Loading [MathJax]/jax/output/SVG/jax.js
Perspective Special Issues

Study of the structure and mechanical properties of composites used in the oil and gas industry

  • This article describes the structure and properties of the developed hybrid composite Hastelloy X (NiCrFeMo)-AlMoNbTaTiZr-cBNSiCNiAlCo. The composite was obtained by the high velocity oxygen fuel spraying (HVOF) method in a protective atmosphere with a subsequent high-temperature thermomechanical treatment. In order to obtain new information about the structure, we studied the metallophysical properties of the composite using electron microscopy and X-ray diffraction analysis, as well as the mechanical properties and phase composition. We studied the influence of high-energy mechanical processing of high-entropic and ceramic materials on the structural-phase state and composite quality. We determined the optimal technological parameters of HVOF in a protective atmosphere, followed by a high-temperature thermomechanical treatment. Additionally, we optimized these parameters to form a hybrid composite providing the highest adhesion and low porosity. Moreover, we investigated the microhardness of the composite layers. On the basis of complex metallophysical studies, we examined the composite formation. In order to determine the endurance limit in comparison to various other composite materials, we carried out cyclic endurance tests of the developed materials.

    Citation: Peter Rusinov, Zhesfina Blednova, Anastasia Rusinova, George Kurapov, Maxim Semadeni. Study of the structure and mechanical properties of composites used in the oil and gas industry[J]. AIMS Materials Science, 2023, 10(4): 589-603. doi: 10.3934/matersci.2023033

    Related Papers:

    [1] Shuaikang Wang, Yunzhi Jiang, Yongbin Ge . High-order compact difference methods for solving two-dimensional nonlinear wave equations. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(6): 3145-3168. doi: 10.3934/era.2023159
    [2] Jinxiu Zhang, Xuehua Yang, Song Wang . The ADI difference and extrapolation scheme for high-dimensional variable coefficient evolution equations. Electronic Research Archive, 2025, 33(5): 3305-3327. doi: 10.3934/era.2025146
    [3] Jiangshan Wang, Lingxiong Meng, Hongen Jia . Numerical analysis of modular grad-div stability methods for the time-dependent Navier-Stokes/Darcy model. Electronic Research Archive, 2020, 28(3): 1191-1205. doi: 10.3934/era.2020065
    [4] Li Tian, Ziqiang Wang, Junying Cao . A high-order numerical scheme for right Caputo fractional differential equations with uniform accuracy. Electronic Research Archive, 2022, 30(10): 3825-3854. doi: 10.3934/era.2022195
    [5] Huanhuan Li, Lei Kang, Meng Li, Xianbing Luo, Shuwen Xiang . Hamiltonian conserved Crank-Nicolson schemes for a semi-linear wave equation based on the exponential scalar auxiliary variables approach. Electronic Research Archive, 2024, 32(7): 4433-4453. doi: 10.3934/era.2024200
    [6] Zhaoxiang Zhang, Xuehua Yang, Song Wang . The alternating direction implicit difference scheme and extrapolation method for a class of three dimensional hyperbolic equations with constant coefficients. Electronic Research Archive, 2025, 33(5): 3348-3377. doi: 10.3934/era.2025148
    [7] Yunxia Niu, Chaoran Qi, Yao Zhang, Wahidullah Niazi . Numerical analysis and simulation of the compact difference scheme for the pseudo-parabolic Burgers' equation. Electronic Research Archive, 2025, 33(3): 1763-1791. doi: 10.3934/era.2025080
    [8] Changling Xu, Tianliang Hou . Superclose analysis of a two-grid finite element scheme for semilinear parabolic integro-differential equations. Electronic Research Archive, 2020, 28(2): 897-910. doi: 10.3934/era.2020047
    [9] Cheng Wang . Convergence analysis of Fourier pseudo-spectral schemes for three-dimensional incompressible Navier-Stokes equations. Electronic Research Archive, 2021, 29(5): 2915-2944. doi: 10.3934/era.2021019
    [10] Xiu Ye, Shangyou Zhang, Peng Zhu . A weak Galerkin finite element method for nonlinear conservation laws. Electronic Research Archive, 2021, 29(1): 1897-1923. doi: 10.3934/era.2020097
  • This article describes the structure and properties of the developed hybrid composite Hastelloy X (NiCrFeMo)-AlMoNbTaTiZr-cBNSiCNiAlCo. The composite was obtained by the high velocity oxygen fuel spraying (HVOF) method in a protective atmosphere with a subsequent high-temperature thermomechanical treatment. In order to obtain new information about the structure, we studied the metallophysical properties of the composite using electron microscopy and X-ray diffraction analysis, as well as the mechanical properties and phase composition. We studied the influence of high-energy mechanical processing of high-entropic and ceramic materials on the structural-phase state and composite quality. We determined the optimal technological parameters of HVOF in a protective atmosphere, followed by a high-temperature thermomechanical treatment. Additionally, we optimized these parameters to form a hybrid composite providing the highest adhesion and low porosity. Moreover, we investigated the microhardness of the composite layers. On the basis of complex metallophysical studies, we examined the composite formation. In order to determine the endurance limit in comparison to various other composite materials, we carried out cyclic endurance tests of the developed materials.



    Dedicated to our friend Giuseppe Rosario Mingione, great mathematician and Master of Regularity, on the occasion of his 50th birthday.

    In this article, we introduce a family of games related to second-order partial differential equations (PDEs) given by arbitrary products of eigenvalues of the Hessian. More precisely, given ΩRN, and k indices i1,,ik{1,,N} (which could be repeated), we consider PDEs of the form

    {Pi1,...,ik(D2u):=kj=1λij(D2u)=f, in Ω,u=g, on Ω. (1.1)

    Here, λ1λN denote the eigenvalues of D2u and the right-hand side f is a continuous, non-negative function. Notice that operators given by Pi1,...,ik are degenerate and do not preserve order in the space of symmetric matrices, the usual condition for ellipticity. Moreover, we want to emphasize that the eigenvalues λi1,,λik in (1.1) could be repeated. For instance, one could take i1=i2=1 and i3=3 to produce the equation λ21λ3=f. Similarly, one could also take k=N and ij=j and consider the product of all the eigenvalues, which corresponds to the classical Monge-Ampère equation, det(D2u)=Ni=1λi=f. We refer the reader to [11,13] for general references on the Monge-Ampère equation.

    Our main goal is to design a game whose value functions approximate viscosity solutions to (1.1) as a parameter that controls the step size of the game goes to zero. The connection between games and PDEs has developed significantly over the last decade; see [10,16,19,20,21,24,25] (and we refer also to [12] in connection with mean-field games). We also refer to the recent books [6,15] and the references therein for general references on this program. The relation between games and PDEs has proven fruitful in obtaining qualitative results, see [4], and regularity estimates; see [1,18,23,27]. A game-theoretical interpretation is available in the case of Hamilton-Jacobi equations in the presence of gradient constraints (both in the convex and non-convex settings), see [28]. The case k=1 for the smallest eigenvalue λ1 gives rise to the Dirichlet problem for the convex envelop studied in [22] and it is also related to the truncated Laplacians considered in [2].

    Our starting point is the case of only one eigenvalue and f=0, which was recently tackled in [5] and has connections with convexity theory. Let us describe the two-player, zero-sum game called "a random walk for λj" introduced there. Given a domain ΩRN, ε>0, and a final payoff function g:RNΩR, the game is played as follows. The game starts with a token at an initial position x0Ω. Player Ⅰ (who wants to minimize the expected payoff) chooses a subspace S of dimension j, and then Player Ⅱ (who wants to maximize the expected payoff) chooses a unitary vector vS. Then, the token moves to x±εv with equal probabilities. The game continues until the token leaves the domain at a point xτ, and the first player gets g(xτ) while the second receives g(xτ) (we can think that Player Ⅰ pays the amount g(xτ) to Player Ⅱ). This game has a value function uε (see below for the precise definition) defined in Ω, which depends on the step size ε. One of the main results in [5] is showing that, under an appropriate condition on Ω, these value functions converge uniformly in ¯Ω to a continuous limit u characterized as the unique viscosity solution to

    {Pj(D2u)=λj(D2u)=0, in Ω,u=g, on Ω. (1.2)

    The right-hand side f is obtained by considering a running payoff, that is, a nonnegative function f:ΩR such that 12ε2f(xn) represents an amount paid by Player Ⅱ to Player Ⅰ when the token reaches xn. Then, the game value approximates viscosity solutions to

    {Pj(D2u)=λj(D2u)=f, in Ω,u=g, on Ω. (1.3)

    Now, we introduce a new game that allows us to obtain a product of eigenvalues. Assume a list of eigenvalues (λij)j=1,,k is given. We consider the set

    Ikε={(αj)j=1,,kRk:kj=1αj=1 and 0<αj<ϕ2(ε)}, (1.4)

    where ϕ(ε) is a positive function such that

    limε0ϕ(ε)=andlimε0εϕ(ε)=0 (1.5)

    (for example one can take ϕ(ε)=ε1/2). At every round, Player Ⅰ chooses k positive real numbers (αj)j=1,,kIkε, after which, an index j{1,,k} is selected uniformly at random. Then, the players play a round of the game "a random walk for λij" described above. Specifically, Player Ⅰ chooses a subspace S of dimension ij, Player Ⅱ chooses a unitary vector vS, and the token is moved to x±εαjv with equal probabilities. The running payoff at every round is given by 12ε2[f(xn)]1k (Player Ⅱ pays this ammount to Player Ⅰ) and the final payoff is given by g (if xτ denotes the first position outside Ω, the game ends and Player Ⅰ pays g(xτ) to Player Ⅱ).

    Notice that in this game we adjust the length of the token jump according to the corresponding αj, and Player Ⅰ may choose to enlarge the game steps associated with λi at the expense of shortening others (since the product of the αj must equal one). Also notice that the restriction ϕ(ε)>αj>0 implies that the maximum step size is bounded as |x(x±εαjv)|<εϕ(ε)0 as ε0.

    When both players fix their strategies, SI for the first player (a choice of (αj)j=1,,k and ijdimensional subspaces S at every step of the game), and SII for the second player (a choice of a unitary vector v in each possible subspace at every step of the game), then we can compute the expected outcome (the amount that Player Ⅱ receives) as

    Ex0SI,SII[g(xτ)12ε2τ1n=0[f(xn)]1k].

    Then, the value for Player Ⅰ of the game starting at any given x0Ω is defined as

    uεI(x0)=infSIsupSIIEx0SI,SII[g(xτ)12ε2τ1n=0[f(xn)]1k],

    while the value for Player Ⅱ is

    uεII(x0)=supSIIinfSIEx0SI,SII[g(xτ)12ε2τ1n=0[f(xn)]1k].

    When these two values coincide we say that the game has a value.

    In our first result, we state that this game has a value and the value verifies an equation in Ω, called a Dynamic Programming Principle (DPP) in the literature.

    Theorem 1. The game has a value

    uε:=uεI=uεII,

    which is characterized as the unique solution to

    {uε(x)=infαjIkε1kkj=1infdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1{12uε(x+εαjv)+12uε(xεαjv)}12ε2[f(x)]1kxΩ,uε(x)=g(x)xΩ. (1.6)

    Let us show intuitively why this holds. At each step, Player Ⅰ chooses (αj)j=1,,k, and then j{1,,k} is selected with probability 1k. Player Ⅰ chooses a subspace S of dimension ij and then Player Ⅱ chooses one unitary vector, v, in the subspace S. The token is then moved with probability 12 to x+εαjv or xεαjv. Finally, the expected payoff at x is given by 12ε2[f(x)]1k (the running payoff) plus the expected payoff for the rest of the game. Then, the equation in (1.6) follows by considering all the possibilities (recall that Player Ⅰ seeks to minimize the expected payoff and Player Ⅱ to minimize it).

    Our next goal is to look for the limit as ε0.

    Theorem 2. Assume that Ω is strictly convex. Let uε be the values of the game. We have

    uεuasε0

    uniformly in ¯Ω, where u is the unique viscosity solution to (1.1).

    We devote Section 3 to proving the theorems. The uniqueness statement in Theorem 2 follows from [8]; see Remark 2.2 below. We need the convexity of Ω to prove that the sequence converges by means of an Arzelà-Ascoli type lemma. In fact, for strictly convex domains, we show that for every point yΩ, a game that starts near y ends nearby with a high probability regardless of the players' strategies. This allows us to obtain a sort of asymptotic equicontinuity near the boundary, which leads to uniform convergence in the whole ¯Ω. Note that, in general, the value functions uε are discontinuous in Ω since we take discrete steps.

    Observe that the result implies the existence of a solution to the PDE. The strict convexity of Ω is needed if a solution to the equation λ1=0 is to exist for every continuous boundary data; see [5]. Since our general setting includes this case, we require the strict convexity. However, in some cases, such as λ2=0, this hypothesis may be relaxed; see [5].

    Let us see intuitively why u is a solution to Eq (1.1). By subtracting uε(x) and dividing by ε2 on both sides we get the term:

    uε(x+εαjv)2uε(x)+uε(xεαjv)ε2

    which in the limit approximates the second derivative of u in the direction of v multiplied by αj. Hence, by the Courant-Fischer min-max principle, the expression

    infdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1uε(x+εαjv)2uε(x)+uε(xεαjv)ε2

    approximates the ij eigenvalue of D2u(x) multiplied by αj. Taking into account the running payoff, we obtain that u is a solution to

    [f(x)]1k=infαjIkε1kkj=1αjλij.

    Then, the result follows from the identity

    (β1β2βk)1k=infαj>0,kj=1αj=11kkj=1αjβjwhenever β1,β2,,βk0,

    which is proved in detail in Lemma 2.4 below.

    The Monge-Ampère equation. Notice that when all the eigenvalues are involved, we have a two-player game that approximates solutions to the Monge-Ampère equation det(D2u)=f. However, in the special case of the Monge-Ampère equation, we can also design a one-player game (a control problem) to approximate the solutions. This game is based on a recent asymptotic mean value formula that characterizes viscosity solutions to the Monge-Ampère equation. In fact, in [3], it is proved that u is a viscosity solution to the Monge-Ampère equation

    det(D2u(x))=f(x)

    if and only if

    u(x)=infVO infαiINε{1NNi=112u(x+εαivi)+12u(xεαivi)}ε22[f(x)]1n+o(ε2)

    as ε0, holds in the viscosity sense. Here we denoted by O the set of all orthonormal bases V={v1,,vN} of Rn, and INε is given by (1.4).

    Now, let us describe a one-player game (control problem). At each play, the player (controller), who aims to minimize the expected total payoff, chooses an orthonormal basis V=(v1,...,vN) and coefficients (αi)i=1,,NINε. Then, the new position of the game goes to x±εαivi with equal probability 1/(2N). In addition, there is a running payoff given by ε22[f(x)]1N at every play and a final payoff g(x) (as before the game ends when the token leaves Ω). Then, the value of the game for any x0Ω for is given by

    uε(x0)=infSIEx0SI[g(xτ)12ε2τ1i=0[f(xi)]1N].

    Here, we take the infimum over all the possible player strategies.

    For this game we have the following result.

    Theorem 3. The game value uε is the unique solution to

    {uε(x)=infVO infαiINε{1NNi=112uε(x+εαivi)+12uε(xεαivi)}12ε2[f(x)]1NxΩ,uε(x)=g(x)xΩ.

    Moreover, if we assume that Ω is strictly convex. Then,

    uεu,asε0,

    uniformly in ¯Ω, where u is the unique viscosity solution to

    {det(D2u)=Ni=1λi(D2u)=f,inΩ,u=g,onΩ. (1.7)

    Notice that here the strict convexity of the domain is a natural assumption for the solvability of (1.7); see [7,26].

    The paper is organized as follows: in Section 2, we collect some preliminary results and include the definition of viscosity solutions. In Section 3, we prove our main results concerning the two-player game, Theorems 1 and 2. In Section 4, we include some details for the control problem for Monge-Ampère. Finally, in Section 5, we present a variant of the game for Monge-Ampère that involves an integral average in the corresponding DPP.

    We begin by stating the definition of a viscosity solution to (1.1). Recall that f:ΩR is a non-negative function. Following [8] (see also [14]), we have that the equation is associated with the cone

    F={M:kj=1λij(M)f and λij(M)0 for every j=1,,k}.

    Here we do not state the definition of viscosity solutions with an explicit reference to the cone, but we prefer to present it using the usual notation; see [9].

    We say that P is a paraboloid if for every x,x0RN we have

    P(x)=P(x0)+xx0,P(x0)+12D2P(x0)(xx0),xx0.

    Definition 4. A continuous function u verifies

    kj=1λij(D2u)=f

    in Ω in the viscosity sense if

    1) for every paraboloid ϕ that touches u from below at x0Ω (ϕ(x0)=u(x0) and ϕu), and with eigenvalues of the Hessian that verify λij(D2ϕ(x0))0, we have

    kj=1λij(D2ϕ(x))f(x).

    2) for every paraboloid ψ that touches u from above at x0Ω (ψ(x0)=u(x0) and ψu), we have λij(D2ψ(x0))0 for j=1,,k and

    kj=1λij(D2ψ(x))f(x).

    Remark 5. The validity of the comparison principle for our equation follows from Theorem 4.9 in [8]. In fact, the map Θ:ΩSN×N given by

    Θ(x)={M:kj=1λij(M)f(x) and λij(M)0 for every j=1,,k}

    is uniformly upper semicontinuous (since f is continuous) and is elliptic (since the operator is monotone on non negative matrices and f0).

    Also observe that the concept of Θ-subharmonic/superharmonic is equivalent to the definition of subsolution/supersolution that we have given. In fact, if we consider

    Φ={M:λij(M)0 for every j=1,,k}

    Then, we have

    Θ(x)={MΦ:F(M,x)0}

    where F is the operator that we are considering here, that is,

    F(M,x)=kj=1λij(M)f(x).

    Therefore, the equivalence between being Θ-subharmonic/superharmonic and being subsolution/supersolution follows from Proposition 2.11 in [8].

    To obtain a convergent subsequence uεu we will require Ω to be strictly convex. Here this means that we have that for every x,y¯Ω, tx+(1t)yΩ for all 0<t<1. In particular, in Lemma 3.6 we will use a geometric condition over Ω equivalent to the strict convexity. We prove the equivalence between these two notions of strict convexity in the following lemma which is a variation of the classical supporting hyperplane theorem.

    Lemma 6. Given an open non-empty bounded set ΩRN, the following statements are equivalent:

    1) Ω is strictly convex (i.e., for every x,y¯Ω, tx+(1t)yΩ for all 0<t<1).

    2) Given yΩ there exists wRN of norm 1 such that w,xy>0 for every x¯Ω{y}.

    3) Given yΩ there exists wRN of norm 1 such that for every δ>0 there exists θ>0 such that

    {xΩ:w,xy<θ}Bδ(y).

    Moreover, the vector w in statements (2) and (3) is the same one.

    Proof. (1) (2): We consider ykRN¯Ω such that yky and zk the projection of xk over ¯Ω (which exists since Ω is convex). We define the vectors

    wk=zkykzkyk.

    Up to a subsequence, we may assume that wkwRN. We have that

    zkyk,xzk0

    for every x¯Ω. Hence, for every x¯Ω, we have

    wk,xwk,zk=wk,zkyk+wk,yk>wk,yk.

    Passing to the limit we get

    w,xy0

    for every x¯Ω.

    It remains to prove that w,xy0 when xy. Suppose, for the sake of contradiction, that w,xy=0 for some xy. By the strict convexity of Ω, we have x+y2Ω. Hence, x+y2εwΩ for ε small enough and

    w,(x+y2εw)y=w,xy2εw=ε<0,

    a contradiction.

    (2) (3): Given δ, we consider f:¯ΩBδ(y)R given by

    f(x)=w,xy.

    Since f is continuous and is defined in a compact set it attains its minimum. We consider θ=min¯ΩBδ(y)f which is positive since w,xy>0 for every x¯Ω{y}. We have that w,xyθ for every x¯ΩBδ(y), and the result follows.

    (3) (2): Given x¯Ω{y} we consider δ=dist(x,y)2>0 and xkΩBδ(x) such that xkx. Since xkBδ(y), we have w,xkyθ. Hence w,xyθ>0.

    (2) (1): We consider the set

    C=yΩ{xRn:wy,xy0}

    where wy stands for the w given by statement (2) for each yΩ. Since C is the intersection of convex sets, it is also convex. We want to prove that ¯Ω is convex by proving that it is equal to C. It is clear that ¯ΩC, let us show that if z¯Ω then zC. We fix x0Ω. Given z¯Ω, there exists t(0,1) such that y=tz+(1t)x0Ω. We know that wy,x0y>0 since x0Ω. Hence wy,zy<0 and zC.

    It remains to prove that the convexity is strict. Given x,y¯Ω, we know that

    tx+(1t)y¯Ω

    for all 0<t<1. We want to prove that tx+(1t)yΩ, that is, tx+(1t)yΩ. Suppose, arguing again by contradiction, that z=tx+(1t)yΩ for some 0<t<1. Then, wz,xz>0 and wz,yz>0, and this implies that 0<wz,(tx+(1t)y)z=0, which is a contradiction.

    The idea that allows us to obtain the product of the eigenvalues relies on the following formula.

    Lemma 7. Given β1,β2,,βk0, we have

    (β1β2βk)1k=infαj>0,kj=1αj=11kkj=1αjβj.

    Proof. The inequality

    (β1β2βk)1kinfαj>0,kj=1αj=11kkj=1αjβj.

    follows from the arithmetic-geometric mean inequality.

    In the case that all the βi are strictly positive, the equality is attained for

    αi=(β1β2βk)1kβi.

    In the case that βi=0 for some i we have to show that the infimum is zero. For that, we consider αi=nk1 and αj=1n, which gives

    limn1kkj=1αjβj=βi=0

    as desired.

    Let us recall that in our setting we have the extra restriction αi<ϕ2(ε). To handle this issue we require the following two lemmas.

    Lemma 8. Given β1,β2,,βk0, it holds

    (β1β2βk)1k=limε0infαjIkε1kkj=1αjβj,

    where Ikε is given by (1.4).

    Proof. If β1,β2,,βk>0, for ε small enough such that

    ϕ2(ε)>(β1β2βk)1kβi

    for all i, we have

    infαjIkε1kkj=1αjβj=(β1β2βk)1k,

    and the result follows.

    Now we consider the case where βi=0 for some i=1,,k and k>1 (if k=1 the result is obvious). We take

    αi=ϕ(ε)2 and αj=(2ϕ(ε))1k1.

    for ji. We have

    infαjIkε1kkj=1αjβj1kji(2ϕ(ε))1k1βj.

    By taking limit as ε0 we conclude the proof.

    Lemma 9. Given β1,β2,,βkR with βi<0 for some i=1,,k, it holds

    limε0infαjIkε1kkj=1αjβj<0.

    Proof. If k=1 we have

    limε0infαjIkε1kkj=1αjβj=β1<0.

    If k>1, we take

    αi=ϕ(ε)2 and αj=(2ϕ(ε))1k1

    and in the limit we get .

    In this section, we describe in detail the two-player zero-sum game presented in the introduction. Let ΩRN be a bounded open set and fix ε>0. The values k and (ij)j=1,,k are given along with a positive function ϕ(ε) such that

    limε0ϕ(ε)=andlimε0εϕ(ε)=0.

    A token is placed at x0Ω and the game begins with Player Ⅰ choosing (αj)j=1,,kIkε where

    Ikε={(αj)j=1,,kRk:kj=1αj=1 and 0<αj<ϕ2(ε)}.

    Then, j{1,,k} is selected uniformly at random. Given the value of j, Player Ⅰ chooses a subspace S of dimension ij and then Player Ⅱ chooses one unitary vector vS. Then, the token is moved to x±εαjv with equal probabilities. After the first round, the game continues from x1 according to the same rules.

    This procedure yields a possibly infinite sequence of game states x0,x1, where every xk is a random variable. The game ends when the token leaves Ω. At this point the token will be in the boundary strip of width εϕ(ε) given by

    Γεϕ(ε)={xRNΩ:dist(x,Ω)εϕ(ε)}.

    We denote by xτΓεϕ(ε) the first point in the sequence of game states that lies in Γεϕ(ε). In other words, τ is the first time we hit Γεϕ(ε) (τ is a stopping time for this game). The payoff is determined by two given functions: g:RNΩR, the final payoff function, and f:ΩR, the running payoff function. We require g to be continuous, f uniformly continuous and both bounded functions. When the game ends, the total payoff is given by

    g(xτ)12ε2τ1l=0[f(xl)]1k.

    Player Ⅱ earns this amount and Player Ⅰ loses it (Player Ⅰ earns g(xτ)+12ε2τ1l=0[f(xl)]1k).

    A strategy SI for Player Ⅰ is a function defined on the partial histories that gives the values of αj at every step of the game

    SI(x0,x1,,xn)=(αj)j=1,,kIkε

    and that for a given value of j returns a ijdimensional subspace S

    SI(x0,x1,,xn,j)=S.

    We call SI both functions to avoid overloading the notation. A strategy SII for Player Ⅱ is a function defined on the partial histories that gives a unitary vector in a prescribed subspace S at every step of the game

    SII(x0,x1,,xn,S,αj)=vS.

    When the two players fix their strategies SI and SII we can compute the expected outcome as follows: Given the sequence x0,,xn with xjΩ the next game position is distributed according to the probability

    πSI,SII(x0,,xn,A)=12kkj=1δxn+εαjv(A)+δxnεαjv(A).

    where

    (αj)j=1,,k=SI(x0,x1,,xn)

    and

    v=SII(x0,,xn,SI(x0,,xn,j),αj).

    By using the Kolmogorov's extension theorem and the one-step transition probabilities, we can build a probability measure Px0SI,SII on the game sequences H. We denote by Ex0SI,SII the corresponding expectation. Then, when starting from x0 and using the strategies SI,SII, the expected payoff is

    Ex0SI,SII[g(xτ)12ε2τ1l=0[f(xl)]1k]. (3.1)

    The value of the game for Player I is given by

    uεI(x0)=infSIsupSIIEx0SI,SII[g(xτ)12ε2τ1l=0[f(xl)]1k],

    while the value of the game for Player II is given by

    uεII(x0)=supSIIinfSIEx0SI,SII[g(xτ)12ε2τ1l=0[f(xl)]1k].

    Intuitively, the values uεI(x0) and uεII(x0) are the best expected outcomes each player can guarantee when the game starts at x0. If uεI=uεII, we say that the game has a value and we denote it by uε:=uεI=uεII.

    Let us observe that the game ends almost surely, and therefore the expectation (3.1) is well defined. Let us be more precise at this point. If we consider the square of the distance to x0, at every step, this quantity increases by at least ε2 with probability 12k (a value of j such that αj1 is selected with probability at least 1k and given a direction v at least one of the vectors xn±εαjv is at least at a distance ε2 greater that the distance from xn to the initial point). As the distance to x0 is bounded (since we assumed that Ω is bounded), with a positive probability the game ends after a finite number of steps. Iterating this argument we get that the game ends almost surely. See Lemma 13 for details concerning this argument.

    To see that the game has a value, we first observe that we have existence of uε, a function that satisfies the DPP. The existence of such a function can be seen by Perron's method. In fact, the operator given by the right-hand side of the DPP, that is,

    uinfαjIkε1kkj=1infdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1{12u(x+εαjv)+12u(xεαjv)}12ε2[f(x)]1k,

    is in the hypotheses of the main result of [17].

    Now, concerning the value functions of our game, we know that uεIuεII (this is immediate from their definition). Hence, to obtain the desired result, it is enough to show that uεuεI and uεIIuε.

    Given η>0 we can consider the strategy S0II for Player Ⅱ that at every step almost maximize u(x+εαjv)+u(xεαjv), that is

    S0II(x0,x1,,xn,S,αj)=wS

    such that

    {12uε(x+εαjw)+12uε(xεαjw)}supvS,|v|=1{12uε(x+εαjv)+12uε(xεαjv)}η2(k+1).

    We have

    Ex0SI,S0II[uε(xk+1)+ε2kn=0f(xn)η2(k+1)|x0,,xk]infαjIkε1kkj=1infdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1{12u(x+εαjv)+12u(xεαjv)}η2(k+1)+12ε2kn=0f(xn)η2(k+1)uε(xk)12ε2f(xk)+12ε2kn=0f(xn)η2kuε(xk)+12ε2k1n=0f(xn)η2k,

    where we have estimated the strategy of Player Ⅰ by inf and used the DPP. Then,

    Mk=uε(xk)+12ε2k1n=0f(xn)η2k

    is a submartingale.

    Now, we have

    uεII(x0)=supSIIinfSIEx0SI,SII[g(xτ)+12ε2τ1n=0f(xn)]infSIEx0SI,S0II[g(xτ)+12ε2τ1n=0f(xn)η2τ]infSIlim infkEx0SI,S0II[Mτk]infSIEx0SI,S0II[M0]=uε(x0)η,

    where τk=min(τ,k), and we used the optional stopping theorem for Mk. Since η is arbitrary this proves that uεIIuε. An analogous strategy can be considered for Player Ⅰ to prove that uεuεI.

    Given a solution to the DPP we have proved that it coincides with the game value. Then, the game value satisfies the DPP and, even more, any solution coincides with it. Uniqueness follows. We have proved Theorem 1.

    Remark 10. From our argument it can be deduced that

    uε(x0)=supSIIinfSIEx0SI,SII[uε(x˜τ)+12ε2˜τ1n=0f(xn)]

    for any stopping time ˜ττ. That is, as long as the game has not ended we can separate the payoff as the cumulative amount payed during the game, 12ε2τ1n=0f(xn) and the expected one for the rest of the game, uε(x˜τ).

    Remark 11. We have a comparison principle for solutions to the DPP. Assume that f1f2 and that g1g2 then the corresponding solutions verify

    uε1uε2

    in Ω. In terms of the game this is quite intuitive since playing with g1 and f1 the palyers have a larger final payoff and a smaller running playoff than playing with g2 and f2.

    Now our aim is to pass to the limit in the values of the game. We aim to prove that, along a subsequence,

    uεu,as ε0

    uniformly in ¯Ω and then obtain in this limit process a viscosity solution to (1.1).

    To obtain a convergent subsequence uεu we will use the following Arzela-Ascoli type lemma. For its proof see Lemma 4.2 from [21].

    Lemma 12. Let {uε:¯ΩR, ε>0} be a set of functions such that

    1) there exists C>0 such that |uε(x)|<C for every ε>0 and every x¯Ω,

    2) given η>0 there are constants r0 and ε0 such that for every ε<ε0 and any x,y¯Ω with |xy|<r0 it holds

    |uε(x)uε(y)|<η.

    Then, there exists a uniformly continuous function u:¯ΩR and a subsequence still denoted by {uε} such that

    uεuuniformlyin¯Ω,

    as ε0.

    Our task now is to show that the family uε satisfies the hypotheses of the previous lemma.

    Lemma 13. There exists C=C(Ω)>0 such that

    Ex0SI,SII[τ]Cε2.

    for every ε>0, SI, SII and x0Ω.

    Proof. Here we write E for Ex0SI,SII. We consider R>0 such that ΩBR(0) and Mn=xn2. Given that the token lies at xn, we have that

    E[Mn+1|xn]=12kkj=1xn+εαjvj2+xnεαjvj2=1kkj=1xn2+ε2αjvj2=xn2+ε21kkj=1αjxn2+ε2kj=1αj=xn2+ε2=Mn+ε2,

    where vj stands for the selected unitary vector when that value of j is chosen.

    We have obtained

    E[Mn+1|Mn]Mn+ε2.

    Hence,

    Mnnε2

    is a submartingale. According to the optional stopping theorem for submartingales

    E[Mτn(τn)ε2]M0.

    Therefore

    E[τn]ε2E[Mτn]M0E[Mτn]R2.

    By taking limit in n, we obtain a bound for the expected exit time,

    E[τ]R2ε2,

    as desired.

    Corollary 14. There exists C=C(Ω,f,g)>0 such that |uε(x)|<C for every ε>0 and every x¯Ω.

    Proof. Since Ex0SI,SII[τ]Cε2, we have

    |uε(x0)|supSIIinfSIEx0SI,SII[|g(xτ)|+12ε2τ1n=0|f(xn)|]maxg+Cmaxf.

    To prove that uε satisfies the second hypothesis we will make the following geometric assumption on the domain. Given yΩ we assume that for every δ>0 there exists wRN of norm 1 and θ>0 such that

    {xΩ:w,xy<θ}Bδ(y). (3.2)

    This condition is equivalent to Ω being strictly convex as proved in Section 2.

    Lemma 15. Given η>0 there are constants r0 and ε0 such that for every ε<ε0 and any x,y¯Ω with |xy|<r0 it holds

    |uε(x)uε(y)|<η.

    Proof. The case x,yΓεϕ(ε) follows from the uniform continuity of g in Γεϕ(ε). Since the rules of the game do not depend on the point, the case x,yΩ follows from the case xΩ and yΓεϕ(ε). The argument is as follows. Suppose that we want to prove that uε(x)uε(y)<η, that is

    supSIIinfSIExSI,SII[g(xτ)+12ε2τ1n=0f(xn)]sup˜SIIinf˜SIEy˜SI,˜SII[g(yτ)+12ε2τ1n=0f(yn)]<η.

    Then, it is enough to show that given S0II and ˜S0I (strategies for Player Ⅱ in the game starting at x and for Player Ⅰ in the game starting at y, respectively) there exists ˜S0II and S0I such that

    ExS0I,S0II[g(xτ)+12ε2τ1n=0f(xn)]Ey˜S0I,˜S0II[g(yτ)+12ε2τ1n=0f(yn)]<η.

    We consider the strategies ˜S0II and S0I that mimic S0II and ˜S0I, that is

    ˜S0II(y,y1,,yn)=S0II(x,y1y+x,,yny+x)

    and

    S0I(x,x1,,xn)=˜S0II(y,x1x+y,,xnx+y).

    Even more, we couple the random steps, then we have that when the token lies at xn, in the other games it lies at yn=xnx+y. We call E the common expectation of the coupled processes. We proceed in this way until one of the games ends, at time ˜τ, that is for the first time xnΓεϕ(ε) or ynΓεϕ(ε). By Remark 10 it is enough to show that

    E[uε(x˜τ)uε(y˜τ)+12ε2˜τ1n=0(f(xn)f(yn))]<η.

    At every point we have |xlyl|=|xy|, and the desired estimate follow from the one for xnΩ, ynΓεϕ(ε) or for xn,ynΓεϕ(ε) together with the uniform continuity of f and the bound for the exit time obtained in Lemma 13.

    Now, we can concentrate on the case xΩ and yΓεϕ(ε). Due to the uniform continuity of g in Γεϕ(ε), we can assume that yΩ. In fact, if we have the bound valid for points on the boundary we can obtain a bound for a generic point yΓεϕ(ε) just by considering zΩ in the line segment between x and y and using the triangular inequality.

    In this case we have

    uε(y)=g(y),

    and we need to obtain a bound for uε(x). We observe that, for any possible strategy of the players (for any possible choice of the direction v at every point) we have that the projection of xn in the direction of the a fixed vector w of norm 1,

    xny,w

    is a martingale. We fix an arbitrary pair of strategies SI and SII, we denote by P=PxSI,SII the corresponding probability playing with these strategies and E=ExSI,SII the corresponding expectation. We take δ>0 and consider xτ, the first time x leaves Ω or Bδ(y). Hence, we have

    Exτy,wxy,wd(x,y)<r0.

    From the geometric assumption on Ω, by choosing w as in Lemma 6, we have that

    xny,wϕ(ε)ε

    because at every step the token moves at most αiεϕ(ε)ε. Therefore, we obtain

    P(xτy,w>r1/20)r1/20(1P(xτy,w>r1/20))ϕ(ε)ε<r0.

    Then, we take ε0>0 such that ϕ(ε)εr0 for every ε<ε0 and we get

    P(xτy,w>r1/20)<2r1/20.

    We consider the corresponding θ such that (3.2) holds, this implies

    {dist(xτ,y)>δ}{xτy,w>θ}

    and hence, for r1/20<θ, we can conclude that

    P(d(xτ,y)>δ)<2r1/20.

    Repeating the argument in Lemma 13 for Mn=xny2 we can show that

    E[τ]δ2ε2.

    Therefore,

    |uε(x)g(y)|E[|g(xτ)g(y)||d(xτ,y)δ]P(d(xτ,y)δ)+P(d(xτ,y)>δ)(2maxg+δ2maxf)supxBδ(y)|g(x)g(y)|+2r1/20(2maxg+δ2maxf)<η

    if r0 and δ are small enough.

    From Corollary 14 and Lemma 15 we have that the hypotheses of the Arzela-Ascoli type lemma, Lemma 12, are satisfied. Hence we have obtained uniform convergence of uε along a subsequence.

    Corollary 16. Let uε be the values of the game. Then, along a subsequence,

    uεu,asε0,

    uniformly in ¯Ω.

    Now, we prove that the uniform limit of uε is a viscosity solution to the limit PDE problem.

    Theorem 17. The uniform limit of the game values uε, denoted by u, is a viscosity solution to

    {kj=1λij(D2u)=f,inΩ,u=g,onΩ. (3.3)

    Proof. First, we observe that since uε=g on Ω it is immediate, form the uniform convergence, that u=g on Ω. Also, notice that Lemma 12 gives that a uniform limit of uε is a continuous function.

    To check that u is a viscosity supersolution to kj=1λij(D2u)=f in Ω, let φ be a paraboloid that touches u from below at xΩ, and with eigenvalues of the Hessian that verify λij(D2φ(x))>0. We need to check that

    kj=1λij(D2φ(x))f(x)0.

    As uεu uniformly in ¯Ω we have the existence of a sequence xε such that xεx as ε0 and

    uε(z)φ(z)uε(xε)φ(xε)ε3

    (notice that uε is not continuous in general). As uε is a solution to (1.6),

    uε(x)=infαjIkε1kkj=1infdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1{12uε(x+εαjv)+12uε(xεαjv)}ε22[f(x)]1k

    we obtain

    0infαjIkε1kkj=1infdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1{12φ(xε+εαjv)+12φ(xεεαjv)φ(xε)}ε22[f(xε)]1kε3.

    Now, using the second-order Taylor expansion of φ,

    φ(y)=φ(x)+φ(x)(yx)+12D2φ(x)(yx),(yx)

    we get

    φ(xε+εαjv)=φ(xε)+εαjφ(xε)v+ε2αj12D2φ(xε)v,v (3.4)

    and

    φ(xεεαjv)=φ(xε)εαjφ(xε)v+ε2αj12D2φ(xε)v,v. (3.5)

    Therefore,

    0infαjIkε1kkj=1infdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1ε22αjD2φ(xε)v,v12ε2[f(xε)]1kε3.

    Dividing by ε22 we get

    [f(xε)]1kinfαjIkε1kkj=1αjinfdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1D2φ(xε)v,v2ε.

    We have

    infdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1D2φ(xε)v,v=λj(D2φ(xε))

    by the Courant-Fischer min-max principle. Even more, since D2φ(xε)=D2φ(x), we have λj(D2φ(xε))=λj(D2φ(x)). Hence, we conclude that

    [f(xε)]1kinfαjIkε1kkj=1αjλj(D2φ(x))+o(1).

    Using Lemma 8 to pass to the limit as ε0 we get

    [f(x)]1k(kj=1λij(D2φ(x)))1k,

    that is,

    kj=1λij(D2φ(x))f(x).

    Now, to check that u is a viscosity subsolution to kj=1λij(D2u)=f in Ω, let ψ be a paraboloid that touches u from above at xΩ. We want to see that λij(D2ψ(x))0 for every j=1,,k and

    kj=1λij(D2ψ(x))f(x)0.

    As uεu uniformly in ¯Ω we have the existence of a sequence xε such that xεx as ε0 and

    uε(z)ψ(z)uε(xε)ψ(xε)ε3

    (notice that uε is not continuous in general). Arguing as before we obtain

    0infαjIkε1kkj=1infdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1{12ψ(xε+εαjv)+12ψ(xεεαjv)ψ(xε)}12ε2[f(xε)]1kε3.

    Using a Taylor expansions we arrive to

    12ε2[f(xε)]1kinfαjIkε1kkj=1infdim(S)=ijsupvS,|v|=1ε22αjD2ψ(xε)v,vε3=ε22infαjIkε1kkj=1αjλij(D2ψ(x))ε3.

    Since f0 by Lemma 9 we get that λij(D2ψ(x))0. Dividing by ε22 and using Lemma 8 as before to pass to the limit as ε0 we get

    [f(x)]1k(kj=1λij(D2ψ(x)))1k,

    that is,

    kj=1λij(D2ψ(x))f(x).

    This concludes the proof.

    Finally, since problem (1.1) has a unique solution, see Remark 5, Theorem 2 follows.

    In this section we describe a one-player/control problem presented in the introduction in order to approximate solutions to the Monge-Ampère equation. As before, let ΩRN be a bounded open set and fix ε>0. Also take a positive function ϕ(ε) such that

    limε0ϕ(ε)=andlimε0εϕ(ε)=0.

    A token is placed at x0Ω and Player Ⅰ (the controller) chooses coefficients (αi)i=1,,NINε where

    INε={(αi)i=1,,NRN:Ni=1αi=1 and 0<αi<ϕ2(ε)}.

    The player/controller also chooses an orthonormal basis of RN, V=(v1,...,vN). Then, the token is moved to x±εαivi with equal probabilities. After the first round, the game continues from the new position x1 according to the same rules.

    As before, the game ends when the token leaves Ω. We denote by xτ the first point in the sequence of game states that lies outside Ω, so that τ is a stopping time for this game. The payoff is determined by two given functions: g:RNΩR, the final payoff function, and f:ΩR, the running payoff function. We require g to be continuous, f uniformly continuous and both bounded functions. When the game ends, the total payoff is given by

    g(xτ)12ε2τ1l=0[f(xl)]1N.

    When the player/controller fixes a strategy SI the expected payoff is given by

    Ex0SI[g(xτ)12ε2τ1l=0[f(xl)]1N]. (4.1)

    The player/controller aims to minimize the expected payoff, hence the value of the game is defined as

    uεI(x0)=infSIEx0SI[g(xτ)12ε2τ1l=0[f(xl)]1N].

    Let us observe that the game ends almost surely, and therefore the expectation (4.1) is well defined. We can proceed as before to prove that the value of the game coincides with the solution to

    {uε(x)=infVO infαiINε{1NNi=112uε(x+εαivi)+12uε(xεαivi)}12ε2[f(x)]1NxΩ,uε(x)=g(x)xΩ. (4.2)

    We first observe that we have existence of solutions to (4.2) and we can apply the main result of [17]. Now, given η>0 we can consider the strategy SI for the player that at every step of the game xk almost realizes the infimum, that is, the player chooses coefficients ^αi and an orthonormal basis (ˆvi) such that

    infVO infαiINε{1NNi=112uε(xk+εαivi)+12uε(xkεαivi)}1NNi=112uε(xk+ε^αiˆvi)+12uε(xkε^αiˆvi)η2k+1.

    Playing with this strategy we have

    Ex0SI[uε(xk+1)+12ε2kn=0f(xn)η2k+1|x0,,xk]infVO infαiINε{1NNi=112uε(xk+εαivi)+12uε(xkεαivi)}η2k+1+12ε2kn=0f(xn)η2k+1=uε(xk)12ε2f(xk)+12ε2kn=0f(xn)η2kuε(xk)+12ε2k1n=0f(xn)η2k.

    Then,

    Mk=uε(xk)+12ε2k1n=0f(xn)η2k

    is a supermartingale.

    From this fact, arguing as before, we get

    uεI(x0)=infSIEx0SI[g(xτ)+12ε2τ1n=0f(xn)]Ex0SI[g(xτ)+12ε2τ1n=0f(xn)]uε(x0)η. (4.3)

    Since η is arbitrary we obtain that

    uεI(x)uε(x).

    To obtain the reverse inequality, we fix an arbitrary strategy SI for the player and we observe that

    Mk=uε(xk)+12ε2k1n=0f(xn)

    is a submartingale. Indeed,

    Ex0SI[uε(xk+1)+12ε2kn=0f(xn)|x0,,xk]infVO infαiINε{1NNi=112uε(xk+εαivi)+12uε(xkεαivi)}+12ε2kn=0f(xn)=uε(xk)12ε2f(xk)+12ε2kn=0f(xn)=uε(xk)+12ε2k1n=0f(xn).

    Taking infimum over all the strategies SI we get

    uεI(x)uε(x).

    Given a solution to the DPP we have proved that it coincides with the game value. Then, the game value is characterized as the unique solution to the DPP.

    Now our aim is to pass to the limit in the values of the game and obtain that, along a subsequence,

    uεu,as ε0

    uniformly in ¯Ω.

    To obtain a convergent subsequence uεu we will use again the Arzela-Ascoli type lemma, Lemma 12. So our task now is to show that the family uε satisfies the hypotheses of the previous lemma.

    First, we observe that Lemma 13 still holds here. Hence, we have that there exists a constant C=C(Ω)>0 such that

    Ex0SI[τ]Cε2.

    for every ε>0, any strategy SI and x0Ω. As an immediate consequence we get that there exists C=C(Ω,f,g)>0 such that

    |uε(x)|<C

    for every ε>0 and every x¯Ω. In fact, using that Ex0SI,SII[τ]Cε2, we have

    |uε(x0)|infSIEx0SI[|g(xτ)|+12ε2τ1n=0|f(xn)|]maxg+Cmaxf.

    Now we observe that uε satisfies the second hypothesis of the Arzela-Ascoli type lemma. We want to see that, given η>0 there are constants r0 and ε0 such that for every ε<ε0 and any x,y¯Ω with |xy|<r0 it holds

    |uε(x)uε(y)|<η.

    The proof of this estimate is analogous to the proof of Lemma 15. In fact, the case x,yΓεϕ(ε) follows from the uniform continuity of g in Γεϕ(ε). As before, since the rules of the game do not depend on the point, the case x,yΩ follows from the case xΩ and yΓεϕ(ε); see the proof of Lemma 15. For the case xΩ and yΓεϕ(ε) we can argue as before considering the projection of xk in the direction of the a fixed vector w of norm 1, choosed as in Lemma 6,

    xky,w.

    This projection is a martingale. Then, with the same computations used before (see the proof of Lemma 15) se obtain

    |uε(x)g(y)|<η

    if |xy| is small enough.

    From these computations we have obtained uniform convergence of uε along a subsequence,

    uεu, as ε0,

    uniformly in ¯Ω. Finally, we observe that the uniform limit of uε is a viscosity solution to the limit PDE problem. This follows from the same computation done in the proof of Theorem 3.3. We observe that Lemmas 7–9 include the case where each eigenvalue is selected once, that is the Monge-Ampère equation. This concludes the proof of Theorem 3.

    One can also study a game for Monge-Ampère in which the possible movements are not discrete.

    In fact, for a small ε and a fixed matrix ASN consider the following random walk in a bounded domain Ω, from x the next position is given by x+Ay with yBε(0) being chosen with uniform distribution in Bε(0). If we fix a final payoff function g in RNΩ and we set

    vε(x)=Ex(g(xτ))

    with τ the first time when this random walk leaves the domain (τ is a stopping time for this process), then, it follows that vε verifies

    vε(x)=Bε(0)vε(x+Ay)dy

    for xΩ and vε(x)=g(x) for xRNΩ. These value functions converge to a solution to

    {trace(AtD2uA)=0 in Ω,u=g on Ω.

    Now, the game/control problem for Monge-Ampère runs as follows: at each turn the player/controller choose a matrix A in the set

    A={ASN×N:detA=1 and 0<Aϕ(ε)I}.

    Then the new position of the game goes to x+Ay with yBε(0) chosen with uniform probability. We add a running payoff N2(N+2)(f(x))1/Nε2 and a final payoff, g(x). In this case the DPP for the value of the game reads as

    uε(x)=infdetA=1Aϕ(ε)IBε(0)uε(x+Ay)dyN2(N+2)(f(x))1/Nε2. (5.1)

    This DPP is related to an asymptotic mean value formula for Monge-Ampère; see [3].

    With similar ideas as the ones used before (assuming that Ω is strictly convex) one can show that

    uεu, as ε0,

    where the limit u is characterized as the unique convex viscosity solution to

    {det(D2u)=infdet(A)=1trace(AtD2uA)=f in Ω,u=g on Ω.

    Remark 18. Observe that for uε to be a solution to (5.1) it must be measurable so that the integral in the right-hand side is well defined. Therefore, in the construction of a solution to the DPP by Perron's method (as in [17]) one has to take into account this measurability issue. The set of sub solutions should be restricted to bounded measurable functions, and we have to check that if u and f are bounded measurable functions, then T(x) given by

    T(x)=infdetA=1Aϕ(ε)IBε(0)u(x+Ay)dyN2(N+2)(f(x))1/Nε2

    is also measurable. This fact holds since the only problematic term is the uncountable infimum and we have

    infdetA=1Aϕ(ε)IBε(0)u(x+Ay)dy=infAQN×NdetA=1Aϕ(ε)IBε(0)u(x+Ay)dy. (5.2)

    The right-hand side is a countable infimum and the equality (5.2) follows from the absolute continuity of the mapping EEu(y)dy.

    P. Blanc partially supported by the Academy of Finland project no. 298641 and PICT-2018-03183 (Argentina). F. Charro partially supported by a Wayne State University University Research Grant, and grants MTM2017-84214-C2-1-P (Spain) and PID2019-110712GB-I100 (Spain), funded by MCIN/AEI/10.13039/501100011033 and by "ERDF A way of making Europe." J. J. Manfredi supported by Simons Collaboration Grants for Mathematicians Award 962828. J. D. Rossi partially supported by CONICET grant PIP GI No 11220150100036CO (Argentina), PICT-2018-03183 (Argentina) and UBACyT grant 20020160100155BA (Argentina).

    The authors declare no conflict of interest.



    [1] Shen JJ, Gonçalves R, Choi YT, et al. (2023) Microstructure and mechanical properties of gas metal arc welded CoCrFeMnNi joints using a 308 stainless steel filler metal. Scripta Mater 222: 115053. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scriptamat.2022.115053 doi: 10.1016/j.scriptamat.2022.115053
    [2] Shen JJ, Agrawal P, Rodrigues TA, et al. (2022) Gas tungsten arc welding of as-cast AlCoCrFeNi2.1 eutectic high entropy alloy. Mater Design 223: 111176. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.matdes.2022.111176 doi: 10.1016/j.matdes.2022.111176
    [3] Li BQ, Wang L, Wang BB, et al. (2022) Electron beam freeform fabrication of NiTi shape memory alloys: Crystallography, martensitic transformation, and functional response. Mater Sci Eng A 2022: 143135. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.msea.2022.143135 doi: 10.1016/j.msea.2022.143135
    [4] Felice IO, Shen JJ, Barragan A, et al. (2023) Wire and arc additive manufacturing of Fe-based shape memory alloys: Microstructure, mechanical and functional behavior. Mater Design 231: 112004. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.matdes.2023.112004 doi: 10.1016/j.matdes.2023.112004
    [5] Yusuf SM, Cutler S, Gao N (2019) Review: The impact of metal additive manufacturing on the aerospace industry. Metal 9: 1286. https://doi.org/10.3390/met9121286 doi: 10.3390/met9121286
    [6] Makhutov NA, Matvienko YG, Blednova ZM, et al. (2022) The effect of surface coating by shape memory alloys on mechanical properties of steel. Fatigue Fract Eng M 45: 1550–1553. https://doi.org/10.1111/ffe.13672 doi: 10.1111/ffe.13672
    [7] Tang H, Tao W, Wang H, et al. (2018) High-performance infrared emissivity of micro-arc oxidation coatings formed on titanium alloy for aerospace applications. Int J Appl Ceram Tec 15: 579–591. https://doi.org/10.1111/ijac.12861 doi: 10.1111/ijac.12861
    [8] Bhutta MU, Khan ZA (2020) Wear and friction performance evaluation of nickel based nanocomposite coatings under refrigerant lubrication. Tribol Int 148: 106312. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.triboint.2020.106312 doi: 10.1016/j.triboint.2020.106312
    [9] Segura-Cardenas E, Ramirez-Cedillo EG, Sandoval-Robles JA, et al. (2017) Permeability study of austenitic stainless steel surfaces produced by selective laser melting. Metals 7: 521. https://doi.org/10.3390/met7120521 doi: 10.3390/met7120521
    [10] Haro EE, Odeshi AG, Szpunar JA (2016) The energy absorption behavior of hybrid composite laminates containing nano-fillers under ballistic impact. Int J Impact Eng 96: 11–22. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijimpeng.2016.05.012 doi: 10.1016/j.ijimpeng.2016.05.012
    [11] Mishnaevsky LJR (2019) Toolbox for optimizing anti‐erosion protective coatings of wind turbine blades: Overview of mechanisms and technical solutions. Wind Energy 22: 1636–1653. https://doi.org/10.1002/we.2378 doi: 10.1002/we.2378
    [12] Ahmadnia A (2000) Energy Absorption of Macrocomposite Laminates, London: Queen Mary University of London. http://qmro.qmul.ac.uk/xmlui/handle/123456789/1342
    [13] Wadsworth J, Lesuer DR (2000) Ancient and modern laminated composites—from the great pyramid of gizeh to Y2K. Mater Charact 45: 289–313. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1044-5803(00)00077-2 doi: 10.1016/S1044-5803(00)00077-2
    [14] Sun MY, Bai YH, Li MX, et al. (2018) Structural design and energy absorption mechanism of laminated SiC/BN ceramics. J Eur Ceram Soc 38: 3742–3751. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeurceramsoc.2018.04.052 doi: 10.1016/j.jeurceramsoc.2018.04.052
    [15] Naidoo LC, Fatoba O, Akinlabi S, et al. (2020) Material characterization and corrosion behavior of hybrid coating Ti-Al-Si-Cu/Ti-6Al-4V composite. Materialwiss Werkstofftech 51: 766–773. https://doi.org/10.1002/mawe.202000019 doi: 10.1002/mawe.202000019
    [16] Rusinov PO, Blednova ZM, Kurapov GV (2023) Functionally oriented composite layered materials with martensitic transformations. Surf Innov 11: 26–37. https://doi.org/10.1680/jsuin.21.00077 doi: 10.1680/jsuin.21.00077
    [17] Anand EE, Natarajan S (2015) Effect of carbon nanotubes on corrosion and tribological properties of pulse-electrodeposited Co-W composite coatings. J Mater Eng Perform 24: 128–135. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11665-014-1306-z doi: 10.1007/s11665-014-1306-z
    [18] Rusinov PO, Blednova ZM, Rusinova AA, et al. (2023) Development and Research of New Hybrid Composites in Order to Increase Reliability and Durability of Structural Elements. Metals 13: 1177. https://doi.org/10.3390/met13071177 doi: 10.3390/met13071177
    [19] Xiong JJ, Zhu YT, Luo CY, et al. (2021) Fatigue-driven failure criterion for progressive damage modelling and fatigue life prediction of composite structures. Int J Fatigue 145: 106110. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfatigue.2020.106110 doi: 10.1016/j.ijfatigue.2020.106110
    [20] Kong WW, Yuan C, Zhang BN (2020) Investigations on cyclic deformation behaviors and corresponding failure modes of a Ni-Based superalloy. Mater Sci Eng A 791: 139775. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.msea.2020.139775 doi: 10.1016/j.msea.2020.139775
    [21] Cho H, Nam S, Hwang I, et al. (2019) Fatigue behaviors of resistance spot welds for 980 MPa grade TRIP steel. Metals 9: 1086. https://doi.org/10.3390/met9101086 doi: 10.3390/met9101086
    [22] Su ZM, Lin PC, Lai WJ, et al. (2020) Fatigue analyses and life predictions of laser-welded lap-shear specimens made of low carbon and high strength low alloy steels. Int J Fatigue 140: 105849. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijfatigue.2020.105849 doi: 10.1016/j.ijfatigue.2020.105849
    [23] Watanabe H, Murata T, Nakamura S, et al. (2021) Effect of cold-working on phase formation during heat treatment in CrMnFeCoNi system high-entropy alloys with Al addition. J Alloys Compd 872: 159668. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jallcom.2021.159668 doi: 10.1016/j.jallcom.2021.159668
    [24] Wang M, Huang MX (2020) Abnormal TRIP effect on the work hardening behavior of a quenching and partitioning steel at high strain rate. Acta Mater 188: 551–559. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.actamat.2020.02.035 doi: 10.1016/j.actamat.2020.02.035
    [25] Behravan A, Zarei-Hanzaki A, Fatemi SM, et al. (2019) The effect of aging temperature on microstructure and tensile properties of a novel designed Fe-12Mn-3Ni Maraging-TRIP steel. Steel Research Int 90: 1800282. https://doi.org/10.1002/srin.201800282 doi: 10.1002/srin.201800282
    [26] Tan XD, He HS, Lu WJ, et al. (2020) Effect of matrix structures on TRIP effect and mechanical properties of low-C low-Si Al-added hot-rolled TRIP steels. Mater Sci Eng A 771: 138629. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.msea.2019.138629 doi: 10.1016/j.msea.2019.138629
    [27] Yang J, Jo YH, Kim DW, et al. (2020) Effects of transformation-induced plasticity (TRIP) on tensile property improvement of Fe45Co30Cr10V10Ni5-xMnx high-entropy alloys. Mater Sci Eng A 772: 138809. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.msea.2019.138809 doi: 10.1016/j.msea.2019.138809
    [28] Isakaev EK, Mordynsky VB, Sidorova EV, et al. (2011) Comparative analysis of methods for measuring the porosity of gas-thermal coatings. Eng technol 3: 25–30. http://www.ltc.ru/newsltc/2/1009_1.shtml
    [29] Kustas AB, Jones MR, DelRio FW, et al. (2022) Extreme hardness at high temperature with a lightweight additively manufactured multi-principal element superalloy. Appl Mater Today 29: 101669. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apmt.2022.101669 doi: 10.1016/j.apmt.2022.101669
    [30] Whitfield TE, Stone HJ, Jones CN, et al. (2021) Microstructural degradation of the AlMo0.5NbTa0.5TiZr refractory metal high-entropy superalloy at elevated temperatures. Entropy 23: 80. https://doi.org/10.3390/e23010080 doi: 10.3390/e23010080
    [31] Rusinov PO, Blednova, ZM (2022) Study of the structure and properties of a high-entropy ceramic composite material. Surf Innov 10: 217–226. https://doi.org/10.1680/jsuin.21.00047 doi: 10.1680/jsuin.21.00047
    [32] Zhao YC, Zhao PB, Li WS, et al. (2019) The microalloying effect of Ce on the mechanical properties of medium entropy bulk metallic glass composites. Crystals 9: 483. https://doi.org/10.3390/cryst9090483 doi: 10.3390/cryst9090483
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(2152) PDF downloads(113) Cited by(0)

Figures and Tables

Figures(5)  /  Tables(2)

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog