Citation: Semu Mitiku Kassa. Three-level global resource allocation model for HIV control: A hierarchical decision system approach[J]. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2018, 15(1): 255-273. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2018011
[1] | Oluwaseun Sharomi, Chandra N. Podder, Abba B. Gumel, Baojun Song . Mathematical analysis of the transmission dynamics of HIV/TB coinfection in the presence of treatment. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2008, 5(1): 145-174. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2008.5.145 |
[2] | Agustín Gabriel Yabo, Jean-Baptiste Caillau, Jean-Luc Gouzé . Optimal bacterial resource allocation: metabolite production in continuous bioreactors. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(6): 7074-7100. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020364 |
[3] | Dana Paquin, Doron Levy, Lei Xing . Multiscale deformable registration of noisy medical images. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2008, 5(1): 125-144. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2008.5.125 |
[4] | Shahab Shamshirband, Javad Hassannataj Joloudari, Sahar Khanjani Shirkharkolaie, Sanaz Mojrian, Fatemeh Rahmani, Seyedakbar Mostafavi, Zulkefli Mansor . Game theory and evolutionary optimization approaches applied to resource allocation problems in computing environments: A survey. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2021, 18(6): 9190-9232. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2021453 |
[5] | Ali Gharouni, Lin Wang . Modeling the spread of bed bug infestation and optimal resource allocation for disinfestation. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2016, 13(5): 969-980. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2016025 |
[6] | Dana Paquin, Doron Levy, Lei Xing . Hybrid multiscale landmark and deformable image registration. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2007, 4(4): 711-737. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2007.4.711 |
[7] | Gesham Magombedze, Winston Garira, Eddie Mwenje . Modelling the immunopathogenesis of HIV-1 infection and the effect of multidrug therapy: The role of fusion inhibitors in HAART. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2008, 5(3): 485-504. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2008.5.485 |
[8] | Yafei Li, Yuxi Liu . Multi-airport system flight slot optimization method based on absolute fairness. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(10): 17919-17948. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023797 |
[9] | Zehan Liu, Daoxin Qiu, Shengqiang Liu . A two-group epidemic model with heterogeneity in cognitive effects. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2025, 22(5): 1109-1139. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2025040 |
[10] | Gordon Akudibillah, Abhishek Pandey, Jan Medlock . Optimal control for HIV treatment. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(1): 373-396. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019018 |
Funds have been raised globally to help the fight for HIV and AIDS epidemics in low-and middle-income countries. In the year 2014 alone USD 19.2 billion was made available globally to finance the response to AIDS in such countries. Out of this, USD 8.5 billion was handled by the global organizations like The Global Fund to fight AIDS, Tuberculosis and Malaria, and UNITAID [1,14,25]. The type and intensity of response may vary from region to region and from country to country depending on the type of risk groups, rate of prevalence, social make-ups and economic conditions they have.
Globally over 36.7 million people are leaving with HIV and of these cases about 70.5% live in Sub-Saharan Africa, 13.8% live in Asia, 4.6% in Latin America, and around 3% live in Eastern Europe and central Asia. More than 1.8 million children under the age of 15 live with HIV/AIDS globally and among them more than 83 percent live in Sub-Sahara African region. A further 2.1 million people were infected in the year 2015 [24]. Every day over 5,700 new HIV infections occur worldwide. Out of these more than 95 percent occur in low-and middle-income countries and above 600 new cases per day are among children under 15 [24]. It is estimated that more than 90% of infant infection is caused by mother-to-child transmission which could have been prevented. In general global HIV prevalence (proportion of people with HIV) is remaining at the same level, although the global number of people with HIV is rising because of new infections and longer survival times, and continuously growing global total population.
In the absence of a curing medicine and a working vaccination, the investment to control the HIV epidemics is mainly to reduce the total number of new infections and the rate of progression to AIDS.
Untreated HIV progress to AIDS and death in most individuals. The antiretroviral (ARV) therapy to HIV infected people limits the viral replication allowing either immune preservation (at the earlier course of the infection) or immune reconstruction, resulting in durable, life-saving effects. The ARV treatment has two fold advantages: an advantage to the infected person as a treatment to increase the healthy life of the infected individual and an advantage to the society at large in decreasing the rate of infectiousness of the infected individual. The use of ART can significantly reduce the plasma viral load (by up to six orders of magnitude [16]) which decreases the rate of infectiousness of a treated person.
The other outcome of the ART intervention both to the individual and the society is that it reduces the costs of illness which may include hospitalization and the use of other expensive therapies. However, only about 17 million people worldwide received ART at the end of 2015 [24] and this amounts to only 46% of the total.
The intervention to reduce, and eventually eliminate the Mother-to-Child Transmission (MTCT), which is also called a vertical transmission, is through the use of ARVs during pregnancy and delivery and to the infants following births and the use of replacement infant feeding [4]. It is known that potent viral suppression greatly reduces perinatal HIV transmission.
To finance the interventions, the fund raised globally is very limited. It is only up to 70% of the required amount even at its pick stage [15,25] (see Fig. 1).
Due to economic difficulties or political reasons international aid may fluctuate significantly and hence the investment on health care could be highly affected, in particular in low-and middle-income countries. Therefore, the scarce resources have to be allocated optimally to get better and tangible achievements, in epidemic terms.
Health economics theory states that allocating resources to medical interventions in increasing order of their cost-effectiveness ratios until the available budget has been exhausted will result in the optimal allocation of funds [6,27]. Actually this leads to a Give-it-all or nothing strategy. Moreover, to establish the Cost-Effectiveness criteria one needs to collect adequate data on the population distribution and generate cost-effectiveness data for individual and community-level interventions. Even in the perfect information case, 'Allocation by Cost-Effectiveness' (ACE) does not allow for several important factors such as, increasing or diminishing marginal returns to scale, mutual exclusivity of programmes, and interaction of program outcomes, which are necessary to be taken into consideration [18].
Therefore, several researchers have proposed the method of operations research in allocating resources for HIV interventions (see for instance [2,3,7,8,30,31] and the references therein). However, all of them use one level-optimization procedures, which assume that resources are allocated by the same country where the programs are implemented. Such models may work well for resource allocation decisions in developed countries, where the fund is raised only from within the country itself.
A two level resource allocation model has been proposed in [18]. However, this model assumes that the lower level problem has a unique solution, which is not normally the case, especially when the production functions used are not linear (which is true even with the model formulation of the same paper). Therefore, it could be difficult to apply the proposed method in practical situations. Moreover, the effect of ART in reducing new infections was not considered in the model.
In this work a simplified epidemic model with the inclusion of the effect of ART will be used to formulate a global resource allocation model for HIV control. The paper shall concentrate on developing and analyzing the model where the decision for resource allocation passes through various levels. Such levels could be two or more depending on the organizational structure of the global financing agencies and on the mechanism they allocate resources to developing countries.
The remaining part of this paper is organized as follows: the resource allocation problem and the structure of the levels have been formulated and analyzed separately in Section 2, while Section 3 is devoted for the analysis of the model in its entirety. The paper is concluded with a discussion in Section 4.
The decision for international fund allocation for HIV prevention programs to low-and middle-income countries usually passes through various stages, with all of them aiming in controlling the epidemics and reducing human sufferings. We assume that major decision points in allocating funds can be classified into three hierarchical groupings; the upper level can be taken as the International funding organization, the middle level can be the Regional representatives and the lower level being the Country representatives. Due to the variation in prevalence, the main factors in the transmission mode of the disease, the economic condition and their social set-up, etc. countries with closer features (in addition to their geographic proximities) are classified by many international funding agencies in to some regions, like the Sub-Sahara Africa, Latin America, the Middle East and North Africa, Asia, etc. We take these regional forms as a middle level decision points in the resource allocation process. The diagram in Fig. 2 indicates the structure of the model under study.
At each stage of the resource allocation process indicated in Fig. 2, the final common goal of investment, which is assumed to be controlling the epidemics and improving the quality of healthy life of the society, will be checked. That means, the investment is targeted to positively affect the dynamics of the epidemics. There are several models in literature which try to describe the dynamics of the HIV infection and spread in the population with ARV treatment. The schematic diagram in Fig. 3 indicates one of such models where interventions have impact on the disease dynamics.
The dynamical system representing the schematic diagram in Fig. 3 will be given by the following set of differential equations.
dVdt=mβ(I+ε2T)−(γρ+μ+δV)VdSdt=π−λS(I+ε1T)Q−μSdIdt=λS(I+ε1T)Q−(ρ+σ+μ)IdTdt=ρ(γV+I)−(α+μ)TdAdt=σI+αT−(μ+δA)A S(0)+V(0)+I(0)+T(0)+A(0)=1, |
where
If we assume that the interventions have direct effect on some of the parameters in the system, allocation of resources should yield in decreasing the rate of infection (
dVdt=ϕm(y1)β(I+ε2T)−(γϕρ(y3)+μ+δV)V | (1) |
dSdt=π−ϕλ(y2)S(I+ε1T)Q−μS | (2) |
dIdt=ϕλ(y2)S(I+ε1T)Q−(ρ+σ+μ)I | (3) |
dTdt=ϕρ(y3)(γV+I)−(ϕα(y4)+μ)T | (4) |
dAdt=σI+ϕα(y4)T−(μ+δA)A | (5) |
S(0)+V(0)+I(0)+T(0)+A(0)=1 | (6) |
If
Since non-treated children with HIV have a 10 times higher mortality rate compared to those of other children [21], it is assumed that they will not become sexually active in the population (especially in low-income countries where child mortality rate is significantly high). However, those who are getting proper ARV treatment may mature to adulthood at a rate of
Assume that there are
The goal of the interventions program is mainly to minimize the total number of individuals who become newly infected, both in the category of the newly born children with an infected status (
The objective function of the resource optimization problem at the lower level is, therefore, simply taking the total sum of the contribution of the incidence of the newborns and the incidence of adults due to sexual contacts in the given period of time in all the community groups of a country, which is a function of the investment variables.
If a total of
fkj(ykji)=Mj∑i=1∫τ0e−rt{(ϕλi(y2kji)Si(t)[Ii(t)+ε1Ti(t)Qi(t)]) +ϕmi(y1kji)β(Ii(t)+ε2Ti(t))}dt, | (7) |
where
T(t+δt)=T(t)+[ϕρ(y3)(γV(t)+I(t))−(ϕα(y4)+μ)T(t)]δt =ϕρ(y3)[γV(t)+I(t)]δt−[(ϕα(y4)+μ)δt−1]T(t) |
By reformulating this last equation we can get the value of
T(t)=ϕρ(y3)[γV(t−δt)+I(t−δt)]δt−[(ϕα(y4)+μ)δt−1]T(t−δt), | (8) |
where,
fkj(ykji)=Mj∑i=1∫τ0e−rt{ϕλi(y2kji)Si(t)Qi(t)[Ii(t) +ε1(ϕρi(y3kji)[γVi(t−δt)+Ii(t−δt)]δt −[(ϕαi(y4kji)+μ)δt−1]Ti(t−δt))] +ϕmi(y1kji)β[Ii(t)+ε2(ϕρi(y3kji)[γVi(t−δt)+Ii(t−δt)]δt −[(ϕαi(y4kji)+μ)δt−1]Ti(t−δt))]}dt, | (9) |
which is a nonlinear (non-convex) function of the investment variables. Even in the cases when the cost functions
In determining the value of
In the expression above, the variable vectors
If the planning time horizon
Therefore, the resource allocation problem at the lower decision point will be given by a non convex optimization problem:
minykjiNjfkj(ykji)Subject to Mj∑i=1(y1kji+y2kji+y3kji+y4kji)≤xkj | (10) |
Here, the constraint reflects that the total investment in country
The solution
On the other hand the Middle-Level decision maker (region
maxxk1,…,xkNn Fk=hk1xk1+hk2xk2+⋯+hkNnxkNn Subject to xk1+xk2+⋯+xkNn≤vk | (11) |
where
One possible way of estimating the values of
hkj=w1r1kj×e1kjNkj×c1kj+w2r2kj×e2kjNkj×c2kj, |
where,
The coefficients
If a solution
Fk(vk)=hk1x∗k1(vk)+hk2x∗k2(vk)+⋯+hkNkx∗kNk(vk) | (12) |
The upper level problem will then be finding an optimal allocation
maxv1,…,vn n∑kFk(vk)Subject to v1+v2+⋯+vn≤B xkj≥dkjvk for each k=1 to n Mj∑i=1yℓkji≥zℓkjvk for each ℓ=1,2,3,4, | (13) |
where,
When we combine all the three problems described in the previous section in sequential order the general resource allocation problem takes the form,
maxv1,…,vn n∑kFk(vk) Subject to v1+v2+⋯+vn≤B xkj≥dkjvk for each k=1ton Mj∑i=1yℓkji≥zℓkjvk for each ℓ=1,2,3,4, where xkj,ylkji solvemaxxk1,…,xkNn Fk=hk1xk1+hk2xk2+⋯+hkNnxkNnSubject toxk1+xk2+⋯+xkNn≤vk where, ykji solves minykjiNjfkj(ykji) Subject to Mj∑i=1(y1kji+y2kji+y3kji+y4kji)≤xkj | (14) |
where all the variables are nonnegative. i.e.,
Given a total budget
Accepting the values
Therefore, the optimization problem solved at each stage is a (multi-)parametric problem, where the parameters are decision variables at other decision levels. Moreover, the decision process is hierarchical as the global planner should declare its optimal allocation of funds first for the middle level to act. However, a one level solution procedures may not help to arrive at the optimal solution of such kind of problems as the parameters need to be rechecked again for their agreement with the optimality requirements at each other levels. That means, we need to apply solution techniques for multilevel programming problems to eventually arrive at the optimal allocation of resources for HIV interventions. The techniques that we may choose to solve the problem, however, depend on the types of the production functions for investment of each of the 4 types of the interventions.
Since all the constraints in problem (14) are linear inequalities in investment variables at all levels, the constraint set is polyhedral. But since the objective function of the lower level problem is non-convex, even when all the production functions are chosen to be linear, unique solutions may not be obtained at lower levels and we do not also expect that only full utilization of funds give optimal solutions. Proper definition of the production functions for each of the intervention types requires a closer study on the nature of the investment and its impact on the corresponding parameter values. Although linear functions are easy to work with, such linear approximations may not take important behaviors of the parameters into consideration. Therefore, it is advisable to use a combination of models depending on the nature of interventions.
In some of the intervention programs each incremental unit of money spent may produce the same incremental reduction or upsurge in epidemic component. In such type of programs the production function could be taken to be linear as a function of investment variables [2,3]. In our model, for example, to formulate the proportion of investment in increasing the rate of recruitment for treatment (
On the other hand, production functions that are related to a change in the risky behavior of group of individuals, an incremental investment in such programs may not usually produce the same incremental reduction in the risky behavior of individuals [12]. This is because, as the program expands the individuals reached are increasingly less likely to change their risky behavior. In such cases we may better model the corresponding production function by a function which is convex with respect to the investment variables. In our model, the investment in reducing the rate of infection due to unsafe sexual contacts (
ϕλ(y)={λmin, if 0≤y≤F;λmin(a+bec(F−y)), if y>F, |
where
Once the model is properly formulated the next step will be to choose the best solution procedure that can give us an optimal solution. Since, all the constraint sets are polyhedral in investment variables, the solution approach depends on the type of definition of the production functions which appear in the objective function of the lower level problem. If all the production functions are twice continuously differentiable functions,
To show the procedure for solving the global resource allocation problem using a tri-level hierarchical model, we formulated a hypothetical example. In this situation, assume there are 3 regions globally and a total of
1In this example, the allocated budget
For the formulation of the upper level (global) and the middle level (regional) resource allocation problems, the following parameters values are used.
hkj=(0.20.30.310.390.250.4), dkj=(20%25%30%15%25%20%), |
where, the rows represent the regions and the columns represent the countries. The entries in the matrix
In the lower level problem there are various parameters to be used. Some of them are disease parameters that remain constant across the glob and some others are country or risk group specific. They are summarized in Tables 1 and 2. (Some of these parameters are from [5,13,19,23,26,28] and the rest are estimated.)
Parameter value | Description |
mortality rate for infected children | |
additional death rate due to AIDS | |
rate of progression to AIDS, if not treated | |
preferential rate of recruitment for children to receive ART | |
transmission probability | |
factor of reduction on rate of disease transmission due to ART | |
factor of reduction on rate of MTCT due to treatment |
Parameter values | Description (each is for the 6 countries) |
Birth rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Death rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for high risk groups | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for high risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of defaulting in the use of ART-assumed to be the same for both risk groups in each of the countries | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in High risk groups | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in Low risk groups |
Initial size for the Low Risk population group in the 6 countries is assumed to be as in the table below,
Pop. Size | R1C1 | R1C2 | R2C1 | R2C2 | R3C1 | R3C2 | |
S(0) | 15652504 | 870885.6 | 35863200 | 7341600 | 28122000 | 16815000 | , |
V(0) | 87640 | 12854.4 | 652800 | 151200 | 548250 | 285000 | |
I(0) | 1016624 | 107120 | 1632000 | 361200 | 1322250 | 627000 | |
T(0) | 438200 | 47132.8 | 1836000 | 411600 | 1451250 | 855000 | |
A(0) | 333032 | 33207.2 | 816000 | 134400 | 806250 | 418000 |
and the initial size for High Risk population group in the 6 countries is taken to be as in the following table.
Pop. Size | R1C1 | R1C2 | R2C1 | R2C2 | R3C1 | R3C2 |
S(0) | 11706200 | 611078.4 | 13785600 | 2656800 | 7998000 | 4512000 |
V(0) | 110176 | 25708.8 | 499200 | 57600 | 193500 | 90000 |
I(0) | 1170620 | 208636.8 | 2515200 | 417600 | 1236250 | 666000 |
T(0) | 454476 | 84048 | 1632000 | 342000 | 1053500 | 600000 |
A(0) | 330528 | 59328 | 768000 | 126000 | 268750 | 132000 |
The production functions for the model are chosen to be
ϕmi(y1)=m(1+a2y1), ϕλi(y2)=λ(1+e−(c1y2))ϕρi(y3)=ρ(1+a1y3), ϕαi(y4)=α(1+e−(c2y4)), |
with
Then, given the leader's variable
In choosing a solution approach, it is considered that since the lower level objective of the problem is defined in terms of an integral form, it will be expensive to calculate the first and second order derivatives. Hence, the algorithm in [29] is used to get the solution. After reformulation and running the SEAMSP algorithm [29] for the above tri-level problem, we obtain the solutions as in Table 3. The values in this table are given in millions of USD.
Low Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
125.46 | 234.63 | 310.64 | 107.62 | 172.46 | 423.69 | |||
89.14 | 193.46 | 154.29 | 98.947 | 193.42 | 244.36 | |||
97.432 | 102.46 | 196.98 | 69.442 | 207.16 | 219.80 | |||
49.864 | 299.87 | 130.26 | 124.67 | 154.32 | 501.64 | |||
High Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
28.808 | 125.01 | 120.09 | 77.004 | 124.50 | 142.29 | |||
65.128 | 166.29 | 276.41 | 85.677 | 103.49 | 321.64 | |||
56.836 | 257.30 | 233.75 | 115.18 | 89.809 | 346.20 | |||
104.41 | 60.049 | 300.46 | 59.954 | 142.64 | 64.384 |
When these optimal investment values are used in the dynamical system it can be seen from the simulation graphs (Fig. 4 - 6) that the prevalence of the disease decreases significantly in each of the countries in the region.
In this paper a hierarchical model for global resource allocation of the funds that are raised to fight HIV/AIDS is formulated and analyzed. It has been shown that when the effect of treatment in the aversion of new infection is employed in the model, the objective function of the lower level decision making structure is neither convex nor concave in the allocation variables even if all the production functions are assumed to be linear. This made the resulting multilevel optimization problem difficult to solve with classical operations research methods.
Here, it is assumed that there are three levels of decisions in the global allocation of resources. However, a two level decision system can also be analyzed using a similar approach by simply merging the middle level with the upper level decision making structure. Since the main difficulty (in terms of solution approaches) arises due to the properties of the lower level objective function, the two level version of the problem also requires the same solution techniques recommended in this paper. On the other hand if the number of levels (or hierarchies) is increased from 3 to any possible number in the formulation of the model, the analysis of the model again follows a similar argument and structure. The solution techniques of any such multilevel problems also depend on the type of constraints and criteria functions formulated at each level of decision. The effectiveness of this model is not yet proved by taking actual data from the field. Nonetheless, unlike the conclusion in [18] (which recommends the use of equity -optimal approach), the author recommends the use of optimal -optimal approach over the other possible decision approaches between the levels as equity parameters are already included in the model constraints.
This study considered the allocation of resources to control the HIV epidemic in a multiple but independent communities of the population in any country. Though the model relies upon the epidemic behavior of HIV/AIDS, the model structure and the analysis given in this paper are likely to be applied to other types of diseases provided some of the interventions also result in reducing the infectiousness of the infected individuals. Moreover, one can also use a similar model to allocate resources to control multiple diseases in the same population (like, for example, Tuberculosis (TB) and Malaria) if the epidemics are assumed to be independent. But since some infections are not independent, one need to apply a different modeling structure for non-independent diseases (like, for example, HIV and TB, HIV and other sexually transmitted diseases) because the same intervention may have an impact on the incidence of the other diseases as well.
In this paper it is also assumed that countries within a region, or regions within the global settings do not compete each other to receive higher resources from higher level resource allocation body for any of the intervention programs. If the resource allocation structure allows for such a competition, then one has to apply a multi-level multi-follower method to get an optimal solution. However, such techniques are not well developed yet to handle various formulations of lower level problems. Therefore, this requires a further research especially when the objective functions of the lower level decision makers (in our case the country level resource allocation structure) need to solve non-convex and non-concave problems with resources are shared among them.
This work is partly supported by the Swedish International Science Program (ISP), through the project at the Department of Mathematics, Addis Ababa University.
[1] | [ Avert, Funding for HIV and AIDS, 2016. Available from URL http://www.avert.org/node/353/pdf |
[2] | [ M. L. Brandeau,G. S. Zaric,A. Richter, Resource allocation for control of infectious diseases in multiple independent populations: Beyond cost-effectiveness analysis, Journal of Health Economics, 22 (2003): 575-598. |
[3] | [ M. L. Brandeau,G. S. Zaric,V. De Angelis, Improved allocation of HIV prevention resources: Using information about prevention program production functions, Health Care Management Science, 8 (2005): 19-28. |
[4] | [ Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC), Achievements in public health, reduction in perinatal transmission of HIV infection -United States, 1985 -2005, MMWR Morb Mortal Wkly Rep, 55 (2006), 592-597. |
[5] | [ D. Donnell,J. M. Baeten,J. Kiarie,K. K. Thomas,W. Stevens,C. R. Cohen,J. Mclntyre,J. R. Lingappa,C. Celum, Heterosexual HIV-1 transmission after initiation of antiretroviral therapy: A prospective cohort analysis, Lancet, 375 (2010): 2092-2098. |
[6] | [ M. Drummond, B. O'Brien, G. L. Stoddart and G. J. Torrance (Eds. ), Methods for the Economic Evaluation of Health Care Programs, Oxford University Press, New York, 2000. |
[7] | [ S. R. Earnshaw,K. Hicks,A. Richter,A. Honeycutt, A linear programming model for allocating HIV prevention funds with state agencies: A pilot study, Health Care Manage Sci, 10 (2007): 239-252. |
[8] | [ S. Flessa, Where efficiency saves lives: A linear programme for the optimal allocation of health care resources in developing countries, Health Care Management Science, 3 (2000): 249-267. |
[9] | [ A. M. Kassa,S. M. Kassa, A multi-parametric programming algorithm for special classes of non-convex multilevel optimization problems, An International Journal of Optimization and Control: Theories & Applications (IJOCTA), 3 (2013): 133-144. |
[10] | [ A. M. Kassa,S. M. Kassa, A branch-and-bound multi-parametric programming approach for non-convex multilevel optimization with polyhedral constraints, Journal of Global Optimization, 64 (2016): 745-764. |
[11] | [ A. M. Kassa,S. M. Kassa, Deterministic solution approach for some classes of nonlinear multilevel programs with multiple followers, J Glob Optim, null (2017): 1-19. |
[12] | [ S. M. Kassa,A. Ouhinou, The impact of self-protective measures in the optimal interventions for controlling infectious diseases of human population, Journal of Mathematical Biology, 70 (2015): 213-236. |
[13] | [ S. M. Kassa,A. Ouhinou, Epidemiological models with prevalence dependent endogenous self-protection measure, Mathematical Biosciences, 229 (2011): 41-49. |
[14] | [ J. Kates, J. A. Izazola and E. Lief, Financing the response to HIV in low-and middle-income countries: , International assistance from donor governments in 2015,2015. Available from: http://files.kff.org/attachment/Financing-the-Response-to-HIV-in-Low-and-Middle-Income-Countries-International-Assistance-from-Donor-Governments-in-2015 |
[15] | [ J. Kates, A. Wexler and E. Lief, Financing the response to HIV in low-and middle-income countries: International assistance from donor governments in 2013, UNAIDS Report, July 2014. Available from: https://kaiserfamilyfoundation.files.wordpress.com/2014/07/7347-10-financing-the-response-to-hiv-in-low-and-middle-income-countries.pdf |
[16] | [ J. M. Kilby,H. Y. Lee,J. D. Hazelwood,A. Bansal,R. P. Bucy,M. S. Saag,G. M. Shaw,E. P. Acosta,V. A. Johnson,A. S. Perelson,P. A. Goepfert, Treatment response in acute/early infection versus advanced AIDS: Equivalent first and second phase of HIV RNA decline, AIDS, 22 (2008): 957-962. |
[17] | [ A. P. Kourtis,C. H. Schmid,D. J. Jamieson,J. Lau, Use of Antiretroviral therapy in HIV-infected pregnant women and the risk of premature delivery: A meta-analysis, AIDS, 21 (2007): 607-615. |
[18] | [ A. Lasry,G. S. Zaric,M. W. Carter, Multi-level resource allocation for HIV prevention: A model for developing countries, European Journal of Operational Research, 180 (2007): 786-799. |
[19] | [ F. J. Palella,K. M. Delaney,A. C. Moorman,M. O. Loveless,J. Fuhrer,G. A. Satten, Declining morbidity and mortality among patients with advanced human immunodeficiency virus infection, The New England Journal of Medicine, 338 (1998): 853-860. |
[20] | [ L. Palombi,M. C. Marazzi,A. Voetberg,N. A. Magid, Treatment acceleration program and the experience of the DREAM program in prevention of mother-to-child transmission of HIV, AIDS, 21 (2007): S65-S71. |
[21] | [ A. Prendergast,G. Tudor-Williams,S. Burchett,P. Goulder, International perspectives, progress, and future challenges of paediatric HIV infection, Lancet, 370 (2007): 68-80. |
[22] | [ N. Siegfried, L. van der Merwe, P. Brocklehurst and T. T. Sint, Antiretrovirals for reducing the risk of mother-to-child transmission of HIV infection, Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews 2011, 7 (2011), Art. CD003510. |
[23] | [ J. A. C. Sterne,M. A. Henán,B. Ledergerber,K. Tilling,R. Weber,P. Sendi, Long-term effectiveness of potent antiretroviral therapy in preventing AIDS and death: A prospective cohort study, Lancet, 366 (2005): 378-384. |
[24] | [ UNAIDS, AIDS by the numbers, 2016. Available from: http://www.unaids.org/sites/default/files/media_asset/AIDS-by-the-numbers-2016_en.pdf. |
[25] | [ UNAIDS, Fast-track update on investments needed in the AIDS response, UNAIDS Reference, 2016. Available from: http://www.unaids.org/sites/default/files/media_asset/UNAIDS_Reference_FastTrack_Update_on_investments_en.pdf |
[26] | [ R. Vardavas and S. Blower, The emergence of HIV transmitted resistance in Botswana: When will the WHO detection threshold be exceeded? PLoS ONE, 2 (2007), e152. |
[27] | [ M. C. Weinstein, From cos-effectiveness ratios to resource allocation: where to draw the line?, in Valuing Healthcare: Costs, Benefits, Effectiveness of phramaceuticals and other medical technologies (eds. F. A. Sloan), Cambridge University Press, New York (1995), 77-97. |
[28] | [ World Health Organization, Towards Universal Access: Scaling up Priority HIV/AIDS Interventions in the Health Sector: Progress Report 2009, WHO, 2009. |
[29] | [ A. T. Woldemariam,S. M. Kassa, Systematic evolutionary algorithm for general multilevel Stackelberg problems with bounded decision variables (SEAMSP), Annals of Operations Research, 229 (2015): 771-790. |
[30] | [ G. S. Zaric,M. L. Brandeau, Resource allocation for epidemic control over short time horizons, Mathematical Biosciences, 171 (2001): 33-58. |
[31] | [ G. S. Zaric,M. L. Brandeau, A little planning goes a long way: Multilevel allocation of HIV prevention resources, Medical Decision Making, 27 (2007): 71-81. |
1. | Stephan Dempe, 2020, Chapter 20, 978-3-030-52118-9, 581, 10.1007/978-3-030-52119-6_20 | |
2. | Sofie Stulens, Kim De Boeck, Nico Vandaele, HIV supply chains in low- and middle-income countries: overview and research opportunities, 2021, ahead-of-print, 2042-6747, 10.1108/JHLSCM-08-2020-0072 | |
3. | Natnael Nigussie Goshu, Semu Mitiku Kassa, Stochastic bilevel programming with multiple followers: a solution approach using the systematic sampling evolutionary method, 2021, 0305-215X, 1, 10.1080/0305215X.2021.1912034 | |
4. | Addis Belete Zewde, Semu Mitiku Kassa, Hierarchical multilevel optimization with multiple-leaders multiple-followers setting and nonseparable objectives, 2021, 55, 0399-0559, 2915, 10.1051/ro/2021146 | |
5. | Seyfe Belete Worku, Birilew Belayneh Tsegaw, Semu Mitiku Kassa, Multilevel Reverse Stackelberg Differential Games: Existence and Solution Approach for Affine Strategies, 2023, 196, 0022-3239, 617, 10.1007/s10957-022-02149-1 | |
6. | Addis Belete Zewde, Semu Mitiku Kassa, Multilevel multi-leader multiple-follower games with nonseparable objectives and shared constraints, 2021, 18, 1619-697X, 455, 10.1007/s10287-021-00398-5 | |
7. | Seyfe Belete Worku, Birilew Belayneh Tsegaw, Semu Mitiku Kassa, Existence and computations of best affine strategies for multilevel reverse Stackelberg games, 2023, 1432-2994, 10.1007/s00186-023-00820-5 | |
8. | Ashenafi Awraris, Berhanu Guta Wordofa, Semu Mitiku Kassa, Branch-and-cut solution approach for multilevel mixed integer linear programming problems, 2023, 11, 21924406, 100076, 10.1016/j.ejco.2023.100076 | |
9. | Andres Cardenas, Aura Jalal, Alfredo Moreno, Prioritizing public resources for riverbank erosion protection: A decision support framework, 2024, 22124209, 105029, 10.1016/j.ijdrr.2024.105029 |
Parameter value | Description |
mortality rate for infected children | |
additional death rate due to AIDS | |
rate of progression to AIDS, if not treated | |
preferential rate of recruitment for children to receive ART | |
transmission probability | |
factor of reduction on rate of disease transmission due to ART | |
factor of reduction on rate of MTCT due to treatment |
Parameter values | Description (each is for the 6 countries) |
Birth rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Death rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for high risk groups | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for high risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of defaulting in the use of ART-assumed to be the same for both risk groups in each of the countries | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in High risk groups | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in Low risk groups |
Low Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
125.46 | 234.63 | 310.64 | 107.62 | 172.46 | 423.69 | |||
89.14 | 193.46 | 154.29 | 98.947 | 193.42 | 244.36 | |||
97.432 | 102.46 | 196.98 | 69.442 | 207.16 | 219.80 | |||
49.864 | 299.87 | 130.26 | 124.67 | 154.32 | 501.64 | |||
High Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
28.808 | 125.01 | 120.09 | 77.004 | 124.50 | 142.29 | |||
65.128 | 166.29 | 276.41 | 85.677 | 103.49 | 321.64 | |||
56.836 | 257.30 | 233.75 | 115.18 | 89.809 | 346.20 | |||
104.41 | 60.049 | 300.46 | 59.954 | 142.64 | 64.384 |
Parameter value | Description |
mortality rate for infected children | |
additional death rate due to AIDS | |
rate of progression to AIDS, if not treated | |
preferential rate of recruitment for children to receive ART | |
transmission probability | |
factor of reduction on rate of disease transmission due to ART | |
factor of reduction on rate of MTCT due to treatment |
Parameter values | Description (each is for the 6 countries) |
Birth rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Death rates for the six countries, respectively | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for high risk groups | |
Initial unsafe contact rates for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for high risk groups | |
Initial rate of MTCT for low risk groups | |
Initial rate of defaulting in the use of ART-assumed to be the same for both risk groups in each of the countries | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in High risk groups | |
Initial rate of recruitment for ART in Low risk groups |
Low Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
125.46 | 234.63 | 310.64 | 107.62 | 172.46 | 423.69 | |||
89.14 | 193.46 | 154.29 | 98.947 | 193.42 | 244.36 | |||
97.432 | 102.46 | 196.98 | 69.442 | 207.16 | 219.80 | |||
49.864 | 299.87 | 130.26 | 124.67 | 154.32 | 501.64 | |||
High Risk | ||||||||
Com. Grp | ||||||||
28.808 | 125.01 | 120.09 | 77.004 | 124.50 | 142.29 | |||
65.128 | 166.29 | 276.41 | 85.677 | 103.49 | 321.64 | |||
56.836 | 257.30 | 233.75 | 115.18 | 89.809 | 346.20 | |||
104.41 | 60.049 | 300.46 | 59.954 | 142.64 | 64.384 |