Loading [MathJax]/jax/output/SVG/jax.js
Research article Special Issues

Applications of linear regression models in exploring the relationship between media attention, economic policy uncertainty and corporate green innovation

  • The media plays a dual role of "supervision" and "collusion" in governance mechanisms. This study investigates the impact of media attention and economic policy uncertainty on green innovation by analyzing A-share industrial listed enterprises data between 2011 and 2020. The results show that media attention can effectively promote green innovation and that this impact is significantly heterogeneous. Media attention significantly affects green innovation in non-state-owned enterprises and manufacturing companies positively, but it is insignificant for state-owned enterprises and mining and energy supply industries. Moreover, the results indicate that external economic policy uncertainty can lead enterprises to take early measures to hedge risks, thereby positively regulating the promotion effect of media attention on green innovation during economic fluctuations. Finally, media attention can promote green innovation by increasing environmental regulation intensity, reducing corporate financing constraints, and enhancing corporate social responsibility. Therefore, paying full attention to the media as an institutional subject outside of laws and regulations, gradually forming a pressure-driven mechanism for corporate green innovation, and reducing information opacity, is a pivotal way to promote enterprises' green innovation.

    Citation: Yang Xu, Conghao Zhu, Runze Yang, Qiying Ran, Xiaodong Yang. Applications of linear regression models in exploring the relationship between media attention, economic policy uncertainty and corporate green innovation[J]. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(8): 18734-18761. doi: 10.3934/math.2023954

    Related Papers:

    [1] Aziz Belmiloudi . Time-varying delays in electrophysiological wave propagation along cardiac tissue and minimax control problems associated with uncertain bidomain type models. AIMS Mathematics, 2019, 4(3): 928-983. doi: 10.3934/math.2019.3.928
    [2] Zuliang Lu, Xiankui Wu, Fei Huang, Fei Cai, Chunjuan Hou, Yin Yang . Convergence and quasi-optimality based on an adaptive finite element method for the bilinear optimal control problem. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(9): 9510-9535. doi: 10.3934/math.2021553
    [3] Zahra Pirouzeh, Mohammad Hadi Noori Skandari, Kamele Nassiri Pirbazari, Stanford Shateyi . A pseudo-spectral approach for optimal control problems of variable-order fractional integro-differential equations. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(9): 23692-23710. doi: 10.3934/math.20241151
    [4] Xin Yi, Rong Liu . An age-dependent hybrid system for optimal contraception control of vermin. AIMS Mathematics, 2025, 10(2): 2619-2633. doi: 10.3934/math.2025122
    [5] Yuanyuan Cheng, Yuan Li . A novel event-triggered constrained control for nonlinear discrete-time systems. AIMS Mathematics, 2023, 8(9): 20530-20545. doi: 10.3934/math.20231046
    [6] Woocheol Choi, Young-Pil Choi . A sharp error analysis for the DG method of optimal control problems. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(5): 9117-9155. doi: 10.3934/math.2022506
    [7] Xiang Wu, Yuzhou Hou, Kanjian Zhang . Optimal feedback control for a class of fed-batch fermentation processes using switched dynamical system approach. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(5): 9206-9231. doi: 10.3934/math.2022510
    [8] Tainian Zhang, Zhixue Luo . Optimal harvesting for a periodic competing system with size structure in a polluted environment. AIMS Mathematics, 2022, 7(8): 14696-14717. doi: 10.3934/math.2022808
    [9] Qian Li, Zhenghong Jin, Linyan Qiao, Aichun Du, Gang Liu . Distributed optimization of nonlinear singularly perturbed multi-agent systems via a small-gain approach and sliding mode control. AIMS Mathematics, 2024, 9(8): 20865-20886. doi: 10.3934/math.20241015
    [10] Asaf Khan, Gul Zaman, Roman Ullah, Nawazish Naveed . Optimal control strategies for a heroin epidemic model with age-dependent susceptibility and recovery-age. AIMS Mathematics, 2021, 6(2): 1377-1394. doi: 10.3934/math.2021086
  • The media plays a dual role of "supervision" and "collusion" in governance mechanisms. This study investigates the impact of media attention and economic policy uncertainty on green innovation by analyzing A-share industrial listed enterprises data between 2011 and 2020. The results show that media attention can effectively promote green innovation and that this impact is significantly heterogeneous. Media attention significantly affects green innovation in non-state-owned enterprises and manufacturing companies positively, but it is insignificant for state-owned enterprises and mining and energy supply industries. Moreover, the results indicate that external economic policy uncertainty can lead enterprises to take early measures to hedge risks, thereby positively regulating the promotion effect of media attention on green innovation during economic fluctuations. Finally, media attention can promote green innovation by increasing environmental regulation intensity, reducing corporate financing constraints, and enhancing corporate social responsibility. Therefore, paying full attention to the media as an institutional subject outside of laws and regulations, gradually forming a pressure-driven mechanism for corporate green innovation, and reducing information opacity, is a pivotal way to promote enterprises' green innovation.



    A century ago, the first metric fixed-point theorem was published by Banach [1]. In fact, before Banach, some famous mathematicians such as Picard and Liouville had used the fixed point approach to solve certain differential equations, more precisely, initial value problems. Inspired by their results, Banach considered it as a separated and independent result in the framework of the nonlinear functional analysis and point-set topology. The statement and the proof of an outstanding work of Banach, also known as contraction mapping principle, can be considered as an art piece: Each contraction, in the setting of a complete metric space, possesses a unique fixed point. Metric fixed point theory has been appreciated and investigated by several researchers. These researchers have different reasons and motivations to study this theory. The most important reason why the researchers find worthful to work and investigate metric fixed point theory is the natural and strong connection of the theoretical result in nonlinear functional analysis with applied sciences. If we look at it with the chronological aspect, we note that the fixed point theory was born as a tool to solve certain differential equations. Banach liberated the theory from being a tool in applied mathematics to an independent work of nonlinear functional analysis. On Picard and Liouville's side, it is a tool to solve the initial value problem. On the other side, from Banach's point of view, the fixed point theory is an independent research topic that has enormous application potential on almost all qualitative sciences, including applied mathematics. Secondly, Banach fixed point theorem not only guarantee the solution (the existence of a fixed point) but also indicate how we reach the mentioned solution (how to find the fixed point). Finally, we need to underline that almost all real world problems can be transferred to a fixed point problem, easily.

