Loading [MathJax]/jax/output/SVG/jax.js
  Special Issues

A simple model of HIV epidemic in Italy: The role of the antiretroviral treatment

  • Received: 21 September 2016 Accepted: 06 December 2016 Published: 01 February 2018
  • MSC : Primary: 34D05, 37B25; Secondary: 92B05, 92D30

  • In the present paper we propose a simple time-varying ODE model to describe the evolution of HIV epidemic in Italy. The model considers a single population of susceptibles, without distinction of high-risk groups within the general population, and accounts for the presence of immigration and emigration, modelling their effects on both the general demography and the dynamics of the infected subpopulations. To represent the intra-host disease progression, the untreated infected population is distributed over four compartments in cascade according to the CD4 counts. A further compartment is added to represent infected people under antiretroviral therapy. The per capita exit rate from treatment, due to voluntary interruption or failure of therapy, is assumed variable with time. The values of the model parameters not reported in the literature are assessed by fitting available epidemiological data over the decade 2003÷2012. Predictions until year 2025 are computed, enlightening the impact on the public health of the early initiation of the antiretroviral therapy. The benefits of this change in the treatment eligibility consist in reducing the HIV incidence rate, the rate of new AIDS cases, and the rate of death from AIDS. Analytical results about properties of the model in its time-invariant form are provided, in particular the global stability of the equilibrium points is established either in the absence and in the presence of infected among immigrants.

    Citation: Federico Papa, Francesca Binda, Giovanni Felici, Marco Franzetti, Alberto Gandolfi, Carmela Sinisgalli, Claudia Balotta. A simple model of HIV epidemic in Italy: The role of the antiretroviral treatment[J]. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2018, 15(1): 181-207. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2018008

    Related Papers:

    [1] Godwin Amechi Okeke, Akanimo Victor Udo, Rubayyi T. Alqahtani, Nadiyah Hussain Alharthi . A faster iterative scheme for solving nonlinear fractional differential equations of the Caputo type. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(12): 28488-28516. doi: 10.3934/math.20231458
    [2] Hasanen A. Hammad, Hassan Almusawa . Modified inertial Ishikawa iterations for fixed points of nonexpansive mappings with an application. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(4): 6984-7000. doi: 10.3934/math.2022388
    [3] Buthinah A. Bin Dehaish, Rawan K. Alharbi . On fixed point results for some generalized nonexpansive mappings. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(3): 5763-5778. doi: 10.3934/math.2023290
    [4] Noor Muhammad, Ali Asghar, Samina Irum, Ali Akgül, E. M. Khalil, Mustafa Inc . Approximation of fixed point of generalized non-expansive mapping via new faster iterative scheme in metric domain. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(2): 2856-2870. doi: 10.3934/math.2023149
    [5] Kaiwich Baewnoi, Damrongsak Yambangwai, Tanakit Thianwan . A novel algorithm with an inertial technique for fixed points of nonexpansive mappings and zeros of accretive operators in Banach spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(3): 6424-6444. doi: 10.3934/math.2024313
    [6] Hamza Bashir, Junaid Ahmad, Walid Emam, Zhenhua Ma, Muhammad Arshad . A faster fixed point iterative algorithm and its application to optimization problems. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(9): 23724-23751. doi: 10.3934/math.20241153
    [7] Junaid Ahmad, Kifayat Ullah, Hasanen A. Hammad, Reny George . On fixed-point approximations for a class of nonlinear mappings based on the JK iterative scheme with application. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(6): 13663-13679. doi: 10.3934/math.2023694
    [8] Junaid Ahmad, Kifayat Ullah, Hasanen A. Hammad, Reny George . A solution of a fractional differential equation via novel fixed-point approaches in Banach spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(6): 12657-12670. doi: 10.3934/math.2023636
    [9] Siniša N. Ješić, Nataša A. Ćirović, Rale M. Nikolić, Branislav M. Ranƌelović . A fixed point theorem in strictly convex b-fuzzy metric spaces. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(9): 20989-21000. doi: 10.3934/math.20231068
    [10] Doaa Filali, Mohammad Dilshad, Mohammad Akram . Generalized variational inclusion: graph convergence and dynamical system approach. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(9): 24525-24545. doi: 10.3934/math.20241194
  • In the present paper we propose a simple time-varying ODE model to describe the evolution of HIV epidemic in Italy. The model considers a single population of susceptibles, without distinction of high-risk groups within the general population, and accounts for the presence of immigration and emigration, modelling their effects on both the general demography and the dynamics of the infected subpopulations. To represent the intra-host disease progression, the untreated infected population is distributed over four compartments in cascade according to the CD4 counts. A further compartment is added to represent infected people under antiretroviral therapy. The per capita exit rate from treatment, due to voluntary interruption or failure of therapy, is assumed variable with time. The values of the model parameters not reported in the literature are assessed by fitting available epidemiological data over the decade 2003÷2012. Predictions until year 2025 are computed, enlightening the impact on the public health of the early initiation of the antiretroviral therapy. The benefits of this change in the treatment eligibility consist in reducing the HIV incidence rate, the rate of new AIDS cases, and the rate of death from AIDS. Analytical results about properties of the model in its time-invariant form are provided, in particular the global stability of the equilibrium points is established either in the absence and in the presence of infected among immigrants.


    In the last decades stochastic optimal control theory has received an increasing attention by the mathematical community, also in connection with several concrete applications, spanning from industry to finance, from biology to crowd dyamics, etc. In all of above applications a rigorous theory of stochastic optimal control (SOC), under suitable assumption on the source of random noise, revealed to be a fundamental point.

    To this aim different theoretical approaches have been developed. They can be broadly divided into two classes: partial differential equations (PDE) methods via the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation, and methods based on the maximum principle via backward stochastic differential equations (BSDEs), see, e.g., [12,24,27]

    In particular BSDEs' methods have proved to be particularly adapted for a large set of SOC-problems, as reported, e.g., in [25]. Within previously mentioned problems a particular role is played by those SOC problems characterized by the specification of a random terminal time. In particular, this a classical task in Finance at least since the recent financial credit crunch which imposed the need to model possible defaults and credit risks. When dealing with optimal control with random terminal time, two main approaches are possible. The first possible setting considers the random terminal time as a to be completely inaccessible to the reference filtration. The related classical approach consists in enlarging the reference filtration, see, e.g., [20]. In this way, via a suitable density assumption on the conditional law of the random time, the original problem is converted into a control problem with fixed terminal time, with respect to the new enlarged filtration, see, e.g., [11,23] for more theoretical insights and to [2,3,5,18] for some concrete applications.

    A second, alternative, approach assumes that the stopping times are accessible from the reference filtration, hence implying a perfect information about the triggered random times. The typical assumption in this setting is that the stopping time τ is defined as the first hitting time of a barrier v for a reference system whose dynamic is given by a stochastic differential equation (SDE). In a credit risk setting, such an approach is known as the structural approach, and it has a long-standing financial literature whose first results date back to [21]. It is worth stressing that this last scenario does not fall back into previous one, where inaccessible stopping times are considered. In fact, if the stopping time is to be defined as the first hitting time, it does not satisfy above mention density hypothesis.

    The present paper investigates a SOC-problem with multiple random events of the latter type. Therefore, differently from [18,23], we will not assume random events to be totally inaccessible, but, instead, they will be defined as first hitting time, against a predetermined boundary, of the driving process.

    In particular, we will consider a controlled system of nN SDEs of the general form

    {dXi(t)=μi(t,Xi(t),αi(t))dt+σi(t,Xi(t),αi(t))dWi(t),i=1,,n,Xi(0)=xi, (1)

    under standard assumptions of Lipschitz coefficients μi and σi with at most linear growth, being αi the control. The notation will be specified in detail within subsequent sections.

    We aim at minimizing the following functional up to a given stopping time τ,

    J(x,α)=Eτ0L(t,X(t),α(t))dt+G(τ,X(τ)),

    for some suitable functions L and G, where we have denoted by X(t)=(X1(t),,Xn(t)) and α(t)=(α1(t),,αn(t)).

    Then we assume that the system, instead of being stopped as soon as the stopping time τ is triggered, continues to evolve according to a new system of SDEs written as follows

    {dXi1(t)=μi1(t,Xi1(t),αi1(t))dt+σi1(t,Xi1(t),αi1(t))dWi(t),i=1,,n1,Xi1(τ)=xi1,

    for some new coefficients μi1 and σi1 again satisfying standard assumptions of linear growth and Lipschitz continuity. In particular, we will assume that, according to the triggered stopping time the kth component in Eq (1) has been set to 0, according to rigorous definitions later specified. Then, we again aim at minimizing a functional of the form

    J1(x1,α)=Eτ1τL1(t,X1(t),α1(t))dt+G1(τ1,X1(τ1)),

    with the same notation used before, τ1 being a new stopping time. We repeat such a scheme for a series of n stopping times. Moreover, in complete generality, we assume that the order of the random times is not know a priori, hence forcing us to consider all possible combinations of random events with associated all the possible combinations of driving SDEs.

    The main result of the present paper consists in deriving a stochastic maximum principle, both in necessary and sufficient form, for the whole series of control problems stated above. To the best of our knowledge this is the first work that derives a maximum principle for a series of interconnected optimal problem. The maximum principle can in turn help in deriving a closed–loop optimal control problem. This will be further showed into the work for the relevant case of a linear–quadratic optimal control problem whose closed-form solution is of affine form.

    Clearly, we cannot expect that the global optimal solution is given by gluing each optimal control between two consecutive stopping times. Instead, we will tackle the problem following a dynamic programming principle approach, as exploited, e.g., in [23]. In particular, we will solve the problem backward. Therefore, the case of all stopping times but one have been triggered is considered first, then we consider the problem with two random events left, etc., until the very first control problem. Following this scheme, we are able to provide the global optimal solution recursively, so that the kth optimal control problem depends on the (k+1)th optimal solution. We remark that altough the backward approach has been used in literature, see, e.g., [18,23], to the best of our knowledge the present work is the first one using such techniques where stopping times are defined as hitting times.

    After having derived the main result, i.e., the aforementioned maximum principle, we will consider the particular case of a linear–quadratic control problem, that is we assume the underlying dynamics to be linear in both the state variable and the control, with quadratic costs to be minimized. Such type of problems have been widely studied both from a theoretical and practical point of view since they often allow to obtain closed form solution for the optimal control.

    In particular, usually one can write the solution to a linear–quadratic control problem in terms of the solution of a Riccati backward ordinary differential equation (ODE), hence reducing the original linear–quadratic stochastic control problem to the solution of a simpler ODE, see, e.g., [27] and [24,Section 6.6], for possible financial applications. Let us recall that, considering either random coefficients for the driving equation or random terminal time in the control problem, the latter case being the one here treated, the backward Riccati ODE becomes a Riccati BSDE, see, e.g., [13,14,16,17].

    We stress that the results derived in the present paper find natural applications in many areas related to mathematical finance, and mainly related to systemic risk, where after recent credit crisis, the assumption of possible failures has become the main ingredient in many robust financial models. Also, network models have seen an increasing mathematical attention during last years, as witnessed by the development of several ad hoc techniques derived to consider general dynamics on networks. We refer the interested reader to [6,7,9], for general results on network models, and to [15] for a financially oriented treatment.

    In particular, these models have proved to be particularly suitable if one is to consider a system of interconnected banks. Following thus the approach of [4,10,19], results derived in the present work can be successfully applied to a system of n interconnected banks, lending and borrowing money. As in [4,8] one can assume the presence of an external controller, typically called lender of last resort (LOLR), who actively supervises the banks' system and possibly lending money to actors in needs. A standard assumption is that the LOLR lends money in order to optimize a given quadratic functional. Therefore, modelling the system as in [8], we recover a linear–quadratic setting allowing us to apply results obtained in the present work.

    The paper is organized as follows: In Section 2 we introduce the general setting, clarifying main assumptions; then, Section 2.1 is devoted to the proof of the necessary maximum principle, whereas in Section 2.2 we will prove the sufficient maxim principle; at last, in Section 3, we apply previous results to the case of a linear–quadratic control problems also deriving the global solution by an iterative scheme to solve a system of Riccati BSDEs.

    Let nN and T< a fixed terminal time and let us consider a standard complete filtered probability space (Ω,F,(Ft)t[0,T],P) satisfying usual assumptions.

    In what follows we are going to consider a controlled system of n SDEs, for t[0,T] and i=1,,n, evolvong has folllows

    {dXi;0(t)=μi;0(t,Xi;0(t),αi;0(t))dt+σi;0(t,Xi;0(t),αi;0(t))dWi(t),Xi;0(0)=xi;00, (2)

    where Wi(t) is a standard Brownian motion, αi;0 being the control. In particular, we assume

    Ai:={αi;0L2ad([0,T];R):αi;0(t)Ai,a.e.t[0,T]},

    where AiR is assumed to be convex and closed, and we have denoted by L2ad([0,T];R) the space of (Ft)t[0,T]–adapted processes α such that

    ET0|αi;0(t)|2dt<,

    while A:=ni=1Ai.

    In what follows we will assume the following assumptions to hold.

    Assumptions 2.1. Let μ:[0,T]×R×AR and σ:[0,T]×R×AR be measurable functions and suppose that there exits a constant C>0 such that, for any x, yR, for any aA and for any t[0,T], it holds

    |μ(t,x,a)μ(t,y,a)|+|σ(t,x,a)σ(t,y,a)|C|xy|,|μ(t,x,a)|+|σ(t,x,a)|C(1+|x|+|a|).

    We thus assume the coefficients μi;0 and σi;0, for i=1,,n, in Eq (2), satisfy assumptions 2.1. Thererfore, we have that there exists a unique strong solution to Eq (2), see, e.g., [12,24].

    Remark 2.2. In Eq (2) we have considered an Rvalued SDE, nevertheless what follows still holds if we consider a system of SDEs, each of which takes values in Rmi, miN, i=1,,n.

    Let us denote by

    X0(t)=(X1;0(t),,Xn;0(t)),α0(t)=(α1;0(t),,αn;0(t)),

    then define the coefficients

    B0:[0,T]×Rn×ARn,Σ0:[0,T]×Rn×ARn×n,,

    as

    B0(t,X0(t),α0(t)):=(μ1;0(t,X1;0(t),α1;0(t)),,μn;0(t,Xn;0(t),αn;0(t)))T,

    and

    Σ0(t,X0(t),α0(t)):=diag[σ1;0(t,X1;0(t),α1;0(t)),,σn;0(t,Xn;0(t),αn;0(t))],

    that is the matrix with σi;0(t,x,a) entry on the diagonal and null off-diagonal.

    Let us also denote x00=(x1;00,,xn;00) and W(t)=(W1(t),,Wn(t))T. Hence, system (2) can be compactly rewritten as follows

    {dX0(t)=B0(t,X0(t),α0(t))dt+Σ0(t,X0(t),α0(t))dW(t),X0(0)=x00. (3)

    We will minimize the following functional

    J(x,α)=Eˆτ10L0(t,X0(t),α0(t))dt+G0(ˆτ1,X0(ˆτ1)), (4)

    where L0 and G0 are assumed to satisfy the following assumptions:

    Assumptions 2.3. Let L0:[0,T]×Rn×A0R and G0:[0,T]×RnR be two measurable and continuous functions such that there exist two constants K, k>0 such that, for any t[0,T], xRn and aA0, it holds

    |L0(t,x,a)|K(1+|x|k+|a|k),|G0(t,x)|K(1+|x|k).

    Let us underline that in the cost functional defined by (4), the terminal time ˆτ1 is assumed to be triggered as soon as X0 reaches a given boundary v0. In particular, we assume the stopping boundary to be of the form

    v0=(v1;0,,vn;0),

    for some given constants vi;0R, i=1,,n. We thus denote by

    τi;0:=Tmin{t0:Xi;0(t)=vi;0},i=1,,n, (5)

    the first time Xi;0 reaches the boundary vi;0 and we set

    ˆτ1:=τ1;0τn;0,

    the first stopping time to happen.

    We stress that, in what follows we will denote by ˆτ the ordered stopping times. In particular, ˆτ1ˆτn, where ˆτk denotes the kth stopping time to happen. On the contrary, the notation τk indicates that the stopping time has been triggered by the k-th node. In what follows, we will use the convention that, if ˆτ1=τk, then τj=T, for jk.

    Remark 2.4. From a practical point of view, we are considering a controller that aims at supervise n different elements defining a system, up to the first time one of the element of it exits from a given domain. From a financial perspective, each element represents a financial agent, while the stopping time denotes its failure time. Hence, a possible cost to be optimized, as we shall see in Section 3, is to maximize the distance between the element/financial agent from the associated stopping/default boundary.

    As briefly mentioned in the introduction, instead of stopping the overall control problem when the first stopping time is triggered, we assume that the system continues to evolve according to a (possibly) new dynamic. As to make an example, let us consider the case of ˆτ1ˆτk;0, that is the first process to hit the stopping boundary is Xk;0. We thus set to 0 the kth component of X0, then considering the new process

    Xk(t)=(X1;k(t),,Xk1;k(t),0,Xk+1;k(t),,Xk;n(t)),

    with control given by

    αk(t)=(α1;k(t),,αk1;k(t),0,αk+1;k(t),,αk;n(t)),

    where the superscript k denotes that the kth component hit the stopping boundary and therefore has been set to 0.

    Then, we consider the ndimensional system, for t[ˆτ1,T], defined by

    {dXi;k(t)=μi;k(t,Xi;k(t),αi;k(t))dt+σi;k(t,Xi;k(t),αi;k(t))dWi(t),Xi;k(ˆτ1)=Xi;0(ˆτ1)=:xi;k,i=1,,k1,k+1,,n,

    where the coefficients μi;k and σi;k satisfy assumptions 2.1 and we have also set Xk;k(t)=0.

    We therefore define Bk:[ˆτ1,T]×Rn×ARn and Σk:[ˆτ1,T]×Rn×ARn×n as

    Bk(t,Xk(t),αk(t)):=(μ1;k(t,X1;k(t),α1;k(t)),,μn;k(t,Xn;k(t),αn;k(t)))T,Σk(t,Xk(t),αk(t)):=diag[σ1;k(t,X1;k(t),α1;k(t)),,σn;k(t,Xn;k(t),αn;k(t))],

    which allows us to rewrite the above system as

    {dXk(t)=Bk(t,Xk(t),αk(t))dt+Σk(t,Xk(t),αk(t))dW(t),tˆτ1,Xk(τk)=Φk(τk)X0(τk)=:xk, (6)

    where Φk is the diagonal n×n matrix defined as

    Φk(τk)=diag[1,,1,0,1,,1],

    the null-entry being in the kth position.

    Then we minimize the following functional

    Jk(x,α)=Eˆτ2ˆτ1Lk(t,Xk(t),αk(t))dt+Gk(ˆτ2,Xk(ˆτ2)),

    where Lk and Gk are assumed to satisfy assumptions 2.3, while ˆτ2 is a stopping time triggered as soon as Xk hits a defined boundary. In particular, we define the stopping boundary

    vk=(v1;k,,vk1;k,1,vk+1;k,,vn;k),t[ˆτ1,T],

    and, following the same scheme as before, we define by

    τi;k:=Tmin{tˆτ1:Xi;k(t)=vi;k},i=1,,k1,k+1,,n,

    the first time Xi;k reaches the boundary vi;k, denoting

    ˆτ2:=τ1;kτk1;kτk+1;kτn;k.

    It follows that, considering for instance the case τl;k has been triggered by Xl;k, we have ˆτ2ˆτl;k, meaning that vl;k has been hit. Iteratively proceeding, we consequently define

    X(k,l)(t)=(X1;(k,l)(t),,Xk1;(k,l)(t),0,Xk+1;(k,l)(t),,,Xl1;(k,l)(t),0,Xl+1;(k,l)(t),,Xn;(k,l)(t))T,

    again assuming X(k,l)(t) evolves according to a system as in (3), and so on until either no nodes are left or the terminal time T is reached.

    As mentioned above, one of the major novelty of the present work consists in not assuming the knowledge of the stopping times order. From a mathematical point of view, the latter implies that we have to consider all the possible combinations of such critical points during a given time interval [0,T]. Let us note that this is in fact the natural setting to work with having in mind the modelling of concrete scenarios, as happens, e.g., concerning possible multiple failures happening within a system of interconnected banks.

    Therefore, in what follows we are going to denote by Cn,k the combinations of k elements from a set of n, while πkCn,k stands for one of those element. Hence, exploiting the notation introduced above, we define the process X=(X(t))t[0,T] as

    X(t)=X0(t)1{t<ˆτ1}+n1k=1πkCn,kXπk(t)1{τπk<t<ˆτk+1}, (7)

    where each Xπk(t) is defined as above and, consequently, the the global control reads as follow

    α(t)=α0(t)1{t<ˆτ1}+n1k=0πkCn,kαπk(t)1{τπk<t<ˆτk+1}. (8)

    Remark 2.5. Let us underlined within the setting defined so far, each stopping time ˆτk depends on previously triggered stopping times τπj, j=1,,k1. As a consequence, also the solution Xπk in (7) depends on triggered stopping times as well as on their order. To simplify notation, we have avoided to explicitly write such dependencies, defining for short

    ˆτk:=ˆτk(ˆτ1,,ˆτk1).

    By Eq (7) we have that the dynamic for X is given by

    dX(t)=B(t,X(t),α(t))dt+Σ(t,X(t),α(t))dW(t), (9)

    where, according to the above introduced notation, we have defined

    B(t,X(t),α(t))=B0(t,X0(t),α0(t))1{t<ˆτ1}++n1k=1πkCn,kBπk(t,Xπk(t),απk(t))1{τπk<t<ˆτk+1},Σ(t,X(t),α(t))=Σ0(t,X0(t),α0(t))1{t<ˆτ1}++n1k=1πkCn,kΣπk(t,Xπk(t),απk(t))1{τπk<t<ˆτk+1}, (10)

    aiming at minimizing the following functional

    J(x,α):=Eˆτn0L(t,X(t),α(t))dt+G(ˆτn,X(ˆτn)). (11)

    L and G being defined as

    L(t,X(t),α(t))=L0(t,X0(t),α0(t))1{t<ˆτ1}++n1k=1πkCn,kLπk(t,Xπk(t),απk(t))1{τπk<t<ˆτk+1},G(ˆτn,X(ˆτn))=G0(ˆτ1,X0(ˆτ1))1{ˆτ1T}++nk=1πkCn,kGπk(τπk,Xπk(τπk))1{τπk<Tˆτk+1}.

    Remark 2.6. It is worth to mention that we are considering the sums stated above as to be done over all possible combinations, hence implying we are not considering components' order, namely considering X(k,l)=X(l,k). Dropping such an assumption implies that the sums in Eqs (7), (8) and (10) have to be considered over the disposition Dn,k.

    In what follows we shall give an example of the theory developed so far, as to better clarify our approach as well as its concrete applicability.

    Example 2.1. Let us consider the case of a system constituted by just n=2 components. Then Eq (7) becomes

    X(t)=X0(t)1{t<ˆτ1}+X1(t)1{τ1<t<ˆτ2}+X2(t)1{τ2<t<ˆτ2},

    where X0(t), resp. X1(t), resp. X2(t), denotes the dynamics in case neither 1 nor 2 has hit the stopping boundary, resp. 1 has, resp. 2 has.

    Then, denoting by α0(t), α1(t) and α2(t) the respective associated controls, we have that the functional (11) reads

    J(x,α):=Eˆτ10L0(t,X0(t),α0(t))dt+G0(ˆτ1,X0(ˆτ1))++Eˆτ2τ1L1(t,X1(t),α1(t))dt+G1(ˆτ2,X1(ˆτ2))++Eˆτ2τ2L2(t,X2(t),α2(t))dt+G2(ˆτ2,X2(ˆτ2)).

    The main issue in solving the optimal control problem defined in Section 2 consists in solving a series of connected optimal problems, each of which may depends on previous ones. Moreover, we do not assume to have an a priori knowledge about the stopping times' order.

    To overcome such issues, we consider a backward approach. In particular, we first solve the last control problem, then proceeding with the penultimate, and so on, until the first one, via backward induction. Let us underline that assuming the perfect knowledge of the stopping times' order would imply a simplification of the backward scheme, because of the need to solve only n control problems, then saving us to take into account all the combinations. Nevertheless in one case as in the other, the backward procedure runs analogously.

    Aiming at deriving a global maximum principle, in what follows we denote by x the partial derivative w.r.t. the space variable xRn and by a the partial derivative w.r.t. the control aAn. Moreover we assume

    Assumptions 2.7. () For any πkCn,k, k=1,,n, it holds that Bπk and Σπk are continuously differentiable w.r.t. to both xRn and to aA. Furthermore, there exists a constant C1>0 such that for any t[0,T], xRn and aA, it holds

    |xBπk(t,x,a)|+|aBπk(t,x,a)|C1,|xΣπk(t,x,a)|+|aΣπk(t,x,a)|C1.

    () For any πkCn,k, k=1,,n, it holds that Lπk, resp. Gπk, is continuously differentiable w.r.t. to both xRn and aAn, resp. only w.r.t. xRn. Furthermore, there exists a constant C2>0 such that for any t[0,T], xRn and aAn, it holds

    |xLπk(t,x,a)|+|aLπk(t,x,a)|C2(1+|x|+|a|),|xGπk(t,x)|C2.

    We thus have the following result.

    Theorem 2.8. [Necessary Maximum Principle] Let assumptions 2.1–2.3–2.7 hold and let (ˉX,ˉα) be an optimal pair for the problem (9)–(11), then it holds

    aH(t,ˉX(t),ˉα(t),ˉY(t),ˉZ(t)),(ˉα(t)˜α)0,a.e.t[0,ˆτn],Pa.s,˜αA, (12)

    equivalently

    ˉα(t)=argmin˜αAH(t,ˉX(t),˜α(t),Y(t),Z(t)),

    where the pair (Y(t),Z(t)) solves the following dual backward equation

    Y(t)=Y0(t)1{t<ˆτ1}+n1k=1πkCn,kYπk(t)1{τπk<t<ˆτk+1},Z(t)=Z0(t)1{t<ˆτ1}+n1k=1πkCn,kZπk(t)1{τπk<t<ˆτk+1},

    the pairs (Yπk(t),Zπk(t)) being solutions of the following system of interconnected BSDEs

    {dYπn1(t)=xHπn1(t,Xπn1(t),απn1(t),Yπn1(t),Zπn1(t))dtZπn1dW(t),Yπn1(ˆτn)=xGπn1(ˆτn,Xπn1(ˆτn)),{dYπk(t)=xHπk(t,Xπk(t),απk(t),Yπk(t),Zπk(t))dtZπkdW(t),Yπk(ˆτk+1)=xGπk(ˆτk+1,Xπk(ˆτk+1))+ˉYk+1(ˆτk+1),{dY0(t)=xH0(t,X0(t),α0(t),Y0(t),Z0(t))dtZ0dW(t),Y0(τ1)=xG0(τ1,X0(τ1))+ˉY1(τ1), (13)

    having denoted by

    ˉYπk+1(ˆτk+1):=πk+1Cn,k+1Yπk+1(τπk+1)1{ˆτk+1=τπk+1},

    where Hπk is the generalized Hamiltonian

    Hπk:[0,T]×Rn×A×Rn×Rn×nR,

    defined as

    Hπk(t,xπk,aπk,yπk,zπk):=Bπk(t,xπk,aπk)yπk++Tr[(Σπk(t,xπk,aπk))zπk]+Lπk(t,xπk,aπk), (14)

    and H represents the global generalized Hamiltonian defined as

    H(t,x,a,y,z)=H0(t,x,a,y,z)1{t<ˆτ1}++n1k=1πkCn,kHπk(t,x,a,y,z)1{τπk<t<ˆτk+1}.

    Remark 2.9. Before entering into details about proving Theorem 2.8, let us underline some of its characteristics. In particular, here the main idea is to find a solution iteratively acting backward in time. Therefore, starting from the very last control problem, namely the case where a single node is left into the system, we consider a standard maximum principle. Indeed, Yπn1 in (13) represents a classical dual BSDE form associated to the standard stochastic maximum principle, see, e.g., [27,Th. 3.2]. Then, we can consider the second last control problem. A this point, a naive tentative to obtain a global solution, could be to first solve such penultimate problem to then gluing together the obtained solutions. Nevertheless, such a method only produces a a suboptimal solution. Instead, the right approach, similarly to what happens applying the standard dynamic programming principle, consists in treating the solution to the last control problem as the terminal cost for the subsequent (second last) control problem, and so on for the remaining ones.

    It follows that, in deriving the global optimal solution, one considers the cost coming from future evolution of the system. Mathematically, this is clearly expressed by the terminal condition Yπk the Eq (13) is endowed with. Therefore the solution scheme resulting in a global connection of all the control problems we have to consider, from the very last of them and then backward to the first one.

    Proof. [Necessary Maximum Principle.] We proceed according to a backward induction technique. In particular,

    for t0>ˆτn1 the proof follows from the standard stochastic necessary maximum principle, see, e.g., [27,Th. 3.2]. Then we consider the case of ˆτn2<t0<ˆτn1, and we define

    ˉα:={ˉαπn2(t)t0<t<ˆτn2,ˉαπn1(t)ˆτn2<t<ˆτn1.

    to be the optimal control, α being another admissible control and further setting αh as

    αh:=ˉα+hα,h>0.

    Since in the present case the cost functional reads as follow

    J(x,α):=Eˆτn1t0Lπn2(t,Xπn2(t),απn2(t))dt+Gπn2(ˆτn1,X(ˆτn1))++πn1Cn,n1Eˆτnτπn1Lπn1(t,Xπn1(t),απn1(t))dt++Gπn1(ˆτn,X(ˆτn)),

    we can choose α=ˉα˜α, ˜αA. Then, by the optimality of ˉα and via a standard variational argument, see, e.g., [1,22,27], we have

    J(x,ˉα)J(x,αh)0,

    which implies

    limh0J(x,ˉα)J(x,αh)h0.

    In what follows, for the sake of clarity, we will denote by Xα the solution X with control α. Thus, from the optimality of ˉα, we have

    Eˆτn1t0Lπn2(t,ˉXπn2ˉα(t),ˉαπn2(t))dt+Gπn2(ˆτn1,ˉXπn2ˉα(ˆτn1))++πn1Cn,n1ˆτnτπn1Lπn1(t,ˉXπn1ˉα(t),ˉαπn1(t))dt+Gπn1(ˆτn,ˉXπn1ˉα(ˆτn))Eˆτn1t0Lπn2(t,ˉXπn2αh(t),ˉαπn2(t))dt+Gπn2(ˆτn1,ˉXπn2αh(ˆτn1))++πn1Cn,n1ˆτnτπn1Lπn1(t,ˉXπn1αh(t),ˉαπn1(t))dt+Gπn1(ˆτn,ˉXπn1αh(ˆτn)). (15)

    Then, for any αA, by (15), we obtain

    Eˆτn1t0xLπn2(t,ˉXπn2ˉα(t),ˉαπn2(t))Zπn2(t)dt++xGπn2(ˆτn1,ˉXπn2ˉα(ˆτn1))Zπn2(ˆτn1)++πn1Cn,n1Eˆτnτπn1xLπn1(t,ˉXπn1ˉα(t),ˉαπn1(t))Zπn1(t)dt++πn1Cn,n1xGπn1(ˆτn,ˉXπn1ˉα(τπn))Zπn1(ˆτn)0 (16)

    where Zπn1 and Zπn2 solve the first variation process

    {dZπn1(t)=xBπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),απn1(t))Zπn1(t)dt++aBπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),απn1(t))απn1(t)dt++xΣπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),απn1(t))Zπn1(t)dW(t)++aΣπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),απn1(t))απn1(t)dW(t),Zπn1(ˆτn1)=ˉZπn2(ˆτn1),t[ˆτn1,ˆτn],{dZπn2(t)=xBπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),απn2(t))Zπn2(t)dt++aBπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),απn2(t))απn2(t)dt++xΣπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),απn2(t))Zπn2(t)dW(t)++aΣπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),απn2(t))απn2(t)dW(t),Zπn2(t0)=0,t[t0,ˆτn1].

    Applying Itô formula to Yπn2Zπn2, we have

    E(xGπn2(ˆτn1,Xπn2(ˆτn1))+ˉYn1(ˆτn1))Zπn2(ˆτn1)==EYπn2(ˆτn1)Zπn1(ˆτn1)==Eτπn1t0(xHπn2(t,Xπn2(t),απn2(t),Yπn2(t),Zπn2(t))dt)Zπn2(t)dt++Eˆτn1t0(xBπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),απn2(t))Zπn2(t))Yπn2(t)dt++Eˆτn1t0(aBπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),απn2(t))απn2(t))Yπn2(t)dt++Eˆτn1t0(xΣπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),απn2(t))Zπn2(t))Zπn2(t)dt++Eˆτn1t0(aΣπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),απn2(t))απn2(t))Zπn2(t)dt==Eˆτn1t0xLπn2(t,Xπn2(t),απn2(t))Zπn2(t)+Eˆτn1t0(aBπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),απn2(t))Yπn2(t))απn2(t)dt++Eˆτn1t0(aΣπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),απn2(t))Zπn2(t))απn2(t)dt+, (17)

    and similarly for Yπn1Zπn1, we obtain

    E(xGπn1(ˆτn,Xπn1(ˆτn)))Zπn1(ˆτn)=EYπn1(ˆτn)Zπn1(ˆτn)==EYπn1(τπn1)Zπn1(τπn1)+Eˆτnτπn1xLπn1(t,Xπn1(t),ˉαπn1(t))Zπn1(t)dt++Eˆτnτπn1(aBπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),απn1(t))Yπn1(t))απn1(t)dt++Eˆτnτπn1(aΣπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),απn1(t))Zπn1(t))απn1(t)dt. (18)

    Exploiting Eq (16), together with Eqs (17) and (18), we thus have

    ˆτn1t0(αHπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),ˉαπn2(t),ˉYπn2(t),ˉZπn2(t)))απn2(t)dt++πn1Cn,n1ˆτnτπn1(αHπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),ˉαπn1(t),ˉYπn1(t),ˉZπn1(t)))απn1(t)dt0,

    for all α=ˉα˜α, and thus we eventually obtain, for t0>ˆτn2

    αH(t,ˉX(t),ˉα(t),ˉY(t),ˉZ(t))(ˉα(t)˜α)0,a.e. t[t0,ˆτn],Pa.s,˜αA,

    which is the desired local form for optimality (12). Analogously proceeding via backward induction, we derive that the same results also hold for any πkCn,k, hence obtaining the system (13) and concluding the proof.

    In this section we consider a generalization of the classical sufficient maximum principle, see, e.g., [24,Th. 6.4.6], for the present setting of interconnected multiple optimal control problems with random terminal time. To this end, we assume

    Assumptions 2.10. For any πkCn,k the derivative w.r.t. x of B, Σ and L are continuous and there exists a constant La>0 such that, for any a1, a2A,

    |Bπk(t,x,a1)Bπk(t,x,a2)|+|Σπk(t,x,a1)Σπk(t,x,a2)|++|Lπk(t,x,a1)Lπk(t,x,a2)|La|a1a2|.

    Theorem 2.11 (Sufficient maximum principle). Let 2.1–2.3–2.7–2.10 hold, let (Y,Z) be the solution to the dual BSDE 13, and suppose the following conditions hold true

    () the maps xGπk(x) are convex for any πk;

    () the maps (x,a)Hπk(x,a,Yπk,Zπk) are convex for a.e. t[0,T] and for any πk;

    () for a.e. t[0,T] and Pa.s. it holds

    ˉαπk(t)=argmin˜απkAπkHπk(t,Xπk(t),˜α(t),Yπk,Zπk),

    then (ˉα,ˉX) is an optimal pair for the problem (9)–(11).

    Proof. Let us proceed as in the proof of Theorem 2.8, namely via backward induction. For t0>ˆτn1 the proof follows from the standard sufficient stochastic maximum principle, see, e.g., [27,Th. 5.2].

    Let us thus then consider the case of ˆτn2<t0<ˆτn1, denoting by ΔXπk(t):=ˉXπk(t)Xπk(t) and, for the sake of clarity, by using similar notations for any other function.

    The convexity of Gπn1, together with the terminal condition

    Yπn1(ˆτn)=xGπn1(ˆτn,ˉXπn1(ˆτn)),

    yields

    EΔGπn1(ˆτn,ˉXπn1(ˆτn))E[ΔXπn1(ˆτn)xGπn1(ˆτn,ˉXπn1(ˆτn))]=E[ΔXπn1(ˆτn)Yπn1(ˆτn)]. (19)

    Applying the Itô-formula to ΔXπn1Yπn1(ˆτn), we obtain

    E[ΔXπn1(ˆτn))Yπn1(ˆτn)]=E[ΔXπn1(ˆτn1)Yπn1(ˆτn1)]++Eˆτnˆτn1ΔXπn1(t)dYπn1(t)+Eˆτnˆτn1Yπn1(t)dΔXπn1(t)++Eˆτnˆτn1Tr[ΔΣπn1(t,Xπn1(t),απn1(t))Zπn1(t)]dt==E[ΔXπn1(ˆτn1)Yπn1(ˆτn1)]+Eˆτnˆτn1ΔXπn1(t)xHπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),ˉαπn1(t),Yπn1(t),Zπn1(t))dt++Eˆτnˆτn1(ΔBπn1(t)Yπn1(t)+ΔΣπn1(t)Zπn1(t))dt. (20)

    Similarly, from the convexity of the Hamiltonian, we also have

    Eˆτnˆτn1[ΔLπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),ˉαπn1(t))]dt==Eˆτnˆτn1[ΔHπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),ˉαπn1(t),Yπn1(t),Zπn1(t))]dt+Eˆτnˆτn1(ΔBπn1(t)Yπn1(t)+ΔΣπn1(t)Zπn1(t))dtEˆτnˆτn1[ΔXπn1(t)xHπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),ˉαπn1(t),Yπn1(t),Zπn1(t))]dt+Eˆτnˆτn1(ΔBπn1(t)Yπn1(t)+ΔΣπn1(t)Zπn1(t))dt, (21)

    so that, for any πn1, by combining Eqs (19)–(21), we derive

    Eˆτnˆτn1[ΔLπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),ˉαπn1(t))]dt+EΔGπn1(ˆτn,ˉXπn1(ˆτn))E[ΔXπn1(ˆτn1)Yπn1(ˆτn1)]. (22)

    Analogously, for t0[ˆτn2,ˆτn1], and since

    Yπn2(ˆτn1)=xGπn2(ˆτn1,ˉXπn2(ˆτn1))+ˉYπn1(ˆτn1),

    together with the convexity of Gπn2, we have

    EΔGπn2(ˆτn1,ˉXπn2(ˆτn1))E[ΔXπn2(ˆτn1)xGπn2(ˆτn1,ˉXπn2(ˆτn1))]==E[ΔXπn2(ˆτn1)Yπn2(ˆτn1)ΔXπn2(ˆτn1)ˉYπn1(ˆτn1)].

    Similar computations also give us

    Eˆτn1ˆτn2[ΔLπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),ˉαπn2(t))]dt+EΔGπn2(ˆτn1,ˉXπn2(ˆτn1))EΔXπn2(ˆτn1)ˉYπn1(ˆτn1), (23)

    so that, for t0[ˆτn2,ˆτn1], by Eqs (22) and (23), we infer that

    J(t0,x,ˉα)J(t0,x,α):=Eˆτn1t0Lπn2(t,ˉXπn2(t),ˉαπn2(t))dt++EGπn2(ˆτn1,ˉXπn2(ˆτn1))++πn1Cn,n1Eˆτnτπn1Lπn1(t,ˉXπn1(t),ˉαπn1(t))dt++Gπn1(ˆτn,ˉXπn1(ˆτn))++Eˆτn1t0Lπn2(t,Xπn2(t),απn2(t))dt++EGπn2(ˆτn1,X(ˆτn1))++πn1Cn,n1Eˆτnτπn1Lπn1(t,Xπn1(t),απn1(t))dt++Gπn1(ˆτn,X(ˆτn))0, (24)

    which implies that

    J(t0,x,ˉα)J(t0,x,α),

    and the optimality of (ˉα,ˉX).

    Proceeding backward, previously exploited arguments allow us to show the same results for any πkCn,k, hence ending the proof.

    In the present section we consider a particular case for the control problem stated in Sections 2.1 and 2.2. In particular, we will assume that the dynamic of the state equation is linear in both the space and the control variable. Moreover, we impose that the control enters (linearly) only in the drift and that the cost functional is quadratic and of a specific form. More precisely, let us first consider μ0(t) as the n×n matrix defined as follows

    μ0(t):=diag[μ1;0(t),,μn;0(t)],

    that is the matrix with μi;0(t) entry on the diagonal and null off-diagonal, μi;0:[0,T]R being a deterministic and bounded function of the time. Also let

    b0(t)=(b1;0(t),,bn;0(t))T,

    where again bi;0:[0,T]R is a deterministic and bounded function of time. Then we set

    B0(t,X0(t),α(t))=μ0(t)X0(t)+b0(t)+α(t). (25)

    Let us also define the n×n matrix Σ0, to be independent of the control, as follows

    Σ0(t,X0(t)):=(σ1;0(t)X1;0(t)+ν1;0(t)000000σn;0(t)Xn;0(t)+νn;0(t)), (26)

    σi;0, νi;0:[0,T]R being deterministic and bounded function of time.

    Same assumptions of linearity holds for any other coefficients Bπk and Σπk, so that, using the same notation introduced along previous sections, we consider the system

    dX(t)=B(t,X(t),α(t))dt+Σ(t,X(t))dW(t), (27)

    where both the drift and the volatility coefficients are now assumed to be linear. In the present (particular) setting, both the running and the terminal cost are assumed to be suitable quadratic weighted averages of the distance from the stopping boundaries, namely we set

    Lπk(t,x,a)=ni=1(γπki|xivi;πk|22+12|ai;πk|2),Gπk(t,x)=ni=1γπki|xivi;πk|22, (28)

    for some given weights γπk such that

    γπk=(γπk1,,γπkn)T.

    Remark 3.1. From a financial perspective, converting the minimization problem into a maximization one, the above cost functional can be seen as a financial supervisor, such as the one introduced in [4,8], aiming at lending money to each node (e.g., a bank, a financial player, an institution, etc.) in the system to avert it from the corresponding (default) boundary. Continuing the financial interpretation, different weights γ can be used to assign to any node a relative importance. This allows to establish a hierarchy of (financial) relevance within the system, resulting in a priority scale related to the systemic (monetary) importance took on by each node. As to give an example, in [8] a systematic procedure has been derived to obtain the overall importance of any node in a financial network.

    In what follows, we derive a set of Riccati BSDEs to provide the global optimal control in feedback form. For the sake of notation clarity, we denote by Xk;k(t) the dynamics when only the kth node is left. Similarly, Xk;(k,l)(t), resp. Xl;(k,l)(t), denotes the evolution of the node k, resp. of the node l, when this pair (k,l) survives. Analogously, we will make use of a component-wise notation, namely Xi;k will denote the ith component of the ndimensional vector Xk. According to such a notation, we have the following

    Theorem 3.2. The optimal control problem (27), with associated costs given by (28), has an optimal feedback control solution given by

    ˉα(t)=P(t)X(t)+φ(t),

    where P and φ are defined as follows

    P(t)=P0(t)1{t<ˆτ1}+n1k=1πkCn,kPπk(t)1{τπk<t<ˆτk+1},φ(t)=φ0(t)1{t<ˆτ1}+n1k=1πkCn,kφπk(t)1{τπk<t<ˆτk+1}, (29)

    Pπk and φπk being solution to the following recursive system of Riccati BSDEs

    {dPπn1(t)=((Pπn1(t))2+(σπn1(t))2Pπn1(t)+2Zπn1;P(t)σπn1(t)1)dt+Zπn1;P(t)dWπn1(t),Pπn1(ˆτn)=1,{dφπn1(t)=((Pπn1(t)μπn1(t))φπn1(t)+σπn1(t)Zπn1;φ(t)hπn1(P(t),v(t)))dt+Zπn1;φ(t)dWπn1(t),φπn1(ˆτn)=vπn1(ˆτn),{dPπk(t)=(Pπk(t)2+(σπk)2Pπk(t))dt++(Zπk;Pj(t)σπk(t)γπk)dtZπk;P(t)dWπk(t),Pπk(ˆτn1)=γπkπk+1Cn,k+1Pπk+1(ˆτn1)1{ˆτk+1=τπk+1},{dφπk(t)=((μπk(t)Pπk(t))φπk(t)+σπk(t)Zπk;φ(t))dt+hπk(Pπk(t),vπk(t))dtZπk;φ(t)dWπk(t),φ(ˆτn1)=γvˆτn1(ˆτn1)+πk+1Cn,k+1φπk+1(ˆτn1)1{ˆτk+1=τπk+1},{dP0)(t)=((P0(t))2+(σ0(t))2P0(t)+Z0;P(t)σ0(t)γ0)dt+Z0;P(t)dW(t),P0(ˆτ1)=γ0πCn,1P1(ˆτ1)1{ˆτ1=τπ},{dφ0(t)=((μ0)P0(t))φ0(t)+σ0(t)Z0;φ(t)γ0v0(t))dt+Z0;φ(t)dW(t),φ0(ˆτ1)=γ0v0(ˆτ1)πCn,1φ1(ˆτ1)1{ˆτ1=τπ}.

    Proof. Let us thus first consider the last control problem, recalling that Hk(t,x,a,y,z) is the generalized Hamiltonian defined in (14), where Bk, resp. Σk, resp. Lk, is given in Eq (25), resp. Eq (26), resp. Eq (28). An application of the stochastic maximum principle, see Theorems 2.8–2.11, leads us to consider the following adjoint BSDE

    Yk(t)=xGk(Xk(ˆτn))+ˆτntxHk(Xk(s),αk(s),Yk(s),Zk(s))ds+ˆτntZk(s)dW(s),t[0,ˆτn], (30)

    Yk being a ndimensional vector, whereas Zk is a n×n matrix whose (i,j)entry is denoted by Zki,j. Then, considering the particular form for Bk(t,x,a), Σk(t,x), Lk(t,x,a) and Gk(t,x), in Eqs (25), (26) and (28), we have

    xkHk(t,x,a,y,z)=μk;k(t)yk+σk:kzk,k+γkk|xkvk;k|,xkGk(t,x)=γkk|xkvk;k|,

    and

    xiHk(t,x,a,y,z)=0=xiGk(t,x), if ik,

    where xi denotes the derivative w.r.t. the ith component of xRn.

    Thus we have that the kth component of the BSDE (30) now reads

    Yk;k(t)=γkkXk;k(ˆτn)γkkvk;k(ˆτn)++ˆτnt(μk;k(s)Yk;k(s)+σk;k(s)Zkk,k(s)+γkkXk;k(s)γkkvk;k(s))ds+ˆτntZkk,k(s)dWk(s),t[0,ˆτn]. (31)

    Analogously, we have that the second last control problem is associated to the following system of BSDEs

    Yi;(k,l)(t)=γ(k,l)iXi;(k,l)(ˆτn1)γ(k,l)vi;(k,l)(τπn1)+ˉYi;n1(ˆτn1)+ˆτn1t(μi;(k,l)(s)Yi;(k,l)(s)+lj=kσj;(k,l)(s)Z(k,l)j,j(s))ds++ˆτn1t(γ(k,l)iXi;(k,l)(s)γ(k,l)ivi;(k,l)(s))ds+lj=kˆτn1tZ(k,l)i,j(s)dWj(s),t[0,τπn1],i=k,l, (32)

    and so on for any πk, until we reach the first control problem with associated the following BSDEs system

    Yi;0(t)=γ0iXi;0(ˆτ1)γ0iv0(ˆτ1)+ˉYi;1(ˆτ1)++ˆτ1t(μi;0(s)Yi;0(s)+nj=1σj;0(s)Z0j,j(s)+γ0iXi;0(s)γ0iv0(s))ds+nj=1ˆτ1tZ0i,j(s)dWj(s),t[0,τ0],i=1,,n. (33)

    Therefore, for t[0,ˆτn], we are left with the minimization problem for

    J(x,t):=Etˆτnt(|Xk;k(s)vk;k(s)|2+12|αk;k(s)|2)ds++Et|Xk;k(ˆτ1)vk;k(ˆτ1)|2.

    Exploiting Theorem 2.8, we have that, on the interval [τπn1,ˆτn], the above control problem is associated to the following forward–backward system

    {dXk;k(t)=(μk;k(t)Xk;k(t)+bk;k(t)+αk;k(t))dt++(σk;k(t)Xk;k(t)+νk;k(t))dWk(t),Xk;k(τπn1)=Xk;n1(τπn1),dYk;k(t)=(μk;k(t)Yk;k(t)+σk;k(t)Zkk,k(t)+Xk;k(t)vk;k(t))dt+Zk;kk,k(t)dWk(t),Yk;k(ˆτn)=Xk;k(ˆτn)vk;k(ˆτn). (34)

    In what follows, for the sake of brevity, we will drop the index (k;k). Therefore, until otherwise specified, we will write X instead of Xk;k, and similarly for any other coefficients. We also recall that system (47) has to be solved for any k=1,,n.

    We thus guess the solution of the backward component Y in Eq (47) to be of the form

    Y(t)=P(t)X(t)φ(t), (35)

    for P and φ two Rvalued processes to be determined.

    Notice that in standard cases, that is when the coefficients are not random or the terminal time is deterministic, P and φ solve a backward ODE, while in the present case, because of the terminal time randomness, P and φ will solve a BSDE.

    Let us thus assume that (P(t),ZP(t)) is the solution to

    dP(t)=FP(t)dtZP(t)dW(t),P(ˆτn)=1, (36)

    and that (φ(t),Zφ(t)) solves

    dφ(t)=Fφ(t)dtZφ(t)dWj(t),φ(ˆτn)=v(ˆτn). (37)

    From the first order condition, namely aH(t,x,a,y,z)=0, we have that the optimal control is given by

    ˉα=Y(t)=P(t)X(t)φ(t). (38)

    An application of Itô formula yields

    (μ(t)Y(t)+σ(t)Z(t)+X(t)v(t))dtZ(t)dW(t)=dY(t)=d(P(t)X(t))dφ(t)==(FP(t)X(t)+P(t)μ(t)X(t)+P(t)α(t)+ZP(t)σ(t)X(t)+ZP(t)ν(t)+P(t)b(t)+Fφ(t))dt++(ZP(t)X(t)+P(t)σ(t)X(t)+P(t)ν(t)Zφj(t))dW(t)==(FP(t)+P(t)μ(t)+ZP(t)σ(t))X(t)dt+P(t)α(t)dt+(ZP(t)ν(t)+P(t)b(t)+Fφ(t))dt++(ZP(t)+P(t)σ(t))X(t)dW(t)+(P(t)ν(t)Zφ(t))dW(t). (39)

    Therefore, equating the left hand side and the right hand side of Eq (39), we derive

    Z(t)=(ZP(t)+P(t)σ(t))X(t)+(P(t)ν(t)Zφ(t)), (40)

    moreover, by substituting Eq (40) into the left hand side of Eq (39), exploiting the first order optimality condition (38), and equating again the left hand side and the right hand side of Eq (39), we obtain

    (μ(t)P(t)σ(t)ZP(t)σ2(t)P(t)+1)X(t)(μ(t)φ(t)+σ(t)P(t)ν(t)σ(t)Zφ(t)+v(t))==(FP(t)+P(t)μ(t)+ZP(t)σ(t)+P2(t))X(t)+(ZP(t)ν(t)+P(t)b(t)+Fφ(t)P(t)φ(t)). (41)

    Since Eq (41) has to hold for any X(t), we have

    μ(t)P(t)σ(t)ZP(t)σ2(t)P(t)+1=FP(t)+P(t)μ(t)+ZP(t)σ(t)+P(t)2, (42)

    which, after some computations, leads to

    FP(t)=P(t)2+σ2(t)P(t)+2ZP(t)σ(t)1. (43)

    Similarly, we also have that

    Fφ(t)=(P(t)μ(t))φ(t)+σ(t)Zφ(t)v(t)σ(t)ν(t)P(t)ZP(t)ν(t)P(t)b(t), (44)

    hence using the particular form for the generator FP, resp. of Fφ, stated in Eq (43), resp. in Eq (44), in Eq (36), resp. in Eq (37), and reintroducing, for the sake of clarity, the index k, the last optimal control ˉαk;k(t) reads as follow

    ˉαk;k(t)=Pk;k(t)Xk;k(t)φk;k(t),

    Pk;k(t) and φk;k(t) being solutions to the BSDEs

    {dPk;k(t)=((Pk;k(t))2+(σk;k(t))2Pk;k(t)+2Zk;Pk,k(t)σk;k(t)1)dt+Zk;Pk,k(t)dWk(t),Pk;k(ˆτn)=1, (45)
    {dφk;k(t)=((Pk;k(t)μk;k(t))φk;k(t)+σk;k(t)Zk;φk,k(t)hk;k(P(t),v(t)))dt+Zk;φk,k(t)dWk(t),φ(ˆτn)=vk;k(ˆτn), (46)

    where we have introduced the function

    hk;k(P(t),v(t)):=v(t)+σ(t)ν(t)P(t)+ZP(t)ν(t)+P(t)b(t).

    Notice that, from Eq (46), we have that φ is a BSDE with linear generator, so that its solution is explicitly given by

    φk;k(t)=Γ1(t)Et[Γ(ˆτn)vk;k(ˆτn)ˆτntΓ(s)hk;k(P(s),v(s))ds],

    where Γ solves

    dΓ(t)=Γ(t)[(Pk;k(t)μk;k(t))dt+σk;k(t)dW(t)],Γ(0)=1.

    Moreover, by [26,Th. 5.2,Th. 5.3], it follows that Eq (45) admits a unique adapted solution on [0,ˆτn]. Therefore, iterating the above analysis for any k=1,,n, we gain the optimal solution to the last control problem. Having solved the last control problem, we can consider the second last control problem. Assuming, with no loss of generality, that nodes (k,l) are left, all subsequent computation has to be carried out for any possible couple k=1,,n, l=k+1,,n.

    By Theorem 2.8, the optimal pair (ˉXi,ˉαi), i=k,l, satisfies, component–wise, the following forward–backward system for i=k,l,

    {dXi;(k,l)(t)=(μi;(k,l)(t)Xi;(k,l)(t)+bi;(k,l)(t)+αi;(k,l)(t))dt++(σi;(k,l)(t)Xi;(k,l)(t)+νi;(k,l)(t))dWi(t),Xi;(k,l)(τπn2)=Xi;n2(τπn2),dYi;(k,l)(t)=(μi;(k,l)(t)Yi;(k,l)(t)+σi;(k,l)Zi;(k,l)i,i(t))dt++(γi;(k,l)Xi;(k,l)(t)γi;(k,l)vi;(k,l)(t))dtlj=kZi;(k,l)i,j(t)dWj(t),Yi;(k,l)(ˆτn1)=γi;(k,l)Xi;(k,l)(ˆτn1)γi;(k,l)vi;(k,l)(ˆτn1)+ˉYk;n1(ˆτn1); (47)

    in what follows we will denote by Zj the jth ndimensional column of Z in Eq (32). Note that the only non null entries of Z will be Zi,j, for i,j=k,l. Also, for the sake of simplicity, we will avoid to use the notation Xi;(k,l), i=k,l, only using Xi, i=k,l, instead.

    Mimicking the same method earlier used, we again guess the solution of the backward component Yi to be of the form

    Yi(t)=Pi(t)Xi(t)φi(t),i=k,l, (48)

    for Pi and φi, i=k,l, a Rvalued process.

    Because of the particular form of Eq (34), the ith component of the BSDE Y depends only on the ith component of the forward SDE X, the matrix P has null entry off the main diagonal, namely it has the form

    P(t)=(000000Pk(t)00000000000Pl(t)000000),

    similarly for φ.

    Let us assume that (Pi(t),Zi;P(t)), i=k,l solves

    dPi(t)=Fi;P(t)dtlj=kZPj(t)dWj(t),Pi(ˆτn1)=γiPi(ˆτn1)1{ˆτn1=τi},

    and that (φi(t),Zi;φ(t)) solves

    dφi(t)=Fi;φ(t)dtlj=kZφj(t)dWj(t),φ(ˆτn1)=γivi(ˆτn1)+φi(ˆτn1)1{ˆτn1=τi}.

    From the first order condition we have that the optimal control is of the form

    ˉαi=Yi(t)=Pi(t)Xi(t)φi(t). (49)

    Then, again applying the Itô formula, we have

    (μi(t)φi(t)μi(t)Pi(t)Xi(t)+σi(t)Zii(t)+γiXi(t)γivi(t))dtlj=kZij(t)dWj(t)==dYi(t)=d(Pi(t)Xi(t))dφi(t)==(Fi;P(t)Xi(t)+Pi(t)μi(t)Xi(t)+Pi(t)bi(t)+Pi(t)αi(t)+)+Fi;φ(t)dt++(kj=l(Zi;Pj(t)ρijσi(t)Xi(t)+Zi;Pj(t)ρijνi(t)))dt+lj=kZi;Pj(t)Xi(t)dWj(t)+Pi(t)(σi(t)Xi(t)+νi(t))dWi(t)2j=1Zi;φj(t)dWj(t)==(Fi;P(t)+Pi(t)μi(t)+lj=kZi;Pj(t)ρijσi(t))Xi(t)dt+Pi(t)αi(t)dt++Fi;φ(t)dt+kj=lZi;Pj(t)ρijνi(t)dt+Pi(t)bi(t)dt++(Zi;Pi(t)+Pi(t)σi(t))Xi(t)dWi(t)+lj=kjiZi;Pj(t)Xi(t)dWj(t)+Pi(t)νi(t)lj=kZi;φj(t)dWj(t). (50)

    Thus, substituting Eq (49) into Eq (50), and proceeding as for (42), we have

    Fi;P(t)=(Pi(t))2+(σi(t))2Pi(t)+lj=kZi;Pj(t)ijσi(t)γi, (51)

    with

    ij:={ρijij,2i=j,

    together with

    Fi;φ(t)=(μiPi(t))φ(t)+σiZi;φi(t)kj=lZi;Pj(t)ρijνidtPi(t)νi(t)dtγivi(t)σi(t)νi(t)Pi(t).

    Turning back, for the sake of clarity, to use the extended notation dropped before, we have that ˉαi;(k,l)(t), i=k,l, is given by

    ˉαi;(k,l)(t)=Pi;(k,l)(t)Xi;(k,l)(t)+φi;(k,l)(t),

    where Pi;(k,l) and φi;(k,l) are solutions, for i=k,l, to the BSDEs

    {dPi;(k,l)(t)=(Pi;(k,l)(t)2+(σi;(k,l))2Pi;(k,l)(t))dt++(lj=kZ(k,l);Pj(t)ijσi;(k,l)(t)γi;(k,l))dtZ(k,l);Pi,i(t)dWi(t),Pi;(k,l)(ˆτn1)=γi;(k,l)Pi,i(ˆτn1)1{ˆτn1=τi}, (52)
    {dφi;(k,l)(t)=((μi;(k,l)(t)Pi;(k,l)(t))φi;(k,l)(t)+σi;(k,l)(t)Z(k,l);φi,i(t))dt+hi;(k,l)(Pi;(k,l)(t),vi;(k,l)(t))dtZ(k,l);φi,i(t)dWi(t),φ(ˆτn1)=γi;(k,l)vi;(k,l)(ˆτn1)+φi,i(ˆτn1)1{ˆτn1=τi}, (53)

    with

    hi;(k,l)(Pk;(k,l)(t),,vk;(k,l)(t))=kj=lZi;Pj(t)ρijνi;(k,l)dt+Pi;(k,l)(t)νi;(k,l)(t)dt++γi;(k,l)vi;(k,l)(t)+σi(t)νi;(k,l)(t)Pi;(k,l)(t).

    Let us underline that Eqs (52) and (53) have to be solved for any possible couple k=1,,n, l=k+1,,n. As before, by the linearity of the generator of φi in Eq (53), we have

    φi;(k,l)(t)=(Γi(t))1Et[Γi(ˆτn1)(φi,i(ˆτn1)1{ˆτn1=τi})γivi(ˆτn1)]+(Γi(t))1Et[ˆτn1tΓi(s)hi;(k,l)(Pi;(k,l)(s),vi;(k,l)(s))ds],

    where Γi is the solution to

    dΓi(t)=Γi(t)[μi(t)dt+σi(t)dWi(t)],Γi(0)=1.

    Hence, Eq (52) admits a unique adapted solution on [0,ˆτn1], see [26,Th.5.2,Th. 5.3].

    Analogously, via a backward induction, we can solve the first control problem, that is we solve, for i=1,,n,

    {dXi;0(t)=(μi;0(t)Xi;0(t)+bi;0(t)+αi;0(t))dt+(σi;0(t)Xi;0(t)+νi;0(t))dWi(t),Xi;0(0)=xi0,dYi;0(t)=(μi;0(t)Yi;0(t)+σi;0Z0i,i(t)+γi;0Xi;0(t)γi;0vi;0(t))dtnj=1Z0i,j(t)dWj(t),Yi;0(ˆτ1)=γi;0Xi;0(ˆτ1)γi;0vi;0(ˆτ1)+Yi;1(ˆτ1)1{ˆτ1τi}, (54)

    resulting, exactly repeating what considered so far, to consider an optimal control of the form

    αi;0(t)=Yi;0(t)=Pi;0(t)Xi;0(t)φi;0(t),

    and

    {dPi;0)(t)=((Pi;0(t))2+(σi;0(t))2Pi;0(t)+nj=1Z0;Pj(t)ijσi;0(t)γi;0)dt+Z0;Pi,i(t)dWi(t),Pi;0(ˆτ1)=γi;0Pi;1(ˆτ1)1{ˆτ1τi}, (55)
    {dφi;0(t)=((μi;0)Pi;0(t))φi;0(t)+σi;0(t)Z0;φi,i(t)γi;0vi;0(t))dt+Z0;φi,i(t)dWi(t),φi;0(ˆτ1)=φi;1(ˆτ1)1{ˆτ1τi}γi;0vi;0(ˆτ1), (56)

    with

    hi;0(Pi;0(t),vi;0(t))=nj=1Zi;Pj(t)ρijνi;0dt+Pi;0(t)νi;0(t)dt++γi;0vi;0(t)+σi;0(t)νi;0(t)Pi;0(t),

    which concludes the proof.

    [1] [ M. Arcà,C. A. Perucci,T. Spadea, The epidemic dynamics of HIV-1 in Italy: Modelling the interaction between intravenous drug users and heterosexual population, Stat Med, 11 (1992): 1657-1684.
    [2] [ S. M. Blower,H. B. Gershengorn,R. M. Grant, A tale of two futures: HIV and antiretroviral therapy in San Francisco, Science, 287 (2000): 650-654.
    [3] [ C. Bonifazi,F. Heins,S. Strozza,M. Vitiello, The italian transition from emigration to immigration country, IRPPS Working Papers, 24 (2009): 2-91.
    [4] [ L. Camoni,S. Boros,V. Regine,M. Ferri,M. Santaquilani, Aggiornamento delle nuove diagnosi di infezione da HIV e dei casi di AIDS in Italia al 31 dicembre 2012, Notiziario Istituto Superiore di Sanitá, 26 (2013): 3-47.
    [5] [ L. Camoni,S. Boros,V. Regine,M. Santaquilani,M. Ferri, Aggiornamento delle nuove diagnosi di infezione da HIV e dei casi di AIDS in Italia al 31 dicembre 2013, Notiziario Istituto Superiore di Sanitá, 27 (2014): 3-46.
    [6] [ L. Camoni,M. Raimondo,M. Dorrucci,V. Regine,M. C. Salfa, Estimating minimum adult HIV prevalence: A cross-sectional study to assess the characteristics of people living with HIV in Italy, AIDS Res Hum Retrov, 31 (2015): 282-287.
    [7] [ L. Camoni, V. Regine, K. Stanecki, M. C. Salfa and M. Raimondo et al. , Estimates of the number of people living with HIV in Italy, Biomed Res Int, 2014 (2014), Article ID 209619, 6 pages.
    [8] [ N. Crepaz,T. A. Hart,G. Marks, Highly active antiretroviral therapy and sexual risk behavior: A meta-analytic review, JAMA-J Am Med Assoc, 292 (2004): 224-236.
    [9] [ O. Diekmann,J. A. P. Heesterbeek,J. A. J. Metz, On the definition and the computation of the basic reproduction ratio R0 in models for infectious diseases in heterogeneous populations, J Math Biol, 28 (1990): 365-382.
    [10] [ D. Donnell,J. M. Baeten,J. Kiarie,K. K. Thomas,W. Stevens, Heterosexual HIV-1 transmission after initiation of antiretroviral therapy: A prospective cohort analysis, Lancet, 375 (2010): 2092-2098.
    [11] [ J. Eaton,N. Menzies,J. Stover,V. Cambiano,L. Chindelevitch, Health benefits, costs, and cost-effectiveness of earlier eligibility for adult antiretroviral therapy and expanded treatment coverage: a combined analysis of 12 mathematical models, Lancet Glob Health, 2 (2014): e23-e34.
    [12] [ M. Franzetti,F. Adorni,C. Parravicini,B. Vergani,S. Antinori, Trends and predictors of non-AIDS-defining cancers in men and women with HIV infection: A single-institution retrospective study before and after the introduction of HAART, J Acquir Immune Defic Syndr, 62 (2013): 414-420.
    [13] [ M. Franzetti, M. Violin, A. Antinori, A. De Luca and F. Ceccherini-Silberstein et al. , Trends and correlates of HIV-1 resistance among subjects failing an antiretroviral treatment over the 2003-2012 decade in Italy, BMC Infect Dis, 14 (2014), p398.
    [14] [ R. Granich, S. Crowley, M. Vitoria, Y. R. Lo and Y. Souteyrand et al. , Highly active antiretroviral treatment for the prevention of HIV transmission, J Int AIDS Soc, 13 (2010), 1pp.
    [15] [ R. M. Granich,C. F. Gilks,C. Dye,K. M. De Cock,B. G. Williams, Universal voluntary HIV testing with immediate antiretroviral therapy as a strategy for elimination of HIV transmission: A mathematical model, Lancet, 373 (2009): 48-57.
    [16] [ H. Guo,M. Y. Li, Impacts of migration and immigration on disease transmission dynamics in heterogeneous populations, Discret Contin Dyn S -Series B, 17 (2012): 2413-2430.
    [17] [ H. Guo,M. Y. Li,Z. Shuai, Global stability of the endemic equilibrium of multigroup SIR epidemic models, Canad Appl Math Quart, 14 (2006): 259-284.
    [18] [ H. Guo,M. Y. Li,Z. Shuai, Global dynamics of a general class of multistage models for infectious diseases, SIAM J Appl Math, 72 (2012): 261-279.
    [19] [ M. Iannelli,F. Milner,A. Pugliese,M. Gonzo, The HIV/AIDS epidemics among drug injectors: A study of contact structure through a mathematical model, Math Biosci, 139 (1997): 25-58.
    [20] [ S. C. Kalichman,L. Eaton,D. Cain,C. Cherry,H. Pope, HIV treatment beliefs and sexual transmission risk behaviors among HIV positive men and women, J Behav Med, 29 (2006): 401-410.
    [21] [ M. Kretzschmar,M. Schim van der Loeff,P. Birrell,D. De Angelis,R. Coutinho, Prospects of elimination of HIV with test-and-treat strategy, Proc Natl Acad Sci USA, 110 (2013): 15538-15543.
    [22] [ J. R. Lingappa, J. P. Hughes, R. S. Wang, J. M. Baeten and C. Celum et al. , Estimating the impact of plasma HIV-1 RNA reductions on heterosexual HIV-1 transmission risk, PLoS One, 5 (2010), e12598.
    [23] [ P. M. Luz, B. Grinsztejn, L. Velasque, A. G. Pacheco and V. G. Veloso et al. , Long-term CD4 + cell count in response to combination antiretroviral therapy, PLoS One, 9 (2014), e93039.
    [24] [ K. A. Lythgoe,L. Pellis,C. Fraser, Is HIV short-sighted? Insights from a multistrain nested model, Evolution, 67 (2013): 2769-2782.
    [25] [ R. Manfredi,L. Calza,F. Chiodo, HIV disease among immigrants coming to Italy from outside of the European Union: A case-control study of epidemiological and clinical features, Epidemiol Infect, 127 (2001): 527-533.
    [26] [ R. May,R. Anderson, Transmission dynamics of HIV infection, Nature, 326 (1987): 137-142.
    [27] [ V. Miller,C. A. Sabin,A. N. Phillips,C. Rottmann,H. Rabenau, The impact of protease inhibitor-containing highly active antiretroviral therapy on progression of HIV disease and its relationship to CD4 and viral load, AIDS, 14 (2000): 2129-2136.
    [28] [ F. Nyabadza,Z. Mukandavire,S. Hove-Musekwa, Modelling the HIV/AIDS epidemic trends in South Africa: Insights from a simple mathematical model, Nonlinear Anal Real World Appl, 12 (2011): 2091-2104.
    [29] [ P. Paci, F. Martini, M. Bernaschi, G. D'Offizi and F. Castiglione, Timely HAART initiation may pave the way for a better viral control, BMC Infect Dis, 11 (2011), p56.
    [30] [ M. Parczewski,M. Leszczyszyn-Pynka,M. Witak-Jedra,K. Maciejewska,W. Rymer, Transmitted HIV drug resistance in antiretroviral-treatment-naive patients from poland differs by transmission category and subtype, J Antimicrob Chemother, 70 (2015): 233-242.
    [31] [ V. Patruno, M. Venturi and S. Roberto, Intercensal Population Estimates. Demographic Balance, National Institute of Statistics of Italy (ISTAT), http://demo.istat.it/index.html.
    [32] [ T. C. Quinn,M. J. Wawer,N. Sewankambo,D. Serwadda,C. Li, Viral load and heterosexual transmission of human immunodeficiency virus type 1. Rakai Project Study Group, N Engl J Med, 343 (2000): 921-929.
    [33] [ A. S. Rao,K. Thomas,K. Sudhakar,P. K. Maini, HIV/AIDS epidemic in India and predicting the impact of the national response: mathematical modeling and analyis, Math Biosci Eng, 6 (2009): 779-813.
    [34] [ R. J. Smith,J. T. Okano,J. S. Kahn,E. N. Bodine,S. Blower, Evolutionary dynamics of complex networks of HIV drug-resistant strains: The case of San Francisco, Science, 327 (2010): 697-701.
    [35] [ T. Sterling,R. E. Chaisson,R. D. Moore, HIV-1 RNA, CD4 T-lymphocytes, and clinical response to highly active antiretroviral therapy, AIDS, 15 (2001): 2251-2257.
    [36] [ B. Taiwo,R. L. Murphy,C. Katlama, Novel antiretroviral combinations in treatment-experienced patients with HIV infection: Rationale and results, Drugs, 70 (2010): 1629-1642.
    [37] [ The INSIGHT START Study Group,J. D. Lundgren,A. G. Babiker,F. Gordin,S. Emery, Initiation of antiretroviral therapy in early asymptomatic HIV infection, N Engl J Med, 373 (2015): 795-807.
    [38] [ P. van den Driessche,J. Watmough, Reproduction numbers and sub-threshold endemic equilibria for compartmental models of disease transmission, Math Biosci, 180 (2002): 29-48.
    [39] [ J. Vercauteren,A. M. Wensing,D. A. van de Vijver,J. Albert,C. Balotta, Transmission of drug-resistant HIV-1 is stabilizing in europe, J Infect Dis, 200 (2009): 1503-1508.
    [40] [ R. Weber,M. Ruppik,M. Rickenbach,A. Spoerri,H. Furrer, Decreasing mortality and changing patterns of causes of death in the Swiss HIV Cohort Study, HIV Med, 14 (2013): 195-207.
    [41] [ When To Start Consortium,J. A. Sterne,M. May,D. Costagliola,F. de Wolf, Timing of initiation of antiretroviral therapy in AIDS-free HIV-1-infected patients: A collaborative analysis of 18 HIV cohort studies, Lancet, 373 (2009): 1352-1363.
    [42] [ WHO Guidelines Approved by the Guidelines Review Committee, Guideline on When to Start Antiretroviral Therapy and on Pre-Exposure Prophylaxis for HIV, World Health Organization, Geneva, 2015.
    [43] [ D. P. Wilson,M. G. Law,A. E. Grulich,D. A. Cooper,J. M. Kaldor, Relation between HIV viral load and infectiousness: A model-based analysis, Lancet, 372 (2008): 314-320.
    [44] [ T. Zhang,M. Jia,H. Luo,Y. Zhou,N. Wang, Study on a HIV/AIDS model with application to Yunnan province, China, Appl Math Model, 35 (2011): 4379-4392.
    [45] [ M. Zwahlen and M. Egger, Progression and Mortality of Untreated HIV-positive Individuals Living in Resource-Limited Settings: Update of Literature Review and Evidence Synthesis, Report to UNAIDS obligation no HQ/05/422204.
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Claudio Bellani, Damiano Brigo, Mechanics of Good Trade Execution in the Framework of Linear Temporary Market Impact, 2019, 1556-5068, 10.2139/ssrn.3458454
    2. Francesco Giuseppe Cordoni, Luca Di Persio, Luca Prezioso, A lending scheme for a system of interconnected banks with probabilistic constraints of failure, 2020, 120, 00051098, 109111, 10.1016/j.automatica.2020.109111
    3. Claudio Bellani, Damiano Brigo, Mechanics of good trade execution in the framework of linear temporary market impact, 2021, 21, 1469-7688, 143, 10.1080/14697688.2020.1814395
    4. Francesco Giuseppe Cordoni, Luca Di Persio, Yilun Jiang, A Bank Salvage Model by Impulse Stochastic Controls, 2020, 8, 2227-9091, 60, 10.3390/risks8020060
    5. Zhun Gou, Nan-jing Huang, Ming-hui Wang, A linear-quadratic mean-field stochastic Stackelberg differential game with random exit time, 2023, 96, 0020-7179, 731, 10.1080/00207179.2021.2011423
    6. Riccardo Cesari, Harry Zheng, Stochastic Maximum Principle for Optimal Liquidation with Control-Dependent Terminal Time, 2022, 85, 0095-4616, 10.1007/s00245-022-09848-1
    7. Giacomo Ascione, Giuseppe D’Onofrio, Deterministic Control of SDEs with Stochastic Drift and Multiplicative Noise: A Variational Approach, 2023, 88, 0095-4616, 10.1007/s00245-023-09978-0
    8. Moh Shahid Khan, Ravi Kumar Mandava, Design of dynamically balanced gait for the biped robot while crossing the obstacle, 2024, 238, 0954-4062, 9125, 10.1177/09544062241246878
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2018 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(4273) PDF downloads(633) Cited by(0)

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog