Items | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | - | m |
1 | - | Y | Y | Y | N | - | Y |
2 | - | N | N | N | - | N | |
3 | - | N | Y | - | Y | ||
4 | - | Y | - | Y | |||
5 | - | - | N | ||||
- | - | - | |||||
m | - |
In this paper, by using the mountain pass lemma and the skill of truncation function, we investigate the existence and concentration phenomenon of nontrivial weak solutions for a class of elastic beam differential equation with two parameters λ and μ when the nonlinear term satisfies some growth conditions only near the origin. In particular, we obtain a concrete lower bound of the parameter λ, and analyze the relationship between λ and μ. In the end, we investigate the concentration phenomenon of solutions when μ→0, and obtain a specific lower bound of the parameter λ which is independent of μ.
Citation: Minggang Xia, Xingyong Zhang, Danyang Kang, Cuiling Liu. Existence and concentration of nontrivial solutions for an elastic beam equation with local nonlinearity[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(1): 579-605. doi: 10.3934/math.2022037
[1] | Suliman Khan, Sakander Hayat, Asad Khan, Muhammad Yasir Hayat Malik, Jinde Cao . Hamilton-connectedness and Hamilton-laceability of planar geometric graphs with applications. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(4): 3947-3973. doi: 10.3934/math.2021235 |
[2] | Milica Anđelić, Tamara Koledin, Zoran Stanić . Notes on Hamiltonian threshold and chain graphs. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(5): 5078-5087. doi: 10.3934/math.2021300 |
[3] | Ali N. A. Koam, Adnan Khalil, Ali Ahmad, Muhammad Azeem . Cardinality bounds on subsets in the partition resolving set for complex convex polytope-like graph. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(4): 10078-10094. doi: 10.3934/math.2024493 |
[4] | Adnan Khali, Sh. K Said Husain, Muhammad Faisal Nadeem . On bounded partition dimension of different families of convex polytopes with pendant edges. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(3): 4405-4415. doi: 10.3934/math.2022245 |
[5] | Wenke Zhou, Guo Chen, Hongzhi Deng, Jianhua Tu . Enumeration of dissociation sets in grid graphs. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(6): 14899-14912. doi: 10.3934/math.2024721 |
[6] | Xia Liu . A related problem on $ s $-Hamiltonian line graphs. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(10): 19553-19561. doi: 10.3934/math.20221073 |
[7] | Zhen Lin . The biharmonic index of connected graphs. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(4): 6050-6065. doi: 10.3934/math.2022337 |
[8] | Shama Liaqat, Zeeshan Saleem Mufti, Yilun Shang . Newly defined fuzzy Misbalance Prodeg Index with application in multi-criteria decision-making. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(8): 20193-20220. doi: 10.3934/math.2024984 |
[9] | Hongzhuan Wang, Xianhao Shi, Ber-Lin Yu . On the eccentric connectivity coindex in graphs. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(1): 651-666. doi: 10.3934/math.2022041 |
[10] | Kooi-Kuan Yoong, Roslan Hasni, Gee-Choon Lau, Muhammad Ahsan Asim, Ali Ahmad . Reflexive edge strength of convex polytopes and corona product of cycle with path. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(7): 11784-11800. doi: 10.3934/math.2022657 |
In this paper, by using the mountain pass lemma and the skill of truncation function, we investigate the existence and concentration phenomenon of nontrivial weak solutions for a class of elastic beam differential equation with two parameters λ and μ when the nonlinear term satisfies some growth conditions only near the origin. In particular, we obtain a concrete lower bound of the parameter λ, and analyze the relationship between λ and μ. In the end, we investigate the concentration phenomenon of solutions when μ→0, and obtain a specific lower bound of the parameter λ which is independent of μ.
The utility of paired comparison (PC) models in analyzing choice behaviors is well appreciated in various fields of research. For example, [1,2] demonstrated the applicability of PC schemes in health surveillance. Similarly, [3,4] applied PC methods to study food preferences and quality characteristics. Further, [5,6] persuaded the PC approach in the exploring the socio-political behaviors of the voters. Moreover, [7,8] employed PC models to conduct sports analysis. Recently, [9,10] elucidated the applicability of PC models in public health administration while facilitating the arduous task of project prioritization. For the account of more applications, one may see [11,12] in field of sensory analysis, [13,14] in engineering and reliability and [15,16] for measurement systems.
The PC models usually arise by considering a latent point-scoring process while conducting a pair-wise comparison among streams of objects, strategies or treatments [17]. Avoiding the literary jargon, a selector is requested to answer a simple query in "yes" or "no" fashion "do you prefer item i over item j?" while pairwise comparing a string of competing items. Table 1 below summarizes the hypothetical choice matrix comprehending the binary responses of a single selector resulting from the above inquiry while comparing m rival items. Each cell of the table documents the comparative choice of the decision maker while comparing a pair of objects specified by a certain row and column of the table. The choice strings then follow Binomial distribution where the likelihood of preferences remains estimable as a function of worth parameters defining the relative utility of competing objects.
Items | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | - | m |
1 | - | Y | Y | Y | N | - | Y |
2 | - | N | N | N | - | N | |
3 | - | N | Y | - | Y | ||
4 | - | Y | - | Y | |||
5 | - | - | N | ||||
- | - | - | |||||
m | - |
It is trivial to extend the afore-mentioned scenario for k selectors or judges. Despite the simplistic formation, the capability of above documented contingency in facilitating the optimization of complex decision making by inter-relating non-linear functionals is well established [10,18,19,20].
Inspired by the subtle nature of the pre-describe design, this research aims at the proposition of a generalized framework encapsulating a broad range of choice or comparative models in a single comprehensive expression. The devised generalization is argued to be advantageous especially due to its capability to entertain various probabilistic structures governing the utility functionals as latent phenomena. The objectives are achieved by exploiting the fundaments of the exponential family of distributions. The choice of the exponential family of distribution in this regard is mainly motivated by three facts. Firstly, the family of distributions provides the fundaments of linear models and generalized linear models [21] and therefore is anticipated to offer natural support to the modeling of the binary choice data [22]. Secondly, the ability of the exponential family in encompassing of complex linear and non-linear functions is well cherished [23,24]. Lastly, the involvement of the exponential function in the estimation procedure usually results in more precise estimates [25]. The legitimacy of the proposed scheme is established through meticulously launched methodological and simulation-based operations using the Bayesian paradigm. Moreover, the inferential aspects of the suggested generalization are explored in order to derive a statistically sound and mathematically workable line of actions to attain an optimal decision-making strategy. Furthermore, the applicability of the targeted generalization is advocated by studying the water brand choice data.
This article is mainly divided into five parts. Section 2 delineates the mathematical foundations of the proposed generalization whereas section 3 reports simulation-based outcomes advocating the legitimacy of the devised scheme. Section 4 is dedicated to the empirical evaluation and lastly, section 5 summarizes the main findings in a compact manner.
Let us say that a pairwise comparison is persuaded among m objects by n judges, where the pair of stimuli elicits a continuous discriminal process. The latent preferences of competing object i and object j are then thought to follow exponential family of distributions over the consistent support in the population, such as;
f(xi;θi)=a(θi)b(xi)eg(xi)h(θi),c<xi<d, |
and
f(xj;θj)=a(θj)b(xj)eg(xj)h(θj),c<xj<d, |
where, θi and θj are worth parameters highlighting the utility associated with respective objects. The interest lies in the deduction of precipitated preferences, such as pij=P(Xi>Xj) and pji=P(Xj>Xi), as a function of estimated worth parameters. We proceed by defining a general functional facilitating the estimation of preference probabilities such as;
P(Xi>Xj)=∫dc∫dxjf(xj;θj)f(xi;θi)dxidxj, | (1) |
where, ∫dxjf(xi;θi)dxi=F(d;θi)−F(xj;θi). By using this expression in Eq (1), we obtained:
P(Xi>Xj)=∫dcf(xj;θj)F(d;θi)dxj−∫dcf(xj;θj)F(xj;θi)dxj. | (2) |
For further simplification, let us denote,
A=∫dcf(xj;θj)F(d;θi)dxj, |
and
B=∫dcf(xj;θj)F(xj;θi)dxj. |
It remain verifiable that on solving, we get
A=F(d;θi)[F(d;θj)−F(c;θj)]. |
B=F(d;θi)F(d;θj)−F(d;θi)F(c;θj)−[F(d;θi)−F(c;θi)][F(d;θj)−F(c;θj)]. |
The Eq (2) now becomes,
P(Xi>Xj)=F(d;θi)[F(d;θj)−F(c;θj)]−F(d;θi)F(d;θj)+F(d;θi)F(c;θj)+[F(d;θi)−F(c;θi)][F(d;θj)−F(c;θj)], |
which on further simplification reduces to,
P(Xi>Xj)=F(d;θi)F(d;θj)−F(d;θi)F(c;θj)−F(c;θi)F(d;θj)+F(c;θi)F(c;θj), |
where, F(d;θi)=[1−F(c;θi)] and F(d;θj)=[1−F(c;θj)]. Using these specifications, we finally achieve the general expression confirming the preference of object i over object j, as under
P(Xi>Xj)=1−2F(c;θi)−2F(c;θj)+4F(c;θi)F(c;θj). | (3) |
The two features of the devised generalized formation given in Eq (3) remain immediately noticeable. Firstly, it remains verifiable that for any permissible value of lower limit of the support, c, the above given functional reduces to 1, ensuring the ability of the general scheme in establishing the true preferences. Secondly, the preference probabilities remain estimable as a function of worth parameters ensuring the desirable character of decision making that is utility based choices. Both realizations are consistent with classic and eminent luce's choice axiom. One may also notice that the above given functional can also be derived for P(Xj>Xi). Table 2, presents seven PC models based on more prominent exponential family of distributions' member which stay as special cases of aforementioned general scheme. It is to be noted that we are only considering these seven cases for demonstration purposes, in fact every PC model which arises due to the assumption that latent point process follows exponential family of distributions can be easily seen as sub-case of the proposition.
Model | p.d.f. | Exponential family f(x;θ)=a(θ)b(x)eg(x)h(θ) |
Preference probability (pij) |
Beta | f(x;θ)=xθ−1(1−x)B(θ,2), 0<x<1 |
a(θ)=θ(θ+1),b(x)=(1−x), g(x)=lnx,h(θ)=(θ−1) |
pij=θi(1+θi)(2+θi+3θj)(θi+θj)(1+θi+θj)(2+θi+θj) |
Power | f(x;θ)=θxθ−1, 0<x<1 |
a(θ)=θ,b(x)=1, g(x)=lnx,h(θ)=(θ−1) |
pij=θiθi+θj |
Exponential | f(x;θ)=1θe−xθ, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ,b(x)=1, g(x)=x,h(θ)=1θ |
pij=θiθi+θj |
Gamma | f(x;θ)=θ12Γ(12)x12−1e−θx, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=√θ,b(x)=1Γ(12)√x, g(x)=−x,h(θ)=θ |
pij=2πtan−1√θiθj |
Maxwell | f(x;θ)=√2πx2θ3e−x22θ2, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ3,b(x)=√2πx2, g(x)=−x22,h(θ)=1θ2 |
pij=1+2π{θ3iθj−θiθ3j(θ2i+θ2j)2−tan−1(θjθi)} |
Rayleigh | f(x;θ)=xθ2e−x22θ2, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ2,b(x)=x, g(x)=−x22,h(θ)=1θ2 |
pij=θ2iθ2i+θ2j |
Weibull | f(x;θ)=3x2θ3e−x3θ3, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ3,b(x)=3x2, g(x)=−x3,h(θ)=1θ3 |
pij=θ3iθ3i+θ3j |
The likelihood function, where n judges are deemed to pairwise comparison of m objects, is written by denoting nij as the total number of times object i and object j are pairwise compared. Also, let us represent, r_=(rij,rji) as a vector comprises of the observed preference data in k'th repetition, when i≠j, i≥1 and j≤m. Based on these specifications, the likelihood function encompassing the preferences of n judges pairwise comparing m objects, is written as under:
l(r_,θ_)=∏mi<j=1nij!rij!(nij−rij)!prijijpnij−rijji, | (4) |
where, pji=1−pij and r_ represents the preference vector along with θ_ denoting the vector of worth parameters. As a fact, the number of worth parameters stays equal to the number of objects to be compared, such that ∑mi=1θi=1. The imposed condition resolves the issue of non-identifiability.
The estimation of worth parameters is persuaded under the Bayesian paradigm – well cherished to channelize the historic information in order to enrich the analytical environment and thus assists the estimation procedure. For demonstration purposes, we consider two prior distributions, that is Jeffreys Prior and Uniform Prior.
The kernel of Jeffreys prior for θ_;(θ1,θ2,θ3,….,θm) is written as follows:
pJ(θ1,θ2,θ3,….,θm)∝√det[I(θ1,θ2,θ3,….,θm)],0<θ_<1. |
where, det[I(θ_)]=(−1)m−1|E[∂2lnL(.)∂θ21]E[∂2lnL(.)∂θ1∂θ2]…E[∂2lnL(.)∂θ1∂θm−1]E[∂2lnL(.)∂θ2∂θ1]E[∂2lnL(.)∂θ22]…E[∂2lnL(.)∂θ2∂θm−1]⋮⋮⋮E[∂2lnL(.)∂θm−1∂θ1]E[∂2lnL(.)∂θm−1∂θ2]…E[∂2lnL(.)∂θ2m−1]|. The estimability of the worth parameter associated with m'th object is conferred by ensuring that θm=1−θ1−θ2⋯−θm−1. The joint posterior distribution for θ1,θ2,…,θm is then written as:
pJ(θ1,θ2,…,θm|r)=1k∏mi<j=1pJ(θ1,θ2,θ3,….,θm)prijijpnij−rijji. | (5) |
Here, k=∫10∫1−θ10…∫1−θ1⋯−θm−10pJ(θ1,θ2,θ3,….,θm)prijijpnij−rijjidθm−1…dθ2dθ1 and is known as normalizing constant while obliging the above given constraint, such as θm=1−∑m−1i=1θi. Also, nij represents the frequency of pair-wise comparisons by selectors and rij denotes the frequency of referring object i over object j. The joint posterior distribution of Eq (5) is not of closed form, therefore Bayes estimates are attained by employing Gibbs sampler – a well cherished procedure of MCMC methods [26,27,28]. The marginal posterior distributions (MPDs) of parameters determining the comparative worth of each object are achieved by iteratively conditioning on interim value in a continuous cycle. Let pJ(θ_;r_) be the joint posterior density, where θ_=(θ1,θ2,…,θm), then the conditional densities are given by, pJ(θ1Iθ2,θ3…,θm), pJ(θ2Iθ1,θ3…,θm) …pJ(θmIθ1,θ2…,θm−1). According to the Gibbs sampler, we assume initial values such as (θ2(0),θ3(0),…,θm(0)) and pursue the conditional distribution of θ1 such that pJ(θ1(1)Iθ2(0),θ3(0),…,θm(0)). The iterative procedure will continue until it converges. Here, for demonstration purposes, we provide the expression of MPD of θm, as follows,
p(θm|r)=1k∫1−θmθ1=0…∫1−∑m−2i=1θi−θmθm=0∏m−1i<j=1pJ(θ1,θ2,θ3,….,θm)dθm−1…dθ1, | (6) |
0<θm<1 |
The MPDs of other parameters remain deductible in similar fashion.
The Uniform prior for θ_;(θ1,θ2,θ3,….,θm), is given as,
pU(θ1,θ2,…,θm)∝1,θ_>0 |
The joint posterior distribution given the preference data is now determined as,
pU(θ1,θ2,…,θm|r)=1k∏mi<j=1prijijpnij−rijji. | (7) |
Here, the normalizing constant under the estimability condition of θm=1−∑m−1i=1θi takes the form such as k=∫10∫1−θ10…∫1−θ1⋯−θm−10∏mi<j=1prijijpnij−rijjidθm−1…dθ2dθ1. Next phase provides the expression of MPD for θm using the above mentioned method of Gibbs sampler. The MPD is given as,
pU(θm|r)=1K∫1−θmθ1=0…∫1−∑m−2i=1θi−θmθm=0∏m−2i<j=1prijijpnij−rijjidθm−1…dθ1,0<θm<1. | (8) |
We now explore the authenticity of the proposed generalization with respect to above documented seven sub-cases. The objective is persuaded through rigorous simulation investigation mimicking wide range of experimental states. Artificial comparative data sets of two sizes n=15and50 are generated comparing three objects, that is i=1,2and3. The worth parameters are pre-set as θ1=0.5, θ2=0.3 and θ3=0.2. This setting is considered for demonstration purposes only, one can use other settings also. Table 3, presents the data under afore-mentioned settings. The Bayes estimates of worth parameters, estimated preference probabilities and Bayes factor are provided under both priors and for all considered sub-cases of the devised generalization. A detail account of the findings is documented in upcoming sections.
(i, j) | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||
rij | rji | rij | rji | |
(1, 2) | 10 | 5 | 32 | 18 |
(1, 3) | 9 | 6 | 38 | 12 |
(2, 3) | 11 | 4 | 28 | 22 |
Figure 1 (a–n) presents the graphical display of the MPDs of worth parameters through side-by-side box plots. The behavior is depicted for both priors, that is Jefferys prior and Uniform priors, while covering sample of sizes n=15 and n=50. The delicacies of displayed outcomes are read with respect to different resultant sub-cases of the proposed family and both sample sizes. Firstly, through side-by-side box plots, it is observed that as the sample size increases more compact behavior of MPDs is observed. This is seen regardless of the considered prior distribution and sub-cases of the proposed family. Furthermore, Uniform prior is found to stand out in terms of the generation of the number of outliers. In most cases, the Uniform prior is noticed to produce a lesser extent of outliers as compared to contemporary prior model of Jefferys. It is thought that the tendency of Uniform prior to outperform Jefferys prior on this front lies in its capability of deducing the same amount of information from the data but through a more parsimonious layout.
The estimation of worth parameters defining the utility of competing objects is facilitated by providing the posterior means of the MPDs. Table 4 comprehends the outcomes of the estimation efforts along with associated absolute differences. One may notice some interesting patterns revealed in the table. Firstly, regardless of the prior distribution, increased sample size produces more close estimates of the utility. It is important to note that the estimation performance, however, remains subject to the sub-cases of the proposed family. Moreover, the estimated worth parameters for each member remain robust towards the change in the prior distribution. This outcome remains arguable as both considered priors are non-informative and thus provide equally enriched estimation environment. As long as, model-wise estimation performance is concerned, the PC model produces the most prolific estimates and therefore is argued to be most capable in using the comparative information more rigorously. From Table 2, one may notice that the Gamma model is attributed with a more vibrant and rich utility function estimating the preference behaviors by not only involving contemporary worth parameters but also employing geometric functions. The next in line remains Exponential and Power models with equal elegancy. This outcome in fact verify the simplifications provided in the Table 2. The characterization is thought to be a result of tendency of these models to entertain the comparative behaviors by exploiting linear, product and ratio formation of the associated worth parameters through more simple manner. The Beta model is ranked third in this comparative evaluation along with Maxwell model holding the forth level in the hierarchy. Whereas, Rayleigh model and Weibull model are placed at fifth and sixth position as contestant models.
Models | Estimators | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||
Jeffreys | Uniform | Jeffreys | Uniform | ||
Beta | ^θ1 | 0.4424 | 0.4424 | 0.5205 | 0.5205 |
^θ2 | 0.3477 | 0.3477 | 0.2783 | 0.2783 | |
^θ3 | 0.2099 | 0.2099 | 0.2012 | 0.2012 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0576 | 0.0576 | 0.0205 | 0.0205 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0477 | 0.0477 | 0.0217 | 0.0217 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0099 | 0.0099 | 0.0012 | 0.0012 | |
Exponential | ^θ1 | 0.4615 | 0.4465 | 0.5376 | 0.5302 |
^θ2 | 0.3434 | 0.3472 | 0.2710 | 0.2738 | |
^θ3 | 0.1952 | 0.2063 | 0.1914 | 0.1960 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0385 | 0.0535 | 0.0376 | 0.0302 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0434 | 0.0472 | 0.0290 | 0.0262 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0048 | 0.0063 | 0.0086 | 0.0040 | |
Power | ^θ1 | 0.4615 | 0.4465 | 0.5376 | 0.5302 |
^θ2 | 0.3434 | 0.3472 | 0.2710 | 0.2738 | |
^θ3 | 0.1952 | 0.2063 | 0.1914 | 0.1960 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0385 | 0.0535 | 0.0376 | 0.0302 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0434 | 0.0472 | 0.0290 | 0.0262 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0048 | 0.0063 | 0.0086 | 0.0040 | |
Gamma | ^θ1 | 0.4872 | 0.4872 | 0.6260 | 0.6260 |
^θ2 | 0.3470 | 0.3470 | 0.2340 | 0.2340 | |
^θ3 | 0.1658 | 0.1658 | 0.1400 | 0.1400 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0128 | 0.0128 | 0.1260 | 0.1260 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0470 | 0.0470 | 0.0660 | 0.0660 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0342 | 0.0342 | 0.0600 | 0.0600 | |
Maxwell | ^θ1 | 0.4287 | 0.4287 | 0.6294 | 0.6294 |
^θ2 | 0.3748 | 0.3748 | 0.2334 | 0.2334 | |
^θ3 | 0.1966 | 0.1966 | 0.1372 | 0.1372 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0713 | 0.0713 | 0.1294 | 0.1294 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0748 | 0.0748 | 0.0666 | 0.0666 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0034 | 0.0034 | 0.0628 | 0.0628 | |
Rayleigh | ^θ1 | 0.3972 | 0.3962 | 0.4336 | 0.4332 |
^θ2 | 0.3432 | 0.3442 | 0.3074 | 0.3076 | |
^θ3 | 0.2597 | 0.2596 | 0.2591 | 0.2592 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.1028 | 0.1038 | 0.0664 | 0.0668 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0432 | 0.0442 | 0.0074 | 0.0076 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0597 | 0.0596 | 0.0591 | 0.0592 | |
Weibull | ^θ1 | 0.3756 | 0.3761 | 0.3992 | 0.3996 |
^θ2 | 0.3411 | 0.3417 | 0.3174 | 0.3176 | |
^θ3 | 0.2834 | 0.2822 | 0.2834 | 0.2829 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.1244 | 0.1239 | 0.1008 | 0.1004 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0411 | 0.0417 | 0.0174 | 0.0176 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0834 | 0.0822 | 0.0834 | 0.0829 |
The estimated preference probabilities highlighting the degree of prevailed utility of competing objects are compiled in Table 5. The estimates verify the preference norms established through the observed magnitude of the worth parameters. It is witnessed without exception that object 1 coined with the worth value of θ1=0.5, is overwhelmingly preferred over the objects characterized with θ2=0.3 and θ3=0.2. Similarly, the second item nominated with θ2=0.3 worth of the parameter value is preferred over the third available option. Also, the extent of preferences can be seen consistent with the magnitude of worth parameters. The larger the difference in the associated worth (utility) of the objects, the clearer will be the choices. Moreover, these realizations are seen regardless of the priors and sample sizes. It is to be noted, that all the findings verify that our proposed scheme successfully maintain the common rationale underlying the PC methods along with offering a general device capable of generating various PC models through the exponential family of distributions.
Models | Preferences | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||
Jeffreys | Uniform | Jeffreys | Uniform | ||
Beta | ^p12 | 0.5636 | 0.5636 | 0.6603 | 0.6603 |
^p13 | 0.6858 | 0.6858 | 0.7311 | 0.7311 | |
^p23 | 0.6281 | 0.6281 | 0.5829 | 0.5829 | |
Exponential | ^p12 | 0.5734 | 0.5626 | 0.6649 | 0.6595 |
^p13 | 0.7028 | 0.6840 | 0.7374 | 0.7301 | |
^p23 | 0.6376 | 0.6273 | 0.5861 | 0.5828 | |
Power | ^p12 | 0.5734 | 0.5626 | 0.6649 | 0.6595 |
^p13 | 0.7028 | 0.6840 | 0.7374 | 0.7301 | |
^p23 | 0.6376 | 0.6273 | 0.5861 | 0.5828 | |
Gamma | ^p12 | 0.5535 | 0.5535 | 0.6504 | 0.6504 |
^p13 | 0.6635 | 0.6635 | 0.7185 | 0.7185 | |
^p23 | 0.6147 | 0.6147 | 0.5806 | 0.5806 | |
Maxwell | ^p12 | 0.5849 | 0.5849 | 0.9313 | 0.9313 |
^p13 | 0.8837 | 0.8837 | 0.9838 | 0.9838 | |
^p23 | 0.8414 | 0.8414 | 0.7970 | 0.7970 | |
Rayleigh | ^p12 | 0.5725 | 0.5699 | 0.6655 | 0.6648 |
^p13 | 0.7005 | 0.6996 | 0.7369 | 0.7364 | |
^p23 | 0.6359 | 0.6374 | 0.5846 | 0.5848 | |
Weibull | ^p12 | 0.5718 | 0.5714 | 0.6655 | 0.6657 |
^p13 | 0.6995 | 0.7030 | 0.7365 | 0.7381 | |
^p23 | 0.6355 | 0.6397 | 0.5842 | 0.5859 |
This sub-section is dedicated to delineate the attainment of rational decision making through inferentially workable scheme by the launch of sound utility theory. We proceed by drawing conjoint posterior samples of worth parameters, that is θi's and θj's, using Eqs (5) and (7). The exercise is conducted under both priors, both samples and with respect to all sub-cases. Table 6 reports the respective hypothesis and their posterior probabilities. Furthermore, the extent of the significance of the dis-agreement between the worth parameters is quantified through the Bayes factor (BF). We decide between the hypothesis, Hij:θi≥θj vs Hji:θi<θj by calculating the posterior probabilities, such as:
pij=∫1ζ=0∫(1+ζ)/2η=ζp(ζ,η|ω)dηdζ, |
Models | Hypotheses | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||||||
Jeffreys | Uniform | Jeffreys | Uniform | ||||||
Pij | BF | Pij | BF | Pij | BF | Pij | BF | ||
Beta | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7331 | 2.7467 | 0.7234 | 2.6153 | 0.9975 | 399.0000 | 0.9971 | 343.8276 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9696 | 31.8947 | 0.9671 | 29.3951 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8958 | 8.5969 | 0.8882 | 7.9445 | 0.9209 | 11.6422 | 0.9082 | 9.8932 | |
Exponential | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7320 | 2.7313 | 0.7228 | 2.6075 | 0.9975 | 399.0000 | 0.9971 | 343.8276 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9691 | 31.3625 | 0.9666 | 28.9401 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8954 | 8.5602 | 0.8879 | 7.9206 | 0.9207 | 11.6103 | 0.9081 | 9.8932 | |
Power | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7320 | 2.7313 | 0.7228 | 2.6075 | 0.9975 | 399.0000 | 0.9971 | 343.8276 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9691 | 31.3625 | 0.9666 | 28.9401 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8954 | 8.5602 | 0.8879 | 7.9206 | 0.9207 | 11.6103 | 0.9081 | 9.8932 | |
Gamma | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7218 | 2.5945 | 0.7156 | 2.5162 | 0.9968 | 311.5000 | 0.9965 | 284.7143 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9626 | 25.7380 | 0.9606 | 24.3807 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8876 | 7.8968 | 0.8816 | 7.4459 | 0.9175 | 11.1212 | 0.9066 | 9.7066 | |
Maxwell | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7379 | 2.8153 | 0.7135 | 2.4904 | 0.9977 | 433.7826 | 0.9967 | 302.0303 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9730 | 36.0370 | 0.9676 | 29.8642 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.9008 | 9.0806 | 0.8852 | 7.7108 | 0.9217 | 11.7714 | 0.8961 | 8.6246 | |
Rayleigh | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7398 | 2.8432 | 0.7212 | 2.5868 | 0.9977 | 433.7826 | 0.9969 | 321.5806 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9730 | 36.0370 | 0.9688 | 31.0513 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.9014 | 9.1420 | 0.8890 | 8.0090 | 0.9216 | 11.7551 | 0.9020 | 9.2041 | |
Weibull | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7405 | 2.8536 | 0.7118 | 2.4698 | 0.9977 | 433.7826 | 0.9964 | 276.7778 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9736 | 36.8788 | 0.9674 | 29.6748 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.9023 | 9.2354 | 0.8843 | 7.6430 | 0.9211 | 11.6743 | 0.8912 | 8.1912 |
where, posterior probability of Hji will be pji=1−pij. Moreover, η represents worth parameter, such as θi and ζ denotes the difference of utility associated with comparative strategies, such as, ζ=θi−θj. The BF is then remains quantifiable as a ratio of the above given posterior probabilities that is, BF=pij/pji through well known criteria highlighting the degree of dis-agreement between hypotheses as:
BF≥1,supportHij |
10−0.5≤BF≤1,minimalevidenceagainstHij |
10−1≤BF≤10−0.5,substantialevidenceagainstHij |
10−2≤BF≤10−1,strongevidenceagainstHij |
BF≤10−2,decisiveevidenceagainstHij. |
Through Table 6, we observe that, the pre-fix preference ordering, that is θ1>θ2>θ3, remains maintained with overwhelming statistical evidences. This outcome is vividly observable through the table, regardless of priors and for both sample sizes with respect to all sub-cases. Moreover, as the mutual difference of the worth parameters increases, the evidence of choice ordering moves from being substantial to decisive. These findings are consistent with usual PC theory and thus validate the legitimacy of the proposed strategy.
The applicability of the proposed generalization is demonstrated by using the water brand preference data gathered through a balance paired comparison (PC) experiment. Thirty-five households of Islamabad were requested to report their preferences for drinking water while the pair-wise comparing three of leading brands of Pakistan that is, Aquafina (AQ), Nestle (NT) and Kinley (KL). Table 7 comprehends the reported choice data of the respondents. An initial analysis reveals that, when comparing AQ and NT, 40% of the respondents reported AQ as their preferred brand, whereas 60% chose NT over AQ. Further, around 63% of the participants preferred AQ brand over KL brand, where remaining 37% were of the favor of KL. Lastly, in comparison of NT and KL, almost 57% contestants favored NT, while 43% participants stayed with KL. Figure 2 depicts the choice data.
Pairs | rij | rji | nij |
(AQ,NT=1,2) | 14 (40%) | 21 (60%) | 35 |
(AQ,KL=1,3) | 22 (62.8%) | 13 (37.1%) | 35 |
(NT,KL=2,3) | 20 (57.1%) | 15 (42.8%) | 35 |
Next, the estimation of worth parameters deriving the utility of competing brands as latent phenomena is persuaded while considering all sub-cases of the devised generalization and both prior distributions. The results related to estimated worth parameters and resultant preference probabilities are comprehended in the Table 8. Most obviously, the empirical estimation of the proposed procedure stays consistent with the simulation evaluation. Firstly, regardless of the prior distributions, all members of the suggested scheme capably retain the preferences exhibited through the comparative data. The uncovered choice hierarchy is estimated such that, ˆθNT>ˆθAQ>ˆθKL indicating Nestle as the most preferred brand followed by Aquafina which is then stayed preferable in comparison to Kinley. Secondly, all of the members showed an equally tendency of using prior information fetched from the considered prior distributions, however, intra-model variations exist. These delicacies are projected in the resulting estimated preference probabilities compiled in the Table 9. One may notice the vivid functional dependency of the preference ordering over the associated worth parameter. As the utility of the object enhances so is the extent of preference increase. The Bayes factors provided in table 10 also reveal the same trends. As the utility associated with water brands vary, so does the evidence of likely preference. For example, there is substantial evidence in the favor of NT as compared to AQ but this evidence turns to be decisive when NT is compared with KL. These variations are in fact the projection of varying degrees of comparative utility prevalent in the choices of the respondents.
Models | Estimated Parameters | Jeffreys | Uniform |
Beta | ˆθAQ | 0.3398 | 0.3398 |
ˆθNT | 0.4057 | 0.4057 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2544 | 0.2544 | |
Exponential | ˆθAQ | 0.3414 | 0.3396 |
ˆθNT | 0.4108 | 0.4091 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2478 | 0.2514 | |
Power | ˆθAQ | 0.3414 | 0.3396 |
ˆθNT | 0.4108 | 0.4091 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2478 | 0.2514 | |
Gamma | ˆθAQ | 0.3388 | 0.3388 |
ˆθNT | 0.4455 | 0.4455 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2157 | 0.2157 | |
Maxwell | ˆθAQ | 0.3520 | 0.3520 |
ˆθNT | 0.4137 | 0.4137 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2343 | 0.2343 | |
Rayleigh | ˆθAQ | 0.3384 | 0.3381 |
ˆθNT | 0.3723 | 0.3726 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2892 | 0.2893 | |
Weibull | ˆθAQ | 0.3370 | 0.3369 |
ˆθNT | 0.3593 | 0.3597 | |
ˆθKL | 0.3037 | 0.3034 |
Models | Preference probabilities | Jeffreys | Uniform |
Beta | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4533 | 0.4533 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5749 | 0.5749 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6200 | 0.6200 | |
Exponential | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4539 | 0.4536 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5794 | 0.5746 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6237 | 0.6194 | |
Power | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4539 | 0.4536 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5794 | 0.5746 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6237 | 0.6194 | |
Gamma | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4564 | 0.4564 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5710 | 0.5710 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6127 | 0.6127 | |
Maxwell | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.3987 | 0.3987 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.7395 | 0.7395 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.8124 | 0.8124 | |
Rayleigh | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4524 | 0.4516 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5779 | 0.5773 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6237 | 0.6239 | |
Weibull | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4521 | 0.4510 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5774 | 0.5779 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6235 | 0.6250 |
Models | Hypotheses | nij=35 | |||
Jeffreys | Uniform | ||||
Pij | BF | Pij | BF | ||
Beta | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2297 | 0.2982 | 0.2297 | 0.2982 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8505 | 5.6890 | 0.8505 | 5.6890 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9580 | 22.8095 | 0.9580 | 22.8095 | |
Exponential | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2311 | 0.3006 | 0.2236 | 0.2880 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8506 | 5.6934 | 0.8434 | 5.3857 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9579 | 22.7530 | 0.9554 | 21.4215 | |
Power | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2311 | 0.3006 | 0.2236 | 0.2880 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8506 | 5.6934 | 0.8434 | 5.3857 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9579 | 22.7530 | 0.9554 | 21.4215 | |
Gamma | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2417 | 0.3187 | 0.2417 | 0.3187 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8508 | 5.7024 | 0.8508 | 5.7024 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9561 | 21.7790 | 0.9561 | 21.7790 | |
Maxwell | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2035 | 0.2555 | 0.2035 | 0.2555 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8349 | 5.0569 | 0.8349 | 5.0569 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9530 | 20.2766 | 0.9530 | 20.2766 | |
Rayleigh | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2088 | 0.2639 | 0.2118 | 0.2687 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8393 | 5.2228 | 0.8420 | 5.3291 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9546 | 21.0264 | 0.9556 | 21.5225 | |
Weibull | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.1912 | 0.2364 | 0.1956 | 0.2432 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8260 | 4.7471 | 0.8301 | 4.8858 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9497 | 18.8807 | 0.9512 | 14.9.4918 |
This research elucidates the proposition of a generalized framework to assist rational decision-making while dealing with binary choices. The objectives are achieved by devising a general paired comparison modeling scheme by employing an exponential family of distributions. The methodological environment is enriched by illuminating various parametric settings such as sample size and prior distributions. Through tiresome evaluation operations, it is delineated that the suggested model is not capable of retaining the preference hierarchy exhibited through the observed data but also treats seven mainstream paired comparison models as sub-cases. It is estimated that the members of the proposed family robustly use the prior information when offered non-informative priors such as Jeffery's prior and Uniform prior. However, the deducted sub-cases reveal a varying degree of estimating accuracy. Also, the suggested generalized scheme capably elaborates the choice hierarchy among the competing objects as a function of associated utility. This realization is in fact consistent with the theoretical understanding of rational decision-making. Moreover, the inferential aspects of the model are explored in depth through the launch of the Bayesian approach. The outcomes of the investigation demonstrate with clarity that as the utility of rival objects distinguishes the statistical evidence establishing the choice ranking varies accordingly. These mentioned realizations are in support of the fondness for professional and commercial research circles exploring capable mechanisms assisting optimal decision-making by defining sound interlinks between utility theory and its inferential dynamics. Thus, it remains deducible that the study encapsulating various choice behaviors and associated utility functional in accordance with choice axioms, is worth pursuing. The estimating hierarchy of the contemporary sub-cases of the newly devised family is observed such that, Gamma>Exponntial=Power>Beta>Maxwell>Rayleigh>Weibull.
At this stage, it is appropriate to mention that this article demonstrates the utility of non-informative priors for the estimation of the worth parameters and directed preferences. In the future, it will be interesting to compare the dynamic behaviors of the devised family while using informative priors as well. Also, it is well known that the self-reported choice data remains vulnerable to the contaminations such as desirability bias, order effects and time-varying subtleties. A more comprehensive framework capable of handling these complexities is an attractive research pursuit.
The authors declare no conflict of interest.
[1] |
C. B. Zhai, R. P. Song, Q. Q. Han, The existence and the uniqueness of symmetric positive solutions for a fourth-order boundary value problem, Comput. Math. Appl., 62 (2011), 2639–2647. doi: 10.1016/j.camwa.2011.08.003. doi: 10.1016/j.camwa.2011.08.003
![]() |
[2] |
B. Yang, Maximum principle for a fourth order boundary value problem, Differ. Equ. Appl., 9 (2017), 495–504. doi: 10.7153/dea-2017-09-33. doi: 10.7153/dea-2017-09-33
![]() |
[3] |
E. Alves, E. Arnaut, L. A. P. Gomes, M. B. S. Cortes, A note on iterative solutions for a nonlinear fourth order oder, Bol. Soc. Paran. Mat., 27 (2009), 15–20. doi: 10.5269/bspm.v27i1.9062. doi: 10.5269/bspm.v27i1.9062
![]() |
[4] | A. Cabada, R. Precup, L. Saavedra, S. A. Tersian, Multiple positive solutions to a fourth-order boundary-value problem, Electron. J. Differ. Eq., 2016 (2016), 1–18. |
[5] | G. Bonanno, A. Chinnì, S. A. Tersian, Existence results for a two point boundary value problem involving a fourth-order equation, Electron. J. Qual. Theo., 33 (2015), 1–9. |
[6] | A. Hadjian, M. Ramezani, Existence of infinitely many solutions for fourth-order equations depending on two parameters, Electron. J. Differ. Eq., 2017 (2017), 1–10. |
[7] |
X. D. Wang, Infinitely many solutions for a fourth-order differential equation on a nonlinear elastic foundation, Bound. Value Probl., 2013 (2013), 1–10. doi: 10.1186/1687-2770-2013-258. doi: 10.1186/1687-2770-2013-258
![]() |
[8] |
L. Yang, H. B. Chen, X. X. Yang, The multiplicity of solutions for fourth-order equations generated from a boundary condition, Appl. Math. Lett., 24 (2011), 1599–1603. doi: 10.1016/j.aml.2011.04.008. doi: 10.1016/j.aml.2011.04.008
![]() |
[9] |
E. Alves, T. F. Ma, M. L. Pelicer, Monotone positive solutions for a fourth order equation with nonlinear boundary conditions, Nonlinear Anal. Theor., 71 (2009), 3834–3841. doi: 10.1016/j.na.2009.02.051. doi: 10.1016/j.na.2009.02.051
![]() |
[10] |
W. X. Wang, Y. P. Zheng, H. Yang, J. X. Wang, Positive solutions for elastic beam equations with nonlinear boundary conditions and a parameter, Bound. Value Probl., 2014 (2014), 1–17. doi: 10.1186/1687-2770-2014-80. doi: 10.1186/1687-2770-2014-80
![]() |
[11] |
S. Heidarkhani, F. Gharehgazlouei, Existence results for a boudary value problem involving a fourth-order elastic beam equation, J. Nonlinear Funct. Anal., 28 (2019), 1–15. doi: 10.23952/jnfa.2019.28. doi: 10.23952/jnfa.2019.28
![]() |
[12] |
M. R. H. Tavani, A. Nazari, Existence of positive solutions for a perturbed fourth-order equation, Kragujev. J. Math., 45 (2021), 623–633. doi: 10.46793/KgJMat2104.623H. doi: 10.46793/KgJMat2104.623H
![]() |
[13] |
M. R. H. Tavani, Existence results for a perturbed fourth-order equation, J. Indones. Math. Soc., 23 (2017), 55–65. doi: 10.22342/jims.23.2.498.76-86. doi: 10.22342/jims.23.2.498.76-86
![]() |
[14] | S. Heidarkhani, M. Ferrara, A. Salari, M. Azimbagirad, A variational approach to perturbed elastic beam problems with nonlinear boundary conditions, Math. Rep., 18 (2016), 573–589. |
[15] |
Y. P. Song, A nonlinear boundary value problem for fourth-order elastic beam equations, Bound. Value Probl., 2014 (2014), 1–11. doi: 10.1186/s13661-014-0191-6. doi: 10.1186/s13661-014-0191-6
![]() |
[16] | M. Jleli, B. Samet, Existence and uniqueness of positive solutions to a fourth-order two-point boundary-value problem, Electron. J. Differ. Eq., 2013 (2013), 1–10. |
[17] |
M. Tuz, The existence of symmetric positive solutions of fourth-order elastic beam equations, Symmetry, 11 (2019), 121. doi: 10.3390/sym11010121. doi: 10.3390/sym11010121
![]() |
[18] |
Q. A. Dang, Q. L. Dang, Existence results and iterative method for a fully fourth-order nonlinear integral boundary value problem, Numer. Algor., 85 (2020), 887–907. doi: 10.1007/s11075-019-00842-3. doi: 10.1007/s11075-019-00842-3
![]() |
[19] |
H. Djourdem, S. Benaicha, N. Bouteraa, Existence and iteration of monotone positive solution for a fourth-order nonlinear boundary value problem, Fundam. J. Math. Appl., 1 (2018), 205–211. doi: 10.33401/fujma.418934. doi: 10.33401/fujma.418934
![]() |
[20] |
X. M. Zhang, M. Q. Feng, Positive solutions of singular beam equations with the bending term, Bound. Value Probl., 2015 (2015), 1–12. doi: 10.1186/s13661-015-0348-y. doi: 10.1186/s13661-015-0348-y
![]() |
[21] |
L. Yang, C. F. Shen, Existence of positive solutions for a fourth-order m-point boundary value problem, J. Funct. Space., 2015 (2015), 1–8. doi: 10.1155/2015/928105. doi: 10.1155/2015/928105
![]() |
[22] |
D. Y. Kang, C. L. Liu, X. Y. Zhang, Existence of solutions for Kirchhoff-Type fractional Dirichlet problem with p-Laplacian, Mathematics, 8 (2020), 106. doi: 10.3390/math8010106. doi: 10.3390/math8010106
![]() |
[23] |
D. G. Costa, Z. Q. Wang, Multiplicity results for a class of superlinear elliptic problems, P. Am. Math. Soc., 133 (2005), 787–794. doi: 10.1090/S0002-9939-04-07635-X. doi: 10.1090/S0002-9939-04-07635-X
![]() |
[24] |
A. R. Li, J. B. Su, Existence and multiplicity of solutions for Kirchhoff-type equation with radial potentials in R3, Z. Angew. Math. Phys., 66 (2015), 3147–3158. doi: 10.1007/s00033-015-0551-9. doi: 10.1007/s00033-015-0551-9
![]() |
[25] | E. S. Medeiros, U. B. Severo, On the existence of signed solutions for a quasilinear elliptic problem in RN, Mat. Contemp., 32 (2007), 193-205. |
[26] |
N. S. Papageorgiou, V. D. Radulescu, D. D. Repov, Double-phase problems with reaction of arbitrary growth, Z. Angew. Math. Phys., 69 (2018), 1–21. doi: 10.1007/s00033-018-1001-2. doi: 10.1007/s00033-018-1001-2
![]() |
[27] |
Y. Xu, Z. Tan, D. Sun, Multiplicity results for a nonlinear elliptic problem involving the fractional Laplacian, Acta Math. Sci., 36 (2016), 1793–1803. doi: 10.1016/S0252-9602(16)30106-0. doi: 10.1016/S0252-9602(16)30106-0
![]() |
[28] |
T. S. He, Z. A. Yao, Z. H. Sun, Multiple and nodal solutions for parametric Neumann problems with nonhomogeneous differential operator and critical growth, J. Math. Anal. Appl., 449 (2017), 1133–1151. doi: 10.1016/j.jmaa.2016.12.020. doi: 10.1016/j.jmaa.2016.12.020
![]() |
[29] |
Q. Zhang, Existence of fast homoclinic solutions for a class of second-order damped vibration systems, Bound. Value Probl., 2018 (2018), 1–13. doi: 10.1186/s13661-018-0995-x. doi: 10.1186/s13661-018-0995-x
![]() |
[30] |
Q. Zhang, Y. Li, Existence and multiplicity of fast homoclinic solutions for a class of nonlinear second-order nonautonomous systems in a weighted Sobolev space, J. Funct. Space., 2015 (2015), 495040. doi: 10.1155/2015/495040. doi: 10.1155/2015/495040
![]() |
[31] |
Q. Zhang, Existence and multiplicity of fast homoclinic solutions for a class of damped vibration problems with impulsive effects, Abstr. Appl. Anal., 2014 (2014), 960276. doi: 10.1155/2014/960276. doi: 10.1155/2014/960276
![]() |
[32] | X. Y. Zhang, Infinitely many solutions for a class of second-order damped vibration systems, Electron. J. Qual. Theo., 2013 (2013), 1–18. |
[33] |
X. Wu, S. X. Chen, K. M. Teng, On variational methods for a class of damped vibration problems, Nonlinear. Anal. Theor., 68 (2008), 1432–1441. doi: 10.1016/j.na.2006.12.043. doi: 10.1016/j.na.2006.12.043
![]() |
[34] |
Q. Zhang, C. Gan, T. Xiao, Z. Jia, Some results of nontrivial solutions for Klein-Gordon-Maxwell systems with local super-quadratic conditions, J. Geom. Anal., 31 (2021), 5372–5394. doi: 10.1007/s12220-020-00483-2. doi: 10.1007/s12220-020-00483-2
![]() |
[35] | M. Willem, Minimax theorems, Springer Science & Business Media, 1997. |
[36] |
J. Xie, X. Y. Zhang, C. L. Liu, D. Y. Kang, Existence and multiplicity of solutions for a class of damped-like fractional differential system, AIMS Mathematics, 5 (2020), 4268–4284. doi: 10.3934/math.2020272. doi: 10.3934/math.2020272
![]() |
[37] |
T. F. Ma, Positive solutions for a beam equation on a nonlinear elastic foundation, Math. Comput. Model., 39 (2004), 1195–1201. doi: 10.1016/j.mcm.2004.06.001. doi: 10.1016/j.mcm.2004.06.001
![]() |
Items | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | - | m |
1 | - | Y | Y | Y | N | - | Y |
2 | - | N | N | N | - | N | |
3 | - | N | Y | - | Y | ||
4 | - | Y | - | Y | |||
5 | - | - | N | ||||
- | - | - | |||||
m | - |
Model | p.d.f. | Exponential family f(x;θ)=a(θ)b(x)eg(x)h(θ) |
Preference probability (pij) |
Beta | f(x;θ)=xθ−1(1−x)B(θ,2), 0<x<1 |
a(θ)=θ(θ+1),b(x)=(1−x), g(x)=lnx,h(θ)=(θ−1) |
pij=θi(1+θi)(2+θi+3θj)(θi+θj)(1+θi+θj)(2+θi+θj) |
Power | f(x;θ)=θxθ−1, 0<x<1 |
a(θ)=θ,b(x)=1, g(x)=lnx,h(θ)=(θ−1) |
pij=θiθi+θj |
Exponential | f(x;θ)=1θe−xθ, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ,b(x)=1, g(x)=x,h(θ)=1θ |
pij=θiθi+θj |
Gamma | f(x;θ)=θ12Γ(12)x12−1e−θx, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=√θ,b(x)=1Γ(12)√x, g(x)=−x,h(θ)=θ |
pij=2πtan−1√θiθj |
Maxwell | f(x;θ)=√2πx2θ3e−x22θ2, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ3,b(x)=√2πx2, g(x)=−x22,h(θ)=1θ2 |
pij=1+2π{θ3iθj−θiθ3j(θ2i+θ2j)2−tan−1(θjθi)} |
Rayleigh | f(x;θ)=xθ2e−x22θ2, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ2,b(x)=x, g(x)=−x22,h(θ)=1θ2 |
pij=θ2iθ2i+θ2j |
Weibull | f(x;θ)=3x2θ3e−x3θ3, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ3,b(x)=3x2, g(x)=−x3,h(θ)=1θ3 |
pij=θ3iθ3i+θ3j |
(i, j) | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||
rij | rji | rij | rji | |
(1, 2) | 10 | 5 | 32 | 18 |
(1, 3) | 9 | 6 | 38 | 12 |
(2, 3) | 11 | 4 | 28 | 22 |
Models | Estimators | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||
Jeffreys | Uniform | Jeffreys | Uniform | ||
Beta | ^θ1 | 0.4424 | 0.4424 | 0.5205 | 0.5205 |
^θ2 | 0.3477 | 0.3477 | 0.2783 | 0.2783 | |
^θ3 | 0.2099 | 0.2099 | 0.2012 | 0.2012 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0576 | 0.0576 | 0.0205 | 0.0205 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0477 | 0.0477 | 0.0217 | 0.0217 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0099 | 0.0099 | 0.0012 | 0.0012 | |
Exponential | ^θ1 | 0.4615 | 0.4465 | 0.5376 | 0.5302 |
^θ2 | 0.3434 | 0.3472 | 0.2710 | 0.2738 | |
^θ3 | 0.1952 | 0.2063 | 0.1914 | 0.1960 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0385 | 0.0535 | 0.0376 | 0.0302 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0434 | 0.0472 | 0.0290 | 0.0262 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0048 | 0.0063 | 0.0086 | 0.0040 | |
Power | ^θ1 | 0.4615 | 0.4465 | 0.5376 | 0.5302 |
^θ2 | 0.3434 | 0.3472 | 0.2710 | 0.2738 | |
^θ3 | 0.1952 | 0.2063 | 0.1914 | 0.1960 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0385 | 0.0535 | 0.0376 | 0.0302 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0434 | 0.0472 | 0.0290 | 0.0262 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0048 | 0.0063 | 0.0086 | 0.0040 | |
Gamma | ^θ1 | 0.4872 | 0.4872 | 0.6260 | 0.6260 |
^θ2 | 0.3470 | 0.3470 | 0.2340 | 0.2340 | |
^θ3 | 0.1658 | 0.1658 | 0.1400 | 0.1400 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0128 | 0.0128 | 0.1260 | 0.1260 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0470 | 0.0470 | 0.0660 | 0.0660 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0342 | 0.0342 | 0.0600 | 0.0600 | |
Maxwell | ^θ1 | 0.4287 | 0.4287 | 0.6294 | 0.6294 |
^θ2 | 0.3748 | 0.3748 | 0.2334 | 0.2334 | |
^θ3 | 0.1966 | 0.1966 | 0.1372 | 0.1372 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0713 | 0.0713 | 0.1294 | 0.1294 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0748 | 0.0748 | 0.0666 | 0.0666 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0034 | 0.0034 | 0.0628 | 0.0628 | |
Rayleigh | ^θ1 | 0.3972 | 0.3962 | 0.4336 | 0.4332 |
^θ2 | 0.3432 | 0.3442 | 0.3074 | 0.3076 | |
^θ3 | 0.2597 | 0.2596 | 0.2591 | 0.2592 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.1028 | 0.1038 | 0.0664 | 0.0668 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0432 | 0.0442 | 0.0074 | 0.0076 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0597 | 0.0596 | 0.0591 | 0.0592 | |
Weibull | ^θ1 | 0.3756 | 0.3761 | 0.3992 | 0.3996 |
^θ2 | 0.3411 | 0.3417 | 0.3174 | 0.3176 | |
^θ3 | 0.2834 | 0.2822 | 0.2834 | 0.2829 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.1244 | 0.1239 | 0.1008 | 0.1004 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0411 | 0.0417 | 0.0174 | 0.0176 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0834 | 0.0822 | 0.0834 | 0.0829 |
Models | Preferences | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||
Jeffreys | Uniform | Jeffreys | Uniform | ||
Beta | ^p12 | 0.5636 | 0.5636 | 0.6603 | 0.6603 |
^p13 | 0.6858 | 0.6858 | 0.7311 | 0.7311 | |
^p23 | 0.6281 | 0.6281 | 0.5829 | 0.5829 | |
Exponential | ^p12 | 0.5734 | 0.5626 | 0.6649 | 0.6595 |
^p13 | 0.7028 | 0.6840 | 0.7374 | 0.7301 | |
^p23 | 0.6376 | 0.6273 | 0.5861 | 0.5828 | |
Power | ^p12 | 0.5734 | 0.5626 | 0.6649 | 0.6595 |
^p13 | 0.7028 | 0.6840 | 0.7374 | 0.7301 | |
^p23 | 0.6376 | 0.6273 | 0.5861 | 0.5828 | |
Gamma | ^p12 | 0.5535 | 0.5535 | 0.6504 | 0.6504 |
^p13 | 0.6635 | 0.6635 | 0.7185 | 0.7185 | |
^p23 | 0.6147 | 0.6147 | 0.5806 | 0.5806 | |
Maxwell | ^p12 | 0.5849 | 0.5849 | 0.9313 | 0.9313 |
^p13 | 0.8837 | 0.8837 | 0.9838 | 0.9838 | |
^p23 | 0.8414 | 0.8414 | 0.7970 | 0.7970 | |
Rayleigh | ^p12 | 0.5725 | 0.5699 | 0.6655 | 0.6648 |
^p13 | 0.7005 | 0.6996 | 0.7369 | 0.7364 | |
^p23 | 0.6359 | 0.6374 | 0.5846 | 0.5848 | |
Weibull | ^p12 | 0.5718 | 0.5714 | 0.6655 | 0.6657 |
^p13 | 0.6995 | 0.7030 | 0.7365 | 0.7381 | |
^p23 | 0.6355 | 0.6397 | 0.5842 | 0.5859 |
Models | Hypotheses | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||||||
Jeffreys | Uniform | Jeffreys | Uniform | ||||||
Pij | BF | Pij | BF | Pij | BF | Pij | BF | ||
Beta | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7331 | 2.7467 | 0.7234 | 2.6153 | 0.9975 | 399.0000 | 0.9971 | 343.8276 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9696 | 31.8947 | 0.9671 | 29.3951 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8958 | 8.5969 | 0.8882 | 7.9445 | 0.9209 | 11.6422 | 0.9082 | 9.8932 | |
Exponential | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7320 | 2.7313 | 0.7228 | 2.6075 | 0.9975 | 399.0000 | 0.9971 | 343.8276 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9691 | 31.3625 | 0.9666 | 28.9401 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8954 | 8.5602 | 0.8879 | 7.9206 | 0.9207 | 11.6103 | 0.9081 | 9.8932 | |
Power | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7320 | 2.7313 | 0.7228 | 2.6075 | 0.9975 | 399.0000 | 0.9971 | 343.8276 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9691 | 31.3625 | 0.9666 | 28.9401 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8954 | 8.5602 | 0.8879 | 7.9206 | 0.9207 | 11.6103 | 0.9081 | 9.8932 | |
Gamma | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7218 | 2.5945 | 0.7156 | 2.5162 | 0.9968 | 311.5000 | 0.9965 | 284.7143 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9626 | 25.7380 | 0.9606 | 24.3807 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8876 | 7.8968 | 0.8816 | 7.4459 | 0.9175 | 11.1212 | 0.9066 | 9.7066 | |
Maxwell | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7379 | 2.8153 | 0.7135 | 2.4904 | 0.9977 | 433.7826 | 0.9967 | 302.0303 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9730 | 36.0370 | 0.9676 | 29.8642 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.9008 | 9.0806 | 0.8852 | 7.7108 | 0.9217 | 11.7714 | 0.8961 | 8.6246 | |
Rayleigh | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7398 | 2.8432 | 0.7212 | 2.5868 | 0.9977 | 433.7826 | 0.9969 | 321.5806 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9730 | 36.0370 | 0.9688 | 31.0513 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.9014 | 9.1420 | 0.8890 | 8.0090 | 0.9216 | 11.7551 | 0.9020 | 9.2041 | |
Weibull | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7405 | 2.8536 | 0.7118 | 2.4698 | 0.9977 | 433.7826 | 0.9964 | 276.7778 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9736 | 36.8788 | 0.9674 | 29.6748 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.9023 | 9.2354 | 0.8843 | 7.6430 | 0.9211 | 11.6743 | 0.8912 | 8.1912 |
Pairs | rij | rji | nij |
(AQ,NT=1,2) | 14 (40%) | 21 (60%) | 35 |
(AQ,KL=1,3) | 22 (62.8%) | 13 (37.1%) | 35 |
(NT,KL=2,3) | 20 (57.1%) | 15 (42.8%) | 35 |
Models | Estimated Parameters | Jeffreys | Uniform |
Beta | ˆθAQ | 0.3398 | 0.3398 |
ˆθNT | 0.4057 | 0.4057 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2544 | 0.2544 | |
Exponential | ˆθAQ | 0.3414 | 0.3396 |
ˆθNT | 0.4108 | 0.4091 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2478 | 0.2514 | |
Power | ˆθAQ | 0.3414 | 0.3396 |
ˆθNT | 0.4108 | 0.4091 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2478 | 0.2514 | |
Gamma | ˆθAQ | 0.3388 | 0.3388 |
ˆθNT | 0.4455 | 0.4455 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2157 | 0.2157 | |
Maxwell | ˆθAQ | 0.3520 | 0.3520 |
ˆθNT | 0.4137 | 0.4137 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2343 | 0.2343 | |
Rayleigh | ˆθAQ | 0.3384 | 0.3381 |
ˆθNT | 0.3723 | 0.3726 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2892 | 0.2893 | |
Weibull | ˆθAQ | 0.3370 | 0.3369 |
ˆθNT | 0.3593 | 0.3597 | |
ˆθKL | 0.3037 | 0.3034 |
Models | Preference probabilities | Jeffreys | Uniform |
Beta | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4533 | 0.4533 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5749 | 0.5749 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6200 | 0.6200 | |
Exponential | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4539 | 0.4536 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5794 | 0.5746 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6237 | 0.6194 | |
Power | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4539 | 0.4536 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5794 | 0.5746 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6237 | 0.6194 | |
Gamma | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4564 | 0.4564 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5710 | 0.5710 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6127 | 0.6127 | |
Maxwell | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.3987 | 0.3987 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.7395 | 0.7395 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.8124 | 0.8124 | |
Rayleigh | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4524 | 0.4516 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5779 | 0.5773 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6237 | 0.6239 | |
Weibull | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4521 | 0.4510 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5774 | 0.5779 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6235 | 0.6250 |
Models | Hypotheses | nij=35 | |||
Jeffreys | Uniform | ||||
Pij | BF | Pij | BF | ||
Beta | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2297 | 0.2982 | 0.2297 | 0.2982 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8505 | 5.6890 | 0.8505 | 5.6890 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9580 | 22.8095 | 0.9580 | 22.8095 | |
Exponential | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2311 | 0.3006 | 0.2236 | 0.2880 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8506 | 5.6934 | 0.8434 | 5.3857 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9579 | 22.7530 | 0.9554 | 21.4215 | |
Power | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2311 | 0.3006 | 0.2236 | 0.2880 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8506 | 5.6934 | 0.8434 | 5.3857 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9579 | 22.7530 | 0.9554 | 21.4215 | |
Gamma | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2417 | 0.3187 | 0.2417 | 0.3187 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8508 | 5.7024 | 0.8508 | 5.7024 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9561 | 21.7790 | 0.9561 | 21.7790 | |
Maxwell | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2035 | 0.2555 | 0.2035 | 0.2555 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8349 | 5.0569 | 0.8349 | 5.0569 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9530 | 20.2766 | 0.9530 | 20.2766 | |
Rayleigh | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2088 | 0.2639 | 0.2118 | 0.2687 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8393 | 5.2228 | 0.8420 | 5.3291 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9546 | 21.0264 | 0.9556 | 21.5225 | |
Weibull | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.1912 | 0.2364 | 0.1956 | 0.2432 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8260 | 4.7471 | 0.8301 | 4.8858 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9497 | 18.8807 | 0.9512 | 14.9.4918 |
Items | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | - | m |
1 | - | Y | Y | Y | N | - | Y |
2 | - | N | N | N | - | N | |
3 | - | N | Y | - | Y | ||
4 | - | Y | - | Y | |||
5 | - | - | N | ||||
- | - | - | |||||
m | - |
Model | p.d.f. | Exponential family f(x;θ)=a(θ)b(x)eg(x)h(θ) |
Preference probability (pij) |
Beta | f(x;θ)=xθ−1(1−x)B(θ,2), 0<x<1 |
a(θ)=θ(θ+1),b(x)=(1−x), g(x)=lnx,h(θ)=(θ−1) |
pij=θi(1+θi)(2+θi+3θj)(θi+θj)(1+θi+θj)(2+θi+θj) |
Power | f(x;θ)=θxθ−1, 0<x<1 |
a(θ)=θ,b(x)=1, g(x)=lnx,h(θ)=(θ−1) |
pij=θiθi+θj |
Exponential | f(x;θ)=1θe−xθ, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ,b(x)=1, g(x)=x,h(θ)=1θ |
pij=θiθi+θj |
Gamma | f(x;θ)=θ12Γ(12)x12−1e−θx, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=√θ,b(x)=1Γ(12)√x, g(x)=−x,h(θ)=θ |
pij=2πtan−1√θiθj |
Maxwell | f(x;θ)=√2πx2θ3e−x22θ2, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ3,b(x)=√2πx2, g(x)=−x22,h(θ)=1θ2 |
pij=1+2π{θ3iθj−θiθ3j(θ2i+θ2j)2−tan−1(θjθi)} |
Rayleigh | f(x;θ)=xθ2e−x22θ2, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ2,b(x)=x, g(x)=−x22,h(θ)=1θ2 |
pij=θ2iθ2i+θ2j |
Weibull | f(x;θ)=3x2θ3e−x3θ3, 0<x<∞ |
a(θ)=1θ3,b(x)=3x2, g(x)=−x3,h(θ)=1θ3 |
pij=θ3iθ3i+θ3j |
(i, j) | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||
rij | rji | rij | rji | |
(1, 2) | 10 | 5 | 32 | 18 |
(1, 3) | 9 | 6 | 38 | 12 |
(2, 3) | 11 | 4 | 28 | 22 |
Models | Estimators | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||
Jeffreys | Uniform | Jeffreys | Uniform | ||
Beta | ^θ1 | 0.4424 | 0.4424 | 0.5205 | 0.5205 |
^θ2 | 0.3477 | 0.3477 | 0.2783 | 0.2783 | |
^θ3 | 0.2099 | 0.2099 | 0.2012 | 0.2012 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0576 | 0.0576 | 0.0205 | 0.0205 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0477 | 0.0477 | 0.0217 | 0.0217 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0099 | 0.0099 | 0.0012 | 0.0012 | |
Exponential | ^θ1 | 0.4615 | 0.4465 | 0.5376 | 0.5302 |
^θ2 | 0.3434 | 0.3472 | 0.2710 | 0.2738 | |
^θ3 | 0.1952 | 0.2063 | 0.1914 | 0.1960 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0385 | 0.0535 | 0.0376 | 0.0302 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0434 | 0.0472 | 0.0290 | 0.0262 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0048 | 0.0063 | 0.0086 | 0.0040 | |
Power | ^θ1 | 0.4615 | 0.4465 | 0.5376 | 0.5302 |
^θ2 | 0.3434 | 0.3472 | 0.2710 | 0.2738 | |
^θ3 | 0.1952 | 0.2063 | 0.1914 | 0.1960 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0385 | 0.0535 | 0.0376 | 0.0302 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0434 | 0.0472 | 0.0290 | 0.0262 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0048 | 0.0063 | 0.0086 | 0.0040 | |
Gamma | ^θ1 | 0.4872 | 0.4872 | 0.6260 | 0.6260 |
^θ2 | 0.3470 | 0.3470 | 0.2340 | 0.2340 | |
^θ3 | 0.1658 | 0.1658 | 0.1400 | 0.1400 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0128 | 0.0128 | 0.1260 | 0.1260 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0470 | 0.0470 | 0.0660 | 0.0660 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0342 | 0.0342 | 0.0600 | 0.0600 | |
Maxwell | ^θ1 | 0.4287 | 0.4287 | 0.6294 | 0.6294 |
^θ2 | 0.3748 | 0.3748 | 0.2334 | 0.2334 | |
^θ3 | 0.1966 | 0.1966 | 0.1372 | 0.1372 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.0713 | 0.0713 | 0.1294 | 0.1294 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0748 | 0.0748 | 0.0666 | 0.0666 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0034 | 0.0034 | 0.0628 | 0.0628 | |
Rayleigh | ^θ1 | 0.3972 | 0.3962 | 0.4336 | 0.4332 |
^θ2 | 0.3432 | 0.3442 | 0.3074 | 0.3076 | |
^θ3 | 0.2597 | 0.2596 | 0.2591 | 0.2592 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.1028 | 0.1038 | 0.0664 | 0.0668 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0432 | 0.0442 | 0.0074 | 0.0076 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0597 | 0.0596 | 0.0591 | 0.0592 | |
Weibull | ^θ1 | 0.3756 | 0.3761 | 0.3992 | 0.3996 |
^θ2 | 0.3411 | 0.3417 | 0.3174 | 0.3176 | |
^θ3 | 0.2834 | 0.2822 | 0.2834 | 0.2829 | |
|^θ1−θ1| | 0.1244 | 0.1239 | 0.1008 | 0.1004 | |
|^θ2−θ2| | 0.0411 | 0.0417 | 0.0174 | 0.0176 | |
|^θ3−θ3| | 0.0834 | 0.0822 | 0.0834 | 0.0829 |
Models | Preferences | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||
Jeffreys | Uniform | Jeffreys | Uniform | ||
Beta | ^p12 | 0.5636 | 0.5636 | 0.6603 | 0.6603 |
^p13 | 0.6858 | 0.6858 | 0.7311 | 0.7311 | |
^p23 | 0.6281 | 0.6281 | 0.5829 | 0.5829 | |
Exponential | ^p12 | 0.5734 | 0.5626 | 0.6649 | 0.6595 |
^p13 | 0.7028 | 0.6840 | 0.7374 | 0.7301 | |
^p23 | 0.6376 | 0.6273 | 0.5861 | 0.5828 | |
Power | ^p12 | 0.5734 | 0.5626 | 0.6649 | 0.6595 |
^p13 | 0.7028 | 0.6840 | 0.7374 | 0.7301 | |
^p23 | 0.6376 | 0.6273 | 0.5861 | 0.5828 | |
Gamma | ^p12 | 0.5535 | 0.5535 | 0.6504 | 0.6504 |
^p13 | 0.6635 | 0.6635 | 0.7185 | 0.7185 | |
^p23 | 0.6147 | 0.6147 | 0.5806 | 0.5806 | |
Maxwell | ^p12 | 0.5849 | 0.5849 | 0.9313 | 0.9313 |
^p13 | 0.8837 | 0.8837 | 0.9838 | 0.9838 | |
^p23 | 0.8414 | 0.8414 | 0.7970 | 0.7970 | |
Rayleigh | ^p12 | 0.5725 | 0.5699 | 0.6655 | 0.6648 |
^p13 | 0.7005 | 0.6996 | 0.7369 | 0.7364 | |
^p23 | 0.6359 | 0.6374 | 0.5846 | 0.5848 | |
Weibull | ^p12 | 0.5718 | 0.5714 | 0.6655 | 0.6657 |
^p13 | 0.6995 | 0.7030 | 0.7365 | 0.7381 | |
^p23 | 0.6355 | 0.6397 | 0.5842 | 0.5859 |
Models | Hypotheses | nij=15 | nij=50 | ||||||
Jeffreys | Uniform | Jeffreys | Uniform | ||||||
Pij | BF | Pij | BF | Pij | BF | Pij | BF | ||
Beta | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7331 | 2.7467 | 0.7234 | 2.6153 | 0.9975 | 399.0000 | 0.9971 | 343.8276 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9696 | 31.8947 | 0.9671 | 29.3951 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8958 | 8.5969 | 0.8882 | 7.9445 | 0.9209 | 11.6422 | 0.9082 | 9.8932 | |
Exponential | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7320 | 2.7313 | 0.7228 | 2.6075 | 0.9975 | 399.0000 | 0.9971 | 343.8276 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9691 | 31.3625 | 0.9666 | 28.9401 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8954 | 8.5602 | 0.8879 | 7.9206 | 0.9207 | 11.6103 | 0.9081 | 9.8932 | |
Power | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7320 | 2.7313 | 0.7228 | 2.6075 | 0.9975 | 399.0000 | 0.9971 | 343.8276 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9691 | 31.3625 | 0.9666 | 28.9401 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8954 | 8.5602 | 0.8879 | 7.9206 | 0.9207 | 11.6103 | 0.9081 | 9.8932 | |
Gamma | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7218 | 2.5945 | 0.7156 | 2.5162 | 0.9968 | 311.5000 | 0.9965 | 284.7143 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9626 | 25.7380 | 0.9606 | 24.3807 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.8876 | 7.8968 | 0.8816 | 7.4459 | 0.9175 | 11.1212 | 0.9066 | 9.7066 | |
Maxwell | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7379 | 2.8153 | 0.7135 | 2.4904 | 0.9977 | 433.7826 | 0.9967 | 302.0303 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9730 | 36.0370 | 0.9676 | 29.8642 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.9008 | 9.0806 | 0.8852 | 7.7108 | 0.9217 | 11.7714 | 0.8961 | 8.6246 | |
Rayleigh | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7398 | 2.8432 | 0.7212 | 2.5868 | 0.9977 | 433.7826 | 0.9969 | 321.5806 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9730 | 36.0370 | 0.9688 | 31.0513 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.9014 | 9.1420 | 0.8890 | 8.0090 | 0.9216 | 11.7551 | 0.9020 | 9.2041 | |
Weibull | H12:θ1≥θ2 | 0.7405 | 2.8536 | 0.7118 | 2.4698 | 0.9977 | 433.7826 | 0.9964 | 276.7778 |
H13:θ1≥θ3 | 0.9736 | 36.8788 | 0.9674 | 29.6748 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | 0.9999 | 9999.0000 | |
H23:θ2≥θ3 | 0.9023 | 9.2354 | 0.8843 | 7.6430 | 0.9211 | 11.6743 | 0.8912 | 8.1912 |
Pairs | rij | rji | nij |
(AQ,NT=1,2) | 14 (40%) | 21 (60%) | 35 |
(AQ,KL=1,3) | 22 (62.8%) | 13 (37.1%) | 35 |
(NT,KL=2,3) | 20 (57.1%) | 15 (42.8%) | 35 |
Models | Estimated Parameters | Jeffreys | Uniform |
Beta | ˆθAQ | 0.3398 | 0.3398 |
ˆθNT | 0.4057 | 0.4057 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2544 | 0.2544 | |
Exponential | ˆθAQ | 0.3414 | 0.3396 |
ˆθNT | 0.4108 | 0.4091 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2478 | 0.2514 | |
Power | ˆθAQ | 0.3414 | 0.3396 |
ˆθNT | 0.4108 | 0.4091 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2478 | 0.2514 | |
Gamma | ˆθAQ | 0.3388 | 0.3388 |
ˆθNT | 0.4455 | 0.4455 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2157 | 0.2157 | |
Maxwell | ˆθAQ | 0.3520 | 0.3520 |
ˆθNT | 0.4137 | 0.4137 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2343 | 0.2343 | |
Rayleigh | ˆθAQ | 0.3384 | 0.3381 |
ˆθNT | 0.3723 | 0.3726 | |
ˆθKL | 0.2892 | 0.2893 | |
Weibull | ˆθAQ | 0.3370 | 0.3369 |
ˆθNT | 0.3593 | 0.3597 | |
ˆθKL | 0.3037 | 0.3034 |
Models | Preference probabilities | Jeffreys | Uniform |
Beta | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4533 | 0.4533 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5749 | 0.5749 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6200 | 0.6200 | |
Exponential | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4539 | 0.4536 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5794 | 0.5746 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6237 | 0.6194 | |
Power | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4539 | 0.4536 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5794 | 0.5746 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6237 | 0.6194 | |
Gamma | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4564 | 0.4564 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5710 | 0.5710 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6127 | 0.6127 | |
Maxwell | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.3987 | 0.3987 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.7395 | 0.7395 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.8124 | 0.8124 | |
Rayleigh | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4524 | 0.4516 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5779 | 0.5773 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6237 | 0.6239 | |
Weibull | ˆpAQ,NT | 0.4521 | 0.4510 |
ˆpAQ,KL | 0.5774 | 0.5779 | |
ˆpNT,KL | 0.6235 | 0.6250 |
Models | Hypotheses | nij=35 | |||
Jeffreys | Uniform | ||||
Pij | BF | Pij | BF | ||
Beta | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2297 | 0.2982 | 0.2297 | 0.2982 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8505 | 5.6890 | 0.8505 | 5.6890 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9580 | 22.8095 | 0.9580 | 22.8095 | |
Exponential | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2311 | 0.3006 | 0.2236 | 0.2880 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8506 | 5.6934 | 0.8434 | 5.3857 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9579 | 22.7530 | 0.9554 | 21.4215 | |
Power | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2311 | 0.3006 | 0.2236 | 0.2880 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8506 | 5.6934 | 0.8434 | 5.3857 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9579 | 22.7530 | 0.9554 | 21.4215 | |
Gamma | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2417 | 0.3187 | 0.2417 | 0.3187 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8508 | 5.7024 | 0.8508 | 5.7024 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9561 | 21.7790 | 0.9561 | 21.7790 | |
Maxwell | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2035 | 0.2555 | 0.2035 | 0.2555 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8349 | 5.0569 | 0.8349 | 5.0569 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9530 | 20.2766 | 0.9530 | 20.2766 | |
Rayleigh | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.2088 | 0.2639 | 0.2118 | 0.2687 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8393 | 5.2228 | 0.8420 | 5.3291 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9546 | 21.0264 | 0.9556 | 21.5225 | |
Weibull | H12:θAQ≥θNT | 0.1912 | 0.2364 | 0.1956 | 0.2432 |
H13:θAQ≥θKL | 0.8260 | 4.7471 | 0.8301 | 4.8858 | |
H23:θNT≥θKL | 0.9497 | 18.8807 | 0.9512 | 14.9.4918 |