    With this motivation, several generalizations and extensions of Banach's fixed point theory have been released by introducing new contractions or by changing the structure of the studied abstract space. Among, we shall mention only a few of them that set up the skeleton of the contraction dealt with it. Historically, the first contraction we shall focus on it is the Meir-Keeler contraction [2]. Roughly speaking, the Meir-Keeler contraction can be considered as a uniform contraction. The second contraction that we dealt with is Jaggi contraction [3]. The interesting part of Jaggi's contraction is the following: Jaggi's contraction is one of the first of its kind that involves some rational expression. The last one is called as an interpolative contraction [4]. In the interpolative contraction the terms are used exponentially instead of standard usage of them.

    In this paper, we shall introduce a new contraction, hybrid Jaggi-Meir-Keeler type contraction, as a unification and generalization of the Meir-Keeler's contraction, the Jaggi's contraction and interpolative contraction in the setting of a complete metric space. We propose certain assumptions to guarantee the existence of a fixed point for such mappings. In addition, we express some example to indicate the validity of the derived results.

    Before going into details, we would like to reach a consensus by explaining the concepts and notations: Throughout the paper, we presume the sets, we deal with, are non-empty. The letter N presents the set of positive integers. Further, we assume that the pair (X,d) is a complete metric space. This notation is required in each of the following theorems, definitions, lemma and so on. We shall use the pair (X,d) everywhere without repeating that it is a complete metric space.

    In what follows we recall the notion of the uniform contraction which is also known as Meir-Keeler contraction:

    Definition 1.1. [2] A mapping f:(X,d)(X,d) is said to be a Meir-Keeler contraction on X, if for every E>0, there exists δ>0 such that

    Ed(x,y)<E+δimpliesd(fx,fy)<E, (1.1)

    for every x,yX.

    Theorem 1.1. [2] Any Meir-Keeler contraction f:(X,d)(X,d) possesses a unique fixed point.

    Very recently, Bisht and Rakočević [5] suggested the following extension of the uniform contraction:

    Theorem 1.2. [5] Suppose a mapping f:(X,d)(X,d) fulfills the following statements:

    (1) for a given E>0 there exists a δ(E)>0 such that

    E<M(x,y)<E+δ(E)impliesd(fx,fy)E;

    (2) d(fx,fy)<M(x,y), whenever M(x,y)>0;

    for any x,yX, where

    M(x,y)=max{d(x,y),αd(x,fx)+(1α)d(y,fy),(1α)d(x,fx)+αd(y,fy),β[d(x,fy)+d(y,fx)]2},

    with 0<α<1,0β<1.Then, f has a unique fixed point uX and fnxu for each xX.

    On the other hand, in 2018, the idea of interpolative contraction was consider to revisit the well-known Kannan's fixed point theorem [6]:

    Definition 1.2. [4] A mapping f:(X,d)(X,d) is said to be an interpolative Kannan type contraction on X if there exist κ[0,1) and γ(0,1) such that

    d(fx,fy)κ[d(x,fx)]γ[d(y,fy)]1γ, (1.2)

    for every x,yXFix(f), where Fix(f)={xX|fx=x}.

    Theorem 1.3. [4] Any interpolative Kannan-contraction mapping f:(X,d)(X,d) possesses a fixed point.

    For more interpolative contractions results, we refer to [7,8,9,10,11] and related references therein.

    Definition 1.3. A mapping f:(X,d)(X,d) is called a Jaggi type hybrid contraction if there is ψΨ so that

    d(fx,fy)ψ(Jsf(x,y)), (1.3)

    for all distinct x,yX where p0 and σi0,i=1,2,3,4, such that σ1+σ2=1 and

    Jsf(x,y)={[σ1(d(x,fx)d(y,fy)d(x,y))s+σ2(d(x,y))s]1/p,ifp>0,x,yX,xy(d(x,fx))σ1(d(y,fy))σ2,ifp=0,x,yXFf(X), (1.4)

    where Ff(X)={zX:fz=z}.

    Theorem 1.4. A continuous mapping f:(X,d)(X,d) possesses a fixed point x if it forms a Jaggi-type hybrid contraction.In particular, for any x0X, the sequence {fnx0} converges to x.

    Definition 1.4. [12] Let α:X×X[0,+) be a mapping, where X. A self-mapping f:(X,d)(X,d) is called triangular α-orbital admissible and denote as fTαX if

    α(x,fx)1impliesα(fx,f2x)1,

    and

    α(x,y)1,andα(y,fy)1,impliesα(x,fy)1

    for all x,yX.

    This concept, was used by many authors, in order to prove variant fixed point results (see, for instance [13,14,15,16,17,18,19] and the corresponding references therein).

    Lemma 1.1. [12] Assume that fTαX. If there exists x0X such that α(x0,fx0)1, then α(xm,xk)1, for all m,nN, where the sequence {xk} is defined by xk+1=xk.

    The following condition is frequently considered to avoid the continuity of the mappings involved.

    (R) if the sequence {xn} in X is such that for each nN,

    α(xn,xn+1)1andlimn+xn=xx,

    then there exists a subsequence {xn(j)} of {xn} such that

    α(xn(j),x)1, for each jN.

    We start this section by introducing the new contraction, namely, hybrid Jaggi-Meir-Keeler type contraction.

    Consider the mapping f:(X,d)(X,d) and the set of fixed point, Ff(X)={zX:fz=z}. We define the crucial expression Rsf as follows:

    Rsf(x,y)={[β1(d(x,fx)d(y,fy)d(x,y))s+β2(d(x,y))s+β3(d(x,fy)+d(y,fx)4)s]1/s,fors>0,x,yX,xy(d(x,fx))β1(d(y,fy))β2(d(x,fy)+d(y,fx)4)β3,fors=0,x,yX, (2.1)

    where p1 and βi0, i=1,2,3 are such that β1+β2+β3=1.

    Definition 2.1. Assume that fTαX. We say that f:(X,d)(X,d) is an α-hybrid Jaggi-Meir-Keeler type contraction on X, if for all distinct x,yX we have:

    (a1) for given E>0, there exists δ>0 such that

    E<max{d(x,y),Rsf(x,y)}<E+δα(x,y)d(fx,fy)E; (2.2)

    (a2)

    α(x,y)d(fx,fy)<max{d(x,y),Rsf(x,y)}. (2.3)

    Theorem 2.1. Any continuous α-hybrid Jaggi-Meir-Keeler type contraction f:(X,d)(X,d) provide a fixed point if there exists x0X, such that α(x0,fx0)1 and α(x0,f2x0)1.

    Proof. Let x0X be an arbitrary, but fixed point. We form the sequence {xm}, as follows:

    xm=fxm1=fmx0,

    for all mN and assume that d(xm,xm+1)>0, for all nN{0}. Indeed, if for some l0N{0} we have d(xl0,xl0+1)=0, it follows that xl0=xl0+1=fxl0. Therefore, xl0 is a fixed point of the mapping f and the proof is closed.

    Since, by assumption, the mapping f is triangular α-orbital admissible, it follows that

    α(x0,fx0)1α(x1,x2)=α(fx0,f2x0)1...
    α(xn,xn+1)1, (2.4)

    for every nN.

    We shall study two cases; these are s>0 and s=0.

    Case (A). For the case s>0, letting x=xn1 and y=xn=fxn1 in (a2), we get

    d(xn,xn+1)α(xn1,xn)d(fxn1,fxn)<max{d(xn1,xn),Rsf(xn1,xn)}, (2.5)

    where

    Rsf(xn1,xn)=[β1(d(xn1,fxn1)d(xn,fxn)d(xn1,xn))s+β2(d(xn1,xn))s++β3(d(xn1,fxn)+d(xn,fxn1)4)s]1/s=[β1(d(xn1,xn)d(xn,xn+1)d(xn1,xn))s+β2(d(xn1,xn))s++β3(d(xn1,xn+1)+d(xn,xn)4)s]1/s[β1(d(xn,xn+1))s+β2(d(xn1,xn))s++β3(d(xn1,xn)+d(xn,xn+1)4)s]1/s.

    If we can find n0N such that d(xn0,xn0+1)d(xn01,xn0), we have

    Rsf(xn01,xn0)[β1(d(xn0,xn0+1))s+β2(d(xn0,xn0+1))s++β3(d(xn0,xn0+1))s]1/s=d(xn0,xn0+1)(β1+β2+β3)1/s=d(xn0,xn0+1).

    Then, max{d(xn0,xn0+1),Rsf(xn01,xn0)}=d(xn0,xn0+1), and using (2.4), respectively (2.5) we get

    d(xn0,xn0+1)α(xn01,xn0)d(fxn+01,fxn0)<max{d(xn0,xn0+1),Rsf(xn01,xn0)}d(xn0,xn0+1),

    which is a contradiction. Therefore, d(xn,xn+1)<d(xn1,xn) for all nN and (2.5) becomes

    d(xn,xn+1)<d(xn1,xn),

    for all nN. Consequently, there exists b0 such that limn+d(xn1,xn)=b. If b>0, we have

    d(xm,xm+1)b>0,

    for any mN. On the one hand, since (2.2) holds for every given E>0, it is possible to choose E=b and let δ>0 be such that (2.2) is satisfied. On the other hand, since, also, limn+max{d(xn1,xn),Rsf(xn1,xn)}=b, there exists m0N such that

    b<max{d(xm01,xm0),Rsf(xm01,xm0)}<b+δ.

    Thus, by (2.2), together with (2.4) we obtain

    d(xm0,xm0+1)α(xm0,xm0+1)d(fxm01,fxm0)<b,

    which is a contradiction. Therefore,

    limn+d(xn,xn+1)=b=0. (2.6)

    We claim now that {xn} is a Cauchy sequence. Let E>0 be fixed and we can choose that δ=min{δ(E),E,1}. Thus, from (2.6) it follows that there exists j0N such that

    d(xn,xn+1)<δ2, (2.7)

    for all nj0. Now, we consider the set

    A={xl|lj0,d(xl,xj0)<E+δ2}. (2.8)

    We claim that fyA whenever y=xlA. Indeed, in case of l=j0, we have fxl=fxj0=xj0+1, and taking (2.7) into account, we get

    d(xj0,xj0+1)<δ2<E+δ2. (2.9)

    Thus, we will assume that l>j0, and we distinguish two cases, namely:

    Case 1. Suppose that

    E<d(xl,xj0)<E+δ2. (2.10)

    We have

    Rsf(xl,xj0)=[β1(d(xl,fxl)d(xj0,fxj0)d(xl,xj0))s+β2(d(xl,xj0))s+β3(d(xl,fxj0)+d(xj0,fxl)4)s]1/s=[β1(d(xl,xl+1)d(xj0,xj0+1)d(xl,xj0))s+β2(d(xl,xj0))s++β3(d(xl,xj0+1)+d(xj0,xl+1)4)s]1/s[β1(d(xl,xl+1)d(xj0,xj0+1)d(xl,xj0))s+β2(d(xl,xj0))s++β3(d(xl,xj0)+d(xj0,xj0+1)+d(xl,xj0)+d(xl,xl+1)4)s]1/s<[β1(d(xl,xl+1))s+β2(d(xl,xj0))s+β3(2d(xl,xj0)+d(xj0,xj0+1)+d(xl,xl+1)4)s]1/s<[β1(δ2)s+β2(E+δ2)s+β3(E2+δ4+δ4)s]1/s(β1+β2+β3)1/s(E+δ2)E+δ.

    In this case,

    E<d(xl,xj0)max{d(xl,xj0),Rsf(xl,xj0)}<max{(E+δ2),(E+δ)}=(E+δ),

    which implies by (a1) that

    α(xl,xj0)d(fxl,fxj0)E. (2.11)

    But, taking into account that the mapping f is triangular α-orbital admissible, together with (2.4) we have

    α(xn,xn+1)1 and α(xn+1,fxn+1)1 implies α(xn,xn+2)1,

    and recursively we get that

    α(xn,xl)1, (2.12)

    for all n,lN. Therefore, from (2.11) and (2.12), we have

    d(xl+1,xj0+1)=d(fxl,fxj0)E. (2.13)

    Now, by the triangle inequality together with (2.7)and (2.13) we get

    d(xl+1,xj0)d(xl+1,xj0+1)+d(xj0+1,xj0)<(E+δ2),

    which means that, indeed fxl=xl+1A.

    Case 2. Suppose that

    d(xl,xj0)E. (2.14)

    Thus,

    d(fxl,xj0)d(fxl,fxj0)+d(fxj0,xj0)α(xl,xj0)d(fxl,fxj0)+d(xj0+1,xj0)<max{d(xl,xj0),Rsf(xl,xj0)}+d(xj0+1,xj0), (2.15)

    where

    Rsf(xl,xj0)=[β1(d(xl,xl+1)d(xj0,xj0+1)d(xl,xj0))s+β2(d(xl,xj0))s++β3(d(xl,xj0)+d(xj0,xj0+1)+d(xl,xj0)+d(xl,xl+1)4)s]1/s.

    We must consider two subcases

    (2a). d(xl,xj0)d(xj0,xj0+1). Then,

    Rsf(xl,xj0)[β1(d(xl,xl+1))s+β2(d(xl,xj0))s++β3(2d(xl,xj0)+d(xj0,xj0+1)+d(xl,xl+1)4)s]1/s<[β1(δ2)s+β2(E))s+β3(2E+2δ24))s]1/s<[β1+β2+β3]1/s(E2+δ4).

    But, since δ=min{δ,E,1}, we get

    Rsf(xl,xj0)<3E4,

    and then

    d(fxl,xj0)<max{d(xl,xj0),Rsf(xl,xj0)}+d(xj0+1,xj0)<max{E,3E4}+δ2=(E+δ2),

    which shows that fxlA.

    (2b). d(xl,xj0)<d(xj0,xj0+1). Then,

    d(fxl,xj0)xl+1,xl)+d(xl,xj0)<δ2+δ2<E+δ2.

    Consequently, choosing some m,nN such that m>n>j0, we can write

    d(xm,xn)d(xm,xj0)+d(xj0,xn)<2(E+δ2)<4E,

    which leads us to

    limm,n+d(xm,xn)=0.

    Therefore, {xm} is a Cauchy sequence in a complete metric space. Thus, we can find a point uX such that limm+xm=u. Moreover, since the mapping f is continuous we have

    u=limm+fm+1x0=limm+f(fmx0)=f(limm+fmx0)=fu,

    that is, u is a fixed point of f.

    Case (B). For the case s=0, letting x=xn1 and y=xn=fxn1 in (2.2), we get

    d(xn,xn+1)α(xn1,xn)d(fxn1,fxn)<max{d(xn1,xn),Rf(xn1,xn)}, (2.16)

    where

    Rf(xn1,xn)=[d(xn1,fxn1)]β1[d(xn,fxn)]β2[d(xn1,fxn)+d(xn,fxn14]β3=[d(xn1,xn)]β1[d(xn,xn+1)]β2[d(xn1,xn+1)+d(xn,xn4]β3=[d(xn1,xn)]β1[d(xn,xn+1)]β2[d(xn1,xn+1)+d(xn,xn4]β3[d(xn1,xn)]β1[d(xn,xn+1)]β2[d(xn1,xn)+d(xn,xn+1)4]β3=[d(xn1,xn)]β1[d(xn,xn+1)]β2[d(xn1,xn)+d(xn,xn+1)4]β3

    Thus, by (2.3) and taking (2.4) into account we have

    d(xn,xn+1)α(xn1,xn)d(fxn1,fxn)<max{d(xn1,xn),Rf(xn1,xn)}.

    Now, if there exists n0N such that d(xn0,xn0+1)d(xn01,xn0), we get

    d(xn0,xn0+1)<max{d(xn01,xn0),Rf(xn01,xn0)}max{d(xn01,xn0),d(xn0,xn0+1)}<d(xn0,xn0+1),

    which is a contradiction. Therefore, d(xn,xn+1)<d(xn1,xn) for all nN, that is, the sequence {xn} decreasing and moreover, converges to some b0. Moreover, since

    Rf(xn1,xn)=[d(xn1,xn)]β1[d(xn,xn+1)]β2[d(xn1,xn+1)4]β3,

    we get that

    limn+max{d(xn1,xn),Rf(xn1,xn)}=b.

    If we suppose that b>0, then, 0<b<d(xn1,xn) and we can find δ>0 such that

    b<max{d(xn1,xn),Rf(xn1,xn)}<b+δ.

    In this way, taking E=b, we get

    b=E<max{d(xn1,xn),Rf(xn1,xn)}<E+δ,

    which implies (by (a1)) that

    d(xn1,xn)α(xn1,xn)d(fxn1,fxn))E=b,

    which is a contradiction. We thus proved that

    limmd(xn1,xn)=0. (2.17)

    We claim now, that the sequence {xn} is Cauchy. Firstly, we remark that, since d(xn1,xn)=0, there exists j0N, such that

    d(xn1,xn)<δ2, (2.18)

    for any nj0, where δ=min{δ,E,1}. Reasoning by induction, we will prove that the following relation

    d(xj0,xj0+m)<E+δ2 (2.19)

    holds, for any mN. Indeed, in case of m=1,

    d(xj0,xj0+1)<δ2<E+δ2,

    so, (2.19) is true. Now, supposing that (2.19) holds for some l, we shall show that it holds for l+1. We have

    Rf(xj0,xj0+l)=(d(xj0,fxj0))β1(xj0+l,fxj0+l)s(d(xj0,fxj0+l)+d(xj0+l,fxj0)4)β3=(d(xj0,xj0+1))β1(xj0+l,xj0+l+1)s(d(xj0,xj0+l+1)+d(xj0+l,xj0+1)4)β3(d(xj0,xj0+1))β1(d(xj0+l,xj0+l+1))s(d(xj0,xj0+l)+d(xj0+l,xj0+l+1)+d(xj0+l,xj0)+d(xj0,xj0+1)4)β3<(δ2)β1+β2((E2+δ4)+δ4)β3(E+δ2). (2.20)

    As in the Case (A), if d(xj0,xj0+l)>E, by (a2), and keeping in mind the above inequalities, we get

    E<d(xj0,xj0+l)max{d(xj0,xj0+l),Rf(xj0,xj0+l)}<max{δ2,(E+δ2)}=E+δ implies α(xj0,xj0+l)d(fxj0,fxj0+l)E.

    But, since using (2.12), it follows that

    d(xj0+1,xj0+l+1)=d(fxj0,fxj0+l)E,

    and then, by (b3) we get

    d(xj0,xj0+l+1)d(xj0,xj0+1)+d(xj0+1,xj0+l+1)<δ2+E<E+δ2.

    Therefore, (2.19) holds for (l+1). In the opposite situation, if d(xj0,xj0+l)E, again by the triangle inequality, we obtain

    d(xj0,xj0+l+1)d(xj0,xj0+1)+d(xj0+1,xj0+l+1)d(xj0,xj0+1)+α(xj0,xj0+l)d(fxj0,fxj0+l)<δ2+max{d(xj0,xj0+l),Rf(xj0,xl)}<δ2+max{E,E2+δ4}=δ2+E.

    Consequently, the induction is completed. Therefore, {xm} is a Cauchy sequence in a complete metric space. Thus, there exists uX such that fu=u.

    In the above Theorem, the continuity condition of the mapping f can be replace by the continuity of f2.

    Theorem 2.2. Suppose that f:(X,d)(X,d) forms an α-hybrid Jaggi-Meir-Keeler type contraction such that f2 is continuous.Then, f has a fixed point, provided that there exists x0X, such that α(x0,fx0)1.

    Proof. Let x0X such that α(x0,fx0)1 and the sequence {xn}, where xn=fxn1, for any nN. Thus, from Theorem 2.3 we know that this is a convergent sequence. Letting u=limn+xn, we claim that u=fu.

    Since the mapping f2 is supposed to be continuous,

    f2u=limn+f2xn=u.

    Assuming on the contrary, that ufu, we have

    Rsf(u,fu)={[β1(d(u,fu)d(fu,f2u)d(u,fu))s+β2(d(u,fu))s+β3(d(u,f2u)+d(fu,fu)4)s]1/s,fors>0(d(u,fu))β1(d(fu,f2u))β2(d(u,f2u)+d(fu,fu)4)β3,fors=0[16pt]={[β1(d(u,fu)d(fu,u)d(u,fu))s+β2(d(u,fu))s+β3(d(u,u)+d(fu,fu)4)s]1/s,fors>0(d(u,fu))β1(d(fu,u))β2(d(u,u)+d(fu,fu)4)β3,fors=0[16pt]={[β1(d(fu,u))s+β2(d(u,fu))s]1/s,fors>00,fors=0={[β1+β2]1/sd(u,fu)),fors>00,fors=0

    Example 2.1. Let X=[0,+), d:X×X[0,+), d(x,y)=|xy|, and the mapping f:XX, where

    f={12,ifx[0,1]16,ifx>1.

    We can easily observe that f is discontinuous at the point x=1, but f2 is a continuous mapping. Let also the function α:X×X[0,+),

    α(x,y)={x2+y2+1,ifx,y[0,1]ln(x+y)+1,ifx,y(1,+)1,ifx=56,y=760, otherwise ,

    and we choose β1=14,β2=12,β1=14 and s=2. The mapping f is triangular α-orbital admissible and satisfies (a2) in Definition 2.1 for any x,y[0,1], respectively for x,y(1,+). Taking into account the definition of the function α, we have more to check the case x=56, y=76. We have

    Rf(56,76)=[14(d(56,f56)d(76,f76)d(56,76))2+12(d(56,76))2+14(d(56,f76)+d(76,f56)4)2]1/2=14+1219+19=13.

    Therefore,

    α(56,76)d(f56,f76)=d(f56,f76)=d(12,16)=13<13=max{d(56,76),Rf(56,76)}.

    Moreover, since the mapping f satisfies condition (a1) for

    δ(E)={1E,forE<11,forE1,

    it follows that the assumptions of Theorem 2.3 are satisfied, and u=12 ia a fixed point of the mapping f.

    Theorem 2.3. If to the hypotheses of Theorem we add the following assumption

    α(u,v)1for anyu,vFf(X),

    then the mapping f admits an unique fixed point.

    Proof. Let uX be a fixed point of f. Supposing on the contrary, that we can find vX such that fu=uv=fv, we have

    (i) For s>0,

    Rsf=[β1(d(u,fu)d(v,fv)d(u,v))s+β2(d(u,v))s+β3(d(u,fv)+d(v,fu)4)s]1/s=[β2(d(u,v))s+β3(d(u,v)2)s]1/s(β2+β3)1/sd(u,v)d(u,v).

    Thus, taking x=u and y=v in (2.3) we get

    d(u,v)α(u,v)d(fu,fv)<max{d(u,v),Rf(u,v)}=d(u,v),

    which is a contradiction.

    (ii) For s=0,

    d(u,v)α(u,v)d(fu,fv)<max{d(u,v),Rf(u,v)}=max{d(u,v),(d(u,fu))β1(d(v,fv))β2(d(u,fv)+d(v,fu)4)β3}=d(u,v),

    which is a contradiction.

    Consequently, if there exists a fixed point of the mapping f, under the assumptions of the theorem, this is unique.

    Example 2.2. Let the set X=[1,+), d:X×X[0,+), d(x,y)=|xy|, and the mapping f:XX, where

    fx={x2+1,ifx[1,0)1,ifx[0,1]1x,ifx>1.

    Let also α:X×X[0,+) defined as follows

    α(x,y)={34,ifx,y[1,0)x2+y2+1,ifx,y[0,1]1,ifx[1,0),y[0,1]0, otherwise .

    It is easy to check that, with these chooses, f is a continuous triangular α-orbital admissible mapping and also, it follows that the mapping f satisfies the conditions (a2) from Definition (2.1). Moreover, f satisfies the condition (a1), considering δ(E)=1E in case of E<1 and δ(E)=1 for E1. Consequently, f satisfies the conditions of Theorem 2.3 and has a unique fixed point, u=0.

    In particular, for the case s=0, the continuity assumption of the mapping f can be replace by the condition (R).

    Theorem 2.4. We presume thatf:(X,d)(X,d)TαX and fulfills

    (ai) for given E>0, there exists δ>0 such that

    E<O(x,y)<E+δimpliesα(x,y)d(fx,fy)E, (2.21)

    with

    O(x,y)=max{d(x,y),(d(x,fx))β1(d(y,fy))β2(d(x,fy)+d(y,fx)4)β3},

    for all x,yX, where βi0, i=1,2,3 so that β1+β2+β3=1;

    (aii)

    α(x,y)d(fx,fy)<O(x,y). (2.22)

    The mapping f has a unique fixed point provided that:

    (α1) there exists x0X such that α(x0,fx0)1;

    (α3) α(u,v)1 for any u,vFf(X);

    (α2) if the sequence {xn} in X is such that for each nN

    α(xn,xn+1)1andlimn+xn=xX,

    then there exists a subsequence {xn(j)} of {xn} such that

    α(xn(j),x)1,for eachjN.

    Proof. Let x0X such that α(x0,fx0)1. Then, we know (following the proof of Theorem 2.3) that the sequence {xn}, with xn=fnx0 is convergent; let u=limn+xn. On the other hand, from (α2), we can find a subsequence {xn(j)} of {xn} such that

    α(xn(j),u)1, for each jN.

    Since we can suppose that d(xn(j)+1,fu)>0, from (aii) we have

    d((xn(j)+1,fu))α(xn(j),u)d(fxn(j),fu)<O(x,y)=max{d(xn(j),u),(d(xn(j),fxn(j)))β1(d(u,fu))β2(d(xn(j),fu)+d(u,fxn(j))4)β3}=max{d(xn(j),u),(d(xn(j),xn(j)+1))β1(d(u,fu))β2(d(xn(j),fu)+d(u,xn(j)+1)4)β3}.

    Letting n+ in the above inequality, we get d(u,fu)=0. Thus, fu=u.

    To proof the uniqueness, we consider that we can find another fixed point of f. From (aii), we have

    d(u,v)=d(fu,fv)α(u,v)d(fu,fv)<O(u,v)=d(u,v)<d(u,v),

    which is a contradiction. Therefore, u=v.

    Considering α(x,y)=1 in the above theorems, we can easily obtain the following result.

    Definition 2.2. A mapping f:(X,d)(X,d) is called hybrid Jaggi-Meir-Keeler type contraction on X if for all distinct x,yX we have:

    (a1) for given E>0, there exists δ>0 such that

    E<max{d(x,y),Rsf(x,y)}<E+δd(fx,fy)E; (2.23)

    (a2) whenever Rf(x,y)>0,

    d(fx,fy)<max{d(x,y),Rsf(x,y)}. (2.24)

    Corollary 2.1. Any hybrid Jaggi-Meir-Keeler type contraction f:(X,d)(X,d) possesses a unique fixed point provided that f is continuous or f2 is continuous.

    The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.



    [1] X. D. Yang, J. N. Zhang, S. Y. Ren, Q. Y. Ran, Can the new energy demonstration city policy reduce environmental pollution? Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in China, J. Clean. Prod., 287 (2021), 125015. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.125015 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.125015
    [2] M. Ellman, F. Germano, What do the papers sell? A model of advertising and media bias, The Economic Journal, 119 (2009), 680–704. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02218.x doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02218.x
    [3] H. T. Wu, Y. W. Li, Y. Hao, S. Y. Ren, P. F. Zhang, Environmental decentralization, local government competition, and regional green development: Evidence from China, Sci. Total Environ., 708 (2020), 135085. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2019.135085 doi: 10.1016/j.scitotenv.2019.135085
    [4] Y. Liu, C. Ma, Z. Huang, Can the digital economy improve green total factor productivity? An empirical study based on Chinese urban data, Math. Biosci. Eng., 20 (2023), 6866–6893. http://doi.org/10.3934/mbe.2023296 doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023296
    [5] L. Katusiime, International monetary spillovers and macroeconomic stability in developing countries, National Accounting Review, 3 (2021), 310–329. http://doi.org/10.3934/NAR.2021016 doi: 10.3934/NAR.2021016
    [6] Y. Liu, L. Chen, L. Lv, P. Failler, The impact of population aging on economic growth: a case study on China, AIMS Mathematics, 8 (2023), 10468–10485. http://doi.org/10.3934/math.2023531 doi: 10.3934/math.2023531
    [7] K. C. Ho, X. X. Shen, C. Yan, X. Hu, Influence of green innovation on disclosure quality: mediating role of media attention, Technol. Forecast. Soc., 188 (2023), 122314. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2022.122314 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2022.122314
    [8] S. Boulianne, J. Ohme, Pathways to environmental activism in four countries: social media, environmental concern, and political efficacy, J. Youth Stud., 25 (2022), 771–792. http://doi.org/10.1080/13676261.2021.2011845 doi: 10.1080/13676261.2021.2011845
    [9] C. C. Lee, M. L. Zeng, C. S. Wang, Environmental regulation, innovation capability, and green total factor productivity: new evidence from China, Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res., 29 (2022), 39384–39399. http://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-021-18388-0 doi: 10.1007/s11356-021-18388-0
    [10] S. Huang, K. T. Huat, Z. Zhou, The studies on Chinese traditional culture and corporate environmental responsibility: literature review and its implications, National Accounting Review, 4 (2022), 1–15. http://doi.org/10.3934/NAR.2022001 doi: 10.3934/NAR.2022001
    [11] J. M. Mazzarino, L. Turatti, S. T. Petter, Environmental governance: media approach on the united nations programme for the environment, Environ. Dev., 33 (2020), 100502. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.envdev.2020.100502 doi: 10.1016/j.envdev.2020.100502
    [12] Z. Li, L. Chen, H. Dong, What are bitcoin market reactions to its-related events?, Int. Rev. Econ. Financ., 73 (2021), 1–10. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2020.12.020 doi: 10.1016/j.iref.2020.12.020
    [13] P. Liu, Y. Zhao, J. Zhu, C. Yang, Technological industry agglomeration, green innovation efficiency, and development quality of city cluster, Green Finance, 4 (2022), 411–435. http://doi.org/10.3934/GF.2022020 doi: 10.3934/GF.2022020
    [14] C. Luo, Z. Li, L. Liu, Does investor sentiment affect stock pricing? Evidence from seasoned equity offerings in China, National Accounting Review, 3 (2021), 115–136. http://doi.org/10.3934/NAR.2021006 doi: 10.3934/NAR.2021006
    [15] M. Akhtaruzzaman, S. Boubaker, Z. Umar, COVID-19 media coverage and ESG leader indices, Financ. Res. Lett., 45 (2022), 102170. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2021.102170 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2021.102170
    [16] G. S. Miller, D. J. Skinner, The evolving disclosure landscape: How changes in technology, the media, and capital markets are affecting disclosure, J. Account. Res., 53 (2015), 221–239. http://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679x.12075 doi: 10.1111/1475-679x.12075
    [17] E. Assifuah-Nunoo, P. O. Junior, A. M. Adam, A. Bossman, Assessing the safe haven properties of oil in African stock markets amid the COVID-19 pandemic: a quantile regression analysis, Quant. Financ. Econ., 6 (2022), 244–269. http://doi.org/10.3934/QFE.2022011 doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022011
    [18] Y. X. Chen, J. Zhang, P. R. Tadikamalla, X. T. Gao, The relationship among government, enterprise, and public in environmental governance from the perspective of multi-player evolutionary game, Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health, 16 (2019), 3351. http://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph16183351 doi: 10.3390/ijerph16183351
    [19] P. C. Tetlock, Giving content to investor sentiment: the role of media in the stock market, J. Financ., 62 (2007), 1139–1168. http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01232.x doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01232.x
    [20] G. X. Zhang, Y. Q. Jia, B. Su, J. Xiu, Environmental regulation, economic development and air pollution in the cities of China: spatial econometric analysis based on policy scoring and satellite data, J. Clean. Prod., 328 (2021), 129496. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.129496 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.129496
    [21] M. Irfan, A. Razzaq, A. Sharif, X. Yang, Influence mechanism between green finance and green innovation: exploring regional policy intervention effects in China, Technol. Forecast. Soc., 182 (2022), 121882. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2022.121882 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2022.121882
    [22] M. Pichlak, A. R. Szromek, Eco-innovation, sustainability and business model innovation by open innovation dynamics, Journal of Open Innovation: Technology, Market, and Complexity, 7 (2021), 149. http://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc7020149 doi: 10.3390/joitmc7020149
    [23] P. A. Nylund, A. Brem, N. Agarwal, Enabling technologies mitigating climate change: the role of dominant designs in environmental innovation ecosystems, Technovation, 117 (2021), 102271. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2021.102271 doi: 10.1016/j.technovation.2021.102271
    [24] Y. Xu, W. F. Ge, G. L. Liu, X. F. Su, J. N. Zhu, C. Y. Yang, et al., The impact of local government competition and green technology innovation on economic low-carbon transition: new insights from China, Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res., 30 (2022), 23714–23735. http://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-022-23857-1 doi: 10.1007/s11356-022-23857-1
    [25] C. Fussler, P. James, Driving eco-innovation: a breakthrough discipline for innovation and sustainability, Financial Times/Prentice Hall, 1996.
    [26] J. Hartmann, Toward a more complete theory of sustainable supply chain management: the role of media attention, Supply Chain Management, 26 (2021), 532–547. http://doi.org/10.1108/scm-01-2020-0043 doi: 10.1108/scm-01-2020-0043
    [27] Z. H. Li, Z. M. Huang, Y. Y. Su, New media environment, environmental regulation and corporate green technology innovation: Evidence from China, Energ. Econ., 119 (2023), 106545. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2023.106545 doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2023.106545
    [28] E. R. Gray, J. M. T. Balmer, Managing corporate image and corporate reputation, Long Range Plann., 31 (1998), 695–702. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0024-6301(98)00074-0 doi: 10.1016/S0024-6301(98)00074-0
    [29] E. Blankespoor, E. deHaan, C. Zhu, Capital market effects of media synthesis and dissemination: evidence from robo-journalism, Rev. Account. Stud., 23 (2018), 1–36. http://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-017-9422-2 doi: 10.1007/s11142-017-9422-2
    [30] X. F. Jiang, C. X. Zhao, J. J. Ma, J. Q. Liu, S. H. Li, Is enterprise environmental protection investment responsibility or rent-seeking? Chinese evidence, Environ. Dev. Econ., 26 (2021), 169–187. http://doi.org/10.1017/s1355770x20000327 doi: 10.1017/s1355770x20000327
    [31] I. S. Farouq, N. U. Sambo, A. U. Ahmad, A. H. Jakada, I. A. Danmaraya, Does financial globalization uncertainty affect CO2 emissions? Empirical evidence from some selected SSA countries, Quant. Financ. Econ., 5 (2021), 247–263. http://doi.org/10.3934/QFE.2021011 doi: 10.3934/QFE.2021011
    [32] T. C. Chiang, Geopolitical risk, economic policy uncertainty and asset returns in Chinese financial markets, China Financ. Rev. Int., 11 (2021), 474–501. http://doi.org/10.1108/CFRI-08-2020-0115 doi: 10.1108/CFRI-08-2020-0115
    [33] J. L. Guan, H. J. Xu, D. Huo, Y. C. Hua, Y. F. Wang, Economic policy uncertainty and corporate innovation: Evidence from China, Pac.-Basin Financ. J., 67 (2021), 101542. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.pacfin.2021.101542 doi: 10.1016/j.pacfin.2021.101542
    [34] Y. Liu, J. Liu, L. Zhang, Enterprise financialization and R & D innovation: a case study of listed companies in China, Electron. Res. Arch., 31 (2023), 2447–2471. http://doi.org/10.3934/era.2023124 doi: 10.3934/era.2023124
    [35] T. C. Chiang, Can gold or silver be used as a hedge against policy uncertainty and COVID-19 in the Chinese market?, China Financ. Rev. Int., 12 (2022), 571–600. http://doi.org/10.1108/CFRI-12-2021-0232 doi: 10.1108/CFRI-12-2021-0232
    [36] L. H. Yin, C. Q. Wu, Promotion incentives and air pollution: from the political promotion tournament to the environment tournament, J. Environ. Manage., 317 (2022), 115491. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2022.115491 doi: 10.1016/j.jenvman.2022.115491
    [37] X. Yang, H. Wu, S. Ren, Q. Ran, J. Zhang, Does the development of the internet contribute to air pollution control in China? Mechanism discussion and empirical test, Struct. Change Econ. Dyn., 56 (2021), 207–224. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.strueco.2020.12.001 doi: 10.1016/j.strueco.2020.12.001
    [38] S. Y. Ren, Y. Hao, H. T. Wu, How does green investment affect environmental pollution? Evidence from China, Environ. Resource Econ., 81 (2022), 25–51. http://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-021-00615-4 doi: 10.1007/s10640-021-00615-4
    [39] Y. Li, X. D. Yang, Q. Y. Ran, H. T. Wu, M. Irfan, M. Ahmad, Energy structure, digital economy, and carbon emissions: evidence from China, Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res., 28 (2021), 64606–64629. http://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-021-15304-4 doi: 10.1007/s11356-021-15304-4
    [40] A. Biscione, R. Caruso, A. de Felice, Environmental innovation in European transition countries, Appl. Econ., 53 (2021), 521–535. http://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2020.1808185 doi: 10.1080/00036846.2020.1808185
    [41] S. C. Zyglidopoulos, A. P. Georgiadis, C. E. Carroll, D. S. Siegel, Does media attention drive corporate social responsibility?, J. Bus. Res., 65 (2012), 1622–1627. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2011.10.021 doi: 10.1016/j.jbusres.2011.10.021
    [42] C. H. Yu, X. Wu, D. Zhang, S. Chen, J. Zhao, Demand for green finance: resolving financing constraints on green innovation in China, Energ. Policy, 153 (2021), 112255. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2021.112255 doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2021.112255
    [43] J. von Bloh, T. Broekel, B. Özgun, R. Sternberg, New(s) data for entrepreneurship research? An innovative approach to use Big Data on media coverage, Small Bus. Econ., 55 (2020), 673–694. http://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00209-x doi: 10.1007/s11187-019-00209-x
    [44] G. B. Xiong, Y. D. Luo, Smog, media attention, and corporate social responsibility-empirical evidence from Chinese polluting listed companies, Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res., 28 (2021), 46116–46129. http://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-020-11978-4 doi: 10.1007/s11356-020-11978-4
    [45] S. R. Baker, N. Bloom, S. J. Davis, Measuring economic policy uncertainty, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131 (2016), 1593–1636. http://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjw024 doi: 10.1093/qje/qjw024
    [46] H. T. Wu, L. N. Xu, S. Y. Ren, Y. Hao, G. Y. Yan, How do energy consumption and environmental regulation affect carbon emissions in China? New evidence from a dynamic threshold panel model, Resour. Policy, 67 (2020), 101678. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2020.101678 doi: 10.1016/j.resourpol.2020.101678
    [47] T. Li, X. Li, G. Liao, Business cycles and energy intensity. Evidence from emerging economies, Borsa Istanb. Rev., 22 (2022), 560–570. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.bir.2021.07.005 doi: 10.1016/j.bir.2021.07.005
    [48] C. J. Hadlock, J. R. Pierce, New evidence on measuring financial constraints: moving beyond the KZ index, Rev. Financ. Stud., 23 (2010), 1909–1940. http://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhq009 doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhq009
    [49] Z. X. He, C. S. Cao, C. Feng, Media attention, environmental information disclosure and corporate green technology innovations in China's heavily polluting industries, Emerg. Mark. Financ. Tr., 58 (2022), 3939–3952. http://doi.org/10.1080/1540496x.2022.2075259 doi: 10.1080/1540496x.2022.2075259
    [50] M. A. Khan, X. Z. Qin, K. Jebran, A. Rashid, The sensitivity of firms' investment to uncertainty and cash flow: evidence from listed state-owned enterprises and non-state-owned enterprises in China, Sage Open, 10 (2020), 17. http://doi.org/10.1177/2158244020903433 doi: 10.1177/2158244020903433
    [51] X. Chang, Impact of risks on forced CEO turnover, Quant. Financ. Econ., 6 (2022), 177–205. http://doi.org/10.3934/QFE.2022008 doi: 10.3934/QFE.2022008
    [52] Y. Yao, D. Hu, C. Yang, Y. Tan, The impact and mechanism of fintech on green total factor productivity, Green Finance, 3 (2021), 198–221. http://doi.org/10.3934/gf.2021011 doi: 10.3934/gf.2021011
    [53] Z. Y. Li, M. Tuerxun, J. H. Cao, M. Fan, C. Y. Yang, Does inclusive finance improve income: a study in rural areas, AIMS Mathematics, 7 (2022), 20909–20929. http://doi.org/10.3934/math.20221146 doi: 10.3934/math.20221146
    [54] Z. Li, C. Yang, Z. Huang, How does the fintech sector react to signals from central bank digital currencies?, Financ. Res. Lett., 50 (2022), 103308. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2022.103308 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2022.103308
    [55] S. El Ghoul, O. Guedhami, R. Nash, A. Patel, New evidence on the role of the media in corporate social responsibility, J. Bus. Ethics, 154 (2019), 1051–1079. http://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-016-3354-9 doi: 10.1007/s10551-016-3354-9
    [56] T. Vanacker, D. P. Forbes, M. Knockaert, S. Manigart, Signal strength, media attention, and resource mobilization: evidence from new private equity firms, Acad. Manage. J., 63 (2020), 1082–1105. http://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2018.0356 doi: 10.5465/amj.2018.0356
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Sana Hadj Amor, Ameni Remadi, Self similarity sets via fixed point theory with lack of convexity, 2023, 37, 0354-5180, 10055, 10.2298/FIL2329055A
    2. Vo Tri, Continuous dependence on parameters of differential inclusion using new techniques of fixed point theory, 2023, 37, 0354-5180, 5469, 10.2298/FIL2316469T
    3. Mohammed Shehu Shagari, Manzuma Mustapha, Hala H. Taha, Sarah Aljohani, Nabil Mlaiki, On Combinational Contractions with Applications, 2025, 24058440, e41905, 10.1016/j.heliyon.2025.e41905
    4. Mohammed Shehu Shagari, Faryad Ali, Monairah Alansari, Akbar Azam, New views on RLC-electric circuit models via combinational contractions, 2025, 2025, 1687-2770, 10.1186/s13661-025-02068-w
    5. Sirajo Yahaya, Mohammed Shagari, Ibrahim Fulatan, Fixed points of bilateral multivalued contractions, 2024, 38, 0354-5180, 2835, 10.2298/FIL2408835Y
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2023 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(5508) PDF downloads(152) Cited by(15)

Figures and Tables

Figures(5)  /  Tables(8)

Other Articles By Authors

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog