This study examines the impact of social learning on consumption and production decisions in a societal context. Individuals learn the actual value of nature through information and subsequent network communication, which is illustrated using the Directed Graph theory and DeGroot social learning process. In this context, individuals with greater access to private information are called "neighbours." Results suggest that in a perfectly rational scenario, individuals have high confidence in their abilities and base their decisions on a combination of personal experience, perception, and intellect; thus, society is expected to converge towards making responsible consumption choices R∗c. However, when individuals are bounded or irrational, they exhibit persuasion bias or stubbornness, and diversity, independence, and decentralization are lacking. It leads to a situation where the consumption network lacks wisdom and may never result in responsible consumption choices. Thus finite, uniformly conspicuous neighbours will swiftly converge towards the opinion of the group. When a large proportion of individuals consume excessively (extravagance) or below the optimal level (misery), the consumption network is dominated by unwise decision-makers, leading to a society that prevents promoting sustainability. In conclusion, this study emphasizes the need for a more rational and informed decision-making process in promoting a sustainable future.
Citation: Syed Sibghatullah Shah, Robinson-Julian Serna, Omaida Sepúlveda Delgado. Modelling the influence of social learning on responsible consumption through directed graphs[J]. Electronic Research Archive, 2023, 31(9): 5161-5206. doi: 10.3934/era.2023264
[1] | Menita Carozza, Luca Esposito, Lorenzo Lamberti . Quasiconvex bulk and surface energies with subquadratic growth. Mathematics in Engineering, 2025, 7(3): 228-263. doi: 10.3934/mine.2025011 |
[2] | Claudia Lederman, Noemi Wolanski . Lipschitz continuity of minimizers in a problem with nonstandard growth. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(1): 1-39. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021009 |
[3] | Luca Capogna, Giovanna Citti, Nicola Garofalo . Regularity for a class of quasilinear degenerate parabolic equations in the Heisenberg group. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(1): 1-31. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021008 |
[4] | Giovanni Scilla, Bianca Stroffolini . Partial regularity for steady double phase fluids. Mathematics in Engineering, 2023, 5(5): 1-47. doi: 10.3934/mine.2023088 |
[5] | Caterina Ida Zeppieri . Homogenisation of high-contrast brittle materials. Mathematics in Engineering, 2020, 2(1): 174-202. doi: 10.3934/mine.2020009 |
[6] | Alessandra De Luca, Veronica Felli . Unique continuation from the edge of a crack. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(3): 1-40. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021023 |
[7] | Piermarco Cannarsa, Rossana Capuani, Pierre Cardaliaguet . C1;1-smoothness of constrained solutions in the calculus of variations with application to mean field games. Mathematics in Engineering, 2019, 1(1): 174-203. doi: 10.3934/Mine.2018.1.174 |
[8] | Zijie Deng, Wenjian Peng, Tian-Yi Wang, Haoran Zhang . Well-posedness of contact discontinuity solutions and vanishing pressure limit for the Aw–Rascle traffic flow model. Mathematics in Engineering, 2025, 7(3): 316-349. doi: 10.3934/mine.2025014 |
[9] | Gennaro Ciampa, Gianluca Crippa, Stefano Spirito . Propagation of logarithmic regularity and inviscid limit for the 2D Euler equations. Mathematics in Engineering, 2024, 6(4): 494-509. doi: 10.3934/mine.2024020 |
[10] | Neil S. Trudinger . On the local theory of prescribed Jacobian equations revisited. Mathematics in Engineering, 2021, 3(6): 1-17. doi: 10.3934/mine.2021048 |
This study examines the impact of social learning on consumption and production decisions in a societal context. Individuals learn the actual value of nature through information and subsequent network communication, which is illustrated using the Directed Graph theory and DeGroot social learning process. In this context, individuals with greater access to private information are called "neighbours." Results suggest that in a perfectly rational scenario, individuals have high confidence in their abilities and base their decisions on a combination of personal experience, perception, and intellect; thus, society is expected to converge towards making responsible consumption choices R∗c. However, when individuals are bounded or irrational, they exhibit persuasion bias or stubbornness, and diversity, independence, and decentralization are lacking. It leads to a situation where the consumption network lacks wisdom and may never result in responsible consumption choices. Thus finite, uniformly conspicuous neighbours will swiftly converge towards the opinion of the group. When a large proportion of individuals consume excessively (extravagance) or below the optimal level (misery), the consumption network is dominated by unwise decision-makers, leading to a society that prevents promoting sustainability. In conclusion, this study emphasizes the need for a more rational and informed decision-making process in promoting a sustainable future.
Dedicated to Giuseppe Mingione on the occasion of his 50th birthday, with admiration.
In this paper we provide a limiting partial regularity criterion for vector-valued minimizers u:Ω⊂Rn→RN, n≥2, N>1, of nonhomogeneous, quasiconvex variational integrals as:
W1,p(Ω;RN)∋w↦F(w;Ω):=∫Ω[F(Dw)−f⋅w]dx, | (1.1) |
with standard p-growth. More precisely, we infer the optimal [31, Section 9] ε-regularity condition
supBϱ⋐Ωϱm−∫Bϱ|f|mdx≲ε⟹ Du has a.e. bounded mean oscillation, |
and the related borderline function space criterion
f∈L(n,∞) ⟹ supBϱ⋐Ωϱm−∫Bϱ|f|mdx≲ε. |
This is the content of our main theorem.
Theorem 1.1. Under assumptions (1.6)1,2,3, (1.7) and (1.10), let u∈W1,p(Ω,RN) be a local minimizer of functional (1.1). Then, there exists a number ε∗≡ε∗(data)>0 such that if
‖f‖Ln,∞(Ω)≤(|B1|4n/m)1/nε∗, | (1.2) |
then there exists an open set Ωu⊂Ω with |Ω∖Ωu|=0 such that
Du∈BMOloc(Ωu;RN×n). | (1.3) |
Moreover, the set Ωu can be characterized as follows
Ωu:={x0∈Ω:∃εx0,ϱx0>0such that E(u;Bϱ(x0))≤εx0 for some ϱ≤ϱx0}, |
where E(⋅) is the usual excess functional defined as
E(w,z0;Bϱ(x0)):=( −∫Bϱ(x0)|z0|p−2|Dw−z0|2+|Dw−z0|p dx)1p. | (1.4) |
We immediately refer to Section 1.2 below for a description of the structural assumptions in force in Theorem 1.1. Let us put our result in the context of the available literature. The notion of quasiconvexity was introduced by Morrey [38] in relation to the delicate issue of semicontinuity of multiple integrals in Sobolev spaces: an integrand F(⋅) is a quasiconvex whenever
−∫B1(0)F(z+Dφ)dx≥F(z)holds for all z∈RN×n, φ∈C∞c(B1(0),RN). | (1.5) |
Under power growth conditions, (1.5) is proven to be necessary and sufficient for the sequential weak lower semicontinuity on W1,p(Ω;RN); see [1,4,35,36,38]. It is worth stressing that quasiconvexity is a strict generalization of convexity: the two concepts coincide in the scalar setting (N=1), or for 1-d problems (n=1), but sharply differ in the multidimensional case: every convex function is quasiconvex thanks to Jensen's inequality, while the determinant is quasiconvex (actually polyconvex), but not convex, cf. [24, Section 5.1]. Another distinctive trait is the nonlocal nature of quasiconvexity: Morrey [38] conjectured that there is no condition involving only F(⋅) and a finite number of its derivatives that is both necessary and sufficient for quasiconvexity, fact later on confirmed by Kristensen [29]. A peculiarity of quasiconvex functionals is that minima and critical points (i.e., solutions to the associated Euler-Lagrange system) might have very different behavior under the (partial) regularity viewpoint. In fact, a classical result of Evans [22] states that the gradient of minima is locally Hölder continuous outside a negligible, " singular" set, while a celebrated counterexample due to Müller and Šverák [39] shows that the gradient of critical points may be everywhere discontinuous. After Evans seminal contribution [22], the partial regularity theory was extended by Acerbi and Fusco [2] to possibly degenerate quasiconvex functionals with superquadratic growth, and by Carozza, Fusco and Mingione [8] to subquadratic, nonsingular variational integrals. A unified approach that allows simultaneously handling degenerate/nondegenerate, and singular/nonsingular problems, based on the combination of A-harmonic approximation [21], and p-harmonic approximation [20], was eventually proposed by Duzaar and Mingione [19]. Moreover, Kristensen and Mingione [30] proved that the Hausdorff dimension of the singular set of Lipschitz continuous minimizers of quasiconvex multiple integrals is strictly less than the ambient space dimension n, see also [5] for further developments in this direction. We refer to [3,15,16,25,26,27,28,37,41,42] for an (incomplete) account of classical, and more recent advances in the field. In all the aforementioned papers are considered homogeneous functionals, i.e., f≡0 in (1.1). The first sharp ε-regularity criteria for nonhomogeneous quasiconvex variational integrals guaranteeing almost everywhere gradient continuity under optimal assumptions on f were obtained by De Filippis [12], and De Filippis and Stroffolini [14], by connecting the classical partial regularity theory for quasiconvex functionals with nonlinear potential theory for degenerate/singular elliptic equations, first applied in the context of partial regularity for strongly elliptic systems by Kuusi and Mingione [33]. Potential theory for nonlinear PDE originates from the classical problem of determining the best condition on f implying gradient continuity in the Poisson equation −Δu=f, that turns out to be formulated in terms of the uniform decay to zero of the Riesz potential, in turn implied by the membership of f to the Lorentz space L(n,1), [9,31]. In this respect, a breakthrough result due to Kuusi and Mingione [32,34] states that the same is true for the nonhomogeous, degenerate p-Laplace equation–in other words, the regularity theory for the nonhomogeneous p-Laplace PDE coincides with that of the Poisson equation up to the C1-level. This important result also holds in the case of singular equations [18,40], for general, uniformly elliptic equations [6], up to the boundary [10,11,13], and at the level of partial regularity for p-Laplacian type systems without Uhlenbeck structure, [7,33]. We conclude by highlighting that our Theorem 1.1 fits this line of research as, it determines for the first time in the literature optimal conditions on the inhomogeneity f assuring partial BMO-regularity for minima of quasiconvex functionals expressed in terms of the limiting function space L(n,∞).
In Section 2 we recall some well-known results from the study of nonlinear problems also establishing some Caccioppoli and Gehring type lemmas. In Section 3 we prove the excess decay estimates; considering separately the nondegenerate and the degenerate case. Section 4 is devoted to the proof of Theorem 1.1.
In (1.1), the integrand F:RN×n→R satisfies
{ F∈C2loc(RN×n) Λ−1|z|p≤F(z)≤Λ|z|p |∂2F(z)|≤Λ|z|p−2 |∂2F(z1)−∂2F(z2)|≤μ(|z2−z1||z2|+|z1|)(|z1|2+|z2|2)p−22 | (1.6) |
for all z∈RN×n, Λ≥1 being a positive absolute constant and μ:[0,∞)→[0,1] being a concave nondecreasing function with μ(0)=0. In the rest of the paper we will always assume p≥2. In order to derive meaningful regularity results, we need to update (1.5) to the stronger strict quasiconvexity condition
∫B[F(z+Dφ)−F(z)] dx≥λ∫B(|z|2+|Dφ|2)p−22|Dφ|2dx, | (1.7) |
holding for all z∈RN×n and φ∈W1,p0(B,RN), with λ being a positive, absolute constant. Furthermore, we allow the integrand F(⋅) to be degenerate elliptic in the origin. More specifically, we assume that F(⋅) features degeneracy of p-Laplacian type at the origin, i.e.,
| ∂F(z)−∂F(0)−|z|p−2z|z|p−1 |→0as|z|→0, | (1.8) |
which means that we can find a function ω:(0,∞)→(0,∞) such that
|z|≤ω(s) ⟹ |∂F(z)−∂F(0)−|z|p−2z|≤s|z|p−1, | (1.9) |
for every z∈RN×n and all s∈(0,∞). Moreover, the right-hand side term f:Ω→RN in (1.1) verifies as minimal integrability condition the following
f∈Lm(Ω,RN)with 2>m>{ 2n/(n+2)if n>2, 3/2if n=2, | (1.10) |
which, being p≥2, in turn implies that
f∈W1,p(Ω,RN)∗andm′<2∗≤p∗. | (1.11) |
Here it is intended that, when p≥n, the Sobolev conjugate exponent p∗ can be chosen as large as needed - in particular it will always be larger than p. By (1.5) and (1.6)2 we have
|∂F(z)|≤c|z|p−1, | (1.12) |
with c≡c(n,N,Λ,p); see for example [35, proof of Theorem 2.1]. Finally, (1.7) yields that for all z∈RN×n, ξ∈RN, ζ∈Rn it is
∂2F(z)⟨ξ⊗ζ,ξ⊗ζ⟩≥2λ|z|p−2|ξ|2|ζ|2, | (1.13) |
see [24, Chapter 5].
In this section we display our notation and collect some basic results that will be helpful later on.
In this paper, Ω⊂Rn is an open, bounded domain with Lipschitz boundary, and n≥2. By c we will always denote a general constant larger than one, possibly depending on the data of the problem. Special occurrences will be denoted by c∗,˜c or likewise. Noteworthy dependencies on parameters will be highlighted by putting them in parentheses. Moreover, to simplify the notation, we shall array the main parameters governing functional (1.1) in the shorthand data:=(n,N,λ,Λ,p,μ(⋅),ω(⋅)). By Br(x0):={x∈Rn:|x−x0|<r}, we denote the open ball with radius r, centred at x0; when not necessary or clear from the context, we shall omit denoting the center, i.e., Br(x0)≡Br - this will happen, for instance, when dealing with concentric balls. For x0∈Ω, we abbreviate dx0:=min{1,dist(x0,∂Ω)}. Moreover, with B⊂Rn being a measurable set with bounded positive Lebesgue measure 0<|B|<∞, and a:B→Rk, k≥1, being a measurable map, we denote
(a)B≡−∫Ba(x) dx:=1|B|∫Ba(x)dx. |
We will often employ the almost minimality property of the average, i.e.,
( −∫B|a−(a)B|tdx)1/t≤2( −∫B|a−z|tdx)1/t | (2.1) |
for all z∈RN×n and any t≥1. Finally, if t>1 we will indicate its conjugate by t′:=t/(t−1) and its Sobolev exponents as t∗:=nt/(n−t) if t<n or any number larger than one for t≥n and t∗:=max{nt/(n+t),1}.
When dealing with p-Laplacian type problems, we shall often use the auxiliary vector field Vs:RN×n→RN×n, defined by
Vs(z):=(s2+|z|2)(p−2)/4zwithp∈(1,∞), s≥0, z∈RN×n, |
incorporating the scaling features of the p-Laplacian. If s=0 we simply write Vs(⋅)≡V(⋅). A couple of useful related inequalities are
{ |Vs(z1)−Vs(z2)|≈(s2+|z1|2+|z2|2)(p−2)/4|z1−z2|, |Vs(z1+z2)|≲|Vs(z1)|+|Vs(z2)|, |Vs1(z)|≈|Vs2(z)|, if 12s2≤s1≤2s2, |V(z1)−V(z2)|2≈|V|z1|(z1−z2)|2, if 12|z2|≤|z1|≤2|z2|, | (2.2) |
and
|Vs(z)|2≈sp−2|z|2+|z|pwith p≥2, | (2.3) |
where the constants implicit in " ≲", " ≈" depend on n,N,p. A relevant property which is relevant for the nonlinear setting is recorded in the following lemma.
Lemma 2.1. Let t>−1, s∈[0,1] and z1,z2∈RN×n be such that s+|z1|+|z2|>0. Then
∫10[s2+|z1+y(z2−z1)|2]t2 dy≈(s2+|z1|2+|z2|2)t2, |
with constants implicit in "≈" depending only on n,N,t.
The following iteration lemma will be helpful throughout the rest of the paper; for a proof we refer the reader to [24, Lemma 6.1].
Lemma 2.2. Let h:[ϱ0,ϱ1]→R be a non-negative and bounded function, and let θ∈(0,1), A,B,γ1,γ2≥0 be numbers. Assume that h(t)≤θh(s)+A(s−t)−γ1+B(s−t)−γ2 holds for all ϱ0≤t<s≤ϱ1. Then the following inequality holds h(ϱ0)≤c(θ,γ1,γ2)[A(ϱ1−ϱ0)−γ1+B(ϱ1−ϱ0)−γ2].
We will often consider the "quadratic" version of the excess functional defined in (1.4), i.e.,
˜E(w,z0;Bϱ(x0)):=( −∫Bϱ(x0)|V(Dw)−z0|2dx)12. | (2.4) |
In the particular case z0=(Dw)Bϱ(x0) (z0=(V(Dw))Bϱ(x0), resp.) we shall simply write E(w,(Dw)Bϱ(x0);Bϱ(x0))≡E(w;Bϱ(x0)) (˜E(w,(V(Dw))Bϱ(x0);Bϱ(x0))≡˜E(w;Bϱ(x0)), resp.). A simple computation shows that
E(w;Bϱ(x0))p/2≈˜E(w;Bϱ(x0)). | (2.5) |
Moreover, from (2.1) and from [23, Formula (2.6)] we have that
˜E(w;Bϱ(x0))≈˜E(w,V((Dw)Bϱ(x0));Bϱ(x0)). | (2.6) |
In this section we collect some basic estimates for local minimizers of nonhomogeneous quasiconvex functionals. We start with a variation of the classical Caccioppoli inequality accounting for the presence of a nontrivial right-hand side term, coupled with an higher integrability result of Gehring-type.
Lemma 2.3. Under assumptions (1.6)1,2,3, (1.7) and (1.10), let u∈W1,p(Ω,RN) be a local minimizer of functional (1.1).
● For every ball Bϱ(x0)⋐Ω and any u0∈RN, z0∈RN×n∖{0} it holds that
E(u,z0;Bϱ/2(x0))p≤c−∫Bϱ(x0)|z0|p−2|u−ℓϱ|2+|u−ℓϱ|pdx+c|z0|p−2(ϱm−∫Bϱ(x0)|f|m dx)2m, | (2.7) |
where E(⋅) is defined in (1.4), ℓ(x):=u0+⟨z0,x−x0⟩ and c≡c(n,N,λ,Λ,p).
● There exists an higher integrability exponent p2≡p2(n,N,λ,Λ,p)>p such that Du∈Lp2loc(Ω,RN×n) and the reverse Hölder inequality
( −∫Bϱ/2(x0)|Du−(Du)Bϱ(x0)|p2dx)1p2≤c( −∫Bϱ(x0)|Du|pdx)1p+c(ϱm−∫Bϱ(x0)|f|mdx)1m(p−1), | (2.8) |
is verified for all balls Bϱ(x0)⋐Ω with c≡c(n,N,λ,Λ,p).
Proof. For the ease of exposition, we split the proof in two steps, each of them corresponding to the proof of (2.7) and (2.8) respectively.
Step 1: proof of (2.7).
We choose parameters ϱ/2≤τ1<τ2≤ϱ, a cut-off function η∈C1c(Bτ2(x0)) such that 1Bτ1(x0)≤η≤1Bτ2(x0) and |Dη|≲(τ2−τ1)−1. Set φ1:=η(u−ℓ), φ2:=(1−η)(u−ℓ) and use (1.7) and the equivalence in (2.2)1 to estimate
c∫Bτ2(x0)|V|z0|(Dφ1)|2 dx≤∫Bτ2(x0)[F(z0+Dφ1)−F(z0)]dx=∫Bτ2(x0)[F(Du−Dφ2)−F(Du)]dx+∫Bτ2(x0)[F(Du)−F(Du−Dφ1)]dx+∫Bτ2(x0)[F(z0+Dφ2)−F(z0)]dx=:I1+I2+I3, | (2.9) |
where we have used the simple relation Dφ1+Dφ2=Du−z0. Terms I1 and I3 can be controlled as done in [19, Proposition 2]; indeed we have
I1+I3≤c∫Bτ2(x0)∖Bτ1(x0)|V|z0|(Dφ2)|2dx+c∫Bτ2(x0)∖Bτ1(x0)|V|z0|(Du−z0)|2dx(2.2)2≤c∫Bτ2(x0)∖Bτ1(x0)|V|z0|(Du−z0)|2+| V|z0|(u−ℓτ2−τ1) |2dx, | (2.10) |
for c≡c(n,N,λ,Λ,p). Concerning term I2, we exploit (1.10), the fact that φ1∈W1,p0(Bτ2(x0),RN) and apply Sobolev-Poincaré inequality to get
I2≤|Bτ2(x0)|(τm2−∫Bτ2(x0)|f|m dx)1/m(τ−m′2−∫Bτ2(x0)|φ1|m′ dx)1m′≤|Bτ2(x0)|(τm2−∫Bτ2(x0)|f|m dx)1/m( −∫Bτ2(x0)| φ1τ2 |2∗ dx)12∗≤|Bτ2(x0)|(τm2−∫Bτ2(x0)|f|mdx)1/m( −∫Bτ2(x0)|Dφ1|2dx)12≤ε∫Bτ2(x0)|V|z0|(Dφ1)|2dx+c|Bϱ(x0)|ε|z0|p−2(ϱm−∫Bϱ(x0)|f|mdx)2m, | (2.11) |
where c≡c(n,N,m) and we also used that ϱ/2≤τ2≤ϱ. Merging the content of the two above displays, recalling that η≡1 on Bτ1(x0) and choosing ε>0 sufficiently small, we obtain
∫Bτ1(x0)|V|z0|(Du−z0)|2dx≤c∫Bτ2(x0)∖Bτ1(x0)|V|z0|(Du−z0)|2+| V|z0|(u−ℓτ2−τ1) |2dx+c|Bϱ(x0)||z0|p−2(ϱm−∫Bϱ(x0)|f|mdx)2m, |
with c≡c(n,N,λ,Λ,p). At this stage, the classical hole-filling technique, Lemma 2.2 and (2.3) yield (2.7) and the first bound in the statement is proven.
Step 2: proof of (2.8).
To show the validity of (2.8), we follow [33, proof of Proposition 3.2] and first observe that if u is a local minimizer of functional F(⋅) on Bϱ(x0), setting fϱ(x):=ϱf(x0+ϱx), the map uϱ(x):=ϱ−1u(x0+ϱx) is a local minimizer on B1(0) of an integral with the same integrand appearing in (1.1) satisfying (1.6)1,2,3 and fϱ replacing f. This means that (2.10) still holds for all balls Bσ/2(˜x)⊆Bτ1(˜x)⊂Bτ2(˜x)⊆Bσ(˜x)⋐B1(0), with ˜x∈B1(0) being any point, in particular it remains true if |z0|=0, while condition |z0|≠0 was needed only in the estimate of term I2 in (2.11), that now requires some change. So, in the definition of the affine map ℓ we choose z0=0, u0=(uϱ)Bσ(˜x) and rearrange estimates (2.10) and (2.11) as:
I1+I3(2.3)≤c∫Bτ2(˜x)∖Bτ1(˜x)|Duϱ|p+| uϱ−(uϱ)Bσ(˜x)τ2−τ1 |pdx, |
and, recalling that φ1∈W1,p0(Bτ2(˜x),RN), via Sobolev Poincaré, Hölder and Young inequalities and (1.11)2, we estimate
I2≤|Bτ2(˜x)|(τ(p∗)′2−∫Bτ2(˜x)|fϱ|(p∗)′ dx)1(p∗)′(τ−p∗2−∫Bτ2(˜x)|φ1|p∗ dx)1p∗≤c|Bτ2(˜x)|(τ(p∗)′2−∫Bτ2(˜x)|fϱ|(p∗)′dx)1(p∗)′( −∫Bτ2(˜x)|Dφ1|pdx)1p≤c|Bσ(˜x)|ε1/(p−1)(σ(p∗)′−∫Bσ(˜x)|fϱ|(p∗)′dx)p(p∗)′(p−1)+ε∫Bτ2(˜x)|Dφ1|pdx, |
with c≡c(n,N,p). Plugging the content of the two previous displays in (2.9), reabsorbing terms and applying Lemma 2.2, we obtain
−∫Bσ/2(˜x)|Duϱ|p dx≤c −∫Bσ(˜x)| uϱ−(uϱ)Bσ(˜x)σ |p dx+c(σ(p∗)′−∫Bσ(˜x)|fϱ|(p∗)′dx)p(p∗)′(p−1), | (2.12) |
for c≡c(n,N,Λ,λ,p). Notice that
n(p(p∗)′(p−1)−1)≤pp−1, | (2.13) |
with equality holding when p<n, while for p≥n any value of p∗>1 will do. We then manipulate the second term on the right-hand side of (2.12) as
(σ(p∗)′−∫Bσ(˜x)|fϱ|(p∗)′dx)p(p∗)′(p−1)≤σpp−1−n(p(p∗)′(p−1)−1)( −∫B1(0)|fϱ|(p∗)′ dx)p(p∗)′(p−1)−1−∫Bσ(˜x)|fϱ|(p∗)′dx(2.13)≤( −∫B1(0)|fϱ|(p∗)′ dx)p(p∗)′(p−1)−1−∫Bσ(˜x)|fϱ|(p∗)′ dx=:−∫Bσ(˜x)|Kϱfϱ|(p∗)′ dx, |
where we set
K(p∗)′ϱ:=|B1(0)|1−p(p∗)′(p−1)‖fϱ‖pp−1−(p∗)′L(p∗)′(B1(0)). |
Plugging the content of the previous display in (2.12) and applying Sobolev-Poincaré inequality we get
−∫Bσ/2(˜x)|Duϱ|pdx≤c( −∫Bσ(˜x)|Duϱ|p∗ dx)pp∗+c −∫Bσ(˜x)|Kϱfϱ|(p∗)′ dx, |
with c≡c(n,N,Λ,λ,p). Now we can apply a variant of Gehring lemma [24, Corollary 6.1] to determine a higher integrability exponent s≡s(n,N,Λ,λ,p) such that 1<s≤m/(p∗)′ and
( −∫Bσ/2(˜x)|Duϱ|spdx)1sp≤c( −∫Bσ(˜x)|Duϱ|pdx)1p+cK(p∗)′/pϱ( −∫Bσ(˜x)|fϱ|s(p∗)′ dx)1sp |
for c≡c(n,N,Λ,λ,p). Next, notice that
K(p∗)′/pϱ=( −∫B1(0)|fϱ|(p∗)′dx)1(p∗)′(p−1)−1p≤( −∫B1(0)|fϱ|s(p∗)′dx)1s(p∗)′(p−1)−1sp, |
so plugging this last inequality in (2.14) and recalling that s(p∗)′≤m, we obtain
( −∫Bσ/2(˜x)|Duϱ|spdx)1sp≤c( −∫Bσ(˜x)|Duϱ|pdx)1p+c( −∫Bσ(˜x)|fϱ|m dx)1m(p−1). |
Setting p2:=sp>p above and recalling that ˜x∈B1(0) is arbitrary, we can fix ˜x=0, scale back to Bϱ(x0) and apply (2.1) to get (2.8) and the proof is complete.
In this section we prove some excess decay estimates considering separately two cases: when a smallness condition on the excess functional of our local minimizer u is satisfied and when such an estimate does not hold true.
We start working assuming that a suitable smallness condition on the excess functional E(u;Bϱ(x0)) is fulfilled. In particular, we prove the following proposition.
Proposition 3.1. Under assumptions (1.6)1,2,3, (1.7) and (1.10), let u∈W1,p(Ω,RN) be a local minimizer of functional (1.1). Then, for τ0∈(0,2−10), there exists ε0≡ε0(data,τ0)∈(0,1) and ε1≡ε1(data,τ0)∈(0,1) such that the following implications hold true.
● If the conditions
E(u;Bϱ(x0))≤ε0|(Du)Bϱ(x0)|, | (3.1) |
and
(ϱm−∫Bϱ(x0)|f|m dx)1m≤ε1|(Du)Bϱ(x0)|p−22E(u;Bϱ(x0))p2, | (3.2) |
are verified on Bϱ(x0), then it holds that
E(u;Bτ0ϱ(x0))≤c0τβ00E(u;Bϱ(x0)), | (3.3) |
for all β0∈(0,2/p), with c0≡c0(data)>0.
● If condition (3.1) holds true and
(ϱm−∫Bϱ(x0)|f|m dx)1m>ε1|(Du)Bϱ(x0)|p−22E(u;Bϱ(x0))p2, | (3.4) |
is satisfied on Bϱ(x0), then
E(u;Bτ0ϱ(x0))≤c0(ϱm−∫Bϱ(x0)|f|m dx)1m(p−1), | (3.5) |
for c0≡c0(data)>0.
Proof of Proposition 3.1. For the sake of readability, since all balls considered here are concentric to Bϱ(x0), we will omit denoting the center. Moreover, we will adopt the following notation (Du)Bς(x0)≡(Du)ς and, for all φ∈C∞c(Bϱ;RN), we will denote ‖Dφ‖L∞(Bϱ)≡‖Dφ‖∞. We spilt the proof in two steps.
Step 1: proof of (3.3).
With no loss of generality we can assume that E(u;Bϱ)>0, which clearly implies, thanks to (3.1), that |(Du)ϱ|>0.
We begin proving that condition (3.1) implies that
−∫Bϱ|Du|pdx≤c|(Du)ϱ|p, | (3.6) |
for a constant c≡c(p,ε0)>0. Indeed,
−∫Bϱ|Du|pdx≤c −∫Bϱ|Du−(Du)ϱ|pdx+c|(Du)ϱ|p(1.4)≤cE(u;Bϱ)p+c|(Du)ϱ|p(3.1)≤c(εp0+1)|(Du)ϱ|p, |
and (3.6) follows.
Consider now
Bϱ∋x↦u0(x):=|(Du)ϱ|p−22(u(x)−(u)ϱ−⟨(Du)ϱ,x−x0⟩)E(u;Bϱ)p/2, | (3.7) |
and
d:=(E(u;Bϱ)|(Du)ϱ|)p2. |
Let us note that we have
−∫Bϱ|Du0|2dx+dp−2−∫Bϱ|Du0|pdx≤|(Du)ϱ|p−2E(u;Bϱ)p−∫Bϱ|Du−(Du)ϱ|2dx+(E(u;Bϱ)|(Du)ϱ|)p(p−2)2|(Du)ϱ|p(p−2)2E(u;Bϱ)p22−∫Bϱ|Du−(Du)ϱ|pdx≤1E(u;Bϱ)p−∫Bϱ|(Du)ϱ|p−2|Du−(Du)ϱ|2dx+1E(u;Bϱ)p−∫Bϱ|Du−(Du)ϱ|pdx≤1. |
Since |(Du)ϱ|>0 we have that the hypothesis of [12, Lemma 3.2] are satisfied with
A:=∂2F((Du)ϱ)|(Du)ϱ|2−p. | (3.8) |
Then,
| −∫BϱA⟨Du0,Dφ⟩ dx|≤c‖Dφ‖∞|(Du)ϱ|2−p2E(u;Bϱ)p2(ϱm−∫Bϱ|f|m dx)1m+c‖Dφ‖∞μ(E(u;Bϱ)|(Du)ϱ|)1p[1+(E(u;Bϱ)|(Du)ϱ|)p−22](3.1),(3.2)≤cε1‖Dφ‖∞+c‖Dφ‖∞μ(ε0)1p[1+εp−220]. |
Fix ε>0 and let δ≡δ(data,ε)>0 be the one given by [33, Lemma 2.4] and choose ε0 and ε1 sufficiently small such that
cε1+cμ(ε0)1p[1+εp−220]≤δ. | (3.9) |
With this choice of ε0 and ε1 it follows that u0 is almost A-harmonic on Bϱ, in the sense that
| −∫BϱA⟨Du0,Dφ⟩ dx|≤δ‖Dφ‖∞, |
with A as in (3.8). Hence, by [33, Lemma 2.4] we obtain that there exists h0∈W1,2(Bϱ;RN) which is A-harmonic, i.e.,
∫BϱA⟨Dh0,Dφ⟩ dx=0for all φ∈C∞c(Bϱ;RN), |
such that
−∫B3ϱ/4|Dh0|2dx+dp−2−∫B3ϱ/4|Dh0|pdx≤82np, | (3.10) |
and
−∫B3ϱ/4|u0−h0ϱ|2+dp−2|u0−h0ϱ|pdx≤ε. | (3.11) |
We choose now τ0∈(0,2−10), which will be fixed later on, and estimate
−∫B2τ0ϱ|u0(x)−h0(x0)−⟨Dh0(x0),x−x0⟩τ0ϱ|2dx≤c−∫B2τ0ϱ|h0(x)−h0(x0)−⟨Dh0(x0),x−x0⟩τ0ϱ|2dx+c−∫B2τ0ϱ|u0−h0τ0ϱ|2dx(3.11)≤c(τ0ϱ)2supBϱ/2|D2h0|2+cετn+20≤cτ20−∫B3ϱ/4|Dh0|2dx+cετn+20(3.10)≤cτ20+cετn+20, | (3.12) |
where c≡c(data)>0 and where we have used the following property of A-harmonic functions
ϱγsupBϱ/2|D2h0|γ≤c−∫B3ϱ/4|Dh0|γdx, | (3.13) |
with γ>1 and c depending on n, N, and on the ellipticity constants of A.
Now, choosing
ε:=τn+2p0, |
we have that this together with (3.9) gives that ε0≡ε0(data,τ0) and ε1≡ε1(data,τ0). Recalling the definition of u0 in (3.7) and (3.12) we eventually arrive at
−∫B2τ0ϱ|u−(u)ϱ−⟨(Du)ϱ,x−x0⟩−|(Du)ϱ|2−p2E(u;Bϱ)p/2(h0(x0)−⟨Dh0(x0),x−x0⟩)|2(τ0ϱ)2dx≤c|(Du)ϱ|2−pE(u;Bϱ)pτ20, | (3.14) |
for c≡c(data)>0. By a similar computation, always using (3.13), (3.10) and (3.11), we obtain that
dp−2−∫B2τ0ϱ|u0−h0(x0)−⟨Dh0(x0),x−x0⟩τ0ϱ|pdx≤cdp−2(τ0ϱ)psupBϱ/2|D2h0|p+cετn+p0≤cτp0. |
In this way, as for (3.14), by the definition of u0 in (3.7), we eventually arrive at
−∫B2τ0ϱ|u−(u)ϱ−⟨(Du)ϱ,x−x0⟩−|(Du)ϱ|2−p2E(u;Bϱ)p/2(h0(x0)−⟨Dh0(x0),x−x0⟩)|p(τ0ϱ)pdx≤cd2−p|(Du)ϱ|p(2−p)2E(u;Bϱ)p22τp0≤cE(u;Bϱ)pτ20, | (3.15) |
with c≡c(data).
Denote now with ℓ2τ0ϱ the unique affine function such that
ℓ2τ0ϱ↦minℓ affine−∫B2τ0ϱ|u−ℓ|2dx. |
Hence, by (3.14) and (3.15), we conclude that
−∫B2τ0ϱ|(Du)ϱ|p−2|u−ℓ2τ0ϱ2τ0ϱ|2+|u−ℓ2τ0ϱ2τ0ϱ|pdx≤cτ2E(u;Bϱ)p. | (3.16) |
Notice that we have also used the property that
−∫Bϱ|u−ℓϱ|pdx≤c−∫Bϱ|u−ℓ|pdx, |
for , and for any affine function ; see [33, Lemma 2.3].
Recalling the definition of the excess functional , in (1.4), we can estimate the following quantity as follows
(3.17) |
where we have used the following property of the affine function
for a constant ; see for example [33, Lemma 2.2].
Now, starting from (3.1) and (3.9), we further reduce the size of such that
(3.18) |
where is the same constant appearing in (3.17). Thus, combining (3.17) and (3.18), we get
(3.19) |
The information provided by (3.18) combined with (3.16) allow us to conclude that
(3.20) |
By triangular inequality and (3.19) we also get
which, therefore, implies that
(3.21) |
where . By triangular inequality, we can further estimate
where . We now separately estimate the previous integrals. We begin considering . By Young and triangular inequalities we get
with . In a similar fashion, we can treat the integral
where we have used the following property of the affine function
for a given constant ; see [33, Lemma 2.2]. Finally, the last integral can be treated recalling (3.21) and (2.1), i.e.,
All in all, combining the previous estimate
up to choosing such that
Step 2: proof of (3.5).
The proof follows by [12, Lemma 2.4] which yields
Multiplying both sides by we get the desired estimate.
It remains to considering the case when condition (3.1) does not hold true. We start with two technical lemmas. The first one is an analogous of the Caccioppoli inequality (2.7), where we take in consideration the eventuality .
Lemma 3.1. Under assumptions (1.6), (1.7) and (1.10), let be a local minimizer of functional (1.1). For every ball and any , it holds that
(3.22) |
where is defined in (1.4), and .
Proof. The proof is analogous to estimate (2.7), up to treating in a different way the term in (2.9), taking in consideration the eventuality . Exploiting (1.10) and fact that , an application of the Sobolev-Poincaré inequality yields
(3.23) |
where and we also used that . Hence, proceeding as in the proof of (2.7), we obtain that
with . Concluding as in the proof of (2.7), we eventually arrive at (3.22).
Lemma 3.2. Under assumptions (1.6), (1.7) and (1.10), let be a local minimizer of functional (1.1). For any and any it holds that
(3.24) |
for any , with .
Proof. Given the regularity properties of the integrand , we have that a local minimizer of (1.1) solves weakly the following integral identity (see [42, Lemma 7.3])
(3.25) |
Now, fix and split
We begin estimating the first integral . For we get
(3.26) |
On the other hand, the integral can be estimated as follows
Combining the inequalities above we obtain (3.24).
In this setting the analogous result of Proposition 3.1 is the following one.
Proposition 3.2. Under assumptions (1.6), (1.7) and (1.10), let be a local minimizer of functional (1.1). Then, for any and any , there exists such that if the smallness conditions
(3.27) |
are satisfied on a ball , then
(3.28) |
for any , with is the exponent in (3.34), and .
Proof. We adopt the same notations used in the proof of Proposition 3.1. Let us begin noticing that condition (3.27) implies the following estimate
(3.29) |
Indeed, by (1.4) and (3.27), we have
Consider now
for , which will be fixed later on. Applying (3.24) to the function yields
For any and and let be the one given by [17, Lemma 1.1]. Then, up to choosing , and sufficiently small, we arrive at
Then, Lemma 1.1 in [17] implies
up to taking as small as needed. Now, denoting with , we have that
Now, we choose , with being the exponent given by (2.8). Note that by the proof of (2.8) it actually follows that . Thus, choosing (where is given by (3.34)) we arrive at
By Hölder's Inequality, we have that
(3.30) |
Hence, since by (2.3) , an application of estimates (2.8) and (3.29) now yields
(3.31) |
with .
On the other hand, by classical properties of -harmonic functions, we have that
(3.32) |
Hence, combining (3.30)–(3.32), we get that
(3.33) |
Let us recall that, for any , given the -harmonic function we have
(3.34) |
Moreover, using Jensen's Inequality we can estimate the following difference as follows
Thus, up to taking sufficiently small, by the triangular inequality, we obtain that
Hence, (2.2) yield
and
Then,
and the desired estimate (3.28) follows.
This section is devoted to the proof of Theorem 1.1. First, we prove the following proposition.
Proposition 4.1. Under assumptions (1.6), (1.7) and (1.10), let be a local minimizer of functional (1.1). Then, there exists such that if the following condition
(4.1) |
is satisfied on , for some , then
(4.2) |
for .
Proof. For the sake of readability, since all balls considered in the proof are concentric to , we will omit denoting the center.
Let us start fixing an exponent such that
(4.3) |
where and are the exponents appearing in Propositions 3.1 and 3.2. Moreover, given the constant and from Propositions 3.1 and 3.2, choose such that
(4.4) |
With the choice of as in (4.4) above, we can determine the constant and of Proposition 3.1. Now, we proceed applying Proposition 3.2 taking and as in (4.4) there. This determines the constant and . We consider a ball such that
(4.5) |
and
(4.6) |
where the constant , with appearing in (3.5) and in (3.28). In particular, see that by (4.5) and (4.6) we are in the case when (4.1) does hold true.
Now, we recall Proposition 3.2. Seeing that is satisfied (being (4.5)) we only check whether is verified too. If is satisfied then we obtain from (3.28), with in (4.4) that
(4.7) |
where the last inequality follows from (4.5) and (4.6). If on the other hand it holds , by Proposition 3.1, then by (3.3) or (3.5) we eventually arrive at the same estimate (4.7).
Iterating now the seam argument we arrive at
and the estimate
holds true. By the inequality above we have that for any
Applying a standard interpolation argument we conclude that, for any , it holds
(4.8) |
where . The desired estimate (4.2) now follows.
Proof of Theorem 1.1. We proceed following the same argument used in [33, Theorem 1.5]. We star proving that, for any and any , with positive measure, we have that
(4.9) |
Indeed, fix which will be chosen later on. Then, we have that
(4.10) |
The first integral on the righthand side of (4.10) can be estimated in the following way
On the other hand, the second integral can be estimated recalling the definition of the -norm. Indeed,
Hence, putting all the estimates above in (4.10), choosing , we obtain (4.9).
Now, recalling condition (1.2) we have that
where is the one obtained in the proof of Proposition 4.1. From this it follows that, we can choose a radius such that
(4.11) |
We want to show that the set appearing in (1.3) can be characterized by
thus fixing and . We first star noting that the the set defined in (1.4) is such that . Indeed, let us consider the set
(4.12) |
which is such that by standard Lebesgue's Theory. Moreover, by (2.5) it follows that
so that, and we eventually obtained that . Now we show that is open. Let us fix and find a radius such that
(4.13) |
By absolute continuity of the functional we have that there exists an open neighbourhood such that, for any it holds
(4.14) |
This prove that is open. Now let us start noting that (4.11) and (4.14) yield that condition (4.1) is satisfied with . Hence, an application of Proposition 4.1 yields
for any . Thus concluding the proof.
The authors declare they have not used Artificial Intelligence (AI) tools in the creation of this article.
The author is supported by INdAM Projects "Fenomeni non locali in problemi locali", CUP_E55F22000270001 and "Problemi non locali: teoria cinetica e non uniforme ellitticità", CUP_E53C220019320001, and also by the Project "Local vs Nonlocal: mixed type operators and nonuniform ellipticity", CUP_D91B21005370003.
The author declares no conflict of interest.
[1] |
R. A. McNamara, A. K. Willard, A. Norenzayan, J. Henrich, Weighing outcome vs intent across societies: How cultural models of mind shape moral reasoning, Cognition, 182 (2019), 95–108. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cognition.2018.09.008 doi: 10.1016/j.cognition.2018.09.008
![]() |
[2] |
A. V. Banerjee, A simple model of herd behaviour, Q. J. Econ., 107 (1992), 797–817. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118364 doi: 10.2307/2118364
![]() |
[3] |
S. Bikhchandani, D. Hirshleifer, I. Welch, A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades, J. Political Econ., 100 (1992), 992–1026. https://doi.org/10.1086/261849 doi: 10.1086/261849
![]() |
[4] |
J. R. French Jr, A formal theory of social power, Psychol. Rev., 63 (1956), 181. https://doi.org/10.1037/h0046123 doi: 10.1037/h0046123
![]() |
[5] |
F. Harary, On the measurement of structural balance, Behav. Sci., 4 (1959), 316–323. https://doi.org/10.1002/bs.3830040405 doi: 10.1002/bs.3830040405
![]() |
[6] | T. DeAngelis, Consumerism and its discontents, Monit. Psychol., 35 (2004), 52. |
[7] |
M. S. Granovetter, The strength of weak ties, Am. J. Sociol., 78 (1973), 1360–1380. https://doi.org/10.1086/225469 doi: 10.1086/225469
![]() |
[8] |
M. H. DeGroot, Reaching a consensus, J. Am. Stat. Assoc., 69 (1974), 118–121. https://doi.org/10.1080/01621459.1974.10480137 doi: 10.1080/01621459.1974.10480137
![]() |
[9] |
K. Rrmoku, B. Selimi, L. Ahmedi, Application of trust in recommender systems—Utilizing naive bayes classifier, Computation, 10 (2022), 6. https://doi.org/10.3390/computation10010006 doi: 10.3390/computation10010006
![]() |
[10] |
A. Orland, M. Padubrin, Is there a gender hiring gap in academic economics? Evidence from a network analysis, R. Soc. Open Sci., 9 (2022), 210717. https://doi.org/10.1098/rsos.210717 doi: 10.1098/rsos.210717
![]() |
[11] |
B. Golub, M. O. Jackson, Naive learning in social networks and the wisdom of crowds, Am. Econ. J.: Microeconomics, 2 (2010), 112–149. https://doi.org/10.1257/mic.2.1.112 doi: 10.1257/mic.2.1.112
![]() |
[12] | C. D. Meyer, I. Stewart, Matrix Analysis and Applied Linear Algebra, Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, 2023. https://doi.org/10.1137/1.9781611977448.fm |
[13] |
J. Ensor, B. Harvey, Social learning and climate change adaptation: evidence for international development practice, Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Clim. Change, 6 (2015), 509–522. https://doi.org/10.1002/wcc.348 doi: 10.1002/wcc.348
![]() |
[14] |
C. Tanner, S. W. Kast, Promoting sustainable consumption: Determinants of green purchases by Swiss consumers, Psychol. Mark., 20 (2003), 883–902. https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.10101 doi: 10.1002/mar.10101
![]() |
[15] |
P. W. Schultz, J. M. Nolan, R. B. Cialdini, N. J. Goldstein, V. Griskevicius, The constructive, destructive, and reconstructive power of social norms, Psychol. Sci., 18 (2007), 429–434. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9280.2007.01917.x doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9280.2007.01917.x
![]() |
[16] |
A. R. Brough, J. E. B. Wilkie, J. Ma, M. S. Isaac, D. Gal, Is eco-friendly unmanly? The green-feminine stereotype and its effect on sustainable consumption, J. Consum. Res., 43 (2016), 567–582. https://doi.org/10.1093/jcr/ucw044 doi: 10.1093/jcr/ucw044
![]() |
[17] |
E. Graham-Rowe, D. C. Jessop, P. Sparks, Identifying motivations and barriers to minimising household food waste, Resour. Conserv. Recycl., 84 (2014), 15–23. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2013.12.005 doi: 10.1016/j.resconrec.2013.12.005
![]() |
[18] |
N. Hynes, J. Wilson, I do it, but don't tell anyone! Personal values, personal and social norms: Can social media play a role in changing pro-environmental behaviours, Technol. Forecasting Social Change, 111 (2016), 349–359. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2016.06.034 doi: 10.1016/j.techfore.2016.06.034
![]() |
[19] |
I. Vermeir, W. Verbeke, Sustainable food consumption: Exploring the consumer "attitude–behavioral intention" gap, J. Agric. Environ. Ethics, 19 (2006), 169–194. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10806-005-5485-3 doi: 10.1007/s10806-005-5485-3
![]() |
[20] |
A. Kenis, E. Mathijs, (De)politicising the local: The case of the Transition Towns movement in Flanders (Belgium), J. Rural Stud., 34 (2014), 172–183. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2014.01.013 doi: 10.1016/j.jrurstud.2014.01.013
![]() |
[21] | F. Rattalino, Circular advantage anyone? Sustainability‐driven innovation and circularity at Patagonia, Inc., Thunderbird Int. Bus. Rev., 60 (2018), 747–755. https://doi.org/10.1002/tie.21917 |
[22] |
M. A. Delmas, S. Pekovic, Environmental standards and labor productivity: Understanding the mechanisms that sustain sustainability, J. Organ. Behav., 34 (2013), 230–252. https://doi.org/10.1002/job.1827 doi: 10.1002/job.1827
![]() |
[23] |
G. Spaargaren, Sustainable consumption: a theoretical and environmental policy perspective, Soc. Nat. Resour., 16 (2003), 687–701. https://doi.org/10.1080/08941920309192 doi: 10.1080/08941920309192
![]() |
[24] | E. B. Goldsmith, Social Influence and Sustainable Consumption, Springer International Publishing, 2015. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-20738-4 |
[25] | A. Bandura, R. H. Walters, Social Learning Theory, 1977. |
[26] |
M. Yang, H. Chen, R. Long, J. Yang, The impact of different regulation policies on promoting green consumption behavior based on social network modeling, Sustainable Prod. Consumption, 32 (2022), 468–478. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spc.2022.05.007 doi: 10.1016/j.spc.2022.05.007
![]() |
[27] |
M. Yang, H. Chen, R. Long, J. Yang, How does government regulation shape residents' green consumption behavior? A multi-agent simulation considering environmental values and social interaction, J. Environ. Manage., 331 (2023), 117231. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2023.117231 doi: 10.1016/j.jenvman.2023.117231
![]() |
[28] |
K. Farrow, G. Grolleau, L. Ibanez, Social norms and pro-environmental behavior: A review of the evidence, Ecol. Econ., 140 (2017), 1–13. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.04.017 doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.04.017
![]() |
[29] | D. Centola, How Behavior Spreads: The Science of Complex Contagions, Princeton University Press, 2018. |
[30] |
H. A. Salazar, L. Oerlemans, S. van Stroe‐Biezen, Social influence on sustainable consumption: evidence from a behavioural experiment, Int. J. Consum. Stud., 37 (2013), 172–180. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1470-6431.2012.01110.x doi: 10.1111/j.1470-6431.2012.01110.x
![]() |
[31] |
R. B. Cialdini, R. R. Reno, C. A. Kallgren, A focus theory of normative conduct: Recycling the concept of norms to reduce littering in public places, J. Pers. Social Psychol., 58 (1990), 1015. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.58.6.1015 doi: 10.1037/0022-3514.58.6.1015
![]() |
[32] | M. Newman, Networks, Oxford University Press, 2018. |
[33] |
G. Buenstorf, C. Cordes, Can sustainable consumption be learned? A model of cultural evolution, Ecol. Econ., 67 (2008), 646–657. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.01.028 doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.01.028
![]() |
[34] |
S. Barr, G. Andrew, Sustainable lifestyles: Framing environmental action in and around the home, Geoforum, 37 (2006), 906–920. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geoforum.2006.05.002 doi: 10.1016/j.geoforum.2006.05.002
![]() |
[35] |
R. K. Jain, R. Gulbinas, J. E. Taylor, P. J. Culligan, Can social influence drive energy savings? Detecting the impact of social influence on the energy consumption behavior of networked users exposed to normative eco-feedback, Energy Build., 66 (2013), 119–127. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enbuild.2013.06.029 doi: 10.1016/j.enbuild.2013.06.029
![]() |
[36] |
R. B. Cialdini, N. J. Goldstein, Social influence: Compliance and conformity, Annu. Rev. Psychol., 55 (2004), 591–621. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.psych.55.090902.142015 doi: 10.1146/annurev.psych.55.090902.142015
![]() |
[37] |
S. F. Salem, A. B. Alanadoly, Personality traits and social media as drivers of word-of-mouth towards sustainable fashion, J. Fashion Mark. Manage., 25 (2021), 24–44. https://doi.org/10.1108/jfmm-08-2019-0162 doi: 10.1108/jfmm-08-2019-0162
![]() |
[38] |
M. Jaeger-Erben, J. Rückert-John, M. Schäfer, Sustainable consumption through social innovation: a typology of innovations for sustainable consumption practices, J. Cleaner Prod., 108 (2015), 784–798. https://doi.org/10.1016/J.JCLEPRO.2015.07.042 doi: 10.1016/J.JCLEPRO.2015.07.042
![]() |
[39] |
S. S. Shah, T. Shah, Responsible consumption choices and individual values: an algebraic interactive approach, Mind Soc., 2023 (2023), 1–32. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11299-023-00294-2 doi: 10.1007/s11299-023-00294-2
![]() |
[40] |
P. C. Stern, Information, incentives, and proenvironmental consumer behavior, J. Consum. Policy, 22 (1999), 461–478. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1006211709570 doi: 10.1023/A:1006211709570
![]() |
[41] |
D. J. Watts, P. S. Dodds, Influentials, networks, and public opinion formation, J. Consum. Res., 34 (2007), 441–458. https://doi.org/10.1086/518527 doi: 10.1086/518527
![]() |
[42] |
D. Heckerman, Bayesian networks for data mining, Data Min. Knowl. Discovery, 1 (1997), 79–119. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1009730122752 doi: 10.1023/A:1009730122752
![]() |
[43] | J. Surowiecki, The Wisdom of Crowds, Anchor, 2005. |
[44] | N. Gilbert, K. Troitzsch, Simulation for the Social Scientist, McGraw-Hill Education (UK), 2005. |
[45] | J. M. Epstein, R. Axtell, Growing Artificial Societies: Social Science from the Bottom Up, Brookings Institution Press, 1996. |
[46] |
Z. Yang, Y. Zhao, Energy consumption, carbon emissions, and economic growth in India: Evidence from directed acyclic graphs, Econ. Modell., 38 (2014), 533–540. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2014.01.030 doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2014.01.030
![]() |
[47] | L. C. Freeman, visualizing social networks, J. Social Struct., 1 (2000), 4. |
[48] | A. Gionis, F. P. P. Junqueira, V. Le Roy, M. Serafini, I. Weber, Piggybacking on social networks, in VLDB 2013-39th International Conference on Very Large Databases, (2013), 409–420. |
[49] |
Y. Bramoullé, H. Djebbari, B. Fortin, Identification of peer effects through social networks, J. Econom., 150 (2009), 41–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2008.12.021 doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2008.12.021
![]() |
[50] |
K. Basu, A. Sen, Identifying individuals associated with organized criminal networks: a social network analysis, Social Networks, 64 (2021), 42–54. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socnet.2020.07.009 doi: 10.1016/j.socnet.2020.07.009
![]() |
[51] |
M. Schlüter, A. Baeza, G. Dressler, K. Frank, J. Groeneveld, W. Jager, et al., A framework for mapping and comparing behavioral theories in models of social-ecological systems, Ecol. Econ., 131 (2017), 21–35. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2016.08.008 doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2016.08.008
![]() |
[52] |
H. Dittmar, Perceived material wealth and first impressions, Br. J. Social Psychol., 31 (1992), 379–391. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.2044-8309.1992.tb00980.x doi: 10.1111/j.2044-8309.1992.tb00980.x
![]() |
[53] | R. W. Belk, Possessions and the extended self, J. Consum. Res., 15 (1988), 139–168. |
[54] |
E. J. McCann, Race, protest, and public space: Contextualizing Lefebvre in the US city, Antipode, 31 (1999), 163–184. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8330.00098 doi: 10.1111/1467-8330.00098
![]() |
[55] | F. Harary, R. Z. Norman, Graph Theory as A Mathematical Model in Social Science, No. 2. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, Institute for Social Research, 1953. |
[56] |
D. Acemoglu, A. Ozdaglar, A. Tahbaz-Salehi, Systemic risk and stability in financial networks, Am. Econ. Rev., 105 (2015), 564–608. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20130456 doi: 10.1257/aer.20130456
![]() |
[57] | S. Wasserman, K. Faust, Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications, 1994. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511815478 |
[58] |
X. Gong, D. J. Higham, K. Zygalakis, Directed network Laplacians and random graph models, R. Soc. Open Sci., 8 (2021), 211144. https://doi.org/10.1098/rsos.211144 doi: 10.1098/rsos.211144
![]() |
[59] |
R. S. MacKay, S. Johnson, B. Sansom, How directed is a directed network, R. Soc. Open Sci., 7 (2020), 201138. https://doi.org/10.1098/rsos.201138 doi: 10.1098/rsos.201138
![]() |
[60] | R. A. Horn, C. R. Johnson, Matrix Analysis, Cambridge university press, 2012. |
[61] |
S. Friedland, S. Gaubert, L. Han, Perron-Frobenius theorem for nonnegative multilinear forms and extensions, Linear Algebra Appl., 438 (2013), 738–749. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.laa.2011.02.042 doi: 10.1016/j.laa.2011.02.042
![]() |
[62] | M. O. Jackson, Social and Economic Networks, Princeton: Princeton university press, 2008. |
[63] | B. Golub, M. O. Jackson, How homophily affects diffusion and learning in networks, preprint, arXiv: 0811.4013. |
[64] | B. Golub, E. Sadler, Learning in Social Networks, 2017. http://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2919146 |
[65] | D. H. Meadows, E. I. Goldsmith, P. Meadow, The Limits to Growth, London: Earth Island Limited, 1972. |
[66] | P. A. Latta, "The Tragedy of the Commons" By Garrett Hardin, in Introduction to Sustainable Development, 1 (2009), 98. |
[67] | W. McDonough, M. Braungart, Cradle to Cradle: Remaking the Way We Make Things, North Point Press, 2010. |
[68] | M. O. Jackson, The friendship paradox and systematic biases in perceptions and social norms, J. Political Econ., 127 (2019), 777–818. |
[69] | F. S. Fitzgerald, The Great Gatsby: F. Scott Fitzgerald, CreateSpace, 2015. |
[70] |
A. Shleifer, R. W. Vishny, The limits of arbitrage, J. Finance, 52 (1997), 35–55. https://doi.org/10.2307/2329555 doi: 10.2307/2329555
![]() |
[71] | T. Veblen, The Theory of The Leisure Class: An Economic Study of Institutions, 2005. |
[72] |
V. Bala, S. Goyal, Learning from neighbours, Rev. Econ. Stud., 65 (1998), 595–621. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-937X.00059 doi: 10.1111/1467-937X.00059
![]() |
[73] | J. A. Fisher, Eric Hoffer: Implications for a Social Theory of Communication, PhD thesis, University of Kansas, 1971. |
[74] | R. Descartes, Discourse on the Method of Rightly Conducting the Reason, and Seeking Truth in the Sciences, Sutherland and Knox, 1850. |
[75] | B. Spinoza, Spinoza: Complete Works, Hackett Publishing, 2002. |
[76] | T. Scitovsky, The Joyless Economy: The Psychology of Human Satisfaction, Oxford University Press, USA, 1992. |
[77] |
P. Sheeran, L. W. Thomas, The intention-behavior gap, Social Pers. Psychol. Compass, 10 (2016), 503–518. https://doi.org/10.1111/spc3.12265 doi: 10.1111/spc3.12265
![]() |
[78] |
D. Oyserman, M. Destin, Identity-based motivation: Implications for intervention, Couns. Psychologist, 38 (2010), 1001–1043. https://doi.org/10.1177/0011000010374775 doi: 10.1177/0011000010374775
![]() |
[79] | F. Walsh, Loss and resilience in the time of COVID‐19: Meaning making, hope, and transcendence, Fam. Process, 59 (2020), 898–911. https://doi.org/10.1111/famp.12588 |
[80] | R. J. Hobbs, E. S. Higgs, C. Hall, Novel Ecosystems: Intervening in the New Ecological World Order, John Wiley & Sons, 2013. https://doi.org/10.1002/9781118354186 |
[81] | C. Eisenstein, The More Beautiful World Our Hearts Know Is Possible, North Atlantic Books, 2013. |
[82] | J. R. P. French Jr, A formal theory of social power, Psychol. Rev., 63 (1956), 181. |
[83] |
L. Smith, P. Sørensen, Pathological outcomes of observational learning, Econometrica, 68 (2000), 371–398. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00113 doi: 10.1111/1468-0262.00113
![]() |
[84] |
R. Defila, A. Di Giulio, The concept of "consumption corridors" meets society: How an idea for fundamental changes in consumption is received, J. Consum. Policy, 43 (2020), 315–344. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10603-019-09437-w doi: 10.1007/s10603-019-09437-w
![]() |
[85] |
L. Milios, A. E. Davani, Y. Yu, Sustainability impact assessment of increased plastic recycling and future pathways of plastic waste management in Sweden, Recycling, 3 (2018), 33. https://doi.org/10.3390/recycling3030033 doi: 10.3390/recycling3030033
![]() |
[86] | D. Moscato, The brand behind the activism: Patagonia's domination campaign and the evolution of corporate social responsibility, Case Stud. Strategic Commun., 5 (2016). |
[87] | S. Munawar, Bhutan Improves Economic Development as A Net Carbon Sink, The Climate Institute, 2016. Available from: http://climate.org/bhutan-improves-economic-development-as-a-net-carbon-sink/. |
[88] | R. C. Anderson, Sustainability and the bottom line: The responsible collusion of economics, social responsibility, and the environment, J. Values-Based Leadersh., 2 (2009), 2. |
[89] |
C. A. Hunt, W. H. Durham, L. Driscoll, M. Honey, Can ecotourism deliver real economic, social, and environmental benefits? A study of the Osa Peninsula, Costa Rica, J. Sustainable Tourism, 23 (2015), 339–357. https://doi.org/10.1080/09669582.2014.965176 doi: 10.1080/09669582.2014.965176
![]() |
[90] |
M. Haider, R. Shannon, G. P. Moschis, Sustainable consumption research and the role of marketing: A review of the literature (1976–2021), Sustainability, 14 (2022), 3999. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14073999 doi: 10.3390/su14073999
![]() |
[91] |
A. Chwialkowska, W. A. Bhatti, M. Glowik, The influence of cultural values on pro-environmental behavior, J. Cleaner Prod., 268 (2020), 122305. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.122305 doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.122305
![]() |
[92] |
L. Liu, C. M. K. Cheung, M. K. O. Lee, An empirical investigation of information sharing behavior on social commerce sites, Int. J. Inf. Manage., 36 (2016), 686–699. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijinfomgt.2016.03.013 doi: 10.1016/j.ijinfomgt.2016.03.013
![]() |
[93] |
Y. Fang, M. Perc, H. Zhang, A game theoretical model for the stimulation of public cooperation in environmental collaborative governance, R. Soc. Open Sci., 9 (2022), 221148. https://doi.org/10.1098/rsos.221148 doi: 10.1098/rsos.221148
![]() |
[94] |
D. Fudenberg, D. M. Kreps, Learning in extensive-form games I. Self-confirming equilibria, Games Econ. Behav., 8 (1995), 20–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0899-8256(05)80016-8 doi: 10.1016/S0899-8256(05)80016-8
![]() |
[95] |
P. M. DeMarzo, D. Vayanos, J. Zwiebel, Persuasion bias, social influence, and unidimensional opinions, Q. J. Econ., 118 (2003), 909–968. https://doi.org/10.1162/00335530360698469 doi: 10.1162/00335530360698469
![]() |
[96] | A. J. Hoffman, H. W. Wielandt, The variation of the spectrum of a normal matrix, in Selected Papers of Alan J Hoffman: With Commentary, (2003), 118–120. https://doi.org/10.1142/9789812796936_0011 |
[97] |
M. Mobius, T. Rosenblat, Social learning in economics, Annu. Rev. Econ., 6 (2014), 827–847. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-120213-012609 doi: 10.1146/annurev-economics-120213-012609
![]() |
[98] |
J. Grujić, T. Lenaerts, Do people imitate when making decisions? Evidence from a spatial prisoner's dilemma experiment, R. Soc. Open Sci., 7 (2020), 200618. https://doi.org/10.1098/rsos.200618 doi: 10.1098/rsos.200618
![]() |
[99] | K. Lee, M. Greenstone, Air Quality Life Index Annual Update, Energy Policy Institute, University of Chicago, 2021. |
[100] |
D. Pearce, F. E. Putz, J. K. Vanclay, Sustainable forestry in the tropics: panacea or folly, For. Ecol. Manage., 172 (2003), 229–247. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0378-1127(01)00798-8 doi: 10.1016/S0378-1127(01)00798-8
![]() |
[101] | C. Wright, D. Nyberg, D. Grant, "Hippies on the third floor": Climate change, narrative identity and the micro-politics of corporate environmentalism, Organ. Stud., 33 (2012), 1451–1475. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840612463316 |
[102] |
D. Jaffee, R. A. Case, Draining us dry: Scarcity discourses in contention over bottled water extraction, Local Environ., 23 (2018), 485–501. https://doi.org/10.1080/13549839.2018.1431616 doi: 10.1080/13549839.2018.1431616
![]() |
[103] |
A. E. Bernardo, I. Welch, On the evolution of overconfidence and entrepreneurs, J. Econ. Manage. Strategy, 10 (2001), 301–330. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1430-9134.2001.00301.x doi: 10.1111/j.1430-9134.2001.00301.x
![]() |
[104] |
N. M. Lambert, F. D. Fincham, T. F. Stillman, Gratitude and depressive symptoms: The role of positive reframing and positive emotion, Cognit. Emotion, 26 (2012), 615–633. https://doi.org/10.1080/02699931.2011.595393 doi: 10.1080/02699931.2011.595393
![]() |
[105] |
T. F. Stillman, F. D. Fincham, K. D. Vohs, N. M. Lambert, C. A. Phillips, The material and immaterial in conflict: Spirituality reduces conspicuous consumption, J. Econ. Psychol., 33 (2012), 1–7. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2011.08.012 doi: 10.1016/j.joep.2011.08.012
![]() |
[106] |
E. Assadourian, Transforming cultures: From consumerism to sustainability, J. Macromarketing, 30 (2010), 186–191. https://doi.org/10.1177/0276146710361932 doi: 10.1177/0276146710361932
![]() |
[107] |
L. R. Morgan, G. Birtwistle, An investigation of young fashion consumers' disposal habits, Int. J. Consum. Stud., 33 (2009), 190–198. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1470-6431.2009.00756.x doi: 10.1111/j.1470-6431.2009.00756.x
![]() |
[108] |
M. Jiang, P. Behrens, T. Wang, Z. Tang, Y. Yu, D. Chen, et al., Provincial and sector-level material footprints in China, PNAS, 116 (2019), 26484–26490. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1903028116 doi: 10.1073/pnas.1903028116
![]() |
[109] | T. Clarke, M. Boersma, The governance of global value chains: Unresolved human rights, environmental and ethical dilemmas in the apple supply chain, J. Bus. Ethics, 143 (2017), 111–131. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-015-2781-3 |
[110] |
V. T. Dang, N. Nguyen, S. Pervan, Retailer corporate social responsibility and consumer citizenship behavior: The mediating roles of perceived consumer effectiveness and consumer trust, J. Retailing Consum. Serv., 55 (2020), 102082. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2020.102082 doi: 10.1016/j.jretconser.2020.102082
![]() |
[111] | S. S. Shah, Z. Asghar, Dynamics of social influence on consumption choices: A social network representation, Heliyon, 9 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2023.e17146 |