher L (2013) Enterprise Budgets: Flue-Cured Tobacco-Machine Harvested Piedmont- 2013. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[39] | Bullen G, Fisher L (2013) Enterprise Budgets: Flue-Cured Tobacco-Machine Harvested East- 2013. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[40] | Bullen G, Weddington E (2012) Enterprise Budgets: Wheat for Grain Conventional 2012. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[41] | Bullen G, Weddington E (2012) Enterprise Budgets: Wheat for Grain No-Till 2012. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[42] |
Bullen G, Little B (2013) Enterprise Budgets: Sweet Potato 2013. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[43] | NCSU (2014) Enterprise Budget: No-Till Grain Sorghum for the Coastal Plain Region of NC. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[44] |
Green JT, Benson GA (2013) Bermuda Grass for Pasture. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[45] |
Green JT, Benson GA (2013) Bermuda Grass for Hay. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[46] |
Green JT, Benson GA (2013) Cool Season Perennial Grass for Pasture. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[47] |
Green JT, Benson GA (2013) Hay Harvest Cost, Large Round Baler. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[48] | U.S. DOE (2009) Uniform-Format Solid Feedstock Supply System: A Commodity-Scale Design to Produce an Infrastructure-Compatible Bulk Solid from Lignocellulosic Biomass. Hess, JR, Wright, CT, Kenney, KL, Searcy, EM. US Department of Energy, Idaho National Laboratory, INL/EXT-09-15423. |
[49] | Saxe C (2004) Big Bale Storage Losses. University of Wisconsin Extension, November 2004. |
[50] |
Buchholz T, Volk TA (2011) Improving the Profitability of Willow Crops- Identifying Opportunities with a Crop Budget Model. Bioenergy Research 4: 85-95. doi: 10.1007/s12155-010-9103-5
![]() |
[51] | Atkinson AD, Rich BA, Tungate KD, et al. (2006) North Carolina Canola Production. North Carolina State University, North Carolina Solar Center & College of Agriculture and Life Sciences. SJS/KEL-9/06-W07 |
[52] | MB (2012) 2012 Sorghum Program- Murphy-Brown’s Next Step in Broad Strategy to Improve MB Grain Buying. Murphy-Brown Grain, Available from: http://mbgrain.com/ |
[53] | CC (2014) Current Canola Oil, Meal, and Seed Prices. Canola Council of Canada. Available from: http://www.canolacouncil.org/. |
[54] | Lee D, Owens VN, Boe A, et al. (2007) Composition of Herbaceous Biomass Feedstocks. SunGrant Initiative, North Central Center, South Dakota State University, SGINC1-07. |
[55] |
Liebig MA, Schmer MR, Vogel KP, et al. (2008) Soil Carbon Storage by Switchgrass Grown for Bioenergy. Bioenergy Research 1: 215-222. doi: 10.1007/s12155-008-9019-5
![]() |
[56] | Humbird D, Davis R, Tao L, et al. (2011) Process Design and Economics for Biochemical Conversion of Lignocellulosic Biomass to Ethanol: Dilute-Acid Pretreatment and Enzymatic Hydrolysis of Corn Stover. US Department of Energy, National Renewable Energy Laboratory, NRL/TP-5100-47764. |
[57] | Glassner D, Hettenhaus J, Schechinger T (1998) Corn stover collection project- a pilot for establishing infrastructure for agricultural residue and other crop collection for biomass processing to ethanol. In: Proc. Bioenergy 1998 Conference, 4-8 October, 1998, Madison, WI, pp. 1100-1110. |
[58] | Lazarus WF (2009) Machinery Cost Estimates. University of Minnesota Extension. St Paul, MN. Shelf Location: 378.776 A4744 6696 2009-6. |
[59] | Lazarus WF (2014) Machinery Cost Estimates. University of Minnesota Extension. St. Paul, MN. Available at: https://drive.google.com/a/umn.edu/file/d/0B3psjoooP5QxWWd3a2cwblJCTjQ/view |
[60] | USDA (2015) Cash Rents by County. United States Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service. August 2014. Available at: www.nass.usda.gov |
[61] | U.S. DOE (2011) Biomass multi-year program plan. United States Department of Energy, Energy Efficiency & Renewable Energy, Office of Biomass Program. |
[62] | NCSU (2008) Enterprise Budgets: Hay Production, Harvest and Storage Costs, Round Bales. North Carolina State University, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Available from: http://ag-econ.ncsu.edu/extension/budgets. |
[63] | U.S. DOE (2014) Southeast Biomass Atlas. United States Department of Energy, SunGrant Initiative Southeastern Regional Center, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, University of Tennessee Center for Renewable Carbon. Available from: http://www.biomassatlas.org/ |
1. | YARU GUO, SHULIN SUN, DYNAMIC BEHAVIOR OF A STOCHASTIC NON-AUTONOMOUS PREDATOR–PREY MODEL WITH CROWLEY–MARTIN FUNCTIONAL RESPONSE AND IMPULSES, 2022, 30, 0218-3390, 183, 10.1142/S0218339022500061 | |
2. | Zin Thu Win, Boping Tian, Population dynamical behaviors of jellyfish model with random perturbation, 2023, 28, 1531-3492, 2994, 10.3934/dcdsb.2022201 | |
3. | Yuan Tian, Yan Gao, Kaibiao Sun, A fishery predator-prey model with anti-predator behavior and complex dynamics induced by weighted fishing strategies, 2023, 20, 1551-0018, 1558, 10.3934/mbe.2023071 |