Loading [MathJax]/jax/output/SVG/jax.js
Research article

Network, correlation, and community structure of the financial sector of Bursa Malaysia before, during, and after COVID-19

  • COVID-19 triggered a worldwide economic decline and raised concerns regarding its economic consequences on stock markets across the globe, notably on the Malaysian stock market. We examined how COVID-19 impacted Malaysia's financial market using correlation and network analysis. We found a rise in correlations between stocks during the pandemic, suggesting greater interdependence. To visualize this, we created networks for pre-pandemic, during-pandemic, and post-pandemic periods. Additionally, we built a network for the during-pandemic period with a specific threshold corresponding to pre- and post-pandemic network density. The networks during the pandemic showed increased connectivity and only contained positive correlations, reflecting synchronized stock movements. Last, we analyzed the networks' modularity, revealing highest modularity during the pandemic, which suggests stronger yet risk-prone communities.

    Citation: Nurun Najwa Bahari, Hafizah Bahaludin, Munira Ismail, Fatimah Abdul Razak. Network, correlation, and community structure of the financial sector of Bursa Malaysia before, during, and after COVID-19[J]. Data Science in Finance and Economics, 2024, 4(3): 362-387. doi: 10.3934/DSFE.2024016

    Related Papers:

    [1] Hong Lu, Linlin Wang, Mingji Zhang . Studies on invariant measures of fractional stochastic delay Ginzburg-Landau equations on Rn. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2024, 21(4): 5456-5498. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2024241
    [2] Azmy S. Ackleh, Rainey Lyons, Nicolas Saintier . High resolution finite difference schemes for a size structured coagulation-fragmentation model in the space of radon measures. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(7): 11805-11820. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023525
    [3] H.T. Banks, S. Dediu, H.K. Nguyen . Sensitivity of dynamical systems to parameters in a convex subset of a topological vector space. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2007, 4(3): 403-430. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2007.4.403
    [4] D. Criaco, M. Dolfin, L. Restuccia . Approximate smooth solutions of a mathematical model for the activation and clonal expansion of T cells. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2013, 10(1): 59-73. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2013.10.59
    [5] Azmy S. Ackleh, Rainey Lyons, Nicolas Saintier . Finite difference schemes for a structured population model in the space of measures. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(1): 747-775. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020039
    [6] Qihua Huang, Hao Wang . A toxin-mediated size-structured population model: Finite difference approximation and well-posedness. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2016, 13(4): 697-722. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2016015
    [7] Gheorghe Craciun, Matthew D. Johnston, Gábor Szederkényi, Elisa Tonello, János Tóth, Polly Y. Yu . Realizations of kinetic differential equations. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2020, 17(1): 862-892. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2020046
    [8] Bing Hu, Minbo Xu, Zhizhi Wang, Jiahui Lin, Luyao Zhu, Dingjiang Wang . Existence of solutions of an impulsive integro-differential equation with a general boundary value condition. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2022, 19(4): 4166-4177. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2022192
    [9] Mario Lefebvre . An optimal control problem without control costs. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2023, 20(3): 5159-5168. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2023239
    [10] Azmy S. Ackleh, Mark L. Delcambre, Karyn L. Sutton, Don G. Ennis . A structured model for the spread of Mycobacterium marinum: Foundations for a numerical approximation scheme. Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering, 2014, 11(4): 679-721. doi: 10.3934/mbe.2014.11.679
  • COVID-19 triggered a worldwide economic decline and raised concerns regarding its economic consequences on stock markets across the globe, notably on the Malaysian stock market. We examined how COVID-19 impacted Malaysia's financial market using correlation and network analysis. We found a rise in correlations between stocks during the pandemic, suggesting greater interdependence. To visualize this, we created networks for pre-pandemic, during-pandemic, and post-pandemic periods. Additionally, we built a network for the during-pandemic period with a specific threshold corresponding to pre- and post-pandemic network density. The networks during the pandemic showed increased connectivity and only contained positive correlations, reflecting synchronized stock movements. Last, we analyzed the networks' modularity, revealing highest modularity during the pandemic, which suggests stronger yet risk-prone communities.



    Transport type equations arise ubiquitously in the physical, biological and social sciences (e.g., see [1,2,3]). They were, for example, recently used to approximate the dynamics of opinion formation [3] (see also [4] and [5]), to describe flow on networks (see [6,7,8]) and to model the dynamics of structured populations [9]. Because of the natural setting of the space of measures for these equations, as it allows for unifying discrete and continuous dynamics under the same framework, researchers have recently focused their efforts to study well-posedness of such equations on this space [10,11,12]; hence generalizing previous results that treated these equations in the space of integrable functions (e.g, [1]).

    The importance of understanding differentiability of solutions of differential equation models with respect to parameters is crucial for many applications including optimal control (e.g., [13,14]), parameter estimation and least-square problems of fitting models to data [15,16], and sensitivity analysis of solutions to model parameters that can be used to obtain information on parameter uncertainty including confidence intervals for estimated model parameters (e.g., [17,18,19]). Such applications require the minimization of a functional that depends on the model solution and hence (numerically) solving for the critical points of the equation that represents the derivative of the solutions with respect to parameter often becomes necessary.

    In this paper, we focus on deriving an equation that represents the derivative of a transport equation with respect to the vector field. To this end, consider the following transport equation in the space of bounded, nonnegative Radon measures M+(Rd):

    tμt+x(v(x)μt)=0 (1.1)

    where μt:[0,T]M+(Rd) and v:RdRd is a given vector field. Equation (1.1) is equipped with the initial condition μ|t=0=μ0. It is well-known that if vW1,(Rd), this equation has a unique solution in C([0,+),M+(Rd)) given by μt=T#tμ0 where Tt is the flow of v (defined in (2.2)) and T#t denotes the push - forward along the map Tt (see Eq (2.5)). Here, the space of measures is endowed with the so-called bounded Lipschitz norm BL (see Eq (2.1)).

    Here, we focus on the regularity of μt with respect to v, i.e., if v is slightly perturbed, how will μt change? To be more precise, suppose v(x) is replaced with the new vector field vh(x):=v0(x)+hvp(x) where v0 and vp are fixed vector fields and h can vary. The perturbed equation is then

    tμht+x(vh(x)μht)=0 (1.2)

    which has the unique solution μht=(Tht)#μ0 where Tht is the flow of the vector field vh. It is easy to see, using the representation formula for solutions to (1.2) presented in [20] or [21] (Eq 1.3) and estimates similar to the ones used to prove Lemma 3.8 in [22], that the map hμh is Lipschitz continuous in C([0,T],M+(Rd)) so that in particular limh0μh=μ in C([0,T],M+(Rd)) for any T>0 (see also Eq (2.7)).

    The next step in understanding the regularity of hμht consists in studying the existence of the derivative hμh. This type of questions has been recently addressed in [23] for linear transport equation and for general nonlinear structured population models (including transport equation) in [24]. Briefly, denoting by ρΔht,h:=(μh+Δhtμht)/Δh, a difference quotient, the question is to give a precise mathematical meaning to the limit limΔh0ρΔht,h. It turns out that this type of problems cannot be answered in the framework of bounded Lipschitz norm (see Example 3.5 in [24]). Indeed it is necessary to move to the bigger space Z defined as the closure of M(Rd) endowed with the dual norm (C1,α(Rd) (see Section 2.3 for a brief introduction). Then, according to Theorem 1.1 in [23], one can prove that there exists ρt,hZ such that limΔh0ρΔht,h=ρt,h (see also Theorem 2.1 below).

    In this paper we want to characterize ρ as the unique solution to some equation. In fact, one of the main results in this work (see, Theorem 4.1 below) states that ρ is the unique solution to the equation

    tρt+x(v0(x)ρt)=x(vp(x)μt).

    This equation can then be thought of as the sensitivity equation satisfied by the directional derivative of μ under the perturbation v0+hvp. We will also prove an analogous result in the non-linear case when the vector-field v depends on μ (see Theorem 5.1 below).

    The proofs of these results require the detailed study of a linear transport equation in Z of the form

    tμt+x(v(x)μt)=νt,μ|t=0=μ0. (1.3)

    While the existence of a solution to (1.3) can be established by extending standard techniques to the current setting on the space Z, the uniqueness issue presents some unexpected difficulties which led to a new notion of solution. With this new concept of solution, we are able to prove in Theorem 3.1 that this equation is well-posed.

    The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we briefly recall some known facts concerning transport equations in the space of measures and the space Z. We also establish new properties of the space Z. For a smooth flow of the paper we provide the details of long proofs of these new properties in the Appendix. In Section 3, we prove the existence and uniqueness of a solution to linear equation of type (1.3) in Z. This allows to formulate sensitivity equations in the the linear (Section 4) and the nonlinear (Section 5) cases. In Section 6, we discuss possible applications of our results.

    We briefly review here the formulation of the transport equation

    tμt+x(v(x)μt)=0

    on the space nonnegative Radon measures M+(Rd). This space is equipped with the bounded Lipschitz norm defined for μM+(Rd) as

    μBL=supψW1,(Rd)1Rdψ(x)dμ(x), (2.1)

    as the total variation norm is too strong. Here, W1,(Rd) is the space of bounded and globally Lipschitz functions.

    Let v be a vector field with vW1,(Rd,Rd). Then, the flow of v denoted by Ttv:RdRd is defined as the solution to the ODE:

    ddt(Ttv)(x)=v((Ttv)(x)),(T0v)(x)=x. (2.2)

    Notice that (Ttv)(x) is defined for all tR. If there is no risk of confusion, we write Tt instead of Ttv. Now, the classical method of characteristics allows to solve the transport equation

    tμt+x(v(x)μt)=νt,μt|t=0=μ0, (2.3)

    where νtC([0,T],M+(Rd)). More precisely, the unique measure solution in C([0,T],M(Rd)) to (2.3) is given by propagating the initial condition μ0 along the flow of v, namely

    μt=T#tμ0+t0T#tsνsds, (2.4)

    where for f:RdRd and measure μM+(Rd), f#μ is the push-forward measure defined as

    f#μ(A)=μ(f1(A)) for any measurable ARd. (2.5)

    We remark here that the definition of the push-forward measure yields the following change of variables formula: for all measurable maps T:RdRd and ϕ:RdR,

    Rdϕ(x)d(T#μ)(x)=RdϕT(x)dμ(x). (2.6)

    For the proof, see [25] for the case ν=0 and Proposition 3.6 in [21]. Let us also note that formula (2.4) is true also in the setting of bounded Radon measures M(Rd): as the equation is linear, one can apply the Hahn-Jordan decomposition (see Section 4.2 in [26]) and solve the equations for the positive and the negative parts of the measure separately.

    Now, let v1 and v2 be two bounded and globally Lipschitz vector fields. Let μ(1)t and μ(2)t be the solutions to (2.3) with vector fields v1 and v2, respectively. Then, there is a constant C=C(T,v1W1,,v2W1,,μ0) such that

    μ(1)tμ(2)tBLCv1v2,for any t[0,T]. (2.7)

    For the proof, one simply applies the triangle and Gronwall inequalities as in the proof of Lemma 3.8 in [22]. The solution to (2.3) thus depends continuously on v.

    The transport equation (2.3) can also be studied in a nonlinear setting where the vector field depends on the measure solution itself. Then, the nonlinear transport equation takes the form

    tμt+x(v[μt](x)μt)=0. (2.8)

    where v:M+(Rd)W1,(Rd,Rd). It is common in application that v depends on μ through some weighted mean of μ of the form

    v[μ](x)=V(x,RdKV(x,y)dμ(y)) (2.9)

    for given maps V:Rd×RRd and KV:Rd×RdR.

    Given α(0,1), we consider the space C1,α(Rd) of bounded continuous functions with bounded and α-Hölder derivative endowed with the norm

    uC1,α:=u+Du+supxy|Du(x)Du(y)||xy|α.

    Lemma 2.1. 1. For any uC1,α(Rd),

    |u(x+y)u(y)u(x)y|uC0,α|y|1+αfor any x,yRd. (2.10)

    2. If ϕC1,α(Rd) and TC1,α(Rd,Rd) then ϕTC1,α(Rd) with norm bounded by a constant depending only on a bound of ϕC1,α and TC1,α.

    Proof. The first assertion follows from

    u(x+y)u(y)u(x)y=10ddtu(x+ty)u(x)ydt=10(u(x+ty)u(x))ydt.

    For the second one we only need to estimate |D(ϕT)(x)D(ϕT)(y)|. We have

    |Dϕ(T(x))DT(x)Dϕ(T(y))DT(y)||Dϕ(T(x))(DT(x)DT(y)|+|(Dϕ(T(x))Dϕ(T(y)))DT(y)|ϕC1,αTC1,α|xy|α+ϕC1,α|T(x)T(y)|αTC1,αC|xy|α,

    where C=ϕC1,αTC1,α+ϕC1,αT1+αC1,α.

    We also recall the following result from Cor. 3.16 in [24] regarding the regularity of the flow Ttv defined in (2.2):

    Proposition 2.1. Assume that vC1,α(Rd,Rd). Then there exists a constant CT>0 depending only on T and vC1,α such that D(Ttv)C0,αCT for any t[0,T]. Moreover it can be checked upon inspection of the proof that CT1 as T0.

    We consider the space Z defined as the closure of M(Rd) endowed with the dual norm (C1,α(Rd)) for some α (see Remark 2.1 on the choice of α). This space was first introduced in [23] where the authors demonstrated that Z has a lot of convenient topological properties. In particular, Z is a separable Banach space with its dual being isometrically isomorphic to C1,α(Rd). Indeed it was proved in [23][Prop. 5.1] that span{δx,xQd} is dense in Z. In particular this implies that any element of Z can be approximated by bounded measures.

    Notice that using duality we have for any μZ,

    μZ=supψC1,α1(μ,ψ).

    The main advantage of space Z is its applicability to studying differentiation problems with respect to perturbation of transport equations. More precisely, let us consider Eq (2.3) with νt=0 and vector field v0(x)+hvp(x) where h[M,M] for some M>0, and denote by μht its solution, namely

    tμht+x((v0+hvp)μht)=0,μht|t=0=μ0.

    One is then interested in the limit μh+ΔhtμhtΔh as Δh0. The following result was obtained in [23]:

    Theorem 2.1. Let v0,vpC1+α(Rd,Rd). Then, μh+ΔhtμhtΔh converges in C([0,T],Z) as Δh0.

    Remark 2.1. Let Zα=¯M(Rd)(C1,α(Rd)). Notice that if 0<α<α<1 then C1,αC1,α from which we deduce that ZαZα with continuous injection. Therefore, if incremental quotient μh+ΔhtμhtΔh converges in Zα, it also does so in Zα for any α<α. Moreover, since ZαZα continuously, both limits coincide. So there is no ambiguity and we simply write Z instead of Zα.

    Such a perturbation problem can be also studied for the nonlinear transport equation (2.8) with a vector-field v0[μ] like (2.9). We perturb v0[μ] considering vh[μ](x) defined as

    vh[μ](x)=v0[μ](x)+hvp[μ](x)=V0(x,RdKV0(x,y)dμ(y))+hVp(x,RdKVp(x,y)dμ(y)). (2.11)

    Then, we have the following result:

    Theorem 2.2. Let α>12 and vh[μ] be given by (2.11), where V0,VpC1+α(Rd×R,Rd) and KV0,KVpC2+α(Rd×Rd,R). Let μht be the unique solution to (2.8) with the vector field vh[μ]. Then, μh+ΔhtμhtΔh converges in C([0,T],Z) as Δh0.

    Remark 2.2. The proof of existence and uniqueness of solutions as well as of a differentiability result was actually given only for the case of R+ in [22] and [24] respectively. However, the proof can be easily extended to Rd. Indeed, the main idea is to construct approximating sequence as follows. The interval of time [0,T] is divided into 2k subintervals of the form [lT2k,(l+1)T2k] where l=0,1,...,2k1. Then, the following approximation is defined recursively: for t(lT2k,(l+1)T2k], let μt be the solution to

    tμt+x(v[μlT2k](x)μt)=0.

    with initial condition μlT2k. One then uses the formula for the solution of the linear problem (2.4) to conclude the proof. See [22] and [24] for more details.

    The following Propositions discuss the distributional derivatives of bounded Radon measures as elements of space Z. For easier flow of this section long proofs are provided in the Appendix.

    We can see a Radon measure μM(Rd) as a distribution by (μ,ϕ)=ϕdμ, ϕCc(Rd). We denote by xϕ:=ϕx the derivative of ϕ in direction xRd. We then define a distribution xμ by duality letting (xμ,ϕ)=(μ,xϕ). The next result shows that in fact xμ belongs to Z when μ is bounded.

    Proposition 2.2. For any bounded μM(Rd), the distributional derivative xμ of μ in direction xRd belongs to Z.

    Proof. Let μM(Rd) be bounded. To prove that the distributional derivative xμ belongs to Z, we need to find a sequence νhM(Rd) such that νhxμ as h0 in Z. Let τh be the translation operator defined by τhϕ(y):=ϕ(y+hx) for any ϕ. Take νh:=(τ#hμμ)/hM(Rd). Then for any ϕC1,α(Rd) with ϕC1,α(Rd)1 we have using (2.10) that

    |(νh,ϕ)(xμ,ϕ)|=Rd|ϕ(y+hx)ϕ(y)hxϕ(y)|dμ(y)|h|αμTV

    so that νhxμ in Z as h0.

    Proposition 2.3. Consider μn,μMb(Rd) such that μnμ narrowly (i.e. in duality with bounded and continuous functions Cb(Rd)). Then xμnxμ in Z.

    Proof. See Appendix.

    ,

    Proposition 2.4. For a bounded vector field v on Rd and μMb(Rd) we have

    x(vμ)ZμTVv. (2.12)

    Moreover, consider measures μn,μMb(Rd) such that μnμ narrowly and vector fields vn,vCb(Rd,Rd) such that vnv uniformly. Then x(vnμn)x(vμ) in Z.

    Proof. For any ϕ such that ϕC1,α1 we have

    |(x(vμ),ϕ)|=|(μ,vxϕ)|μTVvxϕμTVv.

    Then, in view of Proposition 2.3, to verify the second assertion, it is sufficient to prove that vnμnvμ narrowly. For ϕCb(Rd), we have

    (vnμnvμ,ϕ)=(μn,(vnv)ϕ)+(μnμ,vϕ)

    where (,) denotes the dual pairing. The first term can be bounded by μnTV(vnv)ϕC(vnv)0 while the second tends to 0 since vϕCb(Rd).

    We deduce that

    Corollary 2.1. Let [0,T]tμtMb(Rd) be a narrowly continuous map and vCb(Rd,Rd). Then x(vμt)C([0,T],Z).

    It will also be useful to define the push-forward of an element of Z. The idea is quite simple. In fact, since this is well-defined on the space of measures, we can extend its definition for elements of Z by means of Cauchy sequences.

    Proposition 2.5. Let TC1,α(Rd,Rd). Then for any μZ we can define T#μZ by

    T#μ:=limnT#μn

    where {μn}nNM(Rd) is any sequence such that μnμ in Z. Then, for any ϕC1,α(Rd) we have the following analogue of the change of variables formula (2.6):

    (T#μ,ϕ)=(μ,ϕT)

    where ϕT denotes composition of the maps ϕ and T.

    Proof. See Appendix.

    We conclude this section with the following classical observation. By definition, if μZ, there is a sequence of bounded measures {μn}nN such that μnμ in Z. Now, if μC([0,T],Z), for each t[0,T], one can choose an approximating sequence for each μt, t[0,T]. However, it is possible to construct an approximating sequence that is continuous in time and so, that approximates the whole curve tμt, t[0,T]. This is the content of the following lemma.

    Lemma 2.2. Let μC([0,T],Z). There is a sequence {μ(n)}nNC([0,T],Mb(Rd)) such that μ(n)μ in C([0,T],Z) as n.

    Proof. See Appendix.

    Corollary 2.2. Let νC([0,T],Z) and vC1,α(Rd). Then the map tTtv#νt is continuous from [0,T] to Z.

    Proof. See Appendix.

    In this section, we study the following transport equation in the space Z:

    tμt+x(v(x)μt)=νt,μ|t=0=μ0, (3.1)

    where vC1,α(Rd,Rd), νC([0,T],Z) and μ0Z. We begin with a concept of a very weak solution.

    Definition 3.1. We say that μC([0,T],Z) is a very weak solution to (3.1) in Z if for any φC([0,T]×Rd) with φC([0,T],C2+α(Rd)) and φtC([0,T],C1+α(Rd)) we have:

    (μT,φ(x,T))=(μ0,φ(x,0))+T0(μt,φt(.,t)+vφ(.,t))dt+T0(νt,ϕ(.,t))dt. (3.2)

    Note that we have to use test functions of regularity at least C2+α in space variable x so that function φt+v(x)xφ lies in Z, the domain of the functional μt.

    Proposition 3.1. Equation (3.1) has at least one very weak solution in C([0,T],Z) given by

    μt=T#tμ0+t0T#tsνsds (3.3)

    where the integral is a Bochner integral in Z.

    Moreover, if μ0=0 and νt=0, then for any weak solution μt we have

    (μt,η)=0 (3.4)

    for all ηC2+α(Rd) and t[0,T].

    Proof. We first verify that the integral appearing on the right-hand side of (3.3) is a Bochner integral in Z. According to Corollary 2 the map f:s[0,t]T#tsνsZ is continuous. Thus for any zZ, zf is also continuous. Since Z is separable, we conclude using Pettis theorem that f is measurable. Moreover for any ϕC1,α(Rd), ϕC1,α1, we have

    |(f(s),ϕ)|=|(νs,ϕTts)|νsZϕTtsC1,αCT

    since νC([0,T],Z) and in view of Lemma 2.1 and Proposition 1. It follows that max0stf(s)ZCT and thus that f is Bochner-integrable. It is also easily seen that t0T#tsνsds is continuous in t.

    Let μt be defined by (3.3). Clearly μC([0,T],Z). We now verify that μt is a solution in the sense of Definition 1. According to Lemma 2, we we can find sequences {ν(n)}nNC([0,T],Mb(Rd)) and {μn0}nNMb(Rd) such that μ(n)0μ0Z0 and ν(n)tνtZ0 uniformly in t[0,T]. Then the transport equation

    tμt+x(v(x)μt)=ν(n)t,μ|t=0=μ(n)0 (3.5)

    has a unique solution μ(n)C([0,T],Mb(Rd)) given by

    μ(n)t=T#tμ(n)0+t0T#tsν(n)sds. (3.6)

    According to Proposition 2.5, T#tμ(n)0T#tμ0 in Z and, for any s, T#tsν(n)sT#tsνs in Z. Since T#tsν(n)sZCT we have applying the Dominated Convergence Theorem that t0T#tsν(n)sdst0T#tsνsds in Z. Thus for any t[0,T], μ(n)t converges in Z to μt given by

    μt:=limn+μ(n)t=T#tμ0+t0T#tsνsds.

    Clearly, μC([0,T],Z). On the other hand, weak formulation for (3.5) is valid for test functions of class C1([0,T]×Rd)W1,([0,T]×Rd). In particular, taking test functions as in Definition 3.1, we send n in the weak formulation for (3.5) to deduce that μt is a very weak solution to (3.1).

    To prove (3.4), we use the so-called dual problem (cf. Remark 8.1.5 and Proposition 8.1.7 in [27] or Proposition 5.34 in [25]). More precisely, given some function ψ(x,t), let φ be the solution of

    tφ+v(x)xφ=ψ,φ(x,T)=0. (3.7)

    which is explicitly given by φ(x,t)=Ttψ(Tst(x),s)ds. We consider ϕ of the form ψ(x,t)=ξ(t)η(x) where ξCc([0,T]) and ηC2,α(Rd). We then use the corresponding solution ϕ of (3.7) as a test function in (3.2) to conclude

    T0ξ(t)(μt,η)dt=0.

    Since the map t(μt,η(x)) is continuous for t[0,T] and since ξ is arbitrary, we deduce that (μt,η)=0 for any ηC2,α(Rd) and t[0,T].

    Unfortunately, condition (3.4) does not imply that μt=0 so that we cannot deduce the uniqueness of a solution to (3.1). The problem here is that C2+α(Rd) is not dense in C1+α(Rd). The following two examples shows the typical problem with approximation of Hölder functions.

    Example 3.1. One can easily check that f(x)=xC1/2([0,1]). Suppose there is a sequence {fn}nNC1([0,1]) such that fnfC1/20. Then

    0fnfC1/2supx(0,1]|1fn(x)fn(0)x|supx(0,1]|fn(x)fn(0)|x1,

    contradicting {fn}nNC1([0,1]).

    Example 3.2. We construct a nontrivial functional on C1/2([0,1]) which vanishes on C1,1/2([0,1]). In particular, this shows that functionals on C1/2([0,1]) cannot be uniquely characterized by their values on C1,1/2([0,1]). Let X=C1([0,1])lin(x) be a linear subspace of C1/2([0,1]). On X, we can define a functional φ:XR with

    φ(f)=limx0f(x)f(0)x.

    Notice that ϕ is continuous since |φ(f)|fC1/2. By the analytic version of Hahn-Banach Theorem (Theorem 1.1 in [28]), we can then extend φ to a continuous functional on C1/2([0,1]). It is easily seen that ϕ(f)=0 for any fC1([0,1]) by Taylor's estimate but that φ(x)=1.

    There is also characterization of subset in Cα consisting of functions that can be approximated by smooth functions:

    Remark 3.1. Let ΩRd. Then, fCα(Ω) can be approximated by smooth functions if and only if f is an element of the set

    Fα(Ω)={fCα(Ω):limt0+sup|xy|t|f(x)f(y)||xy|α=0}.

    One easily checks that for Ω=[0,1], xF1/2(Ω). Moreover, for any β>α, Cβ(Ω)Fα(Ω).

    Therefore, we realize that the space of test functions is too small to deduce uniqueness of weak solutions. This is the case for many PDEs formulated in the weak sense. Probably one of the most famous is Euler's equation where one can construct infinitely many distributional solutions with prescribed energy profile (thus contradicting conservation of energy), see [29] and references therein. The standard procedure in such situation for many evolutionary problems is to require some additional conditions to be satisfied by a weak solution (like entropy condition for conservation laws, see [30], section 3.4).

    To establish additional conditions required from weak solutions, we should get some insight about which solutions we would like to extract. First, note that if νZ, there is an approximating sequence of measures νnM(Rd) such that νnν in Z. Now, recall that we want to find an equation that is satisfied by the derivative of the solution to (3.1) with respect to perturbation parameter h. Therefore, in our case, such approximating sequence is of the form μh+ΔhtμhtΔh. We will see in the proof of Theorem 4.1 below that μh+ΔhtμhtΔhBLCT for some constant C independent of h, Δh and t. This suggests to define the following admissibility class:

    A={νZ:{νn}nNM(Rd) s.t. νnν in Z and νnBLC}. (3.8)

    Notice that A is a subspace of Z containing the bounded measures Mb(Rd) so that A is dense in Z. In view of the proof of Proposition 2.2 we also have that xμA for any μMb(Rd). In fact we have the folowing stronger result:

    Proposition 3.2. Let μ:[0,T]Mb(Rd) be continuous and TV-bounded, and let xRd. Then xμC([0,T],Z) with values in A and in fact there exists ρhC([0,T],Mb(Rd)), h(0,1), such that

    limt0max0tTρhtx(μt)Z=0andsuph(0,1],t[0,T]ρhtBLC.

    Proof. According to Proposition 2.3, xμC([0,T],Z). Let τh be the translation defined by τhϕ(y)=ϕ(y+hx). It is then easy to verify using the same arguments as in the proof of Proposition 2 that ρht:=(τ#hμtμt)/h satisfies the requirements.

    We can now define a weak solutions as follows.

    Definition 3.2. We say that μC([0,T],Z) is a weak solution to (3.1) in Z if μ is a very weak solution (see Definition 3.1) and for all t[0,T], μtA.

    With this definition we are now able to establish the following existence and uniqueness result:

    Theorem 3.1. Let μ0A and νC([0,T],Z) with values in A. Assume that there exists a sequence νnC([0,T],Mb(Rd)), nN, such that

    limn+max0tTνntνtZ=0andsupnN,t[0,T]νntBLC. (3.9)

    Then, equation (3.1) has a unique weak solution in the sense of Definition 3.2 which is given by

    μt=T#tμ0+t0T#tsνsds. (3.10)

    Note that according to Proposition 3.2, the Theorem applies in particular when νt=x(μt) with μ:[0,T]Mb(Rd) continuous and TV-bounded.

    Proof. To prove the uniqueness statement, since the equation is linear, it is sufficient to prove that if μ0=0 and νt=0 for all t[0,T], then μt=0 for all t[0,T]. This is equivalent to (μt,η)=0 for any ηC1,α(Rd). Fix ηC1,α(Rd) and for ϵ>0 denote by ηϵ the standard mollification of η. Since η and its derivatives are uniformly continuous, we have ηϵηW1,0 as ϵ0. Moreover, for fixed ϵ>0, ηϵC2,α(Rd) so that (μt,ηϵ)=0 by (3.4). Since μtA there exists a BL-bounded sequence μ(n)tMb(Rd) converging in Z to μt. For a fixed ε>0 we then write

    (μt,η)=(μt,ηϵ)+(μt,ηηϵ)=limn(μ(n)t,ηηϵ)

    with

    (μ(n)t,ηηϵ)μ(n)tBLηηϵW1,CηηϵW1,

    for some constant C independent of n. Thus

    |(μt,η)|CηηϵW1,.

    Since ϵ>0 is arbitrary, we conclude (μt,η)=0.

    Concerning the existence, we already know from Proposition 3.1 that μt=T#tμ0+t0T#tsνsds belongs to C([0,T],Z) and solves the equation. It remains to prove that μtA for any t[0,T]. Since μ0A there exists a BL-bounded sequence μ(n)0Mb(Rd) converging in Z to μ0. Let

    μ(n)t:=T#tμ(n)0+t0T#tsν(n)sds

    where νn satisfies (3.9). We verify as in the proof of Proposition 3.1 that μ(n)tμt in Z for any given t. Moreover for any bounded Lipschitz ϕ we have

    (μ(n)t,ϕ)=(μ(n)0,ϕTt)+t0(ν(n)s,ϕTts)dsμ(n)0BLϕTtBL+t0ν(n)sBLϕTtsBLds

    Since Lip(Tt)etLip(v) we have ϕTtBLetLip(v). Thus, choosing CT=etLip(v)(supnμ(n)0BL+Tsupn,0sTν(n)sBL) we see that

    (μ(n)t,ϕ)CT.

    Hence, supnN,t[0,T]μntBLCT.

    In this section we formulate an equation that is satisfied by the derivative of the solutions μt with respect to h, i.e., ρt,h=limΔh0μh+ΔhtμhtΔh, where μht solves

    tμht+x(vh(x)μht)=0 (4.1)

    with initial condition μh|t=0=μ0 and vh=v0+hvp where v0,vpC1+α(Rd,Rd) are given vector fields. The derivative ρt,h exists according to Theorem 2.1.

    To obtain the equation ρt,h should solve, we substract the equations satisfied by μht and μh+Δht, namely

    tμht+x(vh(x)μht)=0
    tμh+Δht+x((vh(x)+Δhvp(x))μh+Δht)=0

    to obtain that ρΔht,h:=μh+ΔhtμhtΔh satisfies

    tρΔht,h+x(vh(x)ρΔht,h)=x(vp(x)μh+Δht).

    Thus, intuitively the limit ρt,h=limΔh0ρΔht,h should satisfy

    tρt,h+x(vh(x)ρt,h)=x(vp(x)μht). (4.2)

    Since the right-hand side belongs to Z in view of Proposition 2.4, we are naturally led to study this equation in Z. The following Theorem asserts that this intuition is correct and can be rigurously justifed.

    Theorem 4.1. The derivative ρt,h=limΔh0μh+ΔhtμhtΔh where μht and μh+Δht solve (4.1) is the unique weak solution (cf. Definition 3.2) of

    tρt,h+x(vh(x)ρt,h)=x(vp(x)μht) (4.3)

    with initial condition ρ0,h=0.

    Proof. Let ρΔht,h:=(μh+Δhtμht)/Δh. Since μh+Δht and μht are solutions to (4.1), we have that for any φC1([0,T]×Rd)W1,([0,T]×Rd):

    Rdφ(x,t)dμht(x)Rdφ(x,0)dμ0(x)=t0Rdtφ(x,s)dμhs(x)ds+t0Rd(v0(x)+hvp(x))φ(x,s)dμhsds

    and similarly

    Rdφ(x,t)dμh+Δht(x)Rdφ(x,0)dμ0(x)=t0Rdtφ(x,s)dμh+Δhs(x)ds+t0Rd(v0(x)+(h+Δh)vp(x))φ(x,s)dμh+Δhsds.

    Substracting these equations and dividing by Δh, we obtain that

    Rdφ(x,t)dρΔht,h=t0Rdtφ(x,s)dρΔhs,hds+t0Rdvh(x)φ(x)dρΔhs,h(x)ds+t0Rdvp(x)φ(x)dμh+Δhsds.

    Since μh+Δhμh in C([0,T],M(Rd)) as Δh0, We can pass to the limit Δh0 in the last term on the right-hand side using the Dominated Convergence Theorem to obtain

    Rdφ(x,t)dρΔht,h=t0Rdtφ(x,s)dρΔhs,hds+t0Rdvh(x)φ(x)dρΔhs,h(x)ds+t0Rdvp(x)φ(x)dμhsds. (4.4)

    Recall that we know from Theorem 2.1 that the limit ρh=limh0ρΔhh exists in C([0,T],Z) - in particular ρΔht,hZCT for any t[0,T] and any Δh small. Now, if φ satisfies φC([0,T],C2+α(Rd)) and tφC([0,T],C1+α(Rd)), using that v0,vpC1+α(Rd,Rd), we deduce that as Δh0,

    (ρΔhs,h,tφ(.,s)+vhφ(.,s))(ρs,h,tφ(.,s)+vhφ(.,s)).

    Moreover for any s[0,T] and Δh small,

    |(ρΔhs,h,tφ(.,s)+vhφ(.,s))|ρΔht,hZtφ(.,s)+vhφ(.,s)C1+αCT.

    Using the Dominated Convergence Theorem, we can thus send Δh0 in (4.4) to deduce:

    (ρt,h,φ(,t))=t0Rdvp(x)φ(x,s)dμhsds+t0(ρs,h,tφ(,s)+vh()φ(,s))ds. (4.5)

    Thus, ρt,h is a very weak solution of (4.3) with initial condition ρ0,h=0.

    Let us prove that ρt,h is the unique weak solution to (4.3). First note that due to Corollary 2.1, x(vp(x)μht)C([0,T],Z). Moreover, we claim that ρt,hA for all t[0,T], where A is the admissibility class defined in (3.8). Indeed since ρΔht,hρt,h in Z, it suffices to verify that ρΔht,hBLC with C independent of Δh. Recall that μht=(Tht)#μ0 where Tht is the flow of vh. Using Gronwall inequality it is easy to see that

    ThtTh+ΔhtΔhvpexp(Lip(vh)t).

    Thus for any ϕW1,(Rd), ϕW1,1,

    (μhtμh+Δht,ϕ)=(μ0,ϕThtϕTh+Δht)μ0ThtTh+Δhtμ0Δhvpexp(Lip(vh)t)=:CT,hΔh

    Taking the supremum over such ϕ, we deduce that μhtμh+ΔhtBLCT,hΔh. Therefore, in view of Theorem 3.1, we conclude that ρt,h is the unique weak solution to (4.3).

    Notice that in the previous proof we exploited the fact that we already knew that the derivative ρh=limh0ρΔhh exists due to [23]. But the well-posedness theory we established in the previous section and the fact ρht is characterized as the unique solution to equation (4.3) allow us to give an alternative short proof of the existence of ρh. Indeed let us define ρt,h as the unique solution to (4.3). We then need to prove that

    limΔh0max0tTρΔht,hρt,hZ=0. (4.6)

    In view of (4.4), ρΔht,h satisfies

    tρΔht,h+x(vh(x)ρΔht,h)=x(vp(x)μh+Δht).

    Since ρt,h,ρΔht,hA, Theorem 3.1 yields

    ρt,h=t0(Thts)#νhsds,νhs=x(vp(x)μhs),
    ρΔht,h=t0(Thts)#νh+Δhsds,νh+Δhs=x(vp(x)μh+Δhs),

    where Tht is the flow of vh. Then

    ρΔht,hρt,ht0(Thts)#νh+Δhs(Thts)#νhsZdsCT,ht0νh+ΔhsνhsZds

    where we used in the last equality that ϕThtC1+αCT,h for any ϕC1+α1. We deduce (4.6) using Lemma 4.1 below.

    Lemma 4.1. There holds

    limΔh0max0tTνh+ΔhsνhsZ=0. (4.7)

    Proof. The proof follows the line of the proof of Proposition 2.3. Suppose that (4.7) is not true so that there exist ε>0 and sequences {tΔh}[0,T], {ϕΔh}C1+α(Rd), ϕΔhC1+α1 such that

    (μh+ΔhtΔhμhtΔh,vpϕΔh)ε>0. (4.8)

    As in the proof of Proposition 2.3 there exists ϕC1+α(Rd), ϕC1+α1, such that up to a subsequence ϕΔhϕ in C1loc(Rd). Moreover there exists t0=limΔh0tΔh up to a subsequence. Independently recall that μht=(Tht)#μ0 and μh+Δht=(Th+Δht)#μ0. It follows that μhtTV,μh+ΔhtTVμ0TV and also that for any δ>0 there exists a compact set KRd such that

    |μh+Δht|(RdK),|μht|(RdK)δfor any |Δh|1 and t[0,T].

    Since vpϕΔhvpϕ in Cloc(Rd) it follows that

    (μh+ΔhtΔh,vpϕΔh)(μh+ΔhtΔh,vpϕ)0. (4.9)

    Eventually letting ψ:=vpϕ we have

    (μh+ΔhtΔhμhtΔh,vpϕ)=Rdψ(Th+ΔhtΔh(x))ψ(ThtΔh(x))dμ0(x).

    Since ψ is bounded and Th+ΔhtΔh(x))Tht0(x), ThtΔh(x)Tht0(x) for any xRd, the Dominated Convergence Theorem gives (μh+Δhtμht,vpϕ)0. This and (4.9) contradicts (4.8).

    In this Section we formulate an equation satisfied by the derivative

    ρt,h=limΔh0μh+ΔhtμhtΔh

    where μht solves

    tμht+x(vh[μht](x)μht)=0 (5.1)

    with the initial condition μh|t=0=μ0 and vh[μht] is a vector field which depends a priori in a non-linear way of μht.

    Let us first present some heuristic computations to determine the equation ρt,h should satisfy. Let ρΔht,h:=(μh+Δhtμht)/Δh. Since μh+Δht and μht are solutions to (5.1) we have that for any φC1([0,T]×Rd)W1,([0,T]×Rd):

    Rdφ(x,t)dμht(x)Rdφ(x,0)dμ0(x)==t0Rdtφ(x,s)dμhs(x)ds+t0Rdvh[μhs](x)φ(x,s)dμhsds (5.2)

    and similarly

    Rdφ(x,t)dμh+Δht(x)Rdφ(x,0)dμ0(x)=t0Rdtφ(x,s)dμh+Δhs(x)ds++t0Rd(vh[μh+Δhs](x)+Δh.vp[μh+Δhs](x))φ(x,s)dμh+Δhsds. (5.3)

    Notice that μh+Δhs=μhs+ΔhρΔht,h. Then performing formally a first order Taylor expansion,

    vh[μh+Δhs](x)=vh[μhs+Δh.ρΔht,h]=vh[μhs]+Δh.Dvh[μhs].ρΔht,h+Δh.o(1). (5.4)

    Substracting (5.9) from (5.10) and dividing by Δh, we then obtain

    Rdφ(x,t)dρΔht,h(x)t0Rdtφ(x,s)dρΔhs,h(x)dst0Rdvh[μhs](x)ϕ(x,s)dρΔhs,hds=t0Rd(Dvh[μhs]ρΔhs,h+vp[μh+Δhs]+o(1))ϕ(x,s)dμh+Δhsds.

    Thus ρΔht,h solves the linear equation

    tρΔht,h+x(vh[μht]ρΔht,h)=x((Dvh[μhs]ρΔhs,h+vp[μh+Δhs]+o(1))μh+Δht) (5.5)

    with initial condition ρΔht=0,h=0. We thus expect the limit ρt,h to solve

    tρt,h+x(vh[μht]ρt,h)=x((Dvh[μht]ρt,h+vp[μht]μht). (5.6)

    Comparing with the linear caser studied in the previous section where we obtained the sensitivity equation (4.3), the situation now is more complicated because even if (5.6) is linear in ρt,h, the right-hand side depends on ρt,h and the existence and uniqueness theory developed so far does not apply directly.

    It turns out however that the previous formal reasonning (in particular the formal Taylor expansion (5.4)) can be justified when vh[μ] is of the form (2.11), namely

    vh[μ](x)=v0[μ](x)+hvp[μ](x)=V0(x,RdKV0(x,y)dμ(y))+hVp(x,RdKVp(x,y)dμ(y))

    with V0,VpC1+α(Rd×R,Rd) and KV0,KVpC2+α(Rd×Rd,R) for some α>12. In that case the derivative ρt,h exists according to Theorem 2.2 and we have the following result from [24] (Lemma 4.6):

    Lemma 5.1. Let V,KVC1+α(Rd×Rd) and the map hμht be differentiable in Z. Then, for every xRd, the map hV(x,RdKV(x,y)dμht) is C1+α(R,Rd) with norms bounded by some constant depending on the C1+α norms of V and KV as well as Z norm of derivative of μht. Moreover, if ρt,h=limΔh0μh+ΔhtμhtΔh, we have the following chain rule:

    hV(x,RdKV(x,y)dμht(y))=yV(x,RdKV(x,y)dμht(y))(ρt,h,KV(x,)).

    where yV denotes the gradient of V with respect to the second variable.

    Then Lemma 5.1 and Lemma 2.1 gives the following rigorous Taylor expansion:

    Corollary 5.1. In the framework of Lemma 5.1,

    V(x,RdKV(x,y)dμh+Δht)V(x,RdKV(x,y)dμht)=C[V,μht](x)(ρt,h,KV(x,))+O(|h|1+α) (5.7)

    where

    C[V,μ](x)=yV(x,RdKV(x,y)dμ)

    and the O(|h|1+α) is uniform in xRd.

    The following theorem asserts that the sensitivity equation (5.6) we obtained formally is the correct one:

    Theorem 5.1. The derivative ρt,h=limΔh0μh+ΔhtμhtΔh where μht and μh+Δht solve (5.1) is the unique weak solution of

    tρt,h+x(vh[μht](x)ρt,h)=x(vp(x)μht)x[C[V0,μht](x)(ρs,h,KV0(x,))μht]x[C[Vp,μht](x)(ρs,h,KVp(x,))μht] (5.8)

    with initial condition ρ0,h=0. More precisely, the weak formulation is satisfied for all test functions φ(x,t) of regularity φC([0,T],C2+α(Rd)), φtC([0,T],C1+α(Rd)), and ρt,hA for all t[0,T] where A is defined in (3.8).

    Proof. Let ρΔht,h:=(μh+Δhtμht)/Δh. Since μh+Δht and μht are solutions to (5.1) we have that for any φC1([0,T]×Rd)W1,([0,T]×Rd):

    Rdφ(x,t)dμht(x)Rdφ(x,0)dμ0(x)=t0Rdtφ(x,s)dμhs(x)ds+t0Rd(v0[μhs](x)+hvp[μhs](x))φ(x,s)dμhsds (5.9)

    and similarly

    Rdφ(x,t)dμh+Δht(x)Rdφ(x,0)dμ0(x)=t0Rdtφ(x,s)dμh+Δhs(x)ds+t0Rd(v0[μh+Δhs](x)+(h+Δh)vp[μh+Δhs](x))φ(x,s)dμh+Δhsds. (5.10)

    The plan is to substract these equations, divide by Δh and pass to the limit Δh0. First, in view of (5.7),

    v0[μh+Δhs](x)+hvp[μh+Δhs](x)=v0[μhs](x)+hvp[μhs](x)+C[V0,μhs](x)(ρs,h,KV0(x,))+C[Vp,μhs](x)(ρs,h,KVp(x,))+O(|h|1+α).

    Therefore, for φ(x,t) of regularity φC([0,T],C2+α(Rd)) and φtC([0,T],C1+α(Rd)), we substract (5.9) from (5.10), divide by Δh and send Δh0. Recalling that ρΔht,hρt,h in Z uniformly in t[0,T], we obtain

    (ρt,h,φ(,t))=t0Rdvp[μhs](x)φ(x,s)dμhs(x)ds+t0(ρs,h,tφ(,s)+vh[μhs]()φ(,s))ds+t0Rd[C[V0,μhs](x)(ρs,h,KV0(x,))]φ(x,s)dμhs(x)ds+ht0Rd[C[Vp,μhs](x)(ρs,h,KVp(x,))]φ(x,s)dμhs(x)ds.

    Thus, ρt,h is a weak solution of (5.8). It is also in the admissible class A due to the Lipschitz continuity of solutions with respect to the vector field.

    To obtain uniqueness, suppose that ρ(1)t,h and ρ(2)t,h are solutions to (5.8) with values in A. Then, their difference ρt,h=ρ(1)t,hρ(2)t,hA satisfies

    (ρt,h,φ(,t))=t0(ρs,h,tφ(,s)+vh[μhs]()φ(,s))ds+t0Rd[C[V0,μhs](x)(ρs,h,KV0(x,))]φ(x,s)dμhs(x)ds+ht0Rd[C[Vp,μhs](x)(ρs,h,KVp(x,))]φ(x,s)dμhs(x)ds. (5.11)

    Fix ψC2+α(Rd). As in the proof of Proposition 3.1, we again use the duality method to find a test function φψ(x,t) such that

    tφψ(,s)+vh[μht](x)φψ(x,s)=0φψ(x,t)=ψ(x).

    Actually, it can be given explicitly as φψ(x,s)=ψ(T(x,t,s)) where T is the flow of the non-autonomous vector field vh[μhs] which solves the ODE:

    sT(x,s,t)=vh[μhs](T(x,s,t)),T(x,t,t)=x,

    see Remark 8.1.5 and Proposition 8.1.7 in [27]. Using the test-function ϕv in (5.11) we deduce

    (ρt,h,ψ)=t0Rd[C[V0,μhs](x)(ρs,h,KV0(x,))]φψ(x,s)dμhs(x)ds+ht0Rd[C[Vp,μhs](x)(ρs,h,KVp(x,))]φψ(x,s)dμhs(x)ds (5.12)

    for any ψC2+α(Rd). Since the kernels KV0 and KVp are both assumed to be C2+α(Rd×Rd), there is a constant C such that

    (ρs,h,KV0(x,)),(ρs,h,KVp(x,))CsupψC2+α1(ρs,h,ψ).

    Moreover, for ψC2+α(Rd) with ψC2+α1 we see from the explicit formula that there is another constant C such that φψC. Therefore, from (5.12), we conclude

    supψC2+α1(ρt,h,ψ)Ct0supψC2+α1(ρs,h,ψ)ds

    for some possibly bigger constant C. Now, Gronwall inequality implies

    (ρs,h,ψ)=0

    for all s[0,t] and all ψC2+α(Rd). As ρs,h is in the admissible class A, we can repeat the uniqueness proof from Theorem 3.1 to deduce that ρs,h=0 as desired.

    As mentioned above, transport-type equations like (1.1) represent a big variety of phenomena occurring in physics, biology and social sciences. In this section we present applications that the theory developed here is of use.

    Here we are interested in functionals of the form

    J(h)=RdF(x)dμht(x),

    where μht is a measure solution to the perturbed transport equation (1.2) on the space of nonnegative Radon measure, while FC1+α(Rd). Such functionals can describe various quantities of practical importance. For example, for F(x)=1 this functional provides the total number of individuals in a population, since μhC([0,T],M+(Rd).

    Now, let hμhtC([0,T],Z) be the derivative of μht with respect to h. Then, hJ(h) is differentiable and

    hJ(h)=(hμht,F),

    value of this derivative can be used in the optimization of the functional J, i.e., finding value of h for which J is the smallest. Our work characterizes the derivative as the solutions of some PDE, thus allowing to work on appropriate approximating schemes for the quantity (hμht,F).

    Another application of paramount importance is parameter estimation and fitting models to data, as this allows for model validation. To this end, let Rddμht, represents the total number of individuals in a population at time t provided by the perturbed transport equation model considered on the space of nonnegative Radon measures. Suppose that Dk represents data on the number of individuals in the population at time tk, k=1,,K (a time series of the total population). Consider the following minimization problem involving a least-squares functional that measures the distance between the model solution and data:

    minhJ(h)=minhKk=1|RddμhtkDk|2,

    subject to

    tμht+x(vh[μ](x)μht)=0,μht|t=0=μ0M+(Rd).

    The derivative hJ(h) which depends on the derivative of h(μht), the solution to (4.3), can be used to minimize the least-squares distance J(h). The value ˉh that minimizes J(h), also provides an estimate for the vector field given by vˉh.

    We conclude by pointing our that the above two applications demonstrate the need for the development of numerical approximation schemes for computing solutions to transport equations of the type (4.1) or (4.3). There has been some efforts in the direction of solving transport equations in the space of nonnegative Radon measures endowed with the Bounded Lipschitz norm (e.g. [31,32]), but to our knowledge, no such numerical schemes exist for solving transport equations in the space Z. Furthermore, because minimization problems generally involve computing the solution multiple times until a minimizer is reached, it is important that for any scheme developed to be efficient and fast.

    Proof. We want to prove that if μnμ narrowly, then xμnxμ in Z i.e.

    limn+xμnxμZ=limn+supϕC1,α1|(μnμ,xϕ)|=0.

    Assume that this is not true. Then there exist ε>0, a subsequence (μnk)k that we still denote by (μn)n for simplicity, and functions ϕn, ϕnC1,α1, such that

    |(μnμ,xϕn)|ε>0. (6.1)

    By Arzela-Ascoli theorem, up to a subsequence, ϕnϕ in C1(K) for any compact set KRd. Passing to the limit in |ϕn(x)|1, |ϕn(x)|1, and |ϕn(x)ϕn(y)||xy|α, we obtain that ϕC1,α1. From Theorem 5 in [33], we deduce that

    (μn,xϕn)(μ,xϕ).

    Moreover, from Theorem 4 in [33], we know that the sequence {μn}nN is tight and TV-bounded. It follows that μ is bounded and thus tight. We deduce that

    (μ,xϕn)(μ,xϕ).

    These two facts contradict (6.1).

    Proof. Let {μn}nNM(Rd) be such that μnμ in Z for μZ. Let ϕC1,α(Rd) with ϕC1,α1. Since TC1,α(Rd,Rd) we have ϕTC1,α(Rd) with ϕTC1,αC, independently of ϕ. Then

    |(T#μnT#μm,ϕ)|=|(μnμm,ϕT)|μnμmZϕTC1,αCμnμmZ.

    Thus, T#μnT#μmZCμnμmZ and so the sequence {T#μn}nN is a Cauchy sequence in Z. By completeness of Z, it converges to some element we denote by T#μ. This is indepentent of the choice of the approximating sequence μn because if {˜μn}nNM(Rd) is another sequence such that ˜μnμ in Z then

    |(T˜μnTμn,ϕ)|=|(μn˜μn,ϕT)|CμnμZ+C˜μnμZ

    so that T˜μnTμnZ0. Moreover, for any ϕC1,α(Rd),

    (T#μ,ϕ)=limn(T#μn,ϕ)=lim(μn,ϕT)=(μ,ϕT).

    Proof. First note that map t[0,T]μt is uniformly continuous so there is a nondeacreasing function ω:[0,][0,] with limt0+ω(t)=ω(0)=0 (it is usually called modulus of continuity) such that

    μtμsZω(|ts|)s,t[0,T].

    Given nN, let δn=T/n. We consider the partition {t(n)0,..,t(n)n} of [0,T] with mesh points t(n)k=kδn for k=0,...,n. For each such k, consider a bounded measure μ(n)k such that

    μt(n)kμ(n)kZ1/n.

    Then, we define μ(n)C([0,T],Z) as the polygonal curve passing through the points (t(n)k,μ(n)k), k=0,..,n, namely

    μ(n)t={μ(n)k if t=t(n)k for some k=0,...,n.tt(n)kδnμ(n)k+1+t(n)k+1tδnμ(n)k if t(t(n)k,t(n)k+1) for some k=0,...,n1.

    Clearly, μ(n)C([0,T],Z) and for any n, max0tTμ(n)tTVCn.

    Now, for t[0,T], let ˆt and ˇt be the closest mesh points from left and right respectively. Then,

    μ(n)tμ(n)ˆtZ=t(n)k+1tδnμ(n)ˇtμ(n)ˆtZμ(n)ˇtμ(n)ˆtZ2/n+μˇtμˆtZ2/n+ω(|ˇtˆt|)2/n+ω(δn)

    Therefore, for any t[0,T]:

    μ(n)tμtZμ(n)tμ(n)ˆtZ+μ(n)ˆtμˆtZ+μˆtμtZ(2/n+ω(δn))+1/n+ω(δn)

    Thus limn+max0tTμ(n)tμtZ=0.

    Proof. In view of Lemma 2.2 there exists (νn)nC([0,T],Mb(Rd)) such that limn+νntνtZ=0 uniformly in t[0,T]. For any ϕC1,α(Rd), ϕC1,α1, and any s,t[0,T], we write

    |(T#sνsT#tνt,ϕ)||(T#sνsT#sνns,ϕ)|+|(T#sνnsT#tνnt,ϕ)|+|(T#tνntT#tνt,ϕ)|νsνnsZϕTsC1,α+|(T#sνnsT#tνnt,ϕ)|+νtνntZϕTtC1,α

    In view of Lemma 2.1 and Proposition 2.1 we have ϕTτC1,αCT for any τ[0,T]. Thus

    |(T#sνsT#tνt,ϕ)||(T#sνnsT#tνnt,ϕ)|+2CTmax0tTνtνntZ

    Now, we handle the first term on the right-hand side as follows

    |(T#sνnsT#tνnt,ϕ)||(T#sνnsT#sνnt,ϕ)|+|(T#sνntT#tνnt,ϕ)|νnsνntZϕTsC1,α+νntTVϕTsϕTtCTνnsνntZ+νntTVv|st|.

    Thus,

    |(T#sνsT#tνt,ϕ)|CTνnsνntZ+νntTVv|st|+2CTmax0tTνtνntZ.

    We conclude recalling that for a fixed n, νnt is continuous in t for the Z-norm and TV-bounded uniformly in t[0,T].

    Nicolas Saintier is supported by the University of Buenos Aires through the grant UBACYT 20020170200256BA. Jakub Skrzeczkowski is supported by National Science Center, Poland through project no. 2017/27/B/ST1/01569.

    The authors declare there is no conflicts of interest.



    [1] Abdul Razak F, Ahmad Shahabuddin F, Sarah Nik Zamri N (2019) Analyzing research collaborations within the School of Mathematical Sciences, UKM using Graph Theory. J Physics: Conference Series 1212. https://doi.org/10.1088/1742-6596/1212/1/012033 doi: 10.1088/1742-6596/1212/1/012033
    [2] Abdul Razak F, Expert P (2021) Modelling the Spread of Covid-19 on Malaysian Contact Networks for Practical Reopening Strategies in an Institutional Setting. Sains Malaysiana 50: 1497–1509.
    [3] Ahn K, Cong L, Jang H, et al. (2024) Business cycle and herding behavior in stock returns: Theory and evidence. Financ Innovation 10: 6. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-023-00540-z doi: 10.1186/s40854-023-00540-z
    [4] Aldhamari R, Ku Ismail KNI, Al-Sabri HMH, et al. (2023) Stock market reactions of Malaysian firms and industries towards events surrounding COVID-19 announcements and number of confirmed cases. Pacific Account Rev 35: 390–411. https://doi.org/10.1108/PAR-08-2020-0125 doi: 10.1108/PAR-08-2020-0125
    [5] Ashraf BN (2020) Economic impact of government interventions during the COVID-19 pandemic: International evidence from financial markets. J Behav Exp Financ 27: 100371. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2020.100371 doi: 10.1016/j.jbef.2020.100371
    [6] Aslam F, Mohmand YT, Ferreira P, et al. (2020) Network analysis of global stock markets at the beginning of the coronavirus disease (Covid-19) outbreak. Borsa Istanb Rev 20: S49–S61. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bir.2020.09.003 doi: 10.1016/j.bir.2020.09.003
    [7] Azah N, Othman J, Lugova H, et al. (2020) Malaysia's approach in handling COVID-19 onslaught: Report on the Movement Control Order (MCO) and targeted screening to reduce community infection rate and impact on public health and economy. J Infect Public Heal 13: 1823–1829. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jiph.2020.08.007 doi: 10.1016/j.jiph.2020.08.007
    [8] Bahaludin H, Abdullah MH, Siew LW, et al. (2019) The investigation on the impact of financial crisis on bursa malaysia using minimal spanning tree. Math Stat 7: 1–8. https://doi.org/10.13189/ms.2019.070701 doi: 10.13189/ms.2019.070701
    [9] Bahaludin H, Mahamood FNA, Abdullah MH, et al. (2022) The Impact of the COVID-19 Pandemic on the Interconnectedness of Stocks in Bursa Malaysia. Matematika 38: 69–82. https://doi.org/10.11113/matematika.v38.n2.1355 doi: 10.11113/matematika.v38.n2.1355
    [10] Bahari NN, Azzimi NSM, Ismail M, et al. (n.d.) Comparing the Behaviour of Malaysian Financial Sector Stocks of Pre and During the Coronavirus Outbreak Using Correlation. AIP Conference Proceedings, In press.
    [11] Bahari NN, Expert P, Razak FA (2023) An Analysis of Actors in Malay Films: Small Worlds, Centralities and Genre Diversity. Mathematics 11: 1252. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11051252 doi: 10.3390/math11051252
    [12] Baker SR, Bloom N, Davis SJ, et al. (2020) The unprecedented stock market reaction to COVID-19. Rev Asset Pricing Stud 10: 742–758. https://doi.org/10.1093/rapstu/raaa008 doi: 10.1093/rapstu/raaa008
    [13] Bank Negara Malaysia (2020) Coping with COVID-19: Risk Developments in the First Half of 2020.
    [14] Blondel VD, Guillaume JL, Lambiotte R, et al. (2008) Fast unfolding of communities in large networks. J Stat Mech-Theory E 10: 2–10. https://doi.org/10.1088/1742-5468/2008/10/P10008 doi: 10.1088/1742-5468/2008/10/P10008
    [15] Bouhali H, Dahbani A, Dinar B (2022) How Did Financial Markets Respond to COVID-19 and Governmental Policies During the Different Waves of the Pandemic? Asian Econ Lett 4: 1–5. https://doi.org/10.46557/001c.37191 doi: 10.46557/001c.37191
    [16] Bursa Malaysia (2023) Bursa Malaysia Index Series. Available from: https://www.bursamalaysia.com/trade/our_products_services/indices/bursa_malaysia_index_series.
    [17] Cevik E, Kirci Altinkeski B, Cevik EI, et al. (2022) Investor sentiments and stock markets during the COVID-19 pandemic. Financ Innov 8: 69. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-022-00375-0 doi: 10.1186/s40854-022-00375-0
    [18] Chakrabarti P, Jawed MS, Sarkhel M (2021) COVID-19 pandemic and global financial market interlinkages: a dynamic temporal network analysis. Appl Econ 53: 2930–2945. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2020.1870654 doi: 10.1080/00036846.2020.1870654
    [19] Clauset A, Newman MEJ, Moore C (2004) Finding community structure in very large networks. Phys Rev E 70: 066111. https://doi.org/10.1103/PhysRevE.70.066111 doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.70.066111
    [20] Dellow AA, Ismail M, Bahaludin H, et al. (2024) Comparing the Impacts of Past Major Events on the Network Topology Structure of the Malaysian. J Knowl Econ 2024: 1–43. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-024-02038-0 doi: 10.1007/s13132-024-02038-0
    [21] Dellow AA, Razak F, Ismail M, et al. (n.d.) Comparison of the 2008 Global Financial Crisis, 2015 Stock Market Crash and COVID-19 Pandemic: Impacts on th Consumer Products and Services Sector of Malaysia using Pearson Correlation. AIP Conference Proceedings, In press.
    [22] Deloitte (2020) COVID-19: Impact on Malaysian Financial Institutions and How to Respond. Available from: https://www2.deloitte.com/my/en/pages/risk/articles/covid-19-impact-my-financial-institutions.html.
    [23] Fortunato S (2010) Community detection in graphs. Phys Rep 486: 75–174. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.physrep.2009.11.002 doi: 10.1016/j.physrep.2009.11.002
    [24] Girvan M, Newman MEJ (2002) Community structure in social and biological networks. P Natl Acad Sci Usa 99: 7821–7826. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.122653799 doi: 10.1073/pnas.122653799
    [25] Goodell JW (2020) COVID-19 and finance: Agendas for future research. Financ Res Lett 35: 101512. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101512 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101512
    [26] Haroon O, Rizvi SAR (2020) COVID-19: Media coverage and financial markets behavior—A sectoral inquiry. J Behav Exp Financ 27: 100343. https://doi.org/10.1016/J.JBEF.2020.100343 doi: 10.1016/J.JBEF.2020.100343
    [27] Hassan S, Khodri M, Jati K, et al. (2023) The Impact of COVID-19 on the Malaysia Stock Market: Finance Sector. Int J Adv Res Econ Financ 4: 120–127. https://doi.org/10.55057/ijaref.2022.4.4.13 doi: 10.55057/ijaref.2022.4.4.13
    [28] Hong H, Bian Z, Lee CC (2021) COVID-19 and instability of stock market performance: evidence from the U.S. Financ Innov 7: 1–18. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-021-00229-1 doi: 10.1186/s40854-021-00229-1
    [29] Hu D, Schwabe G, Li X (2015) Systemic risk management and investment analysis with financial network analytics: research opportunities and challenges. Financ Innov 1: 1–9. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-015-0001-x doi: 10.1186/s40854-015-0001-x
    [30] Huang W, Wang H, Wei Y, et al. (2024) Complex network analysis of global stock market co‑movement during the COVID‑19 pandemic based on intraday open‑high‑low‑close data. Financ Innov 10: 7. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-023-00548-5 doi: 10.1186/s40854-023-00548-5
    [31] Hui ECM, Chan KKK (2022) How does Covid-19 affect global equity markets? Financ Innov 8: 25. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-021-00330-5 doi: 10.1186/s40854-021-00330-5
    [32] Keh CG, Tan YT (2021) COVID 19: The impact of government policy responses on economic activity and stock market performance in Malaysia. J Ekonomi Malaysia 55: 123–133. https://doi.org/10.17576/JEM-2021-5501-9 doi: 10.17576/JEM-2021-5501-9
    [33] Kostylenko O, Rodrigues HS, Torres DFM (2019) The spread of a financial virus through Europe and beyond. AIMS Math 4: 86–98. https://doi.org/10.3934/Math.2019.1.86 doi: 10.3934/Math.2019.1.86
    [34] Kumar S, Deo N (2012) Correlation and network analysis of global financial indices. Phys Rev E 86: 1–8. https://doi.org/10.1103/PhysRevE.86.026101 doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.86.026101
    [35] Lancichinetti A, Saramäki J, Kivelä M, et al. (2010) Characterizing the community structure of complex networks. PLoS ONE 5: 1–8. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0011976 doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0011976
    [36] Lee JW, Nobi A (2018) State and Network Structures of Stock Markets Around the Global Financial Crisis. Comput Econ 51: 195–210. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-017-9672-x doi: 10.1007/s10614-017-9672-x
    [37] Li B, Pi D (2018) Analysis of global stock index data during crisis period via complex network approach. PLoS ONE 13: 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0200600 doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0200600
    [38] Liu H, Manzoor A, Wang C, et al. (2020) The COVID-19 Outbreak and Affected Countries Stock Markets Response. Int J Env Res Public Health 17: 2800. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph17082800 doi: 10.3390/ijerph17082800
    [39] Mahamood FNA, Bahaludin H, Abdullah MH (2019) Network analysis of shariah-compliant stocks on Bursa Malaysia by using minimum spanning tree (MST). AIP Conference Proceedings, 2138. https://doi.org/10.1063/1.5121093 doi: 10.1063/1.5121093
    [40] Mamaysky H (2023) News and Markets in the Time of COVID-19. SSRN Electronic J. https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3565597 doi: 10.2139/SSRN.3565597
    [41] Mantegna RN (1999) Hierarchical structure in financial markets. Eur Phys J B 11: 193–197. https://doi.org/10.1007/S100510050929/METRICS doi: 10.1007/S100510050929/METRICS
    [42] Marti G, Nielsen F, Bińkowski M, et al. (2021) A Review of Two Decades of Correlations, Hierarchies, Networks and Clustering in Financial Markets. Prog Inf Geometry-Theor Appl 2021: 245–274. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-65459-7_10 doi: 10.1007/978-3-030-65459-7_10
    [43] Mazur M, Dang M, Vega M (2021) COVID-19 and the march 2020 stock market crash. Evidence from S & P1500. Financ Res Lett 38: 101690. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101690 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101690
    [44] Memon BA (2022) Analysing network structures and dynamics of the Pakistan stock market across the uncertain time of global pandemic (Covid-19). Econ J Emerg Mark 14: 85–100. https://doi.org/10.20885/ejem.vol14.iss1.art7 doi: 10.20885/ejem.vol14.iss1.art7
    [45] Memon BA, Yao H (2019) Structural Change and Dynamics of Pakistan Stock Market during Crisis: A Complex Network Perspective. Entropy 21: 248. https://doi.org/10.3390/E21030248 doi: 10.3390/E21030248
    [46] Memon BA, Yao H (2021) Correlation structure networks of stock market during terrorism: evidence from Pakistan. Data Sci Financ Econ 1: 117–140. https://doi.org/10.3934/dsfe.2021007 doi: 10.3934/dsfe.2021007
    [47] Memon BA, Yao H, Tahir R (2020) General election effect on the network topology of Pakistan's stock market: network-based study of a political event. Financ Innov 6: 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-019-0165-x doi: 10.1186/s40854-019-0165-x
    [48] Millington T, Niranjan M (2021) Stability and similarity in financial networks—How do they change in times of turbulence? Physica A 574: 126016. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.physa.2021.126016 doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2021.126016
    [49] Ming KLY, Jais M (2021) Effectiveness of moving average rules during COVID-19 pandemic: Evidence from Malaysian stock market. J Ekonomi Malaysia 55: 87–98. https://doi.org/10.17576/JEM-2021-5501-6 doi: 10.17576/JEM-2021-5501-6
    [50] Miśkiewicz J, Bonarska-Kujawa D (2022) Evolving network analysis of S & P500 components: Covid-19 influence of cross-correlation network structure. Entropy 24. https://doi.org/10.3390/e24010021 doi: 10.3390/e24010021
    [51] Mohammed GAA, Ali AQA, Mohd NMA, et al. (2021) The Impact of COVID-19 on the Malaysian Stock Market: Evidence from an Autoregressive Distributed Lag Bound Testing Approach. J Asian Financ Econ 8: 1–9. https://doi.org/10.13106/JAFEB.2021.VOL8.NO7.0001 doi: 10.13106/JAFEB.2021.VOL8.NO7.0001
    [52] Mohd Rosli NAI, Tajuddin NII, Ulaganathan P, et al. (2023) Analysis of Stock Market Reaction in Malaysia During Covid-19 Pandemic via ARIMA. Mekatronika 5: 1–12. https://doi.org/10.15282/mekatronika.v5i1.9027 doi: 10.15282/mekatronika.v5i1.9027
    [53] Moody J, Coleman J (2015) Clustering and Cohesion in Networks: Concepts and Measures. 906–912. Elsevier. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.43112-0
    [54] Musa MH, Razak FA (2021) Directed network of Shariah-compliant stock in Bursa Malaysia. J Phys Conference Series 1988: 012019. https://doi.org/10.1088/1742-6596/1988/1/012019 doi: 10.1088/1742-6596/1988/1/012019
    [55] Newman MEJ (2006) Modularity and community structure in networks. P Natl Acad Sci Usa 103: 8577–8582. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0601602103 doi: 10.1073/pnas.0601602103
    [56] Nobi A, Maeng SE, Ha GG, et al. (2014) Effects of global financial crisis on network structure in a local stock market. Physica A 407: 135–143. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.physa.2014.03.083 doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2014.03.083
    [57] Onnela JP, Saramäki J, Kertész J, et al. (2005) Intensity and coherence of motifs in weighted complex networks. Phys Rev E 71: 1–4. https://doi.org/10.1103/PhysRevE.71.065103 doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.71.065103
    [58] Porter MA, Onnela JP, Mucha PJ (2009) Communities in Networks, 56. http://arXiv.org/abs/0902.3788
    [59] Preis T, Kenett DY, Stanley HE, et al. (2012) Quantifying the behavior of stock correlations under market stress. Sci Rep 2: 1–5. https://doi.org/10.1038/srep00752 doi: 10.1038/srep00752
    [60] Qian L, Jiang Y, Long H (2023) What drives the dependence between the Chinese and global stock markets? Mod Financ 1: 12–16. https://doi.org/10.61351/mf.v1i1.5 doi: 10.61351/mf.v1i1.5
    [61] Rehman MU, Ahmad N, Shahzad SJH, et al. (2022) Dependence dynamics of stock markets during COVID-19. Emerg Mark Rev 51: 100894. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ememar.2022.100894 doi: 10.1016/j.ememar.2022.100894
    [62] Rossetti G, Milli L, Cazabet R (2020) CDlib: A python library to extract, compare and evaluate communities from complex networks. CEUR Workshop Proc 2750: 2–5.
    [63] Roy RB, Sarkar UK (2011) Identifying influential stock indices from global stock markets: A social network analysis approach. Procedia Comput Sci 5: 442–449. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.procs.2011.07.057 doi: 10.1016/j.procs.2011.07.057
    [64] Saramäki J, Kivelä M, Onnela JP, et al. (2007) Generalizations of the clustering coefficient to weighted complex networks. Phys Rev E 75: 2–5. https://doi.org/10.1103/PhysRevE.75.027105 doi: 10.1103/PhysRevE.75.027105
    [65] Shah AUM, Safri SNA, Thevadas R, et al. (2020) COVID-19 outbreak in Malaysia: Actions taken by the Malaysian government. Int J Infect Dis 97: 108–116. https://doi.org/10.1016/J.IJID.2020.05.093 doi: 10.1016/J.IJID.2020.05.093
    [66] Song P, Ma X, Zhang X, et al. (2021) The influence of the SARS pandemic on asset prices. Pac-Basin Financ J 67: 101543. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.pacfin.2021.101543 doi: 10.1016/j.pacfin.2021.101543
    [67] Song SI, Yazi E, Morni F, et al. (2021) Covid-19 and Stock Returns: Evidence From Malaysia. Int J Bank Financ 16: 111–140. https://doi.org/10.32890/ijbf2021.16.2.5 doi: 10.32890/ijbf2021.16.2.5
    [68] Sun J, Hou JW (2019) Monetary and Financial Cooperation Between China and the One Belt One Road Countries. Emerg Mark Financ Tr 55: 2609–2627. https://doi.org/10.1080/1540496X.2018.1540976 doi: 10.1080/1540496X.2018.1540976
    [69] Szczygielski JJ, Bwanya PR, Charteris A, et al. (2021) The only certainty is uncertainty: An analysis of the impact of COVID-19 uncertainty on regional stock markets. Financ Res Lett 43: 101945. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2021.101945 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2021.101945
    [70] Topcu M, Gulal OS (2020) The impact of COVID-19 on emerging stock markets. Financ Res Lett 36: 101691. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101691 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101691
    [71] Tse CK, Liu J, Lau FCM (2010) A network perspective of the stock market. J Empir Financ 17: 659–667. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jempfin.2010.04.008 doi: 10.1016/j.jempfin.2010.04.008
    [72] Tumminello M, Aste T, Di Matteo T, et al. (2005) A tool for filtering information in complex systems. P Natl Acad Sci Usa 102: 10421–10426. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0500298102 doi: 10.1073/pnas.0500298102
    [73] Tumminello M, Di Matteo T, Aste T, et al. (2007) Correlation based networks of equity returns sampled at different time horizons. Eur Phys J B 55: 209–217. https://doi.org/10.1140/epjb/e2006-00414-4 doi: 10.1140/epjb/e2006-00414-4
    [74] Wu J, Zhang C, Chen Y (2022) Analysis of risk correlations among stock markets during the COVID-19 pandemic. Int Rev Financ Anal 83: 102220. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2022.102220 doi: 10.1016/j.irfa.2022.102220
    [75] Wu S, Tuo M, Xiong D (2015) Network structure detection and analysis of Shanghai stock market. J Ind Eng Manage 8: 383–398. https://doi.org/10.3926/jiem.1314 doi: 10.3926/jiem.1314
    [76] Xia L, You D, Jiang X, et al. (2018) Comparison between global financial crisis and local stock disaster on top of Chinese stock network. Physica A 490: 222–230. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.physa.2017.08.005 doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2017.08.005
    [77] Yang J, Leskovec J (2015) Defining and evaluating network communities based on ground-truth. Knowl Inf Syst 42: 181–213. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10115-013-0693-z doi: 10.1007/s10115-013-0693-z
    [78] Yao H, Memon BA (2019) Network topology of FTSE 100 Index companies: From the perspective of Brexit. Physica A 523: 1248–1262. https://doi.org/10.1016/J.PHYSA.2019.04.106 doi: 10.1016/J.PHYSA.2019.04.106
    [79] Yaya O, Adenikinju O, Olayinka HA (2024) African stock markets' connectedness: Quantile VAR approach. Mod Financ 2: 51–68. https://doi.org/10.61351/mf.v2i1.70 doi: 10.61351/mf.v2i1.70
    [80] Zhang D, Hu M, Ji Q (2020) Financial markets under the global pandemic of COVID-19. Financ Res Lett 36: 101528. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101528 doi: 10.1016/j.frl.2020.101528
    [81] Zhu B, Zhang S, Zou J, et al. (2023) Structure connectivity and substructure connectivity of data center network. AIMS Math 8: 9877–9889.
    [82] Zuhud DA, Musa MH, Ismail M, et al. (2022) The Causality and Uncertainty of the COVID-19 Pandemic to Bursa Malaysia Financial Services Index's Constituents. Entropy 24. https://doi.org/10.3390/e24081100 doi: 10.3390/e24081100
  • This article has been cited by:

    1. Iftikhar Ahmad, Syed Ibrar Hussain, Hira Ilyas, Juan Luis García Guirao, Adeel Ahmed, Shabnam Rehmat, Tareq Saeed, Numerical solutions of Schrödinger wave equation and Transport equation through Sinc collocation method, 2021, 105, 0924-090X, 691, 10.1007/s11071-021-06596-9
    2. Zuzanna Szymańska, Jakub Skrzeczkowski, Błażej Miasojedow, Piotr Gwiazda, Bayesian inference of a non-local proliferation model, 2021, 8, 2054-5703, 10.1098/rsos.211279
    3. Piotr Gwiazda, Błażej Miasojedow, Jakub Skrzeczkowski, Zuzanna Szymańska, Convergence of the EBT method for a non-local model of cell proliferation with discontinuous interaction kernel, 2023, 43, 0272-4979, 590, 10.1093/imanum/drab102
    4. Lucía Pedraza, Juan Pablo Pinasco, Nicolas Saintier, Pablo Balenzuela, An analytical formulation for multidimensional continuous opinion models, 2021, 152, 09600779, 111368, 10.1016/j.chaos.2021.111368
    5. Sander C. Hille, Esmée S. Theewis, Explicit expressions and computational methods for the Fortet–Mourier distance of positive measures to finite weighted sums of Dirac measures, 2023, 294, 00219045, 105947, 10.1016/j.jat.2023.105947
    6. Christian Düll, Piotr Gwiazda, Anna Marciniak-Czochra, Jakub Skrzeczkowski, Measure differential equation with a nonlinear growth/decay term, 2023, 73, 14681218, 103917, 10.1016/j.nonrwa.2023.103917
    7. Carlo Bianca, Nicolas Saintier, Thermostatted kinetic theory in measure spaces: Well-posedness, 2025, 251, 0362546X, 113666, 10.1016/j.na.2024.113666
    8. Juan Pablo Pinasco, Nicolas Saintier, Martin Kind, Learning, Mean Field Approximations, and Phase Transitions in Auction Models, 2024, 14, 2153-0785, 396, 10.1007/s13235-023-00508-9
  • Reader Comments
  • © 2024 the Author(s), licensee AIMS Press. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0)
通讯作者: 陈斌, bchen63@163.com
  • 1. 

    沈阳化工大学材料科学与工程学院 沈阳 110142

  1. 本站搜索
  2. 百度学术搜索
  3. 万方数据库搜索
  4. CNKI搜索

Metrics

Article views(1967) PDF downloads(66) Cited by(2)

Figures and Tables

Figures(3)  /  Tables(4)

/

DownLoad:  Full-Size Img  PowerPoint
Return
Return

Catalog