The Common Monetary Area (CMA) agreement has effectively granted the South African government sole discretion over monetary policy and implementation in the region. The effectiveness of this arrangement has long been under discussion given the heterogeneity of member countries. This paper uses a structural vector autoregressive (SVAR) to examine the efficacy of the interest rate channel in the CMA. Specifically, our analysis uses data from 2000M1-2018M12 to examine how economic output, inflation, money supply, domestic credit, and lending rate spread for each member country respond to shocks in the South African repo rate. The main findings indicate that a positive shock to the South African repo rate has a statistically significant negative impact on economic output and a positive effect on inflation at the 10 percent level for all countries in the CMA. The results also show that money supply, domestic credit, and lending rate spread respond asymmetrically across members countries.
Citation: Bonang N. Seoela. 2022: Efficacy of monetary policy in a currency union? Evidence from Southern Africa's Common Monetary Area, Quantitative Finance and Economics, 6(1): 35-53. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022002
[1] | Jamal Salah, Hameed Ur Rehman, Iman Al Buwaiqi, Ahmad Al Azab, Maryam Al Hashmi . Subclasses of spiral-like functions associated with the modified Caputo's derivative operator. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(8): 18474-18490. doi: 10.3934/math.2023939 |
[2] | A. A. Azzam, Daniel Breaz, Shujaat Ali Shah, Luminiţa-Ioana Cotîrlă . Study of the fuzzy q−spiral-like functions associated with the generalized linear operator. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(11): 26290-26300. doi: 10.3934/math.20231341 |
[3] | Huo Tang, Shahid Khan, Saqib Hussain, Nasir Khan . Hankel and Toeplitz determinant for a subclass of multivalent q-starlike functions of order α. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(6): 5421-5439. doi: 10.3934/math.2021320 |
[4] | Shujaat Ali Shah, Ekram Elsayed Ali, Adriana Cătaș, Abeer M. Albalahi . On fuzzy differential subordination associated with q-difference operator. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(3): 6642-6650. doi: 10.3934/math.2023336 |
[5] | Ekram E. Ali, Miguel Vivas-Cortez, Rabha M. El-Ashwah . New results about fuzzy γ-convex functions connected with the q-analogue multiplier-Noor integral operator. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(3): 5451-5465. doi: 10.3934/math.2024263 |
[6] | Ahmad A. Abubaker, Khaled Matarneh, Mohammad Faisal Khan, Suha B. Al-Shaikh, Mustafa Kamal . Study of quantum calculus for a new subclass of q-starlike bi-univalent functions connected with vertical strip domain. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(5): 11789-11804. doi: 10.3934/math.2024577 |
[7] | Saqib Hussain, Shahid Khan, Muhammad Asad Zaighum, Maslina Darus . Certain subclass of analytic functions related with conic domains and associated with Salagean q-differential operator. AIMS Mathematics, 2017, 2(4): 622-634. doi: 10.3934/Math.2017.4.622 |
[8] | Jianhua Gong, Muhammad Ghaffar Khan, Hala Alaqad, Bilal Khan . Sharp inequalities for q-starlike functions associated with differential subordination and q-calculus. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(10): 28421-28446. doi: 10.3934/math.20241379 |
[9] | Ibtisam Aldawish, Mohamed Aouf, Basem Frasin, Tariq Al-Hawary . New subclass of analytic functions defined by q-analogue of p-valent Noor integral operator. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(10): 10466-10484. doi: 10.3934/math.2021607 |
[10] | Ekram E. Ali, Nicoleta Breaz, Rabha M. El-Ashwah . Subordinations and superordinations studies using q-difference operator. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(7): 18143-18162. doi: 10.3934/math.2024886 |
The Common Monetary Area (CMA) agreement has effectively granted the South African government sole discretion over monetary policy and implementation in the region. The effectiveness of this arrangement has long been under discussion given the heterogeneity of member countries. This paper uses a structural vector autoregressive (SVAR) to examine the efficacy of the interest rate channel in the CMA. Specifically, our analysis uses data from 2000M1-2018M12 to examine how economic output, inflation, money supply, domestic credit, and lending rate spread for each member country respond to shocks in the South African repo rate. The main findings indicate that a positive shock to the South African repo rate has a statistically significant negative impact on economic output and a positive effect on inflation at the 10 percent level for all countries in the CMA. The results also show that money supply, domestic credit, and lending rate spread respond asymmetrically across members countries.
Let A denote the class of functions of the form
f(z)=z+∞∑k=2akzk, | (1.1) |
which are analytic in the open disc U={z∈C:|z|<1}. Let S denote the subclass of A consisting of functions that are univalent in U. Also, let Ω be the class of all analytic functions w in U that satisfy the conditions w(0)=0 and |w(z)|<1(z∈U). If f and g are analytic in U, we say that f is subordinate to g, written as f≺g in U or f(z)≺g(z) (z∈U), if there exists w∈Ω such that f(z)=g(w(z)) (z∈U). Furthermore, if the function g(z) is univalent in U, then we have the following equivalence holds (see [4] and [11]):
f(z)≺g(z)⟺f(0)=g(0) and f(U)⊂g(U). |
A function f∈A is said to be in the class of γ− spiral-like functions of order λ in U, denoted by S∗(γ;λ) if
ℜ{eiγzf′(z)f(z)}>λ cosγ (0≤λ<1,|γ|<π2;z∈U). | (1.2) |
The class S∗(γ;λ) was studied by Libera [10] and Keogh and Merkes [9]. Note that
1). S∗(γ;0)=S∗(γ) is the class of spiral-like functions introduced by Špaček [17];
2). S∗(0;λ)=S∗(λ) is the class of starlike functions of order λ;
3). S∗(0;0)=S∗ is the familiar class of starlike functions.
For functions f∈A given by (1.1) and g∈A given by
g(z)=z+∞∑k=2bkzk, | (1.3) |
we define the Hadamard product (or Convolution) of f and g by
(f∗g)(z)=z+∞∑k=2akbkzk. | (1.4) |
Also, for f∈A given by (1.1) and 0<q<1, the Jackson's q-derivative operator or q-difference operator for a function f∈A is defined by (see [1,2,3,6,7,15,16])
Dqf(z):={f′(0)if z=0,f(z)−f(qz)(1−q)zif z≠0. | (1.5) |
From (1.5), we deduce that
Dqf(z)=1+∞∑k=2[k]q akzk−1 (z≠0), | (1.6) |
where the q-integer number [i]q is defined by
[i]q=1−qi1−q=1+q+q2+...+qi−1, | (1.7) |
and
limq→1−Dqf(z)=limq→1−f(z)−f(qz)(1−q)z=f′(z), | (1.8) |
for a function f which is differentiable in a given subset of C.
Next, in terms of the q-generalized Pochhammer symbol ([v]q)n given by
([v]q)n=[v]q [v+1]q [v+2]q ... [v+n−1]q, | (1.9) |
we define the function ϕq(a,c;z) by
ϕq(a,c;z)=z+∞∑k=2([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1zk (a∈R;c∈R∖Z−0;Z−0={0,−1,−2,...};z∈U). | (1.10) |
Corresponding to the function ϕq(a,c;z), we consider a linear operator Lq(a,c):A→A which is defined by means of the following Hadamard product (or convolution):
Lq(a,c)f(z)=ϕq(a,c;z)∗f(z)=z+∞∑k=2([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1 ak zk. | (1.11) |
It is easily verified from (1.11) that
qa−1zDq(Lq(a,c)f(z))=[a]q Lq(a+1,c)f(z)−[a−1]qLq(a,c)f(z). | (1.12) |
Moreover, for f∈A, we observe that
1). limq→1−Lq(a,c)f(z)=L(a,c)f(z), where L(a,c) denotes the Carlson-Shaffer operator [5];
2). Lq(δ+1,1)f(z)=Rδqf(z)(δ>0), where Rδq denotes the Ruscheweyh q-derivative of a function f∈A of order δ (see [8]);
3). limq→1−Lq(δ+1,1)f(z)=Rδf(z)(δ>0), where Rδq denotes the Ruscheweyh derivative of order δ (see [14]);
4). Lq(a,a)f(z)=f(z) and Lq(2,1)f(z)=zDqf(z).
Making use of the q-analogue of Carlson-Shaffer operator Lq(a,c), we introduce a new subclass of spiral-like functions.
Definition 1. For 0≤t≤1, 0≤λ<1 and |γ|<π2, we let Saq(γ,λ,t) be the subclass of A consisting of functions of the form (1.1) and satisfying the analytic condition:
ℜ{eiγzDq(Lq(a,c)f(z))(1−t) z+t Lq(a,c)f(z)}>λ cosγ | (1.13) |
(0≤t≤1;0≤λ<1;|γ|<π2;z∈U). |
We note that
1). For t=1, 0≤λ<1 and |γ|<π2, we let Saq(γ,λ,1)=Saq(γ,λ) be the subclass of A consisting of functions of the form (1.1) and satisfying the analytic condition:
ℜ{eiγzDq(Lq(a,c)f(z))Lq(a,c)f(z)}>λ cosγ | (1.14) |
(0≤λ<1;|γ|<π2;z∈U). |
2). For t=0, 0≤λ<1 and |γ|<π2, we let Saq(γ,λ,0)=Kaq(γ,λ) be the subclass of A consisting of functions of the form (1.1) and satisfying the analytic condition:
ℜ{eiγ Dq(Lq(a,c)f(z))}>λ cosγ | (1.15) |
(0≤λ<1;|γ|<π2;z∈U). |
The object of the present paper is to investigate the coefficient estimates and subordination properties for the class of functions Saq(γ,λ,t). Some interesting consequences of the results are also pointed out.
In this section, we obtain several sufficient conditions for a function f∈A to be in the class Saq(γ,λ,t).
Theorem 1. Let f∈A and let σ be a real number with 0≤σ<1. If
|zDq(Lq(a,c)f(z))(1−t) z+t Lq(a,c)f(z)−1|≤1−σ (z∈U), | (2.1) |
then f∈Saq(γ,λ,t) provided that
|γ|≤cos−1(1−σ1−λ) | (2.2) |
Proof. From (2.1) it follows that
zDq(Lq(a,c)f(z))(1−t) z+t Lq(a,c)f(z)=1+(1−σ)w(z), |
where w(z)∈Ω. We have
ℜ{eiγzDq(Lq(a,c)f(z))(1−t) z+t Lq(a,c)f(z)}=ℜ{eiγ[1+(1−σ)w(z)]}=cosγ+(1−σ)ℜ{eiγw(z)}≥cosγ−(1−σ)|eiγw(z)|>cosγ−(1−σ)≥λ cosγ |
provided that |γ|≤cos−1(1−σ1−λ). Thus, the proof is completed.
Putting σ=1−(1−λ)cosγ in Theorem 1, we obtain the following result.
Corollary 1. Let f∈A. If
|zDq(Lq(a,c)f(z))(1−t) z+t Lq(a,c)f(z)−1|≤(1−λ)cosγ (z∈U), | (2.3) |
then f∈Saq(γ,λ,t).
In the following theorem, we obtain a sufficient condition for f to be in Saq(γ,λ,t).
Theorem 2. A function f(z) of the form (1.1) is in Saq(γ,λ,t) if
∞∑k=2{([k]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1|ak|≤1−λ. | (2.4) |
Proof. In virtue of Corollary 1, it suffices to show that the condition (2.3) is satisfied. We have
|zDq(Lq(a,c)f(z))(1−t) z+t Lq(a,c)f(z)−1|=|∞∑k=2{[k]q−t}([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1 ak zk−11+t∞∑k=2([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1ak zk−1|<∞∑k=2{[k]q−t}([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1 |ak|1−∞∑k=2t([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1|ak|. |
The last expression is bounded above by (1−λ)cosγ, if
∞∑k=2{[k]q−t}([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1 |ak|≤(1−λ)cosγ{1−∞∑k=2t([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1|ak|} |
which is equivalent to
∞∑k=2{([k]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1|ak|≤1−λ. |
This completes the proof of the Theorem 2.
Putting t=1 in Theorem 2, we obtain the following corollary.
Corollary 2. A function f(z) of the form (2.1) is in Saq(γ,λ) if
∞∑k=2{([k]q−1)secγ+1−λ}([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1|ak|≤1−λ. | (2.5) |
Putting t=0 in Theorem 2, we obtain the following corollary.
Corollary 3. A function f(z) of the form (2.1) is in Kaq(γ,λ) if
∞∑k=2[k]qsecγ([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1|ak|≤1−λ. | (2.6) |
Before stating and proving our subordination result for the class Saq(γ,λ,t), we need the following definitions and a lemma due to Wilf [19].
Definition 2 [19]. A sequence {bk}∞k=1 of complex numbers is said to be a subordinating factor sequence if, whenever f(z)=z+∞∑k=2akzk is regular, univalent and convex in U, we have
∞∑k=1ak bk ≺f(z) (a1=1;z∈U). | (3.1) |
Lemma 1 [19]. The sequence {bk}∞k=1 is a subordinating factor sequence if and only if
ℜ{1+2∞∑k=1bk zk}>0 (z∈U). | (3.2) |
Theorem 3. Let f∈Saq(γ,λ,t) satisfy the coefficient inequality (2.4) with a≥c>0 and let g(z) be any function in the usual class of convex functions C, then
{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q2[1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q](f∗g)(z)≺g(z) | (3.3) |
and
ℜ{f(z)}>−1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q. | (3.4) |
The constant factor {([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q2[1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q] in (3.3) cannot be replaced by a larger number.
Proof. Let f∈Saq(γ,λ,t) satisfy the coefficient inequality (2.4) and suppose that
g(z)=z+∞∑k=2bkzk∈C. |
Then, by Definition 2, the subordination (3.3) of our theorem will hold true if the sequence
{{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q2[1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q]ak}∞k=1 |
is a subordinating factor sequence, with b1=1. In view of Lemma 1, it is equivalent to the inequality
ℜ{1+∞∑k=1{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]qak zk}>0 (z∈U). | (3.5) |
By noting the fact that {([k]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}([a]q)k−1(1−λ)([c]q)k−1 is an increasing function for k≥2 and a≥c>0. In view of (2.4), when |z|=r<1, we obtain
ℜ{1+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q∞∑k=1ak zk} |
=ℜ{1+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]qz+∞∑k=2{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]qak zk1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q} |
≥1−{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]qr−∞∑k=2{([k]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}([a]q)k−1([c]q)k−1|ak| rk1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q |
≥1−{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]qr−1−λ1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]qr=1−r>0 (|z|=r<1). |
This evidently proves the inequality (3.5) and hence also the subordination result (3.3) asserted by Theorem 3. The inequality (3.4) follows from (3.3) by taking
g(z)=z1−z=z+∞∑k=2zk∈C. |
The sharpness of the multiplying factor in (3.3) can be established by considering a function
F(z)=z−1−λ{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]qz2. |
Clearly F∈Saq(γ,λ,t) satisfy (2.4). Using (3.3) we infer that
{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q2[1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q]F(z)≺z1−z, |
and it follows that
min|z|≤r{{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q2[1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q]ℜ{F(z)}}=−12. |
This shows that the constant {([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q2[1−λ+{([2]q−t)secγ+(1−λ)t}[a]q[c]q] cannot be replaced by any larger one.
For t=1 in Theorem 3, we state the following corollary.
Corollary 4. Let f∈Saq(γ,λ) satisfy the coefficient inequality (2.5) with a≥c>0 and g∈C, then
{qsecγ+1−λ}[a]q[c]q2[1−λ+{qsecγ+1−λ}[a]q[c]q](f∗g)(z)≺g(z) | (3.6) |
and
ℜ{f(z)}>−1−λ+{qsecγ+1−λ}[a]q[c]q{qsecγ+1−λ}[a]q[c]q. | (3.7) |
The constant factor {qsecγ+1−λ}[a]q[c]q2[1−λ+{qsecγ+(1−λ)}[a]q[c]q] in (3.6) cannot be replaced by a larger number.
Taking t=0 in Theorem 3, we state the next corollary.
Corollary 5. Let f∈Kaq(γ,λ) satisfy the coefficient inequality (2.6) with a≥c>0 and g∈C, then
(1+q)secγ[a]q[c]q2[1−λ+(1+q)secγ[a]q[c]q](f∗g)(z)≺g(z) | (3.8) |
and
ℜ{f(z)}>−1−λ+(1+q)secγ[a]q[c]q(1+q)secγ[a]q[c]q. | (3.9) |
The constant factor (1+q)secγ[a]q[c]q2[1−λ+(1+q)secγ[a]q[c]q] in (3.8) cannot be replaced by a larger number.
The Fekete-Szegö problem consists in finding sharp upper bounds for the functional |a3−μa22| for various subclasses of A (see [13] and [18]). In order to obtain sharp upper-bounds for |a3−μa22| for the class Saq(γ,λ,t) the following lemma is required (see, e.g., [12, p.108]).
Lemma 2. Let the function w∈Ω be given by
w(z)=∞∑k=1wk zk (z∈U). |
Then
|w1|≤1, |w2|≤1−|w1|2, | (4.1) |
and
|w2−s w21|≤max{1,|s|}, | (4.2) |
for any complex number s. The functions w(z)=z and w(z)=z2or one of their rotations show that both inequalities (4.1) and (4.2) are sharp.
For the constants λ, γ with 0≤λ<1 and |γ|<π2 denote
Pλ,γ(z)=1+e−iγ(e−iγ−2λcosγ)z1−z (z∈U). | (4.3) |
The function Pλ,γ(z) maps the open unit disk U onto the half-plane Hλ,γ={w∈C:ℜ{eiγw}>λcosγ}. If
Pλ,γ(z)=1+∞∑k=1pkzk (z∈U), |
then it is easy to check that
pk=2e−iγ(1−λ)cosγ (k≥1). | (4.4) |
First we obtain sharp upper-bounds for the Fekete-Szegö functional |a3−μa22| with μ real parameter.
Theorem 4. Let f∈Saq(γ,λ,t) be given by (1.1) and let μ be a real number. Then
|a3−μa22|≤{2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2[1+2(1−λ)t1+q−t −μ2(1−λ)(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q−t )2([a]q)2([c]q)2](μ≤σ1)2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2(σ1≤μ≤σ2)2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2[−1−2(1−λ)t1+q−t +μ2(1−λ)(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q−t )2([a]q)2([c]q)2](μ≥σ2) | (4.5) |
where
σ1=t(1+q−t) ([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([c]q)2([a]q)2 | (4.6) |
σ2= (1+q−t)(1+q−tλ)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1−λ)(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2 ([c]q)2 | (4.7) |
and all estimates are sharp.
Proof. Suppose that f∈Saq(γ,λ,t) is given by (1.1). Then, from the definition of the class Saq(γ,λ,t), there exists w∈Ω,
w(z)=w1z+w2z2+w3z3+... |
such that
zDq(Lq(a,c)f(z))(1−t) z+t Lq(a,c)f(z)=Pλ,γ(w(z)) (z∈U). | (4.8) |
We have
zDq(Lq(a,c)f(z))(1−t) z+t Lq(a,c)f(z)=1+(1+q−t)[a]q[c]qa2 z |
+{(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2 a3−t(1+q−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2 a22}z2+... | (4.9) |
Set
Pλ,γ(z)=1+p1z+p2z2+p3z3+... . |
From (4.4) we have
p1=p2=2e−iγ(1−λ)cosγ. |
Equating the coefficients of z and z2 on both sides of (4.8) and using (4.9), we obtain
a2=p1 [c]q(1+q−t) [a]qw1 |
and
a3=([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2[p1w2+(p2+t (1+q−t) p21)w21] |
and thus we obtain
a2=2e−iγ(1−λ)cosγ [c]q(1+q−t) [a]qw1 | (4.10) |
and
a3=2e−iγ(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2[w2+(1+2te−iγ(1−λ)cosγ 1+q−t )w21]. | (4.11) |
It follows
|a3−μa22|≤2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2[|w2|+|1+2e−iγ(1−λ)cosγ1+q−t (t −μ(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q−t) ([a]q)2([c]q)2)||w1|2] |
Making use of Lemma 2 we have
|a3−μa22|≤2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2[1+(|1+2e−iγ(1−λ)cosγ1+q−t (t −μ(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2 ([c]q)2([c]q)2(1+q−t) ([a]q)2)|−1)|w1|2] |
or
|a3−μa22|≤2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2[1+(√1+M(M+2)cos2γ−1)|w1|2], | (4.12) |
where
M=2(1−λ)1+q−t (t −μ(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2 ([c]q)2([c]q)2(1+q−t) ([a]q)2). | (4.13) |
Denote by
F(x,y)=[1+(√1+M(M+2)x2−1)y2] |
where x=cosγ, y=|w1| and (x,y):[0,1]×[0,1].
Simple calculation shows that the function F(x,y) does not have a local maximum at any interior point of the open rectangle (0,1)×(0,1). Thus, the maximum must be attained at a boundary point. Since F(x,0)=1, F(0,y)=1 and F(1,1)=|1+M|, it follows that the maximal value of F(x,y) may be F(0,0)=1 or F(1,1)=|1+M|. Therefore, from (4.12) we obtain
|a3−μa22|≤2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2max{1,|1+M|}, | (4.14) |
where M is given by (4.13). Consider first the case |1+M|≥1. If μ≤σ1, where σ1 is given by (4.6), then M≥0 and from (4.14) we obtain
|a3−μa22|≤2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2[1+2(1−λ)t1+q−t −μ2(1−λ)(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2 ([c]q)2(1+q−t )2([a]q)2([c]q)2] |
which is the first part of the inequality (4.5). If μ≥σ2, where σ2 is given by (4.7), then M≤−2 and it follows from (4.14) that
|a3−μa22|≤2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2[−1−2(1−λ)t1+q−t +μ2(1−λ)(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2 ([c]q)2(1+q−t )2([a]q)2([c]q)2] |
and this is the third part of (4.5).
Next, suppose σ1≤μ≤σ2. Then, |1+M|≤1 and thus, from (4.14) we obtain
|a3−μa22|≤2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2 |
which is the second part of the inequality (4.5). In view of Lemma 2, the results are sharp for w(z)=z and w(z)=z2 or one of their rotations.
For t=1 in Theorem 4, we state the following corollary.
Corollary 6. Let f∈Saq(γ,λ) be given by (1.1) and let μ be a real number. Then
|a3−μa22|≤{2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2q(1+q)([a]q)2[1+2(1−λ)q−μ2(1−λ)(1+q)([a]q)2([c]q)2q([a]q)2([c]q)2](μ≤σ3)2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2q(1+q)([a]q)2(σ3≤μ≤σ4)2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2q(1+q)([a]q)2[−1−2(1−λ)q+μ2(1−λ)(1+q)([a]q)2([c]q)2q([a]q)2([c]q)2](μ≥σ4) |
where
σ3=([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q)([c]q)2([a]q)2, σ4= (1+q−λ)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1−λ)(1+q)([a]q)2 ([c]q)2 |
and all estimates are sharp.
Taking t=0 in Theorem 4, we state the next corollary.
Corollary 7. Let f∈Kaq(γ,λ) be given by (1.1) and let μ be a real number. Then
|a3−μa22|≤{2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2)([a]q)2[1−μ2(1−λ)(1+q+q2)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q)2([a]q)2([c]q)2](μ≤0)2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2)([a]q)2(0≤μ≤σ5)2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2)([a]q)2[−1+μ2(1−λ)(1+q+q2)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q)2([a]q)2([c]q)2](μ≥σ5) |
where
σ5= (1+q)2([a]q)2([c]q)2(1−λ)(1+q+q2)([a]q)2 ([c]q)2 |
and all estimates are sharp.
We consider the Fekete-Szegö problem for the class Saq(γ,λ,t) with μ complex parameter.
Theorem 5. Let f∈Saq(γ,λ,t) be given by (1.1) and let μ be a complex number. Then,
|a3−μa22|≤2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2max{1,|2(1−λ)cosγ 1+q−t (μ(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2−t)−eiγ|}. | (4.15) |
The result is sharp.
Proof. Assume that f∈Saq(γ,λ,t). Making use of (4.10) and (4.11) we obtain
|a3−μa22|=2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2|w2−[2e−iγ(1−λ)cosγ 1+q−t (μ(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2−t)−1]w21| |
The inequality (4.15) follows as an application of Lemma 2 with
s=2e−iγ(1−λ)cosγ 1+q−t (μ(1+q+q2−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q−t)([a]q)2([c]q)2−t)−1. |
For t=1 in Theorem 5, we state the following corollary.
Corollary 8. Let f∈Saq(γ,λ) be given by (1.1) and let μ be a complex number. Then,
|a3−μa22|≤2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2q(1+q)([a]q)2max{1,|2(1−λ)cosγ q (μ(1+q)([a]q)2([c]q)2([a]q)2([c]q)2−1)−eiγ|}. |
The result is sharp.
Taking t=0 in Theorem 5, we state the next corollary.
Corollary 9. Let f∈Kaq(γ,λ) be given by (1.1) and let μ be a complex number. Then,
|a3−μa22|≤2(1−λ)cosγ([c]q)2(1+q+q2)([a]q)2max{1,|μ2(1−λ)cosγ(1+q+q2)([a]q)2([c]q)2(1+q)2([a]q)2([c]q)2−eiγ|}. |
The result is sharp.
Utilizing the concepts of quantum calculus, we defined new subclass of analytic functions associated with q-analogue of Carlson-Shaffer operator. For this subclass we investigated some useful results such as coefficient estimates, subordination properties and Fekete-Szegö problem. Their are some problems open for researchers such as distortion theorems, closure theorems, convolution propertiies and radii problems. Moreover, these results can be extended to multivalent functions and meromophic functions.
The authors are thankful to the referees for their valuable comments which helped in improving the paper.
The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
[1] |
Ajilore T, Ikhide S (2013) Monetary policy shocks, output and prices in South Africa: a test of policy irrelevance proposition. J Dev Areas 47: 363–386. https://doi.org/10.1353/jda.2013.0039 doi: 10.1353/jda.2013.0039
![]() |
[2] | Arestis P, Sawyer M (2003) Can Monetary Policy Affect The Real Economy? Levy Economics Institute https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.335620 |
[3] |
Aron J, Muellbauer J (2007) Review of Monetary Policy in South Africa since 1994. J Afr Econ 16: 705–744. https://doi.org/10.1093/jae/ejm013 doi: 10.1093/jae/ejm013
![]() |
[4] | Aslanidi, O (2007) The Optimal Monetary Policy and the Channels of Monetary Transmission Mech511 anism in CIS-7 Countries: The Case of Georgia. Available from: https://www.cerge-ei.cz/pdf/wbrf_papers/O_Aslanidi_WBRF_Paper.pdf. |
[5] |
Bernanke B, Gertler M (1995) Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission. J Econ Perspect 9: 27–48. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.9.4.27 doi: 10.1257/jep.9.4.27
![]() |
[6] |
Bernanke BS (1986) Alternative explanations of the money-income correlation. Carnegie-Rochester Confer Series on Public Policy 25: 49–99. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-2231(86)90037-0 doi: 10.1016/0167-2231(86)90037-0
![]() |
[7] | Blanchard O, Watson M (1984) Are Business Cycles All Alike? Nat Bur Econ Res. https://doi.org/10.3386/w1392 |
[8] |
Bonga-Bonga L (2010) Monetary Policy And Long-Term Interest Rates In South Africa. Int Bus Econ Res J 9: 43–54. https://doi.org/10.19030/iber.v9i10.638 doi: 10.19030/iber.v9i10.638
![]() |
[9] | Bonga-Bonga L, Kabundi A (2015) Monetary Policy Instrument and Inflation in South Africa: Structural Vector Error Correction Model Approach. Available from: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/63731/. |
[10] | Buigut S (2009) Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism: Implications for the Proposed East African. Available from: https://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.410.6867&rep=rep1&type=pdf. |
[11] |
Can U, Bocuoglu ME, Can ZG (2020) How does the monetary transmission mechanism work? Evidence from Turkey. Borsa Istanb Rev 20: 375–382. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bir.2020.05.004 doi: 10.1016/j.bir.2020.05.004
![]() |
[12] |
Cheng KC (2006) A VAR Analysis of Kenya's Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism: How Does the Central Bank's REPO Rate Affect the Economy? IMF Working Paper 2006: 1–26. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781451865608.001 doi: 10.5089/9781451865608.001
![]() |
[13] |
Chow GC, Lin AL (1971) Best Linear Unbiased Interpolation, Distribution, and Extrapolation of Time Series by Related Series. Rev Econ Stat 53: 372–375. https://doi.org/10.2307/1928739 doi: 10.2307/1928739
![]() |
[14] | Corden WM (1972) Monetary Integration, Essays in International Finance. Princeton University. |
[15] | Davoodi HR, Dixit S, Pinter G (2013) Monetary Transmission Mechanism in the East African Community: An Empirical Investigation. Available from: https://www.imf.org/en/publications. |
[16] |
Denton FT (1971) Adjustment of Monthly or Quarterly Series to Annual Totals: An Approach Based on Quadratic Minimization. J Am Stat Assoc 66: 99–102. https://doi.org/10.1080/01621459.1971.10482227 doi: 10.1080/01621459.1971.10482227
![]() |
[17] | Dlamini B, Skosana S (2017) Relationship and Causality between Interest Rates and Macroeconomic Variables in Swaziland. Central Bank of Swaziland Research Bulletin 1: 4–25. |
[18] |
Dodge D (2002) The interaction between monetary and fiscal policies. Can Public Pol 28: 187–202. https://doi.org/10.2307/3552324 doi: 10.2307/3552324
![]() |
[19] | Gumata N, Kabundi A, Ndou E (2013) Important channels of transmission monetary policy shock in South Africa. Econ Res Southern Africa. Available from: https://www.econrsa.org/system/files/publications. |
[20] | Herrera AM, Pesavento E (2013) Unit Roots, Cointegration and Pre-Testing in VAR Models. Adv Econom 32: 81–115. |
[21] | Ikhide S, Uanguta E (2010) Impact of South Africa's Monetary Policy on the LNS Economies. J Econ Integr 25: 324–352. |
[22] |
Iwata S, Wu S (2006) Estimating monetary policy effects when interest rates are close to zero. J Monetary Econ 53: 1395–1408. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.05.009 doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.05.009
![]() |
[23] |
Kabundi A, Ngwenya N (2011) Assessing monetary policy in South Africa in a data-rich environment. South Afr J Econ 79: 91–107. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1813-6982.2011.01265.x doi: 10.1111/j.1813-6982.2011.01265.x
![]() |
[24] | Karan A (2013) Quarterly Output Indicator Series for Fiji. Available from: https://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/downloaddoi=10.1.1.1049.3224&rep=rep1&type=pdf. |
[25] |
Kim S, Roubini N (2000) Exchange rate anomalies in the industrial countries: A solution with a structural VAR approach. J Monetary Econ 45: 561–586. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3932(00)00010-6 doi: 10.1016/S0304-3932(00)00010-6
![]() |
[26] |
Kunroo MH (2016) Theory of Optimum Currency Areas: A Literature Survey. Rev Mark Integr 7: 87–116. https://doi.org/10.1177/0974929216631381 doi: 10.1177/0974929216631381
![]() |
[27] |
Leeper EM, Sims CA, Zha T (1996) What Does Monetary Policy Do? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1996: 1–78. https://doi.org/10.2307/2534619 doi: 10.2307/2534619
![]() |
[28] |
Litterman RB (1983) A Random Walk, Markov Model for the Distribution of Time Series. J Bus Econ Stat 1: 169–173. https://doi.org/10.1177/0974929216631381 doi: 10.1177/0974929216631381
![]() |
[29] | Loayza N, Schmidt-Hebbel K (2002) Monetary Policy Functions and Transmission Mechanisms: An Overview. Monetary policy: Rules and transmission mechanisms 1: 1–20. |
[30] | Lütkepohl H, Krätzig M (2004) Applied time series econometrics. Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511606885 |
[31] | Maturu B, Ndirangu L (2010) Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism in Kenya: A Bayesian Vector Auto-regression (BVAR) Approach. Available from: https://www.centralbank.go.ke/images/docs/Research/Discussion-Papers/monetarypolicytransmissionmechanismkenya.pdf. |
[32] | Meyer D, De Jongh J, Van Wyngaard D (2018) An Assessment of the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy in South Africa. Acta Univ Danubius: Oeconomica 14: 281–295. https://doaj.org/article/37362829786d407bbf336c541d5fcb62 |
[33] |
Mishkin F (1995) Symposium on the Monetary Transmission Mechanism. J Econ Perspect 9: 3–10. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.9.4.3 doi: 10.1257/jep.9.4.3
![]() |
[34] | Mkhonta SF (2018) Discount Rate Differential Monetary Policy Decisions in the CMA and Portfolio Investment Assets: The Efficacy of Namibia and Swaziland Monetary Policy. Central Bank of Swaziland Research Bulletin 2: 16–23. |
[35] | Mosikari TJ, Eita JH(2018) Estimating threshold level of inflation in Swaziland: inflation and growth. MPRA. Available from: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/88728/. |
[36] | Mundell RA (1973) Uncommon Arguments for Common Currencies. In Johnson H, Swoboda A, The economics of common currencies (collected works of harry johnson), 1 Eds., London: Routledge, 114–132. https://doi.org/10.4324/9780203427477 |
[37] | Mundell RA (1961) The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas. Am Econ Rev 51: 657–665. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1812792 |
[38] | Ncube M, Ndou E(2013) Effects of Monetary Policy on Output. In Ncube M, Ndou E, In the Monetary policy and the economy of South Africa, London: Palgrave Macmillan, 9–24. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137334152 |
[39] | Peersman G, Smets F (2001) The monetary transmission mechanism in the euro area: more 564 evidence from VAR analysis. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.356269 |
[40] |
Rafiq MS, Mallick SK (2008) The effect of monetary policy on output in EMU3: A sign restriction approach. J Macroecon 30: 1756–1791. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2007.12.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2007.12.003
![]() |
[41] |
Sax C, Steiner P (2013) Temporal Disaggregation of Time Series. R J 5: 80–87. https://doi.org/10.32614/RJ-2013-028 doi: 10.32614/RJ-2013-028
![]() |
[42] | Seleteng M (2016) Effects of South African Monetary Policy Implementation on the CMA: A Panel Vector Autoregression Approach. Economic Research Southern Africa, 1–30. |
[43] | Seleteng M (2005) Inflation and Economic Growth: An estimate of an optimal level of inflation in Lesotho. Central Bank of Lesotho. |
[44] |
Sheefeni JPS, Ocran MK (2012) Monetary policy transmission in Namibia: A review of the interest rate channel. J Stud in Econ Econom 36: 47–63. https://doi.org/10.1080/10800379.2012.12097243 doi: 10.1080/10800379.2012.12097243
![]() |
[45] |
Smets F, Wouters R (2003) An Estimated Stochastic Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area. J Eur Econ Assoc 1: 1123–1175. https://doi.org/10.1162/154247603770383415 doi: 10.1162/154247603770383415
![]() |
[46] |
Tavlas GS (2009) The benefits and costs of monetary union in Southern Africa: A critical survey of the literature. J Econ Surv 23: 1–43. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.2008.00555.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6419.2008.00555.x
![]() |
[47] |
Taylor JB (1995) The Monetary Transmission Mechanism: An Empirical Framework. J Econ Perspect 9: 11–26. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.9.4.11 doi: 10.1257/jep.9.4.11
![]() |
[48] | Wang JY, Masha I, Shirono K, et al. (2007) The Common Monetary Area in Southern Africa: Shocks, Adjustment, and Policy Challenges. Available from: https://www.imf.org/en/publications. |
![]() |
![]() |
1. | K. R. Karthikeyan, G. Murugusundaramoorthy, Unified solution of initial coefficients and Fekete–Szegö problem for subclasses of analytic functions related to a conic region, 2022, 33, 1012-9405, 10.1007/s13370-022-00981-2 | |
2. | Abdel Fatah Azzam, Shujaat Ali Shah, Alhanouf Alburaikan, Sheza M. El-Deeb, Certain Inclusion Properties for the Class of q-Analogue of Fuzzy α-Convex Functions, 2023, 15, 2073-8994, 509, 10.3390/sym15020509 | |
3. | Rana Muhammad Zulqarnain, Wen Xiu Ma, Imran Siddique, Shahid Hussain Gurmani, Fahd Jarad, Muhammad Irfan Ahamad, Extension of aggregation operators to site selection for solid waste management under neutrosophic hypersoft set, 2023, 8, 2473-6988, 4168, 10.3934/math.2023208 | |
4. | A. Senguttuvan, D. Mohankumar, R. R. Ganapathy, K. R. Karthikeyan, Coefficient Inequalities of a Comprehensive Subclass of Analytic Functions With Respect to Symmetric Points, 2022, 16, 1823-8343, 437, 10.47836/mjms.16.3.03 | |
5. | K. R. Karthikeyan, G. Murugusundaramoorthy, S. D. Purohit, D. L. Suthar, Firdous A. Shah, Certain Class of Analytic Functions with respect to Symmetric Points Defined by Q-Calculus, 2021, 2021, 2314-4785, 1, 10.1155/2021/8298848 | |
6. | K. R. Karthikeyan, G. Murugusundaramoorthy, N. E. Cho, Some inequalities on Bazilevič class of functions involving quasi-subordination, 2021, 6, 2473-6988, 7111, 10.3934/math.2021417 | |
7. | Jamal Salah, Hameed Ur Rehman, Iman Al Buwaiqi, Ahmad Al Azab, Maryam Al Hashmi, Subclasses of spiral-like functions associated with the modified Caputo's derivative operator, 2023, 8, 2473-6988, 18474, 10.3934/math.2023939 | |
8. | Qiuxia Hu, Rizwan Salim Badar, Muhammad Ghaffar Khan, Subclasses of q-Uniformly Starlike Functions Obtained via the q-Carlson–Shaffer Operator, 2024, 13, 2075-1680, 842, 10.3390/axioms13120842 |