The paper addresses a trade-off between the degree of fiscal dominance and fiscal and monetary sustainability conditions. The research aims at finding growth incentives in the complex fiscal-monetary environment. By testing the actual data, the study introduces the empirical specification of the non-linear relationship between the dynamics of broad money and public debt, which allows for interpolating the fiscal space. The study develops a Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model for a small open developing economy that, in addition to several rigidities, such as deep habit formation, staggered pricing and wage stickiness, also incorporates the extended fiscal and monetary policy blocks, a composite lifetime utility-generating function, a low level of public investment efficiency and a negative relationship between the interest rate premium and foreign prices fluctuation. Employing the developed DSGE framework made it possible to outline a promising growth path in the policy trade-off between the degree of fiscal dominance and the persistence of sustainability conditions. The modeling results revealed that short-term growth outweighs the crowding-out effect and that excessive macroeconomic volatility, especially price and debt dynamics, is well-curbed. The calculation of elasticity functions allowed for calibrating the interrelationship between the maximum growth rate of output, the degree of fiscal dominance and the persistence of fiscal and monetary sustainability conditions. The study highlights two key messages. The public debt ratio is not the final indicator to determine fiscal sustainability conditions. The degree of dominance, not the ratio of public debt to output, matters most that fiscal and monetary authorities should consider in pursuing growth incentive policy.
Citation: Serhii Shvets. Dominance score in the fiscal-monetary interaction[J]. National Accounting Review, 2023, 5(2): 186-207. doi: 10.3934/NAR.2023012
[1] | Changgui Gu, Ping Wang, Tongfeng Weng, Huijie Yang, Jos Rohling . Heterogeneity of neuronal properties determines the collective behavior of the neurons in the suprachiasmatic nucleus. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(4): 1893-1913. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019092 |
[2] | Miguel Lara-Aparicio, Carolina Barriga-Montoya, Pablo Padilla-Longoria, Beatriz Fuentes-Pardo . Modeling some properties of circadian rhythms. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2014, 11(2): 317-330. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2014.11.317 |
[3] | Ying Li, Zhao Zhao, Yuan-yuan Tan, Xue Wang . Dynamical analysis of the effects of circadian clock on the neurotransmitter dopamine. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(9): 16663-16677. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023742 |
[4] | Yanqin Wang, Xin Ni, Jie Yan, Ling Yang . Modeling transcriptional co-regulation of mammalian circadian clock. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2017, 14(5&6): 1447-1462. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2017075 |
[5] | Zhenzhen Shi, Huidong Cheng, Yu Liu, Yanhui Wang . Optimization of an integrated feedback control for a pest management predator-prey model. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(6): 7963-7981. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019401 |
[6] | Ya'nan Wang, Sen Liu, Haijun Jia, Xintao Deng, Chunpu Li, Aiguo Wang, Cuiwei Yang . A two-step method for paroxysmal atrial fibrillation event detection based on machine learning. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(10): 9877-9894. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022460 |
[7] | E.V. Presnov, Z. Agur . The Role Of Time Delays, Slow Processes And Chaos In Modulating The Cell-Cycle Clock. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2005, 2(3): 625-642. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2005.2.625 |
[8] | Jun Zhou . Bifurcation analysis of a diffusive plant-wrack model with tide effect on the wrack. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2016, 13(4): 857-885. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2016021 |
[9] | Hussein Obeid, Alan D. Rendall . The minimal model of Hahn for the Calvin cycle. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2019, 16(4): 2353-2370. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2019118 |
[10] | Ryotaro Tsuneki, Shinji Doi, Junko Inoue . Generation of slow phase-locked oscillation and variability of the interspike intervals in globally coupled neuronal oscillators. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2014, 11(1): 125-138. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2014.11.125 |
The paper addresses a trade-off between the degree of fiscal dominance and fiscal and monetary sustainability conditions. The research aims at finding growth incentives in the complex fiscal-monetary environment. By testing the actual data, the study introduces the empirical specification of the non-linear relationship between the dynamics of broad money and public debt, which allows for interpolating the fiscal space. The study develops a Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model for a small open developing economy that, in addition to several rigidities, such as deep habit formation, staggered pricing and wage stickiness, also incorporates the extended fiscal and monetary policy blocks, a composite lifetime utility-generating function, a low level of public investment efficiency and a negative relationship between the interest rate premium and foreign prices fluctuation. Employing the developed DSGE framework made it possible to outline a promising growth path in the policy trade-off between the degree of fiscal dominance and the persistence of sustainability conditions. The modeling results revealed that short-term growth outweighs the crowding-out effect and that excessive macroeconomic volatility, especially price and debt dynamics, is well-curbed. The calculation of elasticity functions allowed for calibrating the interrelationship between the maximum growth rate of output, the degree of fiscal dominance and the persistence of fiscal and monetary sustainability conditions. The study highlights two key messages. The public debt ratio is not the final indicator to determine fiscal sustainability conditions. The degree of dominance, not the ratio of public debt to output, matters most that fiscal and monetary authorities should consider in pursuing growth incentive policy.
Wide-type fruit flies, Drosophila melanogaster, might be the most extensively studied organism in circadian rhythm research. The researches of endogenous activity rhythm on Drosophila generally involve two different kinds of clock genes, called period (per, for short) [14,10] and timeless (tim, for short) [20,27]. Their encoded proteins, PER and TIM, bind to each other [5,0,27,29].
PER protein and per mRNA cycle in a
An alternative way to study circadian rhythms is based on a positive feedback, introduced by PER phosphorylation being an activator to PER [26]. Phosphorylation of PER is operated by a double-time gene encoded kinase, DOUBLE-TIME (DBT, for short) [13,16]. As suggested by the dbt mutants phenotypes, PER phosphorylation might be precluded to its degradation. PER and TIM stimulate transcription of per and tim genes by activating dClOCK [2]. Experimental results suggest that per mRNA is stabilized by PER/TIM dimers [24], and PER is stabilized by dimerization with TIM [13,16].
The idea that PER phosphorylation introduces a positive feedback in PER accumulation can be expressed in a model of three-dimensional ordinary differential equations [26] (see (1) below). In [26], by imposing assumptions that the dimerization reactions were fast and dimeric proteins were in rapid equilibrium, they reduced the three-dimensional model to a pair of nonlinear ordinary differential equations of mRNA and total protein concentrations (see (2) below). Then they used the powerful phase plane portraiture to study the simplified two-dimensional model. In this paper, we explore the original three-dimensional model directly. It is shown that the circadian rhythms occur if the model possesses a unique equilibrium which is unstable. Furthermore, we deeply investigate how circadian rhythms are affected by several model parameters, including mRNA translation, mRNA degradation, monomer phosphorylation, protein proteolysis, association of PER/TIM protein and equilibrium constant for dimerization. The results help to explain some former-observed phenomena of circadian rhythms. In particular, our numerical results extremely agree with those given in [26], indicating that their reduction work is greatly reasonable.
In this section, we restate the model proposed by Tyson et al. [26]. The molecular mechanism for the circadian rhythm in Drosophila is summarized in Figure 1. Here the total PER (monomer
The mechanism in Figure 1 could be translated into a set of six differential equations, for per and tim mRNAs, PER and TIM monomers, and PER/TIM dimers in the cytoplasm and nucleus. Such a complicated set of equations could not efficiently illustrate the importance of positive feedback in the reaction mechanism. So by noticing that PER and TIM messages and proteins followed roughly similar time courses in vivo, Tyson et al. [26] lumped them into a single pool of clock proteins. In addition, they assumed that the cytoplasmic and nuclear pools of dimeric protein were in rapid equilibrium. Then they established the following differential equations for [mRNA]=
{dMdt=vm1+(P2/Pcrit)2−kmM,dP1dt=vpM−k′p1P1JP+P1+rP2−kp3P1−2kaP21+2kdP2,dP2dt=kaP21−kdP2−kp2P2JP+P1+rP2−kp3P2. | (1) |
Here monomer was assumed to be phosphorylated more quickly than dimer, i.e.,
In their work, it was further assumed that the dimerization reactions were fast (
{dMdt=vm1+(Pt(1−q)/(2Pcrit))2−kmM,dPtdt=vpM−kp1Ptq+kp2PtJP+Pt−kp3Pt, | (2) |
where
q=q(Pt)=21+√1+8KeqPt. |
Two widely concerned points of circadian rhythms are whether the endogenous rhythms exist and how long the periods are. Since the mechanism has already been translated into mathematical models, attentions are drawn to examine the existence of periodic orbits and calculate the periods. In their work, system (2) has been thoroughly analyzed. In this paper, we try to study system (1). A typical oscillating solution of system (1) is illustrated in Figure 2, where the corresponding parameter values are chosen from Table 1.
Name | Value | Units | | Description |
1 | | 6 | Maximum rate of synthesis of mRNA | |
| 0.1 | | 4 | First-order rate constant for mRNA degradation |
| 0.5 | | 6 | Rate constant for translation of mRNA |
| 10 | | 6 | |
| 0.03 | | 6 | |
| 0.1 | | 6 | First-order rate constant for proteolysis |
| 200 | | -12 | Equilibrium constant for dimerization |
| 0.1 | | 6 | Dimer concen at the half-maximum transcription rate |
| 0.05 | | -16 | Michaelis constant for protein kinase (DBT) |
This table is adapted from Tyson et al. [26]. Parameters |
It is well-known that for higher dimensional ordinary differential equations, there is no so-called Poincaré-Bendixson theory: any limit set is a limit cycle if it contains no steady state. So, in order to use the powerful phase plane analysis tools, Tyson et al. [26] reduced (1) into (2) by imposing some assumptions. Fortunately, we observe that (1) is a three-dimensional competitive system in some sense [8,0,22,23]. For
Theorem 3.1. Suppose (1) has a unique steady state
Numerical calculation suggests that (1) has a unique equilibrium in a large region of parameter values. However, limit cycles do not exist all the time. According to Theorem 3.1, when either
Equilibrium1 | Eigenvalues | ||
| | | |
| | ||
| |||
| | ||
| | ||
| | | |
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | | |
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
1 Those zeros in equilibrium terms are actually very small positive numbers. Other parameter values are as given in Table 1. |
Comparing with the two-dimensional system (2), there are two more parameters
0.001 | 0.1 | 0.8 | 0.9 | 1 | 10 | 100 | |
Period | none | none | none | 72.44 | 63.10 | 50.89 | 32.51 |
| 500 | 1000 | 5000 | ||||
Period | 28.61 | 26.90 | 24.86 | 24.54 | 24.27 | 24.24 | 24.21 |
| |||||||
Period | 24.21 | 24.21 | 24.21 | 24.30 | 24.44 | ||
Periodic oscillations happen when |
| 0.001 | 0.1 | 1.1 | 1.2 | 2 | 10 | 100 | 500 |
Period | none | none | none | 57.19 | 55.67 | 41.34 | 30.98 | 29.21 |
1000 | 2000 | 5000 | ||||||
Period | 28.94 | 28.80 | 28.71 | 28.67 | 28.65 | 28.65 | 29.20 | 30.37 |
Periodic oscillations occur when |
Based on Tables 3 and 4, one can choose a suitable value of
Genotype | | Temp | Period | Genotype | | | Period |
Wild type | 245 | 20 | 24.2 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 |
200 | 25 | 24.2 | | 15 | 0.06 | 24.3 | |
164 | 30 | 24.2 | | 20 | 0.09 | 25.7 | |
| 18.4 | 20 | 26.5 | | 10 | 0.3 | 17.6 |
15.0 | 25 | 28.7 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 | |
12.3 | 30 | 30.4 | | 10 | 0.003 | 25.1 | |
To simplify the integration, we take |
Table 5 is due to the original three-dimensional system (1). As a comparison, we state Table 6, which is cited from [26] and based on the reduced two-dimensional system (2). Clearly, one can see that Table 5 and Table 6 are almost the same, which indicates that the reduction in [26] is greatly reasonable from this perspective.
Genotype | | Temp | Period | Genotype | | | Period |
Wild type | 245 | 20 | 24.2 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 |
200 | 25 | 24.2 | | 15 | 0.06 | 24.4 | |
164 | 30 | 24.2 | | 20 | 0.09 | 25.7 | |
| 18.4 | 20 | 26.5 | | 10 | 0.3 | 17.6 |
15.0 | 25 | 28.7 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 | |
12.3 | 30 | 30.5 | | 10 | 0.003 | 25.2 | |
This table is copied out of Tyson et al. [26]. It is assumed that each parameter |
In the next section, we will see more about the relation between circadian rhythms and parameters of (1).
In the actual experiment, parameters of the circadian rhythms models are hard to be measured, or even unmeasurable. Parameter values in Table 1 have been chosen to yield a period close to 24-hours and ensure temperature compensation of the wild-type oscillator. The parameter values are arbitrary. Other combinations of parameter values may also yield circadian oscillations with possibly different periods.
It is significant to study how parameters of (1) affect its periodic oscillations. The numerical results are given in Figure 3, where the following parameters are considered: mRNA translation, mRNA degradation, monomer phosphorylation, protein proteolysis, association of PER/TIM protein and equilibrium constant for dimerization.
As shown in Figure 3A, periodic oscillation disappears when the protein synthesis rate
The PER/TIM complex formation plays a key role in the model. Circadian rhythm is markedly affected by the dimerization reaction, precisely in the model, by the association rate constant
In Figure 3B we show how the oscillation is affected by mRNA synthesis. Periodic rhythm requires the mRNA synthesis rate
According to Theorem 3.1, in Figure 4 we inspect the dependence of oscillations on parameters
Appendix. The concentrations of mRNA, monomers and dimers are naturally nonnegative. We therefore focus on the first orthant
Let
{f1(a,P1,P2)=vm1+(P2/Pcrit)2−kma<vm−kma<0,f2(M,b,P2)=vpM−k′p1bJP+b+rP2−kp3b−2kab2+2kdP2<vpa−kp3b<0,f3(M,P1,c)=kaP21−kdc−kp2cJP+P1+rc−kp3c<−kp2cJP+P1+rc−kp3c<0. |
The vector field for (1) on the boundary of
Proposition 1. For any
From Proposition 1, there are at least one steady state in
By computing the Jacobian matrix of (1), one has
Df=(−0−+−+0+−), |
where ''
Theorem A. Suppose (1) has a unique steady state
Therefore, in order to study the oscillations for (1), one only needs to discuss its steady state and the local stability of the steady state.
[1] |
Agenor PR (2016) Optimal fiscal management of commodity price shocks. J Dev Econ 122: 183–196. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2016.05.005 doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2016.05.005
![]() |
[2] |
Albonico A, Ascari G, Gobbi A (2021) The public debt multiplier. J Econ Dyn Control 132: 104204. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2021.104204 doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2021.104204
![]() |
[3] |
Augustine B, Rafi OM (2023) Public debt - economic growth nexus in emerging and developing economies: Exploring nonlinearity. Financ Res Lett 52: 103540. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2022.103540 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2022.103540
![]() |
[4] |
Bischi GI, Giombini G, Travaglini G (2022) Monetary and fiscal policy in a nonlinear model of public debt. Econ Anal Policy 76: 397–409. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2022.08.020 doi: 10.1016/j.eap.2022.08.020
![]() |
[5] |
Blanchard O, Leandro A, Zettelmeyer J (2021) Redesigning EU fiscal rules: from rules to standards. Econ Policy 36: 195–236. https://doi.org/10.1093/epolic/eiab003 doi: 10.1093/epolic/eiab003
![]() |
[6] |
"Brad" Crayne RB, Williams X, Neupane RC (2021) The M2 money supply, the economy, and the national debt: A mathematical approach. Appl Math 12: 835–865. https://doi.org/10.4236/am.2021.129056 doi: 10.4236/am.2021.129056
![]() |
[7] |
Cavalcanti MA, Vereda L, Doctors RDB, et al. (2018) The macroeconomic effects of monetary policy shocks under fiscal rules constrained by public debt sustainability. Econ Model 71: 184–201. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2017.12.010 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2017.12.010
![]() |
[8] | Cheng H, Pitterle I (2018) Towards a more comprehensive assessment of fiscal space. DESA Working Paper 153. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3106767 |
[9] |
Christiano L, Eichenbaum M, Rebelo S (2011) When is the government spending multiplier large?. J Polit Econ 119: 78–121. https://doi.org/10.1086/659312 doi: 10.1086/659312
![]() |
[10] |
Corneo G, Blanchard O (2023) Fiscal policy under low interest rates. J Econ 139: 89–91. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-023-00823-0 doi: 10.1007/s00712-023-00823-0
![]() |
[11] |
Corsetti G, Dedola L, Jarociński M, et al. (2019) Macroeconomic stabilization, monetary-fiscal interactions, and Europe's monetary union. Eur J Polit Econ 57: 22‑33. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2018.07.001 doi: 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2018.07.001
![]() |
[12] |
Davig T, Leeper EM (2011) Monetary–fiscal policy interactions and fiscal stimulus. Eur Econ Rev 55: 211–227. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2010.04.004 doi: 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2010.04.004
![]() |
[13] |
Drechsel T, Tenreyro S (2018) Commodity booms and busts in emerging economies. J Int Econ 112: 200–218. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2017.12.009 doi: 10.1016/j.jinteco.2017.12.009
![]() |
[14] |
Dufrénot G, Jawadi F, Khayat GA (2018) A model of fiscal dominance under the "Reinhart Conjecture". J Econ Dyn Control 93: 332–345. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2018.01.046 doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2018.01.046
![]() |
[15] | Ferrer J, Kireyev A (2022) Policy space index: short-term response to a catastrophic event. IMF Working Paper 123. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3106767 |
[16] |
Filiani P (2021) Optimal monetary–fiscal policy in the euro area liquidity crisis. J Macroecon 70: 103364. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2021.103364 doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2021.103364
![]() |
[17] |
Galí J (2020) The effects of a money-financed fiscal stimulus. J Monet Econ 115: 1–19. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2019.08.002 doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2019.08.002
![]() |
[18] |
Gali J, Lopez-Salido J, Valles J (2004) Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. ECB Working Paper 339. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.532982 doi: 10.2139/ssrn.532982
![]() |
[19] |
Di Giorgio G, Traficante G (2018) Fiscal shocks and helicopter money in open economy. Econ Model 74: 77–87. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2018.05.005 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2018.05.005
![]() |
[20] |
Gómez-Puig M, Sosvilla-Rivero S, Martínez-Zarzoso I (2022) On the heterogeneous link between public debt and economic growth. J Int Financ Mark I 77: 101528. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intfin.2022.101528 doi: 10.1016/j.intfin.2022.101528
![]() |
[21] | Iiboshi H, Iwata Y (2023) The nexus between public debt and the government spending multiplier: fiscal adjustments matter. Available from: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/116355/1/MPRA_paper_116355.pdf. |
[22] | IMF (2018) Assessing fiscal space: An update and stocktaking. Available from: https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/Policy-Papers/Issues/2018/06/15/pp041118assessing-fiscal-space. |
[23] |
Kumhof M, Nunes R, Yakadina I (2010) Simple monetary rules under fiscal dominance. J Money Credit Bank 42: 63–92. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1538-4616.2009.00278.x doi: 10.1111/j.1538-4616.2009.00278.x
![]() |
[24] |
Kwon G, McFarlane L, Robinson W (2009) Public debt, money supply, and inflation: A cross-country study. IMF Staff Papers 56: 476–515. https://doi.org/10.1057/imfsp.2008.26 doi: 10.1057/imfsp.2008.26
![]() |
[25] |
Leeper E, Traum N, Walker T (2017) Clearing up the fiscal multiplier morass. Am Econ Rev 107: 2409–2454. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20111196 doi: 10.1257/aer.20111196
![]() |
[26] |
Leeper EM (1991) Equilibria under 'active' and 'passive' monetary and fiscal policies. J Monet Econ 27: 129–147. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(91)90007-B doi: 10.1016/0304-3932(91)90007-B
![]() |
[27] |
Leeper EM, Zhou X (2021) Inflation's role in optimal monetary-fiscal policy. J Monet Econ 124: 1–18. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2021.10.006 doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2021.10.006
![]() |
[28] |
Ma Y, Lv L (2022) Money, debt, and the effects of fiscal stimulus. Econ Anal Policy 73: 152–178. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2021.11.005 doi: 10.1016/j.eap.2021.11.005
![]() |
[29] |
Panizza U, Presbitero AF (2013) Public debt and economic growth in advanced economies: A survey. Swiss J Econ Stat 149: 175–204. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF03399388 doi: 10.1007/BF03399388
![]() |
[30] |
Philippopoulos A, Varthalitis P, Vassilatos V (2015) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy action in a closed economy. Econ Model 48: 175–188. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2014.10.045 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2014.10.045
![]() |
[31] | Sargent TJ, Wallace N (1981) Some unpleasant monetary arithmetic. Quarterly Review (Fall), 1–17. Available from: file: ///C: /Users/zhuan/Downloads/qr531.pdf. |
[32] | Turnovsky S (2004) The transitional dynamics of fiscal policy: long-run capital accumulation and growth. J Money Credit Bank 36: 883–910. |
[33] |
Woodford M, Xie Y (2022) Fiscal and monetary stabilization policy at the zero lower bound: Consequences of limited foresight. J Monet Econ 125: 18–35. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2021.11.003 doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2021.11.003
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
1. | Shuang Chen, Jinqiao Duan, Ji Li, Dynamics of the Tyson–Hong–Thron–Novak circadian oscillator model, 2021, 420, 01672789, 132869, 10.1016/j.physd.2021.132869 | |
2. | Alessio Franci, Marco Arieli Herrera-Valdez, Miguel Lara-Aparicio, Pablo Padilla-Longoria, Synchronization, Oscillator Death, and Frequency Modulation in a Class of Biologically Inspired Coupled Oscillators, 2018, 4, 2297-4687, 10.3389/fams.2018.00051 |
Name | Value | Units | | Description |
1 | | 6 | Maximum rate of synthesis of mRNA | |
| 0.1 | | 4 | First-order rate constant for mRNA degradation |
| 0.5 | | 6 | Rate constant for translation of mRNA |
| 10 | | 6 | |
| 0.03 | | 6 | |
| 0.1 | | 6 | First-order rate constant for proteolysis |
| 200 | | -12 | Equilibrium constant for dimerization |
| 0.1 | | 6 | Dimer concen at the half-maximum transcription rate |
| 0.05 | | -16 | Michaelis constant for protein kinase (DBT) |
This table is adapted from Tyson et al. [26]. Parameters |
Equilibrium1 | Eigenvalues | ||
| | | |
| | ||
| |||
| | ||
| | ||
| | | |
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | | |
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
1 Those zeros in equilibrium terms are actually very small positive numbers. Other parameter values are as given in Table 1. |
0.001 | 0.1 | 0.8 | 0.9 | 1 | 10 | 100 | |
Period | none | none | none | 72.44 | 63.10 | 50.89 | 32.51 |
| 500 | 1000 | 5000 | ||||
Period | 28.61 | 26.90 | 24.86 | 24.54 | 24.27 | 24.24 | 24.21 |
| |||||||
Period | 24.21 | 24.21 | 24.21 | 24.30 | 24.44 | ||
Periodic oscillations happen when |
| 0.001 | 0.1 | 1.1 | 1.2 | 2 | 10 | 100 | 500 |
Period | none | none | none | 57.19 | 55.67 | 41.34 | 30.98 | 29.21 |
1000 | 2000 | 5000 | ||||||
Period | 28.94 | 28.80 | 28.71 | 28.67 | 28.65 | 28.65 | 29.20 | 30.37 |
Periodic oscillations occur when |
Genotype | | Temp | Period | Genotype | | | Period |
Wild type | 245 | 20 | 24.2 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 |
200 | 25 | 24.2 | | 15 | 0.06 | 24.3 | |
164 | 30 | 24.2 | | 20 | 0.09 | 25.7 | |
| 18.4 | 20 | 26.5 | | 10 | 0.3 | 17.6 |
15.0 | 25 | 28.7 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 | |
12.3 | 30 | 30.4 | | 10 | 0.003 | 25.1 | |
To simplify the integration, we take |
Genotype | | Temp | Period | Genotype | | | Period |
Wild type | 245 | 20 | 24.2 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 |
200 | 25 | 24.2 | | 15 | 0.06 | 24.4 | |
164 | 30 | 24.2 | | 20 | 0.09 | 25.7 | |
| 18.4 | 20 | 26.5 | | 10 | 0.3 | 17.6 |
15.0 | 25 | 28.7 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 | |
12.3 | 30 | 30.5 | | 10 | 0.003 | 25.2 | |
This table is copied out of Tyson et al. [26]. It is assumed that each parameter |
Name | Value | Units | | Description |
1 | | 6 | Maximum rate of synthesis of mRNA | |
| 0.1 | | 4 | First-order rate constant for mRNA degradation |
| 0.5 | | 6 | Rate constant for translation of mRNA |
| 10 | | 6 | |
| 0.03 | | 6 | |
| 0.1 | | 6 | First-order rate constant for proteolysis |
| 200 | | -12 | Equilibrium constant for dimerization |
| 0.1 | | 6 | Dimer concen at the half-maximum transcription rate |
| 0.05 | | -16 | Michaelis constant for protein kinase (DBT) |
This table is adapted from Tyson et al. [26]. Parameters |
Equilibrium1 | Eigenvalues | ||
| | | |
| | ||
| |||
| | ||
| | ||
| | | |
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | | |
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
| | ||
1 Those zeros in equilibrium terms are actually very small positive numbers. Other parameter values are as given in Table 1. |
0.001 | 0.1 | 0.8 | 0.9 | 1 | 10 | 100 | |
Period | none | none | none | 72.44 | 63.10 | 50.89 | 32.51 |
| 500 | 1000 | 5000 | ||||
Period | 28.61 | 26.90 | 24.86 | 24.54 | 24.27 | 24.24 | 24.21 |
| |||||||
Period | 24.21 | 24.21 | 24.21 | 24.30 | 24.44 | ||
Periodic oscillations happen when |
| 0.001 | 0.1 | 1.1 | 1.2 | 2 | 10 | 100 | 500 |
Period | none | none | none | 57.19 | 55.67 | 41.34 | 30.98 | 29.21 |
1000 | 2000 | 5000 | ||||||
Period | 28.94 | 28.80 | 28.71 | 28.67 | 28.65 | 28.65 | 29.20 | 30.37 |
Periodic oscillations occur when |
Genotype | | Temp | Period | Genotype | | | Period |
Wild type | 245 | 20 | 24.2 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 |
200 | 25 | 24.2 | | 15 | 0.06 | 24.3 | |
164 | 30 | 24.2 | | 20 | 0.09 | 25.7 | |
| 18.4 | 20 | 26.5 | | 10 | 0.3 | 17.6 |
15.0 | 25 | 28.7 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 | |
12.3 | 30 | 30.4 | | 10 | 0.003 | 25.1 | |
To simplify the integration, we take |
Genotype | | Temp | Period | Genotype | | | Period |
Wild type | 245 | 20 | 24.2 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 |
200 | 25 | 24.2 | | 15 | 0.06 | 24.4 | |
164 | 30 | 24.2 | | 20 | 0.09 | 25.7 | |
| 18.4 | 20 | 26.5 | | 10 | 0.3 | 17.6 |
15.0 | 25 | 28.7 | | 10 | 0.03 | 24.2 | |
12.3 | 30 | 30.5 | | 10 | 0.003 | 25.2 | |
This table is copied out of Tyson et al. [26]. It is assumed that each parameter |