Research article

Factors influencing the adoption of improved wheat varieties by rural households in Sindh, Pakistan

  • This study examines the factors affecting the adoption of high-yield wheat varieties by wheat farmers in Sindh, Pakistan. A cross-sectional data of randomly selected 240 wheat farmers from Shaheed Benazirabad and Naushahro Feroze districts in the middle region of Sindh, Pakistan were collected for this study. We performed the probit model to estimate factors that influence the adoption of improved wheat varieties. The results drawn from the estimations show that the adoption of improved wheat varieties by farmers in the study area was positively and significantly influenced by education, farming experience, landholding size, tube-well ownership, extension contact and access to credit. The study recommends that public and private sectors should encourage access to extension service to improve of dissemination of certified seed of wheat crop among the growers through trainings, workshops and seminars.

    Citation: Abbas Ali Chandio, Yuansheng Jiang. Factors influencing the adoption of improved wheat varieties by rural households in Sindh, Pakistan[J]. AIMS Agriculture and Food, 2018, 3(3): 216-228. doi: 10.3934/agrfood.2018.3.216

    Related Papers:

    [1] Juan-Carlos Felipe-Navarro, Tomás Sanz-Perela . Semilinear integro-differential equations, Ⅱ: one-dimensional and saddle-shaped solutions to the Allen-Cahn equation. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(5): 1-36. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021037
    [2] Francesca G. Alessio, Piero Montecchiari . Gradient Lagrangian systems and semilinear PDE. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(6): 1-28. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021044
    [3] David Cruz-Uribe, Michael Penrod, Scott Rodney . Poincaré inequalities and Neumann problems for the variable exponent setting. Mathematics in Engineering, 2022, 4(5): 1-22. doi: 10.3934/mine.2022036
    [4] Antonio Vitolo . Singular elliptic equations with directional diffusion. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(3): 1-16. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021027
    [5] Luigi Montoro, Berardino Sciunzi . Qualitative properties of solutions to the Dirichlet problem for a Laplace equation involving the Hardy potential with possibly boundary singularity. Mathematics in Engineering, 2023, 5(1): 1-16. doi: 10.3934/mine.2023017
    [6] Italo Capuzzo Dolcetta . The weak maximum principle for degenerate elliptic equations: unbounded domains and systems. Mathematics in Engineering, 2020, 2(4): 772-786. doi: 10.3934/mine.2020036
    [7] Edgard A. Pimentel, Miguel Walker . Potential estimates for fully nonlinear elliptic equations with bounded ingredients. Mathematics in Engineering, 2023, 5(3): 1-16. doi: 10.3934/mine.2023063
    [8] Marco Cirant, Kevin R. Payne . Comparison principles for viscosity solutions of elliptic branches of fully nonlinear equations independent of the gradient. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(4): 1-45. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021030
    [9] Filippo Gazzola, Gianmarco Sperone . Remarks on radial symmetry and monotonicity for solutions of semilinear higher order elliptic equations. Mathematics in Engineering, 2022, 4(5): 1-24. doi: 10.3934/mine.2022040
    [10] Yuzhe Zhu . Propagation of smallness for solutions of elliptic equations in the plane. Mathematics in Engineering, 2025, 7(1): 1-12. doi: 10.3934/mine.2025001
  • This study examines the factors affecting the adoption of high-yield wheat varieties by wheat farmers in Sindh, Pakistan. A cross-sectional data of randomly selected 240 wheat farmers from Shaheed Benazirabad and Naushahro Feroze districts in the middle region of Sindh, Pakistan were collected for this study. We performed the probit model to estimate factors that influence the adoption of improved wheat varieties. The results drawn from the estimations show that the adoption of improved wheat varieties by farmers in the study area was positively and significantly influenced by education, farming experience, landholding size, tube-well ownership, extension contact and access to credit. The study recommends that public and private sectors should encourage access to extension service to improve of dissemination of certified seed of wheat crop among the growers through trainings, workshops and seminars.


    To Sandro Salsa, a fine mathematician with a taste for life.

    In this paper we consider some entire solutions of a degenerate elliptic equation with non linear forcing term, where the behaviour of the solutions is quite different from the uniformly elliptic case.

    We begin by recalling the linear uniformly elliptic model problem we have in mind in order to underline the differences with the degenerate elliptic case that we shall treat here. Consider the entire solutions of the Allen-Cahn equation

    Δu+uu3=0in  RN (1.1)

    where N2.

    Writing the variable as x=(x,xN), with xNR, we are interested in solutions that satisfy the following conditions:

    |u|<1  and limxN±u(x,xN)=±1  uniformly in xRN1. (1.2)

    Any solution of (1.1) satisfying (1.2) is necessarily a function of xN, i.e. it is independent of x. This was referred to as Gibbons conjecture and it has been proved by several authors [3, 5, 18, 19] and then it has been generalized to different contexts [15,20,23]. It is well known that this conjecture is somehow related to a famous conjecture of De Giorgi on the 1 dimensionality of monotone solutions in low dimension, see for its proof [4,21] in the 2 dimensional case, [2] for the 3 dimensional case and for higher cases with some mild further assumptions, the work of Savin [24]. For a counterexample in dimensions N9, providing a sharpness of the conjecture, was constructed by Del Pino, Kowalczyk and Wei in [17]

    The function f(u)=uu3 can be replaced by a much more general class of functions and the result is still valid. On the other hand, if instead of the Laplacian one considers some degenerate elliptic operators, there are few results, let us mention e.g., the works in the Heisenberg group and in Carnot groups [14,16].

    In this work we shall mainly focus on equations whose leading term is the operator Pk which is sometimes referred to as the truncated Laplacian. The operator Pk is defined, for any N×N symmetric matrix X, by the partial sum

    Pk(X)=λ1(X)++λk(X)

    of the ordered eigenvalues λ1λN of X. We shall consider solutions of the equation

    Pk(D2u)+f(u)=0in RN, (1.3)

    for a general class of functions f modelled on f(u)=uu3. Clearly Pk(D2u) corresponds to the Laplacian when k=N, hence in the whole paper we shall suppose that k=1,,N1.

    These operators are degenerate elliptic in the sense that

    XYPk(X)Pk(Y).

    In order to emphasize the strong degeneracy of these operators, let us mention that for any matrix X there exists M0, not identically zero, such that

    Pk(X)=Pk(X+M).

    It is immediate to see that, for example, one can take M=vNvN where vN is an eigenvector corresponding to the largest eigenvalue of X.

    In previous works we have, together with Hitoshi Ishii and/or Fabiana Leoni [9,10,11,13], encountered a certain number of surprising results, related to these degenerate operators. It would be too long to recall them all here but we shall briefly recall some of those closer to the results in this paper.

    The classical Liouville result states that any harmonic function which is bounded from below is a constant. This is not true for bounded from below entire solutions of Pk(D2u)=0.

    Similarly, concerning the semi-linear Liouville theorem, the existence of entire non negative solutions of F(D2u)+up=0 is quite different if F(D2u)=Δu or if F(D2u)=Pk(D2u). Indeed, for the Laplacian there is a threshold for p between existence and non existence. This threshold is different for solutions and supersolutions and it depends on the dimension of the space. Instead, for solutions of the equation

    Pk(D2u)+up=0 in  RN (1.4)

    the following hold:

    1). For any p>0 there exist nonnegative viscosity solutions u0;

    2). For any p1 there exist positive classical solutions;

    3). For p<1 there are no positive viscosity supersolutions of (1.4).

    Interestingly, if one considers instead non positive solutions, the non existence results are very similar to those of the Laplacian in Rk. These Liouville theorems were proved in [13].

    Hence this lead us to wonder what happens to bounded entire solutions of the equation

    Pk(D2u)+uu3=0 (1.5)

    which satisfy |u|<1 and which, a priori, may change sign. Can one expect solutions to be one dimensional? Precisely, can we extend Gibbons conjecture to this degenerate case?

    In order to answer these questions the first step is to study the one dimensional solutions, which is what we do in Section 2. Interestingly the results are completely different from the uniformly elliptic case and this leads to different conjectures. Precisely, we consider only one dimensional solutions u(x,xN)=v(xN) of (1.5) that satisfy |u|<1. The results can be summarized in the following way:

    1). The only classical solution is u0;

    2). Any viscosity subsolution is non negative and there exists a non trivial viscosity solution that satisfies

    limxNv(xN)=0  and limxNv(xN)=1. (1.6)

    3). There are no solutions that are strictly monotone or positive

    Observe that, even though u3u is the derivative of the double well potential F(u)=14(1u2)2, the lack of ellipticity does not allow the solutions to go from 1 to 1. This is the first surprising result.

    Hence Gibbons conjecture should be reformulated in the following way:

    Question 1. Is it true that if u is a solution of (1.5), |u|<1, satisfying

    limxNu(x,xN)=1  and limxNu(x,xN)=1 uniformly in xRN1

    then u is 1 dimensional?

    If the answer was positive, this would imply that there are no solutions of (1.5) that satisfies (1.2), since such one dimensional solutions don't exist in view of point 2 above. Or, equivalently, if such a solution of (1.5) exists then the answer to Question 1 is negative.

    Question 2. Is it true that if u is a solution of (1.5), |u|<1, satisfying

    limxNu(x,xN)=0  and limxNu(x,xN)=1 uniformly in xRN1

    then u is 1 dimensional?

    This is more similar in nature to the uniformly elliptic case. Nonetheless, classical proofs of these symmetry results rely heavily on the strong maximum principle, or strong comparison principle, and on the sliding method and the moving plane method [7], which in general don't hold for the truncated Laplacian (see [9,12]). And in particular they are not true here since we construct ordered solutions that touch but don't coincide.

    Another remark we wish to make is that, even though the solutions we consider are one dimensional, since they are viscosity solutions, the test functions are not necessarily one dimensional. Hence the proofs are not of ODE type.

    Other surprising results concern Liouville type theorems for (1.5) i.e., existence of bounded entire solutions bounded without requiring conditions at infinity. Aronson and Weinberger in [1] and more explicitly, Berestycki, Hamel and Nadirashvili in [6] have proved the following Liouville type result:

    If v is a bounded non negative classical solution of

    Δu+uu3=0  in  RN

    then either u0 or u1.

    Once again this result fails if one replaces the Laplacian with the truncated Laplacian.

    Indeed we prove that there exists infinitely many bounded non negative smooth solutions of

    Pk(D2u)+f(u)=0, in RN

    for a general class of nonlinearities that includes f(u)=uu3. This is done by constructing infinitely many radial solutions of Pk(D2u)+f(u)=0 which are positive in RN but tend to zero at infinity.

    Finally in Section 4 we show a different surprising phenomena related to the so called principal eigenvalue of Pk. This is somehow different in nature but we believe that it sheds some light to these extremal degenerate operators.

    We consider one dimensional viscosity solutions u, i.e., u(x)=v(xN) for x=(x1,,xN), of the problem

    {Pk(D2u)+uu3=0in RN|u|<1. (2.1)

    The main result is the following.

    Proposition 1. Concerning problem (2.1), the following hold:

    i) If uUSC(RN) is a viscosity one dimensional subsolution then u0.

    ii) The only classical one dimensional solution is u0.

    iii) There exist nontrivial viscosity one dimensional solutions, e.g., u(x)=v(xN), satisfying either

    limxNv(xN)=0 andlimxNv(xN)=1. (2.2)

    or

    limxN±v(xN)=1. (2.3)

    iv) There are no positive viscosity one dimensional supersolutions.

    v) If u0 is a viscosity one dimensional supersolution e.g., u(x)=v(xN) and it is nondecreasing in the xN-direction then there exists t0R such that

    u=0 in X0={xRN:xNt0}.

    Remark 1. A consequence of i) and v) is that there are no viscosity one dimensional solutions increasing in the xN-direction.

    Proof. i) Fix ˆx=(ˆx1,,ˆxN)RN and, for α>0, let

    max¯B1(ˆx)[u(x)α(xNˆxN)2]=u(xα)α(xαNˆxN)2,xα¯B1(ˆx).

    Then

    α(xαNˆxN)2u(xα)u(ˆx)2,

    and

    limαxαN=ˆxN. (2.4)

    Moreover, using the one dimensional symmetry, for any x¯B1(ˆx) we have

    u(x)α(xNˆxN)2u(xα)α(xαNˆxN)2=u(ˆx1,,ˆxN1,xαN)α(xαNˆxN)2.

    Hence u(x)α(xNˆxN)2 has a maximum in (ˆx1,,ˆxN1,xαN)B1(ˆx) for α large in view of (2.4). Then

    u3(ˆx1,,ˆxN1,xαN)u(ˆx1,,ˆxN1,xαN)Pk(diag(0,,0,2α))=0.

    We deduce that u(ˆx1,,ˆxN1,xαN)0 for every α big enough. Using semicontinuity and (2.4) we conclude

    u(ˆx)lim supαu(ˆx1,,ˆxN1,xαN)0.

    ii) By contradiction, let us assume that u(x)=v(xN) is a classical solution of (2.1) and that v(t0)0 for some t0R. By i), v(t0)>0. Let

    δ=inf{t<t0:v>0in[t,t0]}andδ+=sup{t>t0:v>0in[t0,t]}.

    If δ= and δ+=+, then v>0 in R and, since v3v<0, we deduce by the Eq (2.1) that v(t)<0 for any tR. In particular v is concave in R, a contradiction to v>0.

    If δ>, then v(t)>0 for any t(δ,t0] and v(δ)=0. Moreover there exists ξ(δ,t0) such that v(ξ)>0. Using the Eq (2.1) we deduce that v0 in [δ,t0], hence v(δ)v(ξ)>0. This implies that for ε small enough v(δε)<0, a contradiction to i).

    The case δ+<+ is analogous.

    iii) Let u(x)=tanh(xN2). Then

    D2u=diag(0,,0,u3u).

    If xN0 then u3u0 and Pk(D2u)=u3u, while if xN<0 the function u fails to be a solution since Pk(D2u)=0<u3u.

    Instead we claim that

    ˜u(x)={tanh(xN2)if xN00otherwise

    is a viscosity solution of (2.1). This is obvious for xN0. Now take ˆx=(ˆx1,,ˆxN1,0). Since there are no test functions φ touching ˜u by above at ˆx, automatically ˜u is a subsolution. Let us prove the ˜u is also a supersolution. Let φC2(RN) such that φ(ˆx)=˜u(ˆx)=0 and φu in Bδ(ˆx). Our aim is to show that λN1(D2φ(ˆx))0, from which the conclusion follows.

    Let W0={wRN:wN=0} and for any wW0 such that |w|=1 let

    gw(t)=φ(ˆx+tw)t(δ,δ).

    Since φ touches ˜u from below at ˆx and ˜u=0 when xN=0, we deduce that gw(t) has a maximum point at t=0. Then

    gw(0)=D2φ(ˆx)w,w0.

    Using the Courant-Fischer formula

    λN1(D2φ(ˆx))=mindimW=N1maxwW,|w|=1D2φ(ˆx)w,wmaxwW0,|w|=1D2φ(ˆx)w,w0

    as we wanted to show.

    As above one can check that, for any c0, the one dimensional function

    ˜u(x)={tanh(xNc2)if xNc0if |xN|<ctanh(xN+c2)if xNc

    see figure 1, is non monotone in the xN-direction and it is a solution of (2.1).

    Figure 1.  The function ˜u.

    iv) By contradiction suppose that u(x)=v(xN) is a positive viscosity supersolution of (2.1). We claim that v is strictly concave, leading to a contradiction with v>0 in R.

    We first prove that v satisfies the inequality

    v(t)<0for any tR (2.5)

    in the viscosity sense. For this let φC2(R) be test function touching v from below at t0. If we consider φ as a function of N variables just by setting ˜φ(x)=φ(xN), then ˜φ is a test function touching u from below at (x1,,xN1,t0), for any (x1,,xN1)RN1. Hence

    Pk(diag(0,,0,φ(t0)))φ3(t0)φ(t0)<0

    and then necessarily φ(t0)<0.

    If v was not strictly concave, then there would exist t1<ˉt<t2R such that

    mint[t1,t2](v(t)v(t1)v(t2)v(t1)t2t1(tt1))=v(ˉt)v(t1)v(t2)v(t1)t2t1(ˉtt1)

    Then using φ(t)=v(t1)+v(t2)v(t1)t2t1(tt1) as a test function in (2.5) we obtain a contradiction.

    v) By iv) there exists t0R such that v(t0)=0. By the monotonicity assumption we get v(t)=0 for any tt0.

    This section is concerned with the existence of entire radial solutions of the equation

    Pk(D2u)+f(u)=0in RN, (3.1)

    where f:RR satisfies the following assumptions: there exists δ>0 such that

    {fC1((δ,δ))and it is nondecreasing in (δ,δ)f(u)>0u(0,δ)f(0)=0. (3.2)

    Prototypes of such nonlinearities are

    f(u)=αu+β|u|γ1u

    with α>0, γ>1 and any βR.

    Proposition 2. Under the assumptions (3.2) there exist infinitely many positive and bounded radial (classical) solutions of the Eq (3.1).

    Proof. For any α[0,δ) let vα be the solution of the initial value problem

    {vα(r)+rkf(vα(r))=0,r0vα(0)=α (3.3)

    defined in its maximal interval Iα=[0,ρα). Since v00, then vα(r)>0 for any rIα if α>0. We claim that Iα=[0,). For this first note that vα(r) is nonpositive in a neighborhood of the origin since, using (3.2)–(3.3), one has

    vα(0)=0andvα(0)=1kf(α)<0.

    If there was ξα(0,ρα) such that vα(r)<0 in (0,ξα) and vα(ξα)=0, then by monotonicity 0<vα(ξα)<α and by (3.3) we should obtain that f(vα(ξ))=0. But this is in contradiction with (3.2). Hence vα is monotone decreasing and positive, so Iα=[0,). Using again (3.3) we deduce moreover that limtvα(r)=0 and for any r>0

    vα(r)=vα(r)rrkf(vα(r))vα(r)vα(r)r. (3.4)

    In the last inequality we have used the facts that vα is monotone decreasing, 0<vα(r)<α for any r>0 and that f is nondecreasing in [0,δ) by assumption.

    By (3.3)

    vα(r)f(vα(r))=rk

    and a straightforward computation gives that the function vα can be written as

    vα(r)=F1(r22k), (3.5)

    F1 being the inverse function of F(τ)=ατ1f(s)ds in (0,α].

    From the above we easily deduce that for any α(0,δ) the radial function

    uα(x)=vα(|x|) (3.6)

    is a positive radial solution of (3.1).

    In the model case f(u)=uu3 the assumptions (3.2) are satisfied with δ=13. Moreover, for α(0,13], we have

    F(τ)=ατ1ss3ds=logα1α2logτ1τ2,forτ(0,α]

    and

    F1(r22k)=11+er2k+log1α2α2.

    Hence, by (3.5)–(3.6), we infer that the functions

    uα(x)=11+e|x|2k+log1α2α2,

    see figure 2, are smooth and positive radial solutions of

    Pk(D2u)+uu3=0in RN.
    Figure 2.  The function uα(x).

    Let us explicitly remark that the condition α(0,13] ensures the validity of the inequality (3.4).

    Let us recall that in [9], given a domain Ω, following Berestycki, Nirenberg and Varadhan [8] we define

    μk(Ω)=sup{μR:ϕUSC(Ω),ϕ<0  s.t.  Pk(D2ϕ)+μϕ0  in Ω}.

    We proved many results among them that μ1 could be called an eigenvalue since under the right conditions on Ω we construct ψ<0 solution of

    P1(D2ψ)+μ1ψ=0 in Ω, ψ=0 on Ω.

    But, differently from the uniformly elliptic case, μ1 does not satisfy the Faber-Krahn inequality, see [11].

    Another feature of μk is that it is the upper bound for the validity of the maximum principle. Precisely if μ<μk and

    Pk(D2v)+μv0 in Ω, v0 on Ω

    then v0 in Ω.

    It is well known that for uniformly elliptic operators, the principal eigenvalue goes to infinity when the domain decreases to a domain with zero Lebesgue measure.

    In this section we shall construct a sequence of domains QnR2 that collapse to a segment such that μ1(Qn) the principal eigenvalue of P1 stays bounded above by 1. Hence not only they collapse to a zero measure set, but they are narrower and narrower.

    Indeed we consider

    Qn={(x,y)R2,0<nx+y2<π, π2<nxy2<π2}.

    And we define

    wn(x,y)=(sin(nx)+siny)=2sin(nx+y2)cos(nxy2).

    Obviously wn<0 in Qn and wn=0 on Ω. We shall prove that

    P1(D2wn)+wn0  in  Ω. (4.1)

    This will imply that μ1(Qn)1. Indeed if 1<μ1(Qn) the maximum principle would imply that wn0 which is a contradiction.

    Let us show (4.1). Clearly

    D2wn=(n2sin(nx)00siny).

    We shall divide Qn in three areas. In Qn(0,πn)×(0,π) both sin(nx) and siny are positive, then

    P1(D2wn)=min(n2sin(nx),siny)sinysin(nx)+siny=wn.

    In Qn({π2n<x0}{πnx<3π2n}) where sin(nx)0 and siny0, then

    P1(D2wn)=n2sin(nx)sin(nx)sin(nx)+siny=wn.

    Finally, in Qn({πy<3π2}{π2<y0}) where sin(nx)0 and siny0 we have

    P1(D2wn)=sin(y)sin(nx)+siny=wn.

    This ends the proof.

    Remark 2. During the revision of the present paper a new preprint, [22], which improves the result of this Section, has been uploaded on ArXiv. In particular, applying [22, Corollary 3.2] to Qn, one would obtain that for any nN, μ1(Qn)=14.

    This research is partially supported by INDAM-GNAMPA.

    The authors declare no conflict of interest.

    [1] Moyo S, Norton GW, Alwang J, et al. (2010) Peanut research and poverty reduction: Impacts of variety improvement to control peanut viruses in Uganda. Am J Agric Econ 89: 448–460.
    [2] Word Bank (2007) The world development report 2008: Agriculture for development. World Bank publications, Washington, DC.
    [3] Kassie M, Shiferaw B, Muricho G (2011) Agricultural technology, crop income, and poverty alleviation in Uganda. World Dev 39: 1784–1795. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2011.04.023
    [4] Government of Pakistan (2017) Pakistan economic survey 2016–17. Agricultural statistics of Pakistan. Finance division: Government of Pakistan URI.
    [5] Ahmad F (2009) Food security in Pakistan. Pak J Agric Sci 46: 83–89.
    [6] Koondhar MA, HeGe, Magsi H, et al. (2016) Comparing economic efficiency of wheat productivity in different cropping systems of Sindh province, Pakistan. J Saudi Soc Agric Sci.
    [7] Buriro RA, Khooharo AA, Talpur GH, et al. (2013) Technical efficiency of wheat farming in Sindh province of Pakistan. Pak J Agric Agric Eng Vet Sci 29: 77–87.
    [8] Chandio AA, Jiang Y, Joyo MA, et al. (2016) Impact of area under cultivation, water availability, credit disbursement, and fertilizer off-take on wheat production in Pakistan. J Appl Environ Biol Sci 6: 10–18.
    [9] Fatima H, Khan MA (2015) Influence of wheat varieties on technical efficiency and production of wheat crop in Pakistan (in selected area of Punjab). Sarhad J Agric 31: 114–122. doi: 10.17582/journal.sja/2015/31.2.114.122
    [10] Farooq A, Ishaq M, Yaqoob S, et al. (2007) Varietal adoption effect on wheat crop production in irrigated areas of NWFP. Sarhad J Agric 23: 481–485.
    [11] Chandio AA, Jiang Y, Magsi H (2016) Agricultural sub-sectors performance: An analysis of sector-wise share in agriculture GDP of Pakistan. Int J Econ Finance 8: 156.
    [12] Pandit DB, Islam MM, Sufian MA (2008) Participatory variety selection in wheat and its impact on scaling-up seed dissemination and varietal diversity. Bangladesh J Agric Res 32: 473–484.
    [13] Shah NA, Saeed I, Farooq A, et al. (2012) Adoption and economic impact of improved wheat varieties in rainfed pothwar, Punjab, Pakistan. J Biotechnol Pharm Res 3: 94–103.
    [14] Endrias G (2003) Adoption of improved sweet potato varieties in boloso sore woreda, sothern Ethiopia. M. Sc. Thesis, Alemaya University.
    [15] Belay K (2001) Factors influencing adoption of high yielding maize varieties in southwestern Ethiopia: An application of logit analysis. Q J of Int Agric 40: 149–167.
    [16] Wu HT, Ding SJ, Pandey S, et al. (2010) Assessing the impact of agricultural technology adoption on farmers' well-being using propensity-score matching analysis in rural China. Asian Econ J 24:141–160. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8381.2010.02033.x
    [17] Sahu RP, Prasad A, Ram D (2010) Adoption of improved wheat cultivation technologies in Unnao district of uttar pradesh. Indian Res J Ext Edu 10: 25–28.
    [18] Mazid A, Amegbeto KN, Keser M, et al. (2009) Adoption and impacts of improved winter and spring wheat varieties in Turkey. International center for agricultural research in the dry areas (ICARDA).
    [19] Shiferaw B, Kassie M, Jaleta M, et al. Adoption of improved wheat varieties and impacts on household food security in Ethiopia. Food Policy 44: 272–284.
    [20] Tesfaye S, Bedada B, Mesay Y (2016) Impact of improved wheat technology adoption on productivity and income in Ethiopia. Afr Crop Sci J 24: 127.
    [21] Mulugeta T and Hundie B (2012) Impacts of adoption of improved wheat technologies on households' food consumption in southeastern Ethiopia. Economists (IAAE) triennial conference, 18–24 august, Foz do Iguacu, Brazil.
    [22] Kotu BH, Verkuijl H, Mwangi W, et al. (2000) Adoption of improved wheat technologies in Adaba and Dodola Woredas of the Bale highlands, Ethiopia. CIMMYT.
    [23] Odoemenem IU, Obinne CPO (2010) Assessing the factors influencing the utilization of improved cereal crop production technologies by small-scale farmers in Nigeria. Indian J Sci Technol 3: 180–183.
    [24] Al-Hassan R, Jatoe JBD (2002) Adoption and impact of improved cereal varieties in Ghana. Paper prepared for the workshop on the green revolution in Asia and its transferability to Africa. Organised by foundation for advanced studies in international development (FASID), from 8 th to 10 th December, 20002, in Tokyo, Japan.
    [25] Gamba P, Ngugi C, Verkuijl H, et al.(2003) Wheat farmers seed management and varietal adoption in Kenya. CIMMYT.
    [26] Briema AEE, Elnow MM, Elimam EE, et al. (2013) Impact of improved seeds on small farmers productivity, income and livelihood in Umruwaba locality of north Kordofan, Sudan. Russ J Agric Socio-Econ Sci 20: 203–208.
    [27] Mussei A, Mwanga J, Mwangi W, et al. (2001) Adoption of improved wheat technologies by small-scale farmers in Mbeya district, southern highlands, Tanzania. CIMMYT.
    [28] Khonje M, Manda J, Alene AD, et al. (2015) Analysis of adoption and impacts of improved maize varieties in eastern Zambia. World Dev 66: 695–706. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2014.09.008
    [29] Ahmad N, Jan I, Ullah S, et al. (2015) Impact of agricultural credit on wheat productivity in district Jhang, Pakistan. Sarhad J Agric 31: 65–69.
    [30] Fayaz M, Jan D, Jan AU, et al. (2006) Effects of short term credit advanced by ZTBL for enhancement of crop productivity and income of growers. J Agric Biol Sci 1: 15–18.
    [31] Bashir MK, Gill ZA, Hassan S, et al. (2007) Impact of credit disbursed by commercial banks on the productivity of sugarcane in Faisalabad district. Pak J Agric Sci 44: 361–363.
    [32] Mwangi M, Kariuki S (2015) Factors determining adoption of new agricultural technology by smallholder farmers in developing countries. J Econ Sustainable Dev 6: 208–216.
    [33] Ahmed AU, Bagchi KK (2004) Factors and constraints for adopting new agricultural technology in Assam with special reference to Nalbari district: An empirical study: J. Contemp. Indian Policy.
    [34] Gabre-Madhin EZ, Haggblade S (2004) Successes in African agriculture: Results of an expert survey. World Dev 32: 745–766. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2003.11.004
    [35] Uaiene RN, Tenywa JS, Taulya G, et al. (2011) Determinants of agricultural technology adoption in Mozambique. Discussion papers, No. 67E.
    [36] Ali A, Erenstein O, Rahut DB (2014) Impact of direct rice-sowing technology on rice producers' earnings: Empirical evidence from Pakistan. Dev Stud Res Open Access J 1: 244–254.
    [37] Chandio AA, Jiang Y (2018) Determinants of adoption of improved rice varieties in northern Sindh, Pakistan. Rice Sci 25: 103–110. doi: 10.1016/j.rsci.2017.10.003
    [38] Frongillo EA, Olson CM, Rauschenbach BS, et al. (1997) Anne Kendall nutritional consequences of food insecurity in a rural New York state county. Institute for research on poverty discussion paper, NO. 1120–97.
    [39] Awotide AB, Abdoulaye T, Alene A, et al. (2014) Assessing the extent and determinants of adoption of improved cassava varieties in south-western Nigeria. J Dev Agric Econ 6: 376–385.
    [40] Diiro GM (2013) Impact of off-farm income on agricultural technology adoption intensity and productivity. IFPRI.
    [41] Reardon T, Stamoulis K, Pingali P (2007) Rural nonfarm employment in developing countries in an era of globalization. Agric Econ 37: 173–183. doi: 10.1111/j.1574-0862.2007.00243.x
    [42] Chang Y, Chatterjee S, Kim J (2014) Household finance and food insecurity. J Fam Econ Issues 35:499–515. doi: 10.1007/s10834-013-9382-z
    [43] Chandio AA, Jiang Y, Wei F, et al. (2017) Famers' access to credit: Does collateral matter or cash flow matter?-Evidence from Sindh, Pakistan. Cogent Econ Finance 5: 1369383.
    [44] Gundersen C, Gruber J (2001) The dynamic determinants of food insufficiency. Second food security measurement and research conference, food assistance and nutrition research report.
    [45] Ribar D, K Hamrick (2003) An analysis of poverty and food sufficiency dynamics. Washington, DC, USDA economic research service.
    [46] Ali A, Khan MA (2013) Livestock ownership in ensuring rural household food security in Pakistan. J Anim Plant Sci 23: 313–318.
    [47] Owusu V, Abdulai A, Abdul-Rahman S (2011) Non-farm work and food security among farm households in northern Ghana. Food Policy 36: 108–118. doi: 10.1016/j.foodpol.2010.09.002
    [48] Kassie M, Ndiritu SW, Stage J (2014) What determines gender inequality in household food security in kenya? Application of exogenous switching treatment regression. World Dev 56: 153–171.
    [49] Obisesan A (2014) Gender differences in technology adoption and welfare impact among nigerian farming households. MPRA Pap No.58920.
    [50] Lavison RK (2013) Factors influencing the adoption of organic fertilizers in vegetable production in accra. M. Sc. Thesis, Ghana University.
    [51] Adeoti AI (2008) Factors influencing irrigation technology adoption and its impact on household poverty in Ghana. J Agric Rural Dev Subtrop 109: 51–63.
    [52] Debebe S, Haji J, Goshu D, et al. (2015) Speed of improved maize seed adoption by smallholders farmers in southwestern Ethiopia: Analysis using the count data models. J Agric Econs, Extens Rural Develop 3: 276–282.
    [53] Simtowe F, Kassie M, Diagne A, et al. (2011) Determinants of agricultural technology adoption: The case of improved pigeonpea varieties in Tanzania. MPRA Pap 50:325–345.
    [54] Dansoabbeam G, Bosiako JA, Ehiakpor DS, et al. (2017) Adoption of improved maize variety among farm households in the Northern Region of Ghana. Cogent Econ Finance 5: 1416896.
    [55] Hagos BG, Hadush M (2017) Does improved wheat seed adoption benefit farmers? Empirical evidence from Southern Tigrai, Ethiopia. J Agric Crops 3: 1–11.
    [56] Adesina AA, Baidu-Forson J (1995) Farmers' perceptions and adoption of new agricultural technology: Evidence from analysis in Burkina Faso and Guinea, West Africa. Agric Econ 13: 1–9. doi: 10.1016/0169-5150(95)01142-8
    [57] Aldosari F, Shunaifi MSA, Ullah MA, et al. (2017) Farmers' perceptions regarding the use of information and communication technology (ICT) in Khyber Pakhtunkhwa–northern Pakistan. J Saudi Soc Agric Sci 2017.
    [58] Zhang Y, Wang L, Duan Y (2016) Agricultural information dissemination using ICTs: A review and analysis of information dissemination models in China. Process Agric 3: 17–29.
    [59] Government of Pakistan (2010) Pakistan economic survey 2010–11. Finance division: Government of Pakistan URI.
    [60] Foster AD, Rosenzweig MR (2010) Microeconomics of technology adoption. Annu Rev Econ 2: 783–789.
    [61] Janvry AD Dustan A, Sadoulet E (2010) Recent advances in impact analysis methods for ex-post impact assessments of agricultural technology : Options for the consultative group on international agricultural research (CGIAR). Independent science and partnership council.
    [62] Asfaw S, Shiferaw B, Simtowe F, et al. (2012) Impact of modern agricultural technologies on smallholder welfare: Evidence from Tanzania and Ethiopia. Food Policy 37: 283–295. doi: 10.1016/j.foodpol.2012.02.013
    [63] Feleke S, Zegeye T (2006) Adoption of improved maize varieties in southern Ethiopia: Factors and strategy options. Food Policy 31: 442–457. doi: 10.1016/j.foodpol.2005.12.003
    [64] Asfaw S, Shiferaw B, Simtowe F, et al. (2011) Agricultural technology adoption, seed access constraints and commercialization in Ethiopia. J Dev Agric Econ 3: 477.
    [65] Kohansal MR, Firoozzare A (2013) Applying multinomial logit model for determining socio-economic factors affecting major choice of consumers in food purchasing: The case of Mashhad. J Agric Sci Technol 15: 1307–1317.
    [66] Feder G, Just RE, Zilberman D (1985) Adoption of agricultural innovations in developing countries: A survey. Econ Dev Cultural Change 33: 255–298. doi: 10.1086/451461
    [67] Heisey PW, Tetlay KA, Ahmad Z, et al. (2010) Varietal change in post-green revolution agriculture: Empirical evidence for wheat in Pakistan. J Agric Econ 44: 428–442.
    [68] Gao XM, Wailes EJ, Cramer GL (1995) Double-hurdle model with bivariate normal errors: An application to U.S. rice demand. J Agric Applied Econ 27: 363–376. doi: 10.1017/S107407080002842X
    [69] Matijevic-Aleksic N, Dulic B, Rolovic Z (2012) Understanding the adoption of systemic innovations in smallholder agriculture: The system of rice intensification (SRI) in Timor Leste. Agric Syst 108: 64–73. doi: 10.1016/j.agsy.2012.01.003
    [70] Khokhar B, Hussain I, Khokhar Z (2010) Effect of different irrigation frequiencies on growth and yield of different wheat genotypes in Sindh. Pakistan J Agric Res 23: 108–112.
    [71] Ullah A, Shah SNM, Zheng S, et al. (2014) Impact of education and certified seeds on wheat production in Kohat, Pakistan. Asian J Agric Ext Econ Sociol 4: 42–48.
    [72] Leake G, Adam B (2015) Factors determining allocation of land for improved wheat variety by smallholder farmers of northern Ethiopia. J Dev Agric Econ 7: 105–112. doi: 10.5897/JDAE2014.0621
    [73] Kebede D, Ketema M, Dechassa N, et al. (2016). Determinants of adoption of wheat production technology package by smallholder farmers: Evidences from eastern Ethiopia. Turkish J Agric-Food Sci Technol 5: 267–274.
    [74] Mirani Z, Leske GW, Labano AH, et al. (2002) Farmers' adoption of recommended technology for rice in larkana district of sindh province of Pakistan. FAO, Rome, Italy.
    [75] Sall S, Norman D, Featherstone AM (2000) Quantitative assessment of improved rice variety adoption: The farmer's perspective. Agric Syst 66: 129–144. doi: 10.1016/S0308-521X(00)00040-8
    [76] Ahmad N, Jan I, Ullah S, et al. (2015) Impact of agricultural credit on wheat productivity in district Jhang, Pakistan. Sarhad J Agric 31: 65–69.
    [77] Zegeye T, Taye G, Tanner D, et al. (2001) Adoption of improved bread wheat varieties and inorganic fertilizer by small-scale farmers in Yelmana Densa and Farta Districts of northwestern Ethiopia. Ethiopia agricultural research organization (EARO), CIMMYT.
    [78] Beshir H, Emana B, Kassa B, et al. (2012) Determinants of chemical fertilizer technology adoption in north eastern highlands of Ethiopia: The double hurdle approach. J Res Econ Int Finance 1: 39–49.
    [79] Ersado L, Amacher G, Alwang J (2004) Productivity and land enhancing technologies in northern Ethiopia: Health, public investments, and sequential adoption. Am J Agric Econ 86: 321–331. doi: 10.1111/j.0092-5853.2004.00581.x
    [80] Okuthe IK, Ngesa FU, Ochola WW (2000) Socio-economic determinants of adoption of improved sorghum varieties and technologies among smallholder farmers in Western Kenya. Ministry of Agriculture and Egerton University, Kenya.
    [81] Tura M, Aredo D, Tsegaye W, et al. (2010) Adoption and continued use of improved maize seeds: Case study of central Ethiopia. Afr J Agric Res 5: 2350–2358.
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Danping Chen, Animation VR scene mosaic modeling based on generalized Laplacian equation, 2022, 0, 2444-8656, 10.2478/amns.2022.2.0156
    2. Matthieu Alfaro, Philippe Jouan, The Allen-Cahn equation with nonlinear truncated Laplacians: Description of radial solutions, 2024, 0, 1078-0947, 0, 10.3934/dcds.2024151
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2018 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(7631) PDF downloads(1635) Cited by(15)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog