Iter. | Time [sec] | |
Algorithm 1 | 297 | 1.7283 |
scheme (1.6) | 482 | 3.0215 |
Algorithm 6.1 in [31] | 1311 | 8.5415 |
Algorithm 3.1 in [32] | 477 | 2.3758 |
We present an empirical test of a new measure to classify organizations according to the tangibility of product (output) flows delivered to customers. Our measure exhibits the empirical consequences of using standard industrial classifications to assume that firms within the same industry either share identical properties or sell homogeneous products. To illustrate the misleading findings that can result from these assumptions, we investigate whether prior literature on capital structure provides a sensible interpretation of organizational behavior, based as it often is on an assumption that all firms within a given industrial classification sell durable goods. In contrast to the product-market literature based upon the trade-off theory of capital structure, that would predict that firms selling physical goods will have proportionately less debt, in fact, when firms within industries are classified using our measure, we find to the contrary. Our intention is not to displace existing systems of industry classification but is, rather, to highlight the dangers of drawing conclusions from assuming homogeneity amongst firms which are formally registered within the same industry.
Citation: Tiago Cardão-Pito, Julia A Smith, João da Silva Ferreira. Using accounting measures of (in)tangibility for organizational classifications[J]. Quantitative Finance and Economics, 2021, 5(2): 325-351. doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021015
[1] | Saudia Jabeen, Bandar Bin-Mohsin, Muhammad Aslam Noor, Khalida Inayat Noor . Inertial projection methods for solving general quasi-variational inequalities. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(2): 1075-1086. doi: 10.3934/math.2021064 |
[2] | Meiying Wang, Luoyi Shi, Cuijuan Guo . An inertial iterative method for solving split equality problem in Banach spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(10): 17628-17646. doi: 10.3934/math.2022971 |
[3] | Lu-Chuan Ceng, Shih-Hsin Chen, Yeong-Cheng Liou, Tzu-Chien Yin . Modified inertial subgradient extragradient algorithms for generalized equilibria systems with constraints of variational inequalities and fixed points. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(6): 13819-13842. doi: 10.3934/math.2024672 |
[4] | Yali Zhao, Qixin Dong, Xiaoqing Huang . A self-adaptive viscosity-type inertial algorithm for common solutions of generalized split variational inclusion and paramonotone equilibrium problem. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(2): 4504-4523. doi: 10.3934/math.2025208 |
[5] | Zheng Zhou, Bing Tan, Songxiao Li . Two self-adaptive inertial projection algorithms for solving split variational inclusion problems. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(4): 4960-4973. doi: 10.3934/math.2022276 |
[6] | Pongsakorn Yotkaew, Nopparat Wairojjana, Nuttapol Pakkaranang . Accelerated non-monotonic explicit proximal-type method for solving equilibrium programming with convex constraints and its applications. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(10): 10707-10727. doi: 10.3934/math.2021622 |
[7] | Mohammad Dilshad, Mohammad Akram, Md. Nasiruzzaman, Doaa Filali, Ahmed A. Khidir . Adaptive inertial Yosida approximation iterative algorithms for split variational inclusion and fixed point problems. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(6): 12922-12942. doi: 10.3934/math.2023651 |
[8] | Ziqi Zhu, Kaiye Zheng, Shenghua Wang . A new double inertial subgradient extragradient method for solving a non-monotone variational inequality problem in Hilbert space. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(8): 20956-20975. doi: 10.3934/math.20241020 |
[9] | Austine Efut Ofem, Jacob Ashiwere Abuchu, Godwin Chidi Ugwunnadi, Hossam A. Nabwey, Abubakar Adamu, Ojen Kumar Narain . Double inertial steps extragadient-type methods for solving optimal control and image restoration problems. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(5): 12870-12905. doi: 10.3934/math.2024629 |
[10] | Cuijie Zhang, Zhaoyang Chu . New extrapolation projection contraction algorithms based on the golden ratio for pseudo-monotone variational inequalities. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(10): 23291-23312. doi: 10.3934/math.20231184 |
We present an empirical test of a new measure to classify organizations according to the tangibility of product (output) flows delivered to customers. Our measure exhibits the empirical consequences of using standard industrial classifications to assume that firms within the same industry either share identical properties or sell homogeneous products. To illustrate the misleading findings that can result from these assumptions, we investigate whether prior literature on capital structure provides a sensible interpretation of organizational behavior, based as it often is on an assumption that all firms within a given industrial classification sell durable goods. In contrast to the product-market literature based upon the trade-off theory of capital structure, that would predict that firms selling physical goods will have proportionately less debt, in fact, when firms within industries are classified using our measure, we find to the contrary. Our intention is not to displace existing systems of industry classification but is, rather, to highlight the dangers of drawing conclusions from assuming homogeneity amongst firms which are formally registered within the same industry.
In a real Hilbert space H, with D being a nonempty closed convex subset, where the inner product ⟨⋅,⋅⟩ and norm ‖⋅‖ are defined, the classical variational inequality problem (VIP) is to determine a point x∗∈D such that ⟨Ax∗,y−x∗⟩≥0 holds for all y∈D, where A:H→H is an operator. Then, we define ◊ as its solution set. Stampacchia [1] proposed variational inequality theory in 1964, which appeared in various models to solve a wide range of engineering, regional, physical, mathematical, and other problems. The mathematical theory of variational inequality problems was first applied to solve equilibrium problems. Within this model, the function is derived from the first-order variation of the respective potential energy. As a generalization and development of classical variational problems, the form of variational inequality has become more diverse, and many projection algorithms have been studied by scholars [2,3,4,5,6,7,8,9,10]. In [11], Hu and Wang utilized the projected neural network (PNN) to solve the VIP under the pseudo-monotonicity or pseudoconvexity assumptions. Furthermore, He et al. [12] proposed an inertial PNN method for solving the VIP, while Eshaghnezhad et al. [13] presented a novel PNN method for solving the VIP. In addition, in [14], a modified neurodynamic network (MNN) was proposed for solving the VIP, and under the assumptions of strong pseudo monotonicity and L-continuity, the fixed-time stability convergence of MNN was established.
The most famous method for solving the VIP is called the projection gradient method (GM), which is expressed as
xn+1=PD(xn−γAxn). | (1.1) |
Observably, the iterative sequence {xn} produced by this method converges towards a solution of the VIP, and PD:H→D is a metric projection, with γ denoting the stepsize parameter, and A being both strongly monotone and Lipschitz continuous. The projection gradient method fails when A is weakened to a monotonic operator. On this basis, Korpelevich [15] proposed a two-step iteration called the extragradient method (EGM)
{x0∈D,sn=PD(xn−γAxn),xn+1=PD(xn−γAsn), | (1.2) |
where γ is the stepsize parameter, and A is Lipschitz continuous and monotone. However, the calculation of projection is a major challenge in each iteration process. Hence, to address this issue, Censor et al. [16] proposed the idea of the half-space and modified the algorithm to
{sn=PD(xn−γAxn),Hn={x∈H:⟨xn−γAxn−sn,x−sn⟩≤0},xn+1=PHn(xn−γAsn). | (1.3) |
Recently, adaptive step size [17,18,19] and inertia [20,21,22,23] have been frequently used to accelerate algorithm convergence. For example, Thong and Hieu [24] presented the following algorithm:
{hn=xn+αn(xn−xn−1),sn=PD(hn−τnAhn),en=PHn(hn−τnAsn),xn+1=βnf(en)+(1−βn)en, | (1.4) |
where Hn={x∈H:⟨hn−τnAhn−sn,x−sn⟩≤0}, and
τn+1={min{μ‖hn−sn‖‖Ahn−Asn‖,τn}, if Ahn−Asn≠0,τn, otherwise. |
They also combined the VIP with fixed point problems [25] (we define Δ as a common solution set). For example, Nadezhkina and Takahashi [26] proposed the following algorithm:
{x0∈D,sn=PD(xn−τnAxn),xn+1=(1−αn)xn+αnTPD(xn−τnAsn), | (1.5) |
where A is Lipschitz continuous and monotone, and T:D→D is nonexpansive. The sequence produced by this algorithm exhibits weak convergence toward an element in Δ. Another instance is the algorithm proposed by Thong et al. [27], which is as follows:
{hn=xn+αn(xn−xn−1),sn=PD(hn−τnAhn),en=PHn(hn−τnAsn),xn+1=(1−βn)hn+βnTen, | (1.6) |
where τn is selected as the maximum τ within the set {γ,γl,γl2,...} that satisfies the condition
τ‖Ahn−Asn‖≤μ‖hn−sn‖. |
Based on the preceding research, we present a self-adaptive step-size and alternated inertial subgradient extragradient algorithm designed for addressing the VIP and fixed-point problems involving non-Lipschitz and pseudo-monotone operators in this paper. The article's structure is outlined as follows: Section 2 contains definitions and preliminary results essential for our approach. Section 3 establishes the convergence of the iterative sequence generated. Finally, Section 4 includes a series of numerical experiments demonstrating the practicality and effectiveness of our algorithm.
For a sequence {xn} and x in H, strong convergence is represented as xn→x, weak convergence is represented as xn⇀x.
Definition 2.1. [28] We define a nonlinear operator T:H→H to have an empty fixed point set (Fix(T)≠∅), if the following expression holds for {qn}∈H:
{qn⇀q(I−T)qn→0⇒q∈Fix(T), |
where I denotes the identity operator. In such cases, we characterize I−T as being demiclosed at zero.
Definition 2.2. For an operator T:H→H, the following definitions apply:
(1) T is termed nonexpansive if
‖Tq1−Tq2‖≤‖q1−q2‖∀q1,q2∈H. |
(2) T is termed quasi-nonexpansive with a non-empty fixed point set Fix(T)≠∅ if
‖Tx−η‖≤‖x−η‖∀x∈H,η∈Fix(T). |
Definition 2.3. A sequence {qn} is said to be Fejér monotone concerning a set D if
‖qn+1−q‖≤‖qn−q‖,∀q∈D. |
Lemma 2.1. For each ζ1,ζ2∈H and ϵ∈R, we have
‖ζ1+ζ2‖2≤2⟨ζ1+ζ2,ζ2⟩+‖ζ1‖2; | (2.1) |
‖ϵζ2+(1−ϵ)ζ1‖2=(1−ϵ)‖ζ1‖2+ϵ‖ζ2‖2−ϵ(1−ϵ)‖ζ2−ζ1‖2. | (2.2) |
Lemma 2.2. [26] Given ψ∈H and φ∈D, then
(1) ‖PDψ−PDφ‖2≤⟨ψ−φ,PDψ−PDφ⟩;
(2) ‖φ−PDψ‖2≤‖ψ−φ‖2−‖ψ−PDψ‖2;
(3) ⟨ψ−PDψ,PDψ−φ⟩≥0.
Lemma 2.3. [29] Suppose A:D→H is pseudomonotone and uniformly continuous. Then, ς is a solution of ◊ ⟺ ⟨Ax,x−ς⟩≥0,∀x∈D.
Lemma 2.4. [30] Let D be a nonempty subset of H. A sequence {xn} in H is said to weakly converge to a point in D if the following conditions are met:
(1) For every x∈D, limn→∞‖xn−x‖ exists;
(2) Every sequential weak cluster point of {xn} is in D.
This section presents an alternated inertial projection algorithm designed to address the VIP and fixed point problems associated with a quasi-nonexpansive mapping T in H. We have the following assumptions:
Assumption 3.1.
(a) The operator A:H→H is pseudo-monotone, uniformly continuous over H, and exhibits sequential weak continuity on D;
(b) ϖ∈(1−μ4,1−μ2), 0<κn<min{1−μ−2ϖ2ϖ,1−ϖ1+ϖ}.
The algorithm (Algorithm 1) is as follows:
Algorithm 1 |
Initialization: Let x0,x1∈H be arbitrary. Given γ>0, l∈(0,1), μ∈(0,1). Iterative step: Calculate xn+1 as follows: Step 1. Set hn={xn,n=even,xn+ϖ(xn−xn−1),n=odd. Step 2. Compute sn=PD(hn−τnAhn). If sn=hn, stop. Otherwise compute en=PHn(hn−τnAsn), where Hn={x∈H:⟨hn−τnAhn−sn,x−sn⟩≤0}, and τn is selected as the maximum τ from the set {γ,γl,γl2,⋯} that satisfies τ⟨Asn−Ahn,sn−en⟩≤μ‖sn−hn‖‖sn−en‖. Step 3. Compute xn+1=(1−κn)en+κnTen. Set n:=n+1 and go back to Step 1. |
To prove the algorithm, we first provide several lemmas.
Lemma 3.1. The sequence produced by Algorithm 1, denoted as {x2n}, is bounded and limn→∞‖x2n−ϱ‖ exists for all ϱ∈Δ.
Proof. Indeed, let ϱ∈Δ. Then, we have
‖en−ϱ‖2=‖PHn(hn−τnAsn)−ϱ‖2≤‖hn−τnAsn−ϱ‖2−‖hn−τnAsn−en‖2=‖hn−ϱ‖2+τ2n‖Asn‖2−2τn⟨hn−ϱ,Asn⟩−‖hn−en‖2−τ2n‖Asn‖2+2τn⟨hn−en,Asn⟩=‖hn−ϱ‖2−‖hn−en‖2+2τn⟨ϱ−en,Asn⟩=‖hn−ϱ‖2−‖hn−en‖2−2τn⟨sn−ϱ,Asn⟩+2τn⟨sn−en,Asn⟩. | (3.1) |
According to ϱ∈Δ, it follows that ⟨Aϱ,s−ϱ⟩≥ for all s∈D, and, at the same time, because of the pseudomonotonicity of A, we establish ⟨As,s−ϱ⟩≥0 for all s∈D. If we set s=sn, then ⟨Asn,sn−ϱ⟩≥0. Thus, by (3.1), we can get
‖en−ϱ‖2≤‖hn−ϱ‖2−‖hn−en‖2+2τn⟨sn−en,Asn⟩=‖hn−ϱ‖2−‖hn−sn‖2−‖en−sn‖2−2⟨hn−sn,sn−en⟩+2τn⟨sn−en,Asn⟩=‖hn−ϱ‖2−‖hn−sn‖2−‖en−sn‖2+2⟨sn−hn+τnAsn,sn−en⟩=‖hn−ϱ‖2−‖hn−sn‖2−‖en−sn‖2+2⟨hn−τnAhn−sn,en−sn⟩+2τn⟨Asn−Ahn,sn−en⟩≤‖hn−ϱ‖2−‖hn−sn‖2−‖en−sn‖2+2μ‖sn−hn‖‖sn−en‖≤‖hn−ϱ‖2−‖hn−sn‖2−‖en−sn‖2+μ[‖sn−hn‖2+‖en−sn‖2]=‖hn−ϱ‖2−(1−μ)‖hn−sn‖2−(1−μ)‖en−sn‖2. | (3.2) |
Subsequently, by (2.2), we obtain
‖xn+1−ϱ‖2=‖(1−κn)en+κnTen−ϱ‖2=‖κn(Ten−ϱ)+(1−κn)(en−ϱ)‖2=κn‖Ten−ϱ‖2+(1−κn)‖en−ϱ‖2−κn(1−κn)‖Ten−en‖2≤κn‖en−ϱ‖2+(1−κn)‖en−ϱ‖2−κn(1−κn)‖Ten−en‖2=‖en−ϱ‖2−κn(1−κn)‖Ten−en‖2≤‖hn−ϱ‖2−(1−μ)‖hn−sn‖2−(1−μ)‖en−sn‖2−κn(1−κn)‖Ten−en‖2. | (3.3) |
Meanwhile, combined with (3.3), it is evident that
‖xn+1−ϱ‖2≤(1−κn)‖hn−ϱ‖2+κn‖en−ϱ‖2. | (3.4) |
In particular,
‖x2n+2−ϱ‖2≤‖h2n+1−ϱ‖2−(1−μ)‖h2n+1−s2n+1‖2−(1−μ)‖e2n+1−s2n+1‖2−κ2n+1(1−κ2n+1)‖Te2n+1−e2n+1‖2. | (3.5) |
By (2.2), we obtain
‖h2n+1−ϱ‖2=‖x2n+1+ϖ(x2n+1−x2n)−ϱ‖2=(1+ϖ)‖x2n+1−ϱ‖2−ϖ‖x2n−ϱ‖2+ϖ(1+ϖ)‖x2n+1−x2n‖2. | (3.6) |
As another special case of (3.3), we have
‖x2n+1−ϱ‖2≤‖x2n−ϱ‖2−(1−μ)‖x2n−s2n‖2−(1−μ)‖e2n−s2n‖2−κ2n(1−κ2n)‖Te2n−e2n‖2≤‖x2n−ϱ‖2−1−μ2‖x2n−e2n‖2−κ2n(1−κ2n)‖Te2n−e2n‖2, | (3.7) |
and then, bringing (3.7) into (3.6), we can get
‖h2n+1−ϱ‖2=‖x2n−ϱ‖2−(1+ϖ)(1−μ)2‖x2n−e2n‖2−κ2n(1−κ2n)(1+ϖ)‖Te2n−e2n‖2+ϖ(1+ϖ)‖x2n+1−x2n‖2. | (3.8) |
Plugging (3.8) into (3.5) gives
‖x2n+2−ϱ‖2≤‖x2n−ϱ‖2−(1+ϖ)(1−μ)2‖x2n−e2n‖2−κ2n(1−κ2n)(1+ϖ)‖Te2n−e2n‖2+ϖ(1+ϖ)‖x2n+1−x2n‖2−(1−μ)‖h2n+1−s2n+1‖2−(1−μ)‖e2n+1−s2n+1‖2−κ2n+1(1−κ2n+1)‖Te2n+1−e2n+1‖2, | (3.9) |
where
‖x2n+1−x2n‖2=‖(1−κ2n)e2n+κ2nTe2n−x2n‖2=‖e2n−x2n+κ2n(Te2n−e2n)‖2=‖e2n−x2n‖2+κ22n‖Te2n−e2n‖2+2κ2n⟨e2n−x2n,Te2n−e2n⟩≤‖e2n−x2n‖2+κ22n‖Te2n−e2n‖2+κ2n(‖e2n−x2n‖2+‖Te2n−e2n‖2)=(1+κ2n)‖e2n−x2n‖2+κ2n(κ2n+1)‖Te2n−e2n‖2. | (3.10) |
Thus, putting (3.10) into (3.9), we have
‖x2n+2−ϱ‖2≤‖x2n−ϱ‖2−[(1+ϖ)(1−μ)2−ϖ(1+ϖ)(1+κ2n)]‖e2n−x2n‖2−[κ2n(1−κ2n)(1+ϖ)−ϖ(1+ϖ)κ2n(κ2n+1)]‖Te2n−e2n‖2−(1−μ)‖h2n+1−s2n+1‖2−(1−μ)‖e2n+1−s2n+1‖2−κ2n+1(1−κ2n+1)‖Te2n+1−e2n+1‖2. | (3.11) |
According to ϖ∈(1−μ4,1−μ2), 0<κn<min{1−μ−2ϖ2ϖ,1−ϖ1+ϖ}, we get the sequence {‖x2n−ϱ‖} is decreasing, and thus limn→∞‖x2n−ϱ‖ exists. This implies {‖x2n−ϱ‖} is bounded, hence, {x2n} is bounded. For (3.7), we can get that {‖x2n+1−ϱ‖} is also bounded. Therefore, {‖xn−ϱ‖} is bounded. Thus, {xn} is bounded.
Lemma 3.2. Consider the sequence {x2n} produced by Algorithm 1. If the subsequence {x2nk} of {x2n} weakly converges to x∗∈H and limk→∞‖x2nk−s2nk‖=0, then x∗∈◊.
Proof. Because of h2n=x2n, using the definition of {s2nk} and Lemma 2.2, we get
⟨x2nk−τ2nkAx2nk−s2nk,x−s2nk⟩≤0,∀x∈D, |
and so
1τ2nk⟨x2nk−s2nk,x−s2nk⟩≤⟨Ax2nk,x−s2nk⟩,∀x∈D. |
Hence,
1τ2nk⟨x2nk−s2nk,x−s2nk⟩+⟨Ax2nk,s2nk−x2nk⟩≤⟨Ax2nk,x−x2nk⟩,∀x∈D. | (3.12) |
Because of limk→∞‖x2nk−s2nk‖=0 and taking the limit as k→∞ in (3.12), we acquire
lim_k→∞⟨Ax2nk,x−x2nk⟩≥0,∀x∈D. | (3.13) |
Select a decreasing sequence {ϵk}⊂(0,∞) to make limk→∞ϵk=0 hold. Then, for each ϵk, based on (3.13) we use Mk to represent the smallest positive integer satisfying
⟨Ax2nj,x−x2nj⟩+ϵk≥0,∀j≥Mk. | (3.14) |
Since {ϵk} is decreasing, then {Mk} is increasing. Also, for each k, Ax2Mk≠0, let
v2Mk=Ax2Mk‖Ax2Mk‖2. |
Here, ⟨Ax2Mk,v2Mk⟩=1 for each k. Then, by (3.14), for each k we have
⟨Ax2Mk,x+ϵkv2Mk−x2Mk⟩≥0. |
Because A is pseudo-monotonic, we get
⟨A(x+ϵkv2Mk),x+ϵkv2Mk−x2Mk⟩≥0. | (3.15) |
Since x2nk⇀x∗ as k→∞, and A exhibits sequential weak continuity on H, it follows that the sequence {Ax2nk} weakly converges to Ax∗. Then, based on the weakly sequential continuity of the norm, we obtain
0<‖Ax∗‖≤lim_k→∞‖Ax2nk‖. |
Since {xMk}⊂{xnk} and limk→∞ϵk=0, we have
0≤¯limk→∞‖ϵkv2Mk‖=¯limk→∞(ϵk‖Ax2nk‖)≤¯limk→∞ϵklim_k→∞‖Ax2nk‖=0‖Ax∗‖=0, |
which means limk→∞‖ϵkv2Mk‖=0. Finally, we let k→∞ in (3.15) and get
⟨Ax,x−x∗⟩≥0. |
This implies x∗∈◊.
Lemma 3.3. Considering {x2n} as the sequence produced by Algorithm 1, since {x2n} is a bounded sequence, there exists a subsequence {x2nk} of {x2n} and x∗∈H such that x2nk⇀x∗. Hence, x∗∈Δ.
Proof. From (3.11) and the convergence of {‖x2n−ϱ‖}, we can deduce that
‖e2n+1−s2n+1‖→0,‖x2n−x2n+1‖→0, | (3.16) |
‖h2n+1−s2n+1‖→0,‖Te2n−e2n‖→0, | (3.17) |
‖Te2n+1−e2n+1‖→0,asn→+∞. |
By the definition of {x2n+1}, we have
‖x2n−e2n‖=‖x2n−x2n+1+κ2n(Te2n−e2n)‖≤‖x2n−x2n+1‖+κ2n‖Te2n−e2n‖, |
then
‖x2n−e2n‖→0, | (3.18) |
and by (3.18) and x2nk⇀x∗, we can get
e2nk⇀x∗. | (3.19) |
Since T is demiclosed at zero, Definition 2.1, (3.17), and (3.19) imply
x∗∈Fix(T). | (3.20) |
From (3.2), we deduce
‖e2n−ϱ‖2≤‖x2n−ϱ‖2−(1−μ)‖x2n−s2n‖2−(1−μ)‖e2n−s2n‖2. |
This implies that
(1−μ)‖x2n−s2n‖2≤‖x2n−ϱ‖2−‖e2n−ϱ‖2. | (3.21) |
Based on the convergence of {‖x2n−ϱ‖2}, we can assume that
‖x2n−ϱ‖2→l. | (3.22) |
At the same time, according to (3.16), it can be obtained that
‖x2n+1−ϱ‖2→l. | (3.23) |
It follows from (3.4) that
‖x2n+1−ϱ‖2≤(1−κ2n)‖x2n−ϱ‖2+κ2n‖e2n−ϱ‖2. |
Then,
‖e2n−ϱ‖2≥‖x2n+1−ϱ‖2−‖x2n−ϱ‖2κ2n+‖x2n−ϱ‖2. | (3.24) |
It implies from (3.22)–(3.24) that
limn→∞‖e2n−ϱ‖2≥limn→∞‖x2n−ϱ‖2=l. | (3.25) |
By (3.2), we get
limn→∞‖e2n−ϱ‖2≤limn→∞‖x2n−ϱ‖2=l. | (3.26) |
Combining (3.25) and (3.26), we get
limn→∞‖e2n−ϱ‖2=l. | (3.27) |
Combining with (3.21), (3.22), and (3.27), we have
limn→∞‖x2n−s2n‖2=0. |
Therefore, it implies from Lemma 3.2 that
x∗∈◊. | (3.28) |
Combining (3.20) and (3.28), we can derive
x∗∈Δ. |
Theorem 3.2. {xn}, a sequence produced by Algorithm 1, weakly converges to a point within Δ.
Proof. Let x∗∈H such that x2nk⇀x∗. Then, by Lemma 3.3, it implies
x∗∈Δ. |
Combining limn→∞‖x2n−ϱ‖2 exists for all ϱ∈Δ, and by Lemma 2.4, we get that {x2n} converges weakly to an element within Δ. Now, suppose {x2n} converges weakly to ξ∈Δ. For all g∈H, it follows that
limn→∞⟨x2n−ξ,g⟩=0. |
Furthermore, by (3.16), for all g∈H,
|⟨x2n+1−ξ,g⟩|=|⟨x2n+1−x2n+x2n−ξ,g⟩|≤|⟨x2n+1−x2n,g⟩|+|⟨x2n−ξ,g⟩|≤‖x2n+1−x2n‖‖g‖+|⟨x2n−ξ,g⟩|→0,asn→∞. |
Therefore, {x2n+1} weakly converges to ξ∈Δ. Hence, {xn} weakly converges to ξ∈Δ
This section will showcase three numerical experiments aiming to compare Algorithm 1 against scheme (1.6) and Algorithm 6.1 in [31], and Algorithm 3.1 in [32]. All codes were written in MATLAB R2018b and performed on a desktop PC with Intel(R) Core(TM) i5-8250U CPU @ 1.60GHz 1.80 GHz, RAM 8.00 GB.
Example 4.1. Assume that H=R3 and D:={x∈R3:Φx≤ϕ}, where Φ represents a 3×3 matrix and ϕ is a nonnegative vector. For A(x):=Qx+q, with Q=BBT+E+F, where B is a 3×3 matrix, E is a 3×3 skew-symmetric matrix, F is a 3×3 diagonal matrix with nonnegative diagonal entries, and q is a vector in R3. Notably, A is both monotone and Lipschitz continuous with constant L=‖Q‖. Define T(x)=x,∀x∈R3.
Under the assumption q=0, the solution set Δ={0}, which means that x∗=0. Now, the error at the n-th step iteration is measured using ‖xn−x∗‖. In both Algorithm 1 and scheme (1.6), we let μ=0.5, γ=0.5, l=0.5; in Algorithm 1, we let ϖ=0.2, κn=0.2; in scheme (1.6), we let αn=0.25, βn=0.5; in Algorithm 6.1 in [31], we let τ=0.01, αn=0.25; in Algorithm 3.1 in [32], we let αn=1n+1, βn=n2n+1, f(x)=0.5x, τ1=1, μ=0.2, θ=0.3, ϵn=100(n+1)2. The outcomes of this numerical experiment are presented in Table 1 and Figure 1.
Iter. | Time [sec] | |
Algorithm 1 | 297 | 1.7283 |
scheme (1.6) | 482 | 3.0215 |
Algorithm 6.1 in [31] | 1311 | 8.5415 |
Algorithm 3.1 in [32] | 477 | 2.3758 |
From Table 1, we can see that the algorithm in this article has the least number of iterations and the shortest required time. Therefore, this indicates that Algorithm 1 is feasible. According to the situation shown in Figure 1, we can see that Algorithm 1 is more efficient than the other two algorithms.
Example 4.2. Consider H=R and the feasible set D=[−2,5]. Let A:H→H be defined as
At:=t+sin(t), |
and T:H→H be defined as
Tt:=t2sin(t). |
It is evident that A is Lipschitz continuous and monotone, while T is a quasi-nonexpansive mapping. Consequently, it is straightforward to observe that Δ={0}.
In Algorithm 1 and scheme (1.6), we let γ=0.5, l=0.5, μ=0.9; in Algorithm 1, we let κn=23, ϖ=0.03; in scheme (1.6), we let αn=0.25, βn=0.5; in Algorithm 6.1 in [31], we let τ=0.4, αn=0.5, in Algorithm 3.1 in [32], we let αn=1n+1, βn=n2n+1, f(x)=0.5x, τ1=1, μ=0.2, θ=0.3, ϵn=100(n+1)2. The results of the numerical experiment are shown in Table 2 and Figure 2.
Iter. | Time [sec] | |
Algorithm 1 | 20 | 0.3542 |
scheme (1.6) | 26 | 0.5168 |
Algorithm 6.1 in [31] | 41 | 0.4293 |
Algorithm 3.1 in [32] | 26 | 0.3574 |
Table 2 and Figure 2 illustrate that Algorithm 1 has a faster convergence speed.
Example 4.3. Consider H=L2([0,1]) with the inner product
⟨m,n⟩:=∫10m(p)n(p)dp∀m,n∈H, |
and the induced norm
‖m‖:=(∫10|m(p)|2dp)12∀m∈H. |
The operator A:H→H is defined as
(Am)(p)=max{0,m(p)},p∈[0,1]∀m∈H. |
The set D:={m∈H:‖m‖≤1} represents the unit ball. Specifically, the projection operator PD(m) is defined as
PD(m)={m‖m‖L2,‖m‖L2>1,m,‖m‖L2≤1. |
Let T:L2([0,1])→L2([0,1]) be defined by
(Tm)(p)=m(p)2. |
Therefore, we can get that Δ={0}.
In Algorithm 1 and scheme (1.6), we let γ=0.5, l=0.5, μ=0.5; in Algorithm 1, we let κn=0.2, ϖ=0.2; in scheme (1.6), we let αn=0.25, βn=0.3; in Algorithm 6.1 in [31], we let τ=0.9, αn=0.6. The results of the numerical experiment are shown in Figure 3.
Figure 3 shows the behaviors of En=‖xn−x∗‖ generated by all the algorithms, commencing from the initial point x0(p)=p2. The presented results also indicate that our algorithm is superior to other algorithms.
This paper introduces a novel approach for tackling variational inequality problems and fixed point problems. Algorithm 1 extends the operator A to pseudo-monotone, uniformly continuous, and incorporates a new self-adaptive step size, and adds an alternated inertial method based on scheme (1.6). The efficiency of our algorithm is validated through the results obtained from three distinct numerical experiments.
The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.
This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 12171435).
The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
[1] |
Abor J (2007) Industry classification and the capital structure of Ghanaian SMEs. Stud Econ Financ 24: 207-219. doi: 10.1108/10867370710817392
![]() |
[2] |
Acha V, Davies A, Hobday M, et al. (2004) Exploring the capital goods economy: complex product systems in the UK. Ind Corporate Change 13: 505-529. doi: 10.1093/icc/dth020
![]() |
[3] |
Al-Najjar B, Hussainev K (2011) Revisiting the capital-structure puzzle: UK evidence. J Risk Financ12: 329-338. doi: 10.1108/15265941111158505
![]() |
[4] |
Andrade G, Kaplan S (1998) How Costly Is Financial (Not Economic) Distress? Evidence from Highly Leveraged Transactions That Became Distressed. J Financ 53: 1443-1493. doi: 10.1111/0022-1082.00062
![]() |
[5] |
Arce DG, Cook DO, Kieschnick RL (2015) On the evolution of corporate capital structures. J Evol Econ 25: 561-583. doi: 10.1007/s00191-015-0394-8
![]() |
[6] |
Baker M, Wurgler J (2002) Market Timing and Capital Structure. J Financ 57: 1-32. doi: 10.1111/1540-6261.00414
![]() |
[7] |
Baldwin J, Sabourin D (2002) Advanced technology use and firm performance in Canadian manufacturing in the 1990s. Ind Corporate Change 11: 761-789. doi: 10.1093/icc/11.4.761
![]() |
[8] | Balestra P, Krishnakumar J (2008) Fixed Effects Models and Fixed Coefficients Models, In: Matyas, L. and P. Sevestre, Editors, The Econometrics of Panel Data, 3rd Edition, Springer. |
[9] | Baltagi BH (2008) Econometric Analysis of Panel Data (fourth ed) John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., Chichester, West Sussex, UK. |
[10] |
Banerjee S, Dasgupta S, Kim Y (2008) Buyer-Supplier Relationships and the Stakeholder Theory of Capital Structure. J Financ 63: 2507-2551. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2008.01403.x
![]() |
[11] |
Bascle G (2008) Controlling for endogeneity with instrumental variables in strategic management research. Strat Organ 6: 285-327. doi: 10.1177/1476127008094339
![]() |
[12] | Baxter N (1967) Leverage, risk of ruin and the cost of capital. J Financ 22: 395-403. |
[13] |
Becker G (1962) Investment in human capital: a theoretical analysis. J Polit Econ 70: 9-49. doi: 10.1086/258724
![]() |
[14] |
Bellone F, Musso P, Nesta L, et al. (2008) Market selection along the firm life cycle. Ind Corporate Change 17: 753-777. doi: 10.1093/icc/dtn025
![]() |
[15] |
Beattie V, Goodacre A, Thomson S (2006) Corporate Financing Decisions: UK Survey Evidence. J Bus Financ Account 33: 1402-1434. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5957.2006.00640.x
![]() |
[16] |
Bhabra HS, Liu T, Tirtiroglu D (2008) Capital structure choice in a nascent market: evidence from listed firms in China. Financ Manage 37: 341-364. doi: 10.1111/j.1755-053X.2008.00015.x
![]() |
[17] |
Bloom M (2009) Accounting for goodwill. Abacus 45: 379-389. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6281.2009.00295.x
![]() |
[18] | Byard D, Darrough M, Suh J, et al. (2017) Finding diamonds in the rough: Analysts' selective following of loss-reporting firms. J Bus Fin Acc 00: 1-26. |
[19] |
Cambini C, Rondi L (2012) Capital structure and investment in regulated network utilities: evidence from EU telecoms. Ind Corporate Change 21: 31-71. doi: 10.1093/icc/dtr035
![]() |
[20] | Cardao-Pito T (2010) The Level of Operating Intangibility and the Economic Characteristics of Firms. paper presented to the American Accounting Association Annual Conference, San Francisco, July 31-August 4, mimeo. |
[21] | Cardao-Pito T (2012a) Intangible flow theory, operating intangibility, and other economic characteristics of firms. Ph.d thesis, University of Strathclyde, Glasgow, Scotland. Available online at British Library: Ethos electronic theses online services. |
[22] |
Cardao-Pito T (2012b) Intangible Flow Theory. Am J Econ Sociol 71: 328-353. doi: 10.1111/j.1536-7150.2012.00833.x
![]() |
[23] |
Cardao-Pito T (2016) A law for the social sciences regarding us human beings. J Interdiscip Econ 28: 202-229. doi: 10.1177/0260107916643471
![]() |
[24] | Cardao-Pito T (2017) Organizations as producers of operating product flows to members of society. SAGE Open 7. |
[25] |
Chan LKC, Lakonishok J, Swaminathan B (2007) Industry classifications and return comovement. Financ Anal J 63: 56-70. doi: 10.2469/faj.v63.n6.4927
![]() |
[26] |
Chava S, Jarrow RA (2004) Bankruptcy prediction with industry effects. Rev Financ 8: 537-567. doi: 10.1093/rof/8.4.537
![]() |
[27] | Cohen G, Yagil J (2007) A multinational survey of corporate financial policies. J Appl Financ 17: 57-69. |
[28] |
Consoli D, Elche D (2013) The evolving knowledge base of professional service sectors. J Evol Econ 23: 477-501. doi: 10.1007/s00191-012-0277-1
![]() |
[29] |
Coombs R, Harvey M, Tether BS (2003) Analysing distributed processes of provision and innovation. Ind Corporate Change 12: 1125-1155. doi: 10.1093/icc/12.6.1125
![]() |
[30] |
Correira C, Cramer P (2008) An analysis of cost of capital, capital structure and capital budgeting practices: a survey of South African listed companies. Meditari Accountancy Res 16: 31-52. doi: 10.1108/10222529200800011
![]() |
[31] | Dedman E, Mouselli S, Shen Y, et al. (2009) Accounting, intangible assets, stock market activity, and measurement and disclosure policy—views from the U.K. Abacus 45: 312-341. |
[32] | Dempsey M (2013) The capital asset pricing model (CAPM): The history of a failed revolutionary idea in finance? Abacus 49: 7-23. |
[33] | Dempsey M (2014) The Modigliani and Miller propositions: The history of a failed foundation for corporate finance? Abacus 50: 279-295. |
[34] |
Dobrev S (1999) The dynamics of the Bulgarian newspaper industry in a period of transition: organizational adaptation, structural inertia and political change. Ind Corporate Change 8: 573-605. doi: 10.1093/icc/8.3.573
![]() |
[35] |
Draper PR (1975) Industry Influences on Share Price Variability. J Bus Financ Account 2: 169-185. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5957.1975.tb00931.x
![]() |
[36] |
Dyckman T (2016) Significance Testing: We Can Do Better. Abacus 52: 319-342. doi: 10.1111/abac.12078
![]() |
[37] |
Evangelista R, Lucchese M, Meliciani V (2015) Business services and the export performances of manufacturing industries. J Evol Econ 25: 959-981. doi: 10.1007/s00191-015-0400-1
![]() |
[38] |
Fama E, MacBeth J (1973) Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: Empirical Tests. J Polit Econ 81: 607-636. doi: 10.1086/260061
![]() |
[39] |
Fama E, French K (2002) Testing Trade-Off and Pecking Order Predictions about Dividends and Debt. Rev Financ Stud 15: 1-33. doi: 10.1093/rfs/15.1.1
![]() |
[40] |
Fan JPH, Titman S, Twite G (2012) An international comparison of capital structure and debt maturity choices. J Financ Quant Anal 47: 23-56. doi: 10.1017/S0022109011000597
![]() |
[41] |
Findlay MC, Williams EE (1987) Toward a positive theory of corporate financial policy. Abacus 23: 107-121. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6281.1987.tb00144.x
![]() |
[42] | Frank MZ, Goyal VK (2009) Capital structure decisions: which factors are reliably important? Financ Manage 38: 1-37. |
[43] |
Glosser S, Golden L (2005) Is labour becoming more or less flexible? Changing dynamic behaviour and asymmetries of labour input in US manufacturing. Cambridge J Econ 29: 535-557. doi: 10.1093/cje/bei006
![]() |
[44] |
Graham J, Harvey C (2001) The theory and practice of corporate finance: evidence from the field. J Financ Econ 61: 187-243. doi: 10.1016/S0304-405X(01)00044-7
![]() |
[45] |
Hamilton BH, Nickerson J (2003) Correcting for Endogeneity in Strategic Management Research. Strat Organ 1: 51-78. doi: 10.1177/1476127003001001218
![]() |
[46] |
Hunter L, Webster E, Wyatt A (2012) Accounting for expenditure on intangibles. Abacus 48: 104-145. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6281.2012.00359.x
![]() |
[47] | Jacob O, Allen M, Feinstein SP (2011) Distortion in corporate valuation: implications of capital structure changes. Managerial Financ 38: 681-696. |
[48] |
Jimenez G, Salas V, Saurina J (2006) Determinants of Collateral. J Financ Econ 81: 255-281. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.06.003
![]() |
[49] |
Kale J, Shahrur H (2007) Corporate Capital Structure and the Characteristics of Suppliers and Customers. J Financ Econ 83: 321-365. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.12.007
![]() |
[50] |
Kaplinsky R, Santos-Paulino A (2006) A disaggregated analysis of EU imports: the implications for the study of patterns of trade and technology. Cambridge J Econ 30: 587-611. doi: 10.1093/cje/bei098
![]() |
[51] | Khalid S (2011) Financial reforms and dynamics of capital structure choice: a case of publically listed firms of Pakistan. J Manage Res 3: 1-16. |
[52] |
Korteweg A (2010) The net benefits to leverage. J Financ 65: 2137-2170. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01612.x
![]() |
[53] | Lazonik W, Mazzucato M (2013) The risk-reward nexus in the innovation-inequality relationship: who takes the risks? Who gets the rewards? Ind Corporate Change 22: 1093-1128. |
[54] |
Lev B, Radhakrishnan S, Zhang W (2009) Organization capital. Abacus 45: 275-298. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6281.2009.00289.x
![]() |
[55] |
Levinthal D (2006) The Neo-Schumpeterian theory of the firm and the strategy field. Ind Corporate Change 15: 391-394. doi: 10.1093/icc/dtl004
![]() |
[56] |
Lovelock C, Gummesson E (2004) Whither Services Marketing? In Search of a New Paradigm and Fresh Perspectives. J Serv Res 7: 20-41. doi: 10.1177/1094670504266131
![]() |
[57] | Lovelock C, Wirtz J (2011) Services Marketing: People, Technology and Strategy, Seventh edition, NY. Pearson. |
[58] | MacKay P, Phillips GM (2005) How does industry affect firm financial structure? Rev Financ Stud 18: 1433-1466. |
[59] |
Marrocu E, Paci R, Pontis M (2012) Intangible capital and firms' productivity. Ind Corporate Change 21: 377-402. doi: 10.1093/icc/dtr042
![]() |
[60] | Mateev M, Ivanov K (2011) How SME uniqueness affects capital structure: evidence from central and Eastern Europe panel data. Q J Financ Account 50: 115-143. |
[61] | Matyas L, Sevestre P (2008) The Econometrics of Panel Data, 3rd Edition, Springer. |
[62] |
Mathews JA (2003) Competitive dynamics and economic learning: An extended resource-based view. Ind Corporate Change 12: 115-145. doi: 10.1093/icc/12.1.115
![]() |
[63] |
Mazzoleni R, Nelson R (2013) An interpretive history of challenges to neoclassical microeconomics and how they have fared. Ind Corporate Change 22: 1409-1451. doi: 10.1093/icc/dtt031
![]() |
[64] |
McNally GM, Eng LH (1980) Management accounting practices and company characteristics. Abacus 16: 142-150. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6281.1980.tb00094.x
![]() |
[65] | Miles ID, Tether B (2001) Surveying Innovation in Service: Measurement and Policy Interpretation Issues, Luxembourg: European Commission Publication. |
[66] | Miller MH (1977) Debt and taxes. J Financ 32: 261-275. |
[67] | Modigliani F, Miller M (1958) The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment. Am Econ Rev 68: 261-297. |
[68] | Modigliani F, Miller MH (1963) Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction. Am Econ Rev: 433-443. |
[69] | Nelson R, Winter S (1982) An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. |
[70] |
Newey WK, West KD (1987) Hypothesis testing with efficient method of moments estimation. Int Econ Rev 28: 777-787. doi: 10.2307/2526578
![]() |
[71] |
Orhangazi O (2008) Financialisation and capital accumulation in the non-financial corporate sector. Cambridge J Econ 32: 863-886. doi: 10.1093/cje/ben009
![]() |
[72] |
Parasuraman A, Zeithaml VA, Berry LL (1985) A Conceptual Model of Service Quality and Its Implications for Future Research. J Mark 49: 41-50. doi: 10.1177/002224298504900403
![]() |
[73] |
Peneder M (2002) Intangible investment and human resources. J Evol Econ 12: 107-134. doi: 10.1007/s00191-002-0103-2
![]() |
[74] |
Penman SH (2009) Accounting for intangible assets: There is also an income statement. Abacus 45: 358-371. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6281.2009.00293.x
![]() |
[75] |
Petersen MA (2009) Estimating standard errors in finance panel data sets: Comparing approaches. Rev Financ Stud 22: 435-480. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhn053
![]() |
[76] |
Rajan R, Zingales L (1995) What Do We Know about Capital Structure? Some Evidence from International Data. J Financ 50: 1421-1460. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1995.tb05184.x
![]() |
[77] |
Rathmell JM (1966) What is meant by services. J Mark 30: 32-36. doi: 10.1177/002224296603000407
![]() |
[78] |
Rauh JD, Sufi A (2012) Explaining corporate capital structure: product markets, leases, and asset similarity. Rev Financ 16: 115-155. doi: 10.1093/rof/rfr023
![]() |
[79] |
Santamaría L, Nieto MJ, Miles I (2012) Service innovation in manufacturing firms: Evidence from Spain. Technovation 32: 144-155. doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2011.08.006
![]() |
[80] |
Scellato G (2007) Patents, firm size and financial constraints: an empirical analysis for a panel of Italian manufacturing firms. Cambridge J Econ 31: 55-76. doi: 10.1093/cje/bel006
![]() |
[81] | Seelantha SL (2010) Determinants of capital structure: further evidence from China. Manage Financ Mark 5: 106-126. |
[82] | Shaver MJ (1998) Accounting for Endogeneity When Assessing Strategy Performance: Does Entry Mode Choice Affect FDI Survival? Manage Sci 44: 571-586. |
[83] | Shi G, Sun J, Zhang L (2017) Product market competition and earnings management: A firm-level analysis. J Bus Fin Acc. |
[84] |
Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1997) A survey of corporate governance. J Financ 52: 737-783. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb04820.x
![]() |
[85] |
Shostack G (1977) Breaking Free From Product Marketing. J Mark 41: 73-80. doi: 10.1177/002224297704100219
![]() |
[86] |
Stadler C, Nobes CW (2014) The influence of country, industry, and topic factors on IFRS policy choice. Abacus 50: 386-421. doi: 10.1111/abac.12035
![]() |
[87] |
Tether BS (2003) The sources and aims of innovation in services: variety between and within sectors. Econ Innovation New Technol 12: 481-505. doi: 10.1080/1043859022000029221
![]() |
[88] |
Tether B, Hipp C, Miles I (2001) Standardisation and Particularisation in Services: evidence from Germany. Res Policy 30: 1115-1138. doi: 10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00133-5
![]() |
[89] |
Titman S (1984) The Determinants of Capital Structure on a Firm's Liquidation Decision. J Financ Econ 13: 137-151. doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(84)90035-7
![]() |
[90] |
Titman S (2002) The Modigliani and Miller Theorem and the Integration of Financial Markets. Financ Manage 31: 101-115. doi: 10.2307/3666323
![]() |
[91] |
Titman S, Tsyplakov S (2007) A dynamic model of optimal capital structure. Rev Financ 11: 401-451. doi: 10.1093/rof/rfm017
![]() |
[92] |
Titman S, Wessels R (1988) The Determinants of Capital Structure Choice. J Financ 43: 1-19. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1988.tb02585.x
![]() |
[93] |
Tollington T, Spinelli G (2012) Applying Wand and Weber's surface and deep structure approaches to financial reporting systems. Abacus 48: 502-517. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6281.2012.00376.x
![]() |
[94] | Ughetto E (2008) Does internal finance matter for R & D? New evidence from a panel of Italian firms. Cambridge J Econ 32: 907-925. |
[95] | Volpe R, Woodlock P (2008) A survey of board financial literacy. Corporate Financ Rev 12: 16-21. |
[96] |
Wang L (2009) Ownership, size, and the formal structure of organizations: evidence from US public and private firms, 1992-2002. Ind Corporate Change 18: 595-636. doi: 10.1093/icc/dtp018
![]() |
[97] |
Wines G, Ferguson C (1993) An empirical investigation of accounting methods for goodwill and identifiable intangible assets: 1985 to 1989. Abacus 29: 90-105. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6281.1993.tb00423.x
![]() |
[98] |
Winter SG (2006) Toward a Neo-Schumpeterian theory of the firm. Ind Corporate Change 15: 125-141. doi: 10.1093/icc/dtj006
![]() |
[99] | Wooldridge J (2002) Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, Boston, MIT Press. |
[100] | Wooldridge J (2006) Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, 3rd edition. Mason, OH: Thomson-South Western. |
[101] |
Zeithaml VA, Parasuraman A, Berry LL (1985) Problems and Strategies in Services Marketing. J Mark 49: 33-46. doi: 10.1177/002224298504900203
![]() |
[102] | Zhang Y (2010) The product category effects on capital structure: evidence from the SMEs of British manufacturing industry. Int J Bus Manage 5: 86-112. |
![]() |
![]() |
1. | Qian Yan, Libo An, Gang Cai, Qiao-Li Dong, Strong convergence of inertial extragradient methods for solving pseudomonotone variational inequality problems, 2025, 10075704, 108938, 10.1016/j.cnsns.2025.108938 